1. Introduction
Chronic diseases, such as diabetes mellitus and hypertension, represent a major threat to public health and socioeconomic development globally. According to data from the World Health Organization, approximately 41 million people die from noncommunicable chronic diseases annually, accounting for 74% of global deaths. Characterized by prolonged duration and persistent progression, these conditions entail a high risk of developing a number of adverse outcomes (AOs), such as disease recurrence and complications, significantly impairing patients’ quality of life while imposing substantial cost burdens on both individuals and the whole healthcare system.
A follow-up policy, comprising scheduled checkups during a defined post-discharge period, has proven effective in delaying chronic disease progression and preventing AOs, thereby controlling medical costs. In practice, however, most hospitals do not implement structured follow-up policies, as they face no mandate to do so and would incur additional costs. Typically, patients are advised to conduct a follow-up based on clinical practice guidelines and their providers’ clinical experience. This ad hoc approach often lacks continuity, potentially leading to increased AOs and associated costs. In an effort to contain healthcare expenditures, the United States enacted the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act in 2010. This legislation spurred new payment programs designed to replace the traditional fee-for-service (FFS) model that has long been criticized for lacking preventive care incentives. Among these innovations, healthcare warranties (inspired by product warranty concepts [
1,
2]) have gained significant attention due to their effectiveness. Under such a warranty, hospitals receive a bundled payment covering all services during initial hospitalization and a predefined post-discharge warranty period, regardless of the actual cost incurred by patients [
3,
4]. If a patient experiences an AO during the warranty period, the hospital will deliver treatment at no additional cost to the patient. By transferring the financial risk from patients to providers, warranties incentivize hospitals to proactively implement continuous follow-up policies to mitigate AO risks and costs. At present, healthcare warranties are applied not only in specific organizations, such as ProvenCare in Geisinger [
5] and PROMETHEUS [
6], but also nationwide, such as in the Bundled Payments for Care Improvement (BPCI) and BPCI advanced models proposed by the Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS) [
7,
8]. Similar practices have emerged in other countries. For instance, in China’s Anhui Province, public hospitals began to implement healthcare warranties for patients with appendicitis in 2011, adopting a policy that bundles payment for the initial admission and any readmission within 15 days after discharge [
9]. Similarly, in Germany, hospitals receive a lump-sum payment covering the initial treatment and any readmissions occurring within a certain time period [
10]. The chronic diseases involved in warranty practices include diabetes mellitus, cardiovascular disease, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease, etc. [
11,
12,
13].
However, some hospitals contend that they are penalized unfairly by the healthcare warranty reimbursement scheme, since the AOs occurrence depends heavily on patient behavior, which is not controllable by the hospitals [
14]. Effective disease management indeed necessitates collaborative efforts between hospitals and patients to achieve optimal outcomes. The successful delay and control of disease progression largely depends on patients’ self-management practices, such as lifestyle modifications and regular monitoring of relevant health indicators [
15,
16]. In such situations, even well-designed follow-up policies fail to deliver value without patient adherence to scheduled protocols. Implementing cost-sharing for these policies serves a dual purpose: motivating proactive disease management while ensuring compliance, thereby guaranteeing intervention effectiveness. This interdependence makes pricing decisions for follow-up policies strategically crucial. Elevated pricing discourages patient participation, whereas insufficient pricing risks hospital losses and service discontinuation. Therefore, it is necessary to study the pricing of follow-up policies under healthcare warranties from the perspectives of both patients and hospitals to achieve win–win outcomes.
Our work is relevant to two streams of research: (i) follow-up policy optimization, (ii) healthcare warranty pricing.
Follow-up policy optimization. There has been a growing body of research on follow-up policy design and optimization for chronic disease. Helm et al. [
17] optimized the timing of the next follow-up based on a current visit for glaucoma patients through an integrated model of Kalman filtering and mathematical programming. Based on this work, Kazemian et al. [
18] developed a linear quadratic Gaussian state space model to simultaneously optimize follow-up timing and modality, as well as control thresholds for key risk indicators. Some research utilized Markov decision processes (MDPs) to investigate sequential follow-up policies involving decisions at predetermined intervals [
19,
20]. Additional studies optimized finite-horizon follow-up policies, under which follow-up timing and modalities over a specified period are determined simultaneously, focusing either on maximizing the policy’s detection rate for potential AOs [
21] or enhancing the checkup’s ability to reduce AO risk [
22,
23]. The aforementioned studies lay the analytical foundation for our work on follow-up policy cost and associated healthcare warranty cost estimation. However, while these studies aim to optimize the timing and modalities of a follow-up policy, our research focuses on determining the win–win interval price for follow-up policies based on relevant cost analysis.
