Next Article in Journal
The Output Gap and Youth Unemployment: An Analysis Based on Okun’s Law
Previous Article in Journal
The Effects of Commodity Discoveries on Small Open Economies: Empirical Evidence from the Falkland Islands
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Embedding Preference Uncertainty for Environmental Amenities in Climate Change Economic Assessments: A “Random” Step Forward

1
Department of Agricultural Economics & Rural Development, Agricultural University of Athens, 11855 Athens, Greece
2
Department of Mining, National Technical University of Athens, 15780 Zografou, Greece
3
Department of Mechanical Engineering, University of Western Macedonia, 50100 Kozani, Greece
4
Center for Renewable Energy Sources, 19009 Pikermi, Greece
5
Department of Economics, University of Bath, Bath BA2 7AY, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2019, 7(4), 107; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7040107
Submission received: 20 April 2019 / Revised: 23 October 2019 / Accepted: 24 October 2019 / Published: 28 October 2019

Abstract

:
While there is a considerable debate regarding the choice of proper discount rates for assessing climate change projects and policies, only a tiny body of literature emphasizes “what to discount”. Usually, climate change economic assessments rely on tools and methods that employ strong simplifications, assuming, among others, given and fixed preferences about the values of man-made and environmental goods. Aiming to fill a gap in the literature, this paper leaves aside the issue of discounting and focuses on the nature and impact of preference uncertainty on the economic estimates of future climate change damages on ecosystem non-market goods and services. To this end, a general random walk-based stochastic model is proposed, combining a number of parameters, e.g., the growth of income, depletion of environmental assets, the elasticity of income and demand, and the change in preferences towards the environment. The illustrative application of the model shows that the value of environmental losses is significantly affected by the change in preferences. By doing so, the model allows the analyst to visualize future paths of preference evolutions and to bring future values of damaged environmental assets realistically to the fore. If these elements are neglected when estimating climate change-related future damages to environmental goods and services, the results may be too narrow from a policy perspective.

1. Introduction

Present policies that aim at addressing issues in health, insurance, education, infrastructure, space exploration, etc., have impacts that frequently extend into the far future. In that sense, current policies impinge on the welfare of future generations above and beyond that of present constituencies. Policy response to climate change provides a very striking example. Climate change is profoundly about the future; mitigation and adaptation policies are impacting future generations, and to a lesser degree the present one, meaning that present costs should be weighed against future benefits. Much of the literature related to climate change—and other projects or policies whose costs and benefits extend into the future—focuses on the choice of proper discount rate on the basis of which future benefits are made comparable to present costs, e.g., (Cline 1992; Arrow et al. 1996; Dasgupta et al. 1999; Dasgupta and Maskin 2005; Stern and Cabinet Office—H.M. Treasury 2007; Stern 2008; Nordhaus 2007; Dasgupta 2008; Gollier 2008; Weisbach and Sunstein 2008; Heal 2009; Baum and Easterling 2010; Scarborough 2010; Gollier and Weitzman 2010; Kaplow and Weisbach 2011; Vale 2016). The debate regarding the appropriate social discount rate is reflected, among others, in the choice of the pure social rate of time preference (usually denoted by δ) and the elasticity of marginal utility of consumption (usually denoted by η). For instance, Nordhaus (2007) uses δ = 1.5 and η = 2, Stern’s (Stern and Cabinet Office—H.M. Treasury 2007) choices are δ = 0.1 and η = 1, and Weitzman (2007) specifies δ = 2 and η = 2, respectively. Employing different consumption growth forecasts may further widen the distance between the discount rates, resulting in staggering differences when discounting over long periods of time.
The debate on discounting future costs and benefits is fascinating from a philosophical and economic perspective. It makes our attitudes toward future generations explicit and strengthens the need for rational and well-informed policy advice. It is, however, surprising that the ongoing discussion on “how to discount” is not matched with an analogous discussion on “what to discount”. To clarify ideas, researchers and policy-makers have relied heavily on integrated assessment models (IAMs) to explore the pathways through which greenhouse gas emissions accumulate in the atmosphere and oceans, and to assess natural impacts and economic consequences (Metcalf and Stock 2015; Bosello 2014). The monetized impacts of climate change, known as social cost of carbon (SCC), are used by national agencies and/or international organizations in cost-benefit analyses of climate change regulations and programs (Watkiss and Hope 2011). Nevertheless, subsequent critiques have challenged the findings of IAMs arguing that the models employ strong simplifications and use weakly defended assumptions; the socio-economic scenarios usually under-sample the range of plausible futures; the models do not incorporate emissions of any greenhouse gas other than carbon dioxide; etc., e.g., ( Sterner and Persson 2008; O’Neill 2010; Warren et al. 2010; Masur and Posner 2011; van Vuuren et al. 2011; Hof et al. 2012; Kopp and Mignone 2012; Metcalf and Stock 2015; Pindyck 2013; Balint et al. 2017).
The cautious reader is puzzled by the list of limitations mentioned above. Yet, there are even more issues that need to be considered when estimating climate change-related future damages to environmental goods and services (e.g., Lee et al. 2015; Balint et al. 2017). The value of environmental goods and services is often underestimated or taken for granted, since markets are usually unable to provide an appropriate unit of account, e.g., (Hein et al. 2006; Boyd and Banzhaf 2007; Fisher et al. 2009). As Sterner and Persson (2008) conclude after modifying DICE model to account for environmental scarcity:
“… Even if the climate damages in the DICE model used in the numerical exercise above are doubled to account for a wider range of nonmarket impacts, following the results in the Stern Review, we would argue that these impacts are still comparatively low …”
“We believe that it is exactly the nonmarket effects of climate change that are the most worrisome. If we focus on the risk for catastrophes, as Weitzman suggests, then we believe the main effect of climate change will not be to stop growth in conventional manufacturing, but rather to damage our ability to enjoy some vital ecosystem services …”
More specifically, there are two key issues; namely, (a) the (tacit) assumption of perfect substitutability between man-made and environmental goods and services (Neumayer 1999) and, accordingly, the calculation of environmental damages predominantly on the basis of market goods (i.e., on a GDP basis through a reduction in the consumption of market goods and services); and (b) the (tacit) assumption that future environmental values do not diverge from present ones. These assumptions raise in turn further questions on models’ capacity to tackle issues such as the uncertainty surrounding the evolution of markets, changes in consumption modes and habits, future generations’ own preferences, and accordingly the influence of future preferences on the monetary estimation of future environmental damages. Despite the relevant literature regarding these issues, e.g., (Horowitz 2002; Ayong Le Kama and Schubert 2004; Hoel and Sterner 2007; Sterner and Persson 2008; Jacobsen et al. 2013; Ackerman and Stanton 2013) most of the economic assessments relating to climate change damages are silent about the potential impact of preference uncertainty on the estimates and how it could be taken into consideration.
This paper, leaving aside the issue of discounting, aims to add to the limited literature on the effect of preference uncertainty on the economic estimates of future climate change damages and in particular on the value that people place on environmental goods and services. For this purpose, a number of parameters, e.g., the growth of income, the depletion of environmental assets, and the change in preferences towards the environment, are explored and combined in a stochastic framework as a general random walk-based model, in order to simulate the growth rate of the non-market value for an environmental good or service.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 sets the scene about the problem of preference uncertainty with a particular focus on the value of non-market goods and services. Section 3 details the theoretical and methodological aspects of the model. Section 4 presents an illustrative example of the proposed approach. Finally, Section 5 summarizes conclusions and recommendations.