Healthcare warranty pricing. BP practices typically determine package prices based on the average historical cost of providing the services. For example, ProvenCare’s case rate for CABG patients encompasses not only the historical average cost of all follow-up care and rehospitalizations for postoperative complications within 90 days of surgery, but also approximately 50% of the mean cost of all related postoperative readmissions derived from a two-year historical financial comparison group [
24]. Similarly, PROMETHEUS proposes evidence-informed case rates comprising three cost components: base services, severity adjusters, and potentially avoidable complications—all calculated from historical data [
25]. The BPCI sets episode prices based on a discounted aggregation of historical payments for services preciously rendered during such episodes [
26]. However, these retrospective pricing approaches fail to account for the efficiency or effectiveness of service delivery. To address this limitation, recent research has developed alternative pricing models. For instance, Hellsten et al. developed innovative clinically informed pricing models for BP by leveraging clinical standards and regional variations, using Ontario stroke care as a case study [
27]. Cher et al. [
28] devised an empirical Bayes approach to calculate target prices for BPCI, while Tanwar et al. [
29] established an efficient pricing interval, bounded by profit maximization and risk minimization values, for fixed price contracts.
Crucially, existing research relies on current healthcare warranty practices, wherein follow-up services and other necessary care are bundled. When pricing such packages, the cost of complications or readmissions receives significant attention, whereas follow-up costs are overlooked. Yet follow-up expenses depend on diverse factors: the frequency and efficacy of checkups, patient risk levels, and other variables. Consequently, follow-up costs can constitute a substantial portion of warranty pricing. Ignoring these costs may discourage patients from proactively managing their conditions. Furthermore, current studies adopt singular perspectives, either the payer’s or the hospital’s, neglecting patient considerations. An equitable price must balance the needs of both patients and hospitals. It should encourage patients’ willingness to pay for follow-up services while ensuring hospitals’ acceptance of their delivery.
To bridge these gaps, this paper proposes a theoretical mathematical modeling framework to investigate the pricing of follow-up policies for chronic diseases under healthcare warranties from dual stakeholder perspectives (hospitals and patients) to achieve mutually beneficial outcomes. The primary purpose is to determine whether there exists a pricing zone of follow-up policies acceptable for both hospitals and patients, thereby establishing a win–win relationship between the two parties. We model heterogeneous patients with varying AO risk levels and three follow-up policies differentiated by implementation timeframes. Hospitals set prices for each policy, and patients select policies based on these prices. By analyzing hazard rate functions and associated costs across policies and risk levels, we derive win–win price intervals for follow-up services under diverse scenarios.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 presents the problem description, necessary assumptions and notations, and formulates the mathematical model for pricing of follow-up policies. In
Section 3, we present a case study of pediatric type 1 diabetes mellitus and conduct sensitivity analyses of key parameters.
Section 4 discusses the principal findings, practical implications, limitations, and potential future research extensions. Conclusions are presented in
Section 5.
3. Results
In this section, pediatric type 1 diabetes mellitus (T1DM) is taken as an example to verify the feasibility and effectiveness of the proposed model. T1DM is associated with multiple risk factors that predispose individuals to acute AOs, including ketoacidosis and hypoglycemia, as well as chronic AOs such as nephropathy and retinopathy. Currently, there are already some healthcare warranty practices for diabetes mellitus, such as PROMETHEUS [
42]. Effective T1DM management not only requires hospitals to develop rational treatment regimens but also necessitates long-term follow-up policies. During each follow-up checkup, activities such as treatment plan adjustments, patient education, and indicator monitoring are conducted. To ensure hospitals are willing to provide these follow-up policies and patients are willing to purchase them, an appropriate win–win price interval must be established that prevents financial losses for both parties.
3.1. Model Parametrization
In this paper, the research data were obtained from the endocrinology department of a children’s hospital in Tianjin, China. The hospital lacks well-established follow-up mechanisms and pricing strategies. Typically, healthcare providers empirically recommend outpatient visits every six months or annually. This has resulted in a relatively low follow-up rate among patients and suboptimal disease management outcomes. Charging a certain fee for follow-up services could effectively enhance both provider and patient engagement in the follow-up, thereby improving treatment efficacy and helping to curb healthcare costs.
A total of 143 patients with T1DM and their relevant data from 2014 to 2018 were collected. The dataset comprises two parts: one is AO treatment data, including patient demographics, family history of diabetes, comorbidities, body mass index (BMI), treatment dates, and treatment costs; the other is follow-up data, including follow-up dates, follow-up costs, and follow-up methods. Patient inclusion/exclusion criteria were applied as follows. Only patients diagnosed with T1DM as their primary condition were included in subsequent analyses, as risk factors influencing AO risk vary across different diseases. Consequently, those with T2DM or other specific types of diabetes were excluded. We also excluded patients with a first-time diagnosis of T1DM due to insufficient follow-up and treatment data required for model parametrization. Furthermore, records with missing essential information (e.g., sex) were removed. Patients with long-term complications (e.g., diabetic retinopathy) were excluded as well, since their management requires collaborative care among multiple departments. For data cleaning, variables with more than 20% missing values were excluded from the analysis. For variables with less than 20% missingness, mean imputation was applied. Physiological outliers were reviewed and either corrected or set as missing if identified as recording errors. As a result, 67 AO treatment records and 149 follow-up records from 37 patients were used for subsequent analysis.
AO treatment data are used to estimate parameters in the conditional hazard rate function:
. Typically, the frailty factor
is assumed to follow a Gamma distribution with a mean of 1 [
43]. Consequently, the probability density function of
is
, where
represents the variance. According to the literature and expert opinions, the observable patient heterogeneity vector
includes five components: age, gender, puberty status, number of comorbidities, length of stay, and body mass index [
44,
45].
Figure 3a presents the histogram of time to develop an AO. Based on that, Weibull, Gamma, and Log-Normal distributions were selected as possible candidates for the baseline hazard rate function
. We employed maximum marginal likelihood estimation to estimate the parameters, including
and
, and the parameters of the chosen distribution for
, across different combinations of
and
. The optimal results are as follows:
follows a Weibull distribution, with the shape and scale parameters being 0.12 and 1.657, respectively; the variance of
is 0.626;
. Based on these results, we further determined that
also follows a Gamma distribution, with a mean of 2.4006 and a variance of 0.0813.
Figure 3b illustrates the histogram and fitted Gamma distribution of
. Based on aforementioned results, the value of
for each patient can be calculated using the formula
, along with the minimum and maximum values (
and
). In this paper, patients are categorized into three risk groups: the low-, medium-, and high-risk groups. Thus, the value of
is set to 3. According to Equations (4) and (5), we have
, where
and
. The cut-offs for patient stratification
can therefore be determined by solving these equations. The average cost of treating an AO
for each group is defined as the mean treatment cost for AOs. The corresponding results are presented in
Table 4.
The average cost of implementing a follow-up checkup
is set as the mean value of follow-up cost, i.e.,
. The age reduction factor
can be estimated using a regression analysis based on changes in key patient indicators, such as blood glucose, glycosylated hemoglobin, and patient compliance with treatment, before and after checkups. However, due to data limitations, this paper is unable to obtain accurate values for
, so we consulted several experienced endocrinologists specializing in pediatric T1DM at our partner hospital for approximate values.