2. Framing the Problem of Future Preference Uncertainty

Present generations invest in climate change adaptation and mitigation for two reasons: an ethical one, meaning a moral sense of responsibility toward the yet unborn; and a rights aspect, meaning that posterity has as much rights as we did to inherit a hospitable Earth (Summers and Zeckhauser 2008). Whatever the reason may be, our attitude toward posterity is either guided by our own preferences and thus contemporary patterns of relative social worth of man-made and ecosystem assets. In this case, we exhibit a paternalistic altruism to future generations. Or, alternatively, we take future preferences seriously and conjecture as to what would future generations themselves consider a welfare-enhancing pattern of man-made and ecosystem assets. This is a non-paternalistic attitude to future generations (Horowitz 2002).
Despite the nature of motives behind climate change policies, analysts (implicitly or explicitly) extend present preferences (derived from market transactions or inferred through stated preference measures) into the future by calculating all damages in prices of a base year, using the price level of the base year as the basis for aggregation (Anderson et al. 2012; Noblet et al. 2015). This is not surprising considering that the neoclassical model traditionally explores theoretical and empirical problems considering preferences as fixed and given (Janssen and Jager 2001). Yet, this view ignores potential changes in preferences and, accordingly, relative values of man-made and environmental goods. For instance, if—in terms of weak sustainability—future generations were richer in material goods but less equipped with environmental amenities, the relative prices could shift, making environmental amenities more valuable than today. That, in turn, would substantially reinforce the value magnitude of the physical loss of non-market goods, possibly counterbalancing the rise in the value of the aggregated man-made assets.
The causes behind the uncertainty of future preferences are well established in the literature. For instance, consumer preferences are influenced by the social setting in which the product is being used (i.e., the preference may be affected by who else uses this product); the proportion of people in the actor’s social network that consumes this product (the so-called “socialization effect”); and the intensity of preference for a product that is repeatedly being consumed (a process known as “exposure effect”) (see Janssen and Jager 2001 for a detailed discussion). In addition, preference uncertainty may be related to overconfidence in forecasting individual future preferences that lead to errors in predictions of future consumption (Thunström et al. 2015). Uncertainty of future preferences is also attributed to incorrect predictions of feelings that have been found to impact consumer behavior, e.g., (Loewenstein and Schkade 2003; MacInnis et al. 2005).
When it comes to environmental amenities in particular, preference uncertainty may be explained by the random state of nature, the uncertainty of future income, or the unfamiliarity with the good (Thunström et al. 2015). To wit, the non-market value refers to small changes in the state of the environment and not the state of the environment itself (TEEB 2010). The estimates are based on people’s willingness-to-pay (WTP)—the maximum amount of money in order to avoid an environmental degradation and its consequences on health, amenity, etc.,—or their willingness-to-accept (WTA)—the minimum compensation in order to endure the environmental impacts incurred (Freeman 2003). In this regard, the value of environmental assets is individual-based and subjective, as well as context- and state-dependent (Goulder and Kennedy 1997; Nunes and van den Bergh 2001; Kontogianni et al. 2010). Hence, the estimates of non-market values reflect only the current choice pattern and are affected by socio-economic-ecological conditions such as the state of the environment, the available income, attitudes (e.g., voluntary participation in activities to protect the environment), opinions and beliefs, and expectations about the future (Barbier et al. 2009; Besley and Persson 2019; Lamb 2019; Pingali et al. 2019). It is evident that a change in socio-economic-ecological conditions might severely affect the estimated values (TEEB 2010).
Despite extensive literature on the topic of preference uncertainty, it is evident that there is a dearth of study on how to account for the effect of changing preferences on the economic estimates of future climate change damages.