indicates the effectiveness of the follow-up checkup, and the endocrinologists believe that their follow-ups are reliable enough to detect potential AOs and reduce AO risks. Since
, they all set
. In order to analyze the effect of
on AO risks, we set
initially and conducted a sensitivity analysis in
Section 3.3.1. To facilitate comparisons between patient groups, this study assigns the same warranty period and planning horizon to all patients. The warranty period
is set to one year following several relevant studies on follow-up and healthcare warranty policy optimization for chronic disease [
21,
22,
46]. The planning horizon
represents a fixed period during which the components of follow-up policies, such as frequency and intervention, remain unchanged. However, our partner hospital empirically recommends outpatient follow-ups every six months or annually without further adjustment. Therefore, the exact value of
cannot be directly determined from current practices. To address this, we again sought expert opinions from endocrinologists specializing in pediatric T1DM at our partner hospital. They suggested that
be defined as the timeframe during which patients remain free of long-term complications, since major adjustments to follow-up policies are typically required once complications emerge. According to clinical practice guidelines [
47,
48], patients often develop long-term complications within two to five years after diabetes onset. Thus, we initially set
as three years and performed a sensitivity analysis in
Section 3.3.4. The values of the relevant parameters are summarized in
Table 5.
3.2. Win–Win Price Intervals
We computed the win–win price intervals and widths of the three follow-up policies for each risk group separately under different values of
.
Figure 4 illustrates the results for the low-risk group. The following insights can be derived:
Overall, the minimum price hospitals will accept, , under either follow-up policy decreases and remains nearly constant as increases. This occurs because the number of checkups provided under each policy decreases with , reducing the profit hospitals can obtain from follow-up services. Consequently, their acceptable price declines. Furthermore, when becomes sufficiently large, the number of checkups almost stabilizes, and the minimum price remains constant. Similarly, as the number of checkups decreases, the maximum price patients are willing to pay declines under either policy II or III, showing a more gradual trend. However, policy I exhibits a distinct pattern. This difference arises because the number of checkups under policy I is relatively low, meaning changes in cause a proportionally larger reduction in checkups. After months, the number of checkups during the warranty period stabilizes at one. At this point, patients become increasingly willing to pay for this single checkup to mitigate their AO risk and associated costs.
For follow-up policy I, after , a win–win price interval emerges and the width of this interval increases slightly with . When , the maximum price for patients fluctuates while the minimum price for hospitals reduces. However, once , both the maximum price and the minimum price gradually rise. This occurs because, within these values, only one checkup occurs during the warranty period. When the checkup is scheduled near the end of the warranty period, AO risk and associated treatment cost during the warranty period increase, while those beyond the warranty decrease. Consequently, patients are more willing to pay for a checkup scheduled close to the warranty period, and hospitals can accept higher prices since the two parties bear AO treatment costs beyond and during the warranty period, respectively.
Under follow-up policy II, a win–win price interval emerges when , with its width increasing rapidly and stabilizing almost completely as rises. Under this policy, patients bear the AO treatment cost during the post-warranty period. Consequently, AO risk and associated cost rise with , leading to a decline in the maximum price patients will pay. For hospitals, changes in primarily affect follow-up implementation cost, resulting in a gradual decrease in their minimum acceptable price. In addition, the interval width under this policy is minimal compared with that under policies I and III. This occurs because follow-up checkups scheduled too late fail to sufficiently reduce AO risk and cost, making patients reluctant to pay higher prices for these services.
Under follow-up policy III, win–win price intervals emerge when . This policy enables patients to receive continuous follow-up services within the planning horizon, significantly reducing AO risk. Moreover, policy III reduces treatment costs for both hospitals during the warranty period and patients in the post-warranty period. The trends of maximum and minimum prices are similar to those under policy II, though both prices under policy III are consistently higher. This difference arises because policy III covers a longer time span, resulting in more follow-up checkups and higher associated costs.
Figure 5 and
Figure 6 present the results for the medium- and high-risk groups, respectively. For both groups, the overall trends in win–win price intervals and interval widths across different follow-up policies largely aligns with those observed in the low-risk group, though key differences emerge in the following aspects. First, win–win intervals appear earliest in the high-risk group, followed by the medium-risk group, and latest in the low-risk group, regardless of follow-up policy. For example, under follow-up policy II, win–win intervals in the three risks groups emerge when
,
,
, respectively. Second, the maximum price patients are willing to pay is highest for the high-risk group, intermediate for the medium-risk group, and lowest for the low-risk group. In contrast, the minimum price hospitals can accept follows an inverse pattern: highest for the low-risk group, intermediate for the medium-risk group, and lowest for the high-risk group, notably falling to zero in most cases. These patterns arise because higher-risk patients present more complex and severe conditions, resulting in elevated treatment cost during either warranty period or post-warranty period. Consequently, both patients and hospitals are willing to invest more in follow-up services, which can effectively reduce AO risk and associated cost.
3.3. Sensitivity Analysis
3.3.1. Effects of the Age Reduction Factor
The age reduction factor
measures the effectiveness of follow-up checkups in reducing AO risk. A smaller
indicates greater checkup efficacy.
Table 6 presents the win–win intervals for the three risk groups under different checkup age reduction factors, with
fixed at 3 months. From the results in
Table 6, we can observe that:
Low-risk group. Under follow-up policy I, win–win price intervals exist for age reduction factors . In addition, these intervals narrow as increases, resulting in a higher minimum price threshold for hospitals and a lower maximum price threshold for patients. This occurs because less effective checkups increase hospitals’ expected number of AOs and costs during the warranty period, prompting them to demand higher prices for follow-up services to offset expenses. Conversely, patients will enter the post-warranty period with a higher AO risk and greater potential costs due to inefficient checkups, making them willing to pay less. Consequently, the maximum price threshold for patients decreases. For policy II, no win–win price interval exists at any value, indicating that post-warranty follow-up services provide no mutual advantage. Under policy III, a win–win price interval emerges only at , demonstrating that profitability requires highly effective checkups. When checkups are ineffective, AO risk reduction is insufficient in both warranty and post-warranty periods, yielding no benefits for either stakeholder.
Medium-risk group. Under follow-up policies I and III, win–win price intervals exist for all values. Similarly to the low-risk group, these intervals narrow as increases, for the reasons previously outlined. For policy II, win–win intervals exist when , with all minimum prices for hospitals fixed at 3424 (equivalent to shown in Equation (18)). The maximum prices for patients decrease as increases, consistent with observations under the other two policies. Compared to the low-risk group, win–win price intervals occur more frequently for the medium-risk group, because the higher AO risk enables even checkups with low effectiveness to sufficiently reduce expected AOs and associated cost. Consequently, both patients and hospitals show greater willingness to invest in follow-up services.
High-risk group. Win–win price intervals exist for all values under all follow-up policies. Consistent with the pattern observed in the low-risk group, the maximum prices for patients face decreases as increases. However, the trend for minimum prices differs slightly across policies. For policy I, the minimum price for hospitals is always zero, indicating that providing follow-up services to high-risk patients during the warranty period remains beneficial for hospitals regardless of checkup efficacy. For policy II, the minimum price for hospitals is consistently 3424, mirroring the medium-risk group scenario. This occurs because follow-up services are delivered after the warranty period, rendering them irrelevant to the cost decisions of hospitals. In addition, the downward trend in maximum prices for patients implies that win–win price intervals cease to exist when the price falls below 3424. For policy III, minimum prices start at zero when or but increase with . This reflects that for ineffective checkups, hospitals require fees to profit from follow-up services during the planning horizon.
3.3.2. Effects of the Follow-Up Checkup Cost
Table 7,
Table 8 and
Table 9 show the results of win–win price intervals under different follow-up checkup costs for the low-, medium- and high-risk groups, respectively, with
fixed at 3 months. Looking at these results, we can see that:
For the low-risk group, win–win intervals consistently exist under follow-up policy I but do not emerge under policy II. Under policy III, these intervals exist specifically when the change in is {−30%, −20%, −10%, 0}. Within these existing intervals, the maximum price for patients remains constant under a given policy, while the minimum price for hospitals increases with . This occurs because directly influences the hospital’s cost of implementing follow-up policies. As rises, hospitals require higher minimum prices to offset their increased implementation cost. Conversely, variations in do not affect the patient’s maximum price, as patients do not bear the cost of follow-up services. Consequently, the win–win price interval for follow-up services narrows as increases.
For the medium- and high-risk groups, win–win price intervals exist across all follow-up policies and varying levels. Similarly to the low-risk group, the maximum price for patients remains constant under any given policy. Regarding the minimum price for hospitals, it increases with under policy II for both groups and under policy III for the medium-risk group. Under the remaining policies and levels, the minimum price remains zero for these groups. However, even in these cases, the minimum price is projected to rise once becomes sufficiently high.
3.3.3. Effects of the AO Treatment Cost
Table 10,
Table 11 and
Table 12 show the results of win–win price intervals under different AO treatment costs for the low-, medium- and high-risk groups, respectively, with
fixed at 3 months. The following findings can be made:
For the low-risk group, win–win price intervals consistently exist under follow-up policy I but do not emerge under policy II. Under policy III, these intervals exist only when the change in is {0, 10%, 20%, 30%}. Furthermore, these intervals widen as increases for a given policy. Specifically, the minimum price for hospitals decreases, while the maximum price for patients increases. This widening occurs because rising increases AO treatment costs for both parties: hospitals face higher treatment costs during the warranty period, and patients face higher treatment costs during the post-warranty period. To mitigate these rising costs, hospitals are incentivized to lower their minimum acceptable price to attract more follow-up service agreements. Patients become willing to pay a higher maximum price for follow-up services to avoid larger future expenses.
For the medium- and high-risk groups, win–win price intervals exist across all follow-up policies and values of . Within these intervals, the maximum price patients pay increases with , which is similar to the low-risk group. However, the minimum price hospitals can accept only decreases under policy III for the medium-risk group. Under other policies and across varying levels, it remains largely stable. Specifically, under policy I, the minimum price starts at 202.41 for the medium-risk group but remains zero thereafter, while it is consistently zero for the high-risk group. This indicates hospitals’ willingness to provide low-price follow-up services during the warranty period, as AO treatment costs can be reduced to a large extent. Moreover, under policy II, the minimum price is calculated as , which is constant at 3424. This occurs because follow-up services are delivered post-warranty, where implementation costs are unaffected by .
3.3.4. Effects of the Planning Horizon
Table 13 shows win–win price intervals across different planning horizons
for the low-, medium- and high-risk groups, with
fixed at 3 months. For the low-risk group, policy I consistently yields win–win intervals. The minimum price for hospitals remains fixed at 1002.65, while the maximum price for patients increases with
. This occurs because hospitals only cover treatment costs during the warranty period, which is unaffected by
, whereas patients bear post-warranty treatment costs that rise with longer horizons. Policy II generates win–win intervals only when
, indicating that follow-up services become mutually beneficial when the planning horizon is sufficiently long. Policy III produces win–win intervals when
is {3, 4, 5}, with both minimum and maximum prices rising with
. This is because follow-up services occur during the planning horizon, concurrently impacting hospitals’ implementation cost and patients’ treatment expenses. Similar patterns emerge for medium- and high-risk groups, with the key difference being that win–win price intervals exist across more policy–horizon combinations relative to the low-risk group.
4. Discussion
4.1. Principal Findings
Healthcare warranties transfer financial risk from patients to hospitals, incentivizing hospitals to provide long-term preventive services, such as follow-up policies, to chronic disease patients for cost control. However, the absence of an appropriate pricing mechanism impedes the practical implementation of these services, as they generate additional costs for hospitals. A feasible solution is to introduce patient copayments for follow-up services, making their pricing critically significant. To ensure mutual participation, pricing must balance two constraints. It should fall within the range that patients are willing to pay while exceeding hospitals’ minimum acceptable threshold. Against this backdrop, our paper investigates follow-up policy pricing for chronic diseases under healthcare warranties from a dual perspective. Accounting for patient heterogeneity, we employ a Cox frailty model to stratify patients into distinct risk groups and analyze pricing strategies per group. For each patient group, we evaluate three follow-up policies: periodic checkups during the warranty period, periodic checkups during the post-warranty period, and periodic checkups across the entire planning horizon. Using the virtual age method, we model hazard rate functions for each policy and derive total expected costs incurred by hospitals and patients via NHPP analysis. This enables identification of win–win price intervals, where upper bounds reflect maximum prices patients are willing to pay, and lower bounds represent hospitals’ minimum acceptable prices.
Applied to pediatric T1DM, our model yields actionable insights. First, win–win price intervals are more readily achievable for patients with higher risk, suggesting hospitals should prioritize these patients. Second, low-efficacy follow-up checkups narrow win–win price intervals. Therefore, hospitals must enhance checkup effectiveness in reducing AO risk to broaden pricing flexibility. Third, win–win price intervals narrow or remain stable as follow-up checkup cost increases, while widening as AO treatment cost rises. This indicates that hospitals must balance these two costs to optimize follow-up policy pricing. Fourth, both upper and lower price bounds increase with planning horizon length, making horizon selection crucial for feasible pricing, which can be further investigated in future research.
Conventional healthcare warranty (e.g., ProvenCare and PROMETHEUS) pricing typically consists of two main components: the average historical cost of providing follow-up services and AO treatments during the warranty period, plus an additional fee portion for AO treatments. Since both parts are calculated based on historical data, our proposed pricing method advances current knowledge in three key aspects. First, we incorporate the stochastic nature of AO occurrence and analyze their frequency and associated costs using stochastic processes, offering a significant advantage over static historical estimates. Second, our approach accounts for the influence of follow-up configuration on pricing, rather than simply averaging historical costs regardless of the number and frequency of follow-up checkups. Third, we consider not only the hospital’s perspective but also patients’ choices regarding follow-up policies, thereby enabling pricing that reflects both parties’ interests and promotes mutually beneficial outcomes. This dual perspective enhances joint and effective engagement in healthcare warranties and follow-up services.
4.2. Practical Implications
Our model will help hospitals effectively manage heterogeneous chronic patients and accurately determine reasonable pricing for follow-up services. First, by applying the patient stratification method proposed in our study, hospitals can categorize patients into different levels of AO risk and determine each patient’s specific risk level. Second, using the cost functions, hospitals can accurately estimate the costs incurred by both themselves and patients under various follow-up policies. Based on this, they can further derive win–win price intervals across different risk levels and types of follow-up policies. In addition, according to our principal findings, to obtain optimal and flexible intervals, hospitals are encouraged to improve the effectiveness of follow-up checkups in reducing AO risk, balance costs between follow-up checkups and AO treatment, and set appropriate planning horizons.
Our model also supports regulators (e.g., the government or insurers) in making decisions regarding reimbursement mechanisms and rates for follow-up policies for both hospitals and patients. Using the win–win price intervals generated by our model, regulators can further analyze the interrelationships between their own decisions and those of hospitals and patients. This enables the determination of optimal reimbursement mechanisms and rates that align with the interests and services of all three parties, thereby maximizing social welfare.
4.3. Limitations and Future Research
This study has several limitations on both model formulation and case study design, which offer avenues for future research.
Model formulation: Many promising extensions may be explored in future research based on our proposed model. First, the current model adopts a single cost perspective. One promising extension currently under consideration is formulating the follow-up policy pricing problem from a market perspective, incorporating factors such as the predicted sales volume of follow-up services and the utilities of both patients and hospitals. Additionally, this paper does not address scenarios where healthcare warranties can be renewed following hospitalizations due to AOs, which should be incorporated in future studies. Finally, this study investigates follow-up pricing with fixed components (e.g., follow-up frequency) under a healthcare warranty that also has fixed components (e.g., warranty period and planning horizon). Future research could treat these components as decision variables and explore the joint optimization of both the follow-up policy and the healthcare warranty structure.
Case study: Using pediatric T1DM as a case study, this paper validates the feasibility and applicability of the proposed model. However, some limitations exist in terms of data collection and analysis. First, the dataset is based on a relatively small sample size (37 patients with 67 AO treatment records and 149 follow-up records) from a single hospital, which may affect the statistical power and robustness of the results and limit the generalizability of the findings. Second, the study relies primarily on modeled outcomes and therefore requires further validation through empirical research. We are actively working to expand the dataset to mitigate these limitations. Third, as the study focuses on T1DM in children and adolescents, the selected risk factors (i.e., age, gender, puberty status, number of comorbidities, length of stay, and body mass index) were constrained by data availability. Health behaviors such as smoking and obesity were not incorporated, although they are recognized as significant factors influencing AO risk, follow-up frequency, and subsequent follow-up policy pricing [
49,
50,
51]. Future research should aim to include these factors by expanding the scope to other chronic conditions, such as type 2 diabetes in adults.