3. Methodology

3.1. Model Considerations

Our model builds upon an early work of Fisher and Krutilla (1975) with respect to changing values for the environment, i.e., the growth rate of the WTP value for an environmental good or service, but it goes a step further by incorporating new factors and employing stochastic random walk-based simulations, as detailed later. Fisher and Krutilla (1975) suggested that evolving preferences at time t (i.e., WTPt) could be captured by the continuous stream of the “present” WTP (i.e., WTP0) for the environment flowing at some pre-determined rate, say α:
WTPt = WTP0eαt
where
  • WTP0 is the present WTP for an environmental good or service.
  • WTPt is the future WTP for the environmental good or service at time t.
  • α is the growth rate of the WTP value for the environmental good or service.
  • t is the time in years (assuming that α and discount rates are expressed on a yearly basis).
The present value (PV) of WTPt, assuming a social discount rate s and continuous compounding, is estimated as follows:
PVWTPt = WTP0eαt/est or PVWTPt = WTP0/e(s−α)t
The issue of non-constant WTP values is acknowledged and then left aside, e.g., (Sterner and Persson (2008) providing examples from Arrow et al. (1996); Nordhaus (1997); Lebègue et al. (2005); Gollier (2007)). Therefore, current IAMs create the feeling that the economic damages due to the effects of climate change are being trivialized (Parry et al. 2001).
According to Fisher and Krutilla (1975) and Horowitz (2002), two factors are likely to determine the growth rate of WTP, which is the focus of this paper: the growth of income and changes in environmental quality (i.e., resource scarcity). Further, and as mentioned previously, WTP values are influenced by the substitution elasticity between natural and man-made capitals, e.g., (Krysiak and Krysiak 2006; Hoel and Sterner 2007; Sterner and Persson 2008) and by the attitude of future generations towards environmental assets (Ayong Le Kama and Schubert 2004). These factors are discussed in more detail below.

3.1.1. Income Growth

The increase in WTP values owing to the growth of income depends on income elasticity of demand (Gravelle and Smith 2000; Horowitz 2002; Groom et al. 2005). The literature provides some evidence regarding the income elasticity of demand for environmental assets, e.g., (Borcherding and Deacon 1972; Bergstrom and Goodman 1973; Thomas and Syme 1988; Dalhuisen et al. 2003; Hökby and Söderqvist 2003; Worthington and Hoffman 2008; Yoo et al. 2014). Income elasticities of demand vary significantly from 0.01 up to 7.8; however, the majority of the estimates are less than 1. In general, estimates of the income elasticity of demand are difficult to derive from non-market valuation studies because contexts in which varying price and quantity combinations are seldom considered. This is the reason why what is usually observed is the income elasticity of WTP, which is estimated as follows:
ω = W T P Y Y W T P
where
  • Y is the income.
  • WTP is the willingness to pay amount.
The relationship between the income elasticity of demand and the income elasticity of WTP is not predetermined, as an environmental good may have income elasticity of demand greater than 1 and income elasticity of WTP greater or less than 1 (Flores and Carson 1997). Several empirical studies suggest that WTP is an increasing function of income (Kriström and Riera 1996), i.e., respondents with more income tend to express higher WTP values for environmental improvements; that is, environmental improvements are typically normal goods. Yet, this is not always the case. Pearce (2003) discusses a general conceptual framework for the analysis of the distribution of environmental costs and benefits using the available empirical literature. As Pearce (2003) points out, with some exceptions the income elasticity of WTP for environmental quality is less than 1. Similar conclusions are drawn also from Jacobsen and Hanley (2009), while Martini and Tiezzi (2014) estimated income elasticities between 1.165 and 1.345, suggesting that as societies get richer they tend to value environmental quality more highly.

3.1.2. Environmental Scarcity

The scarcity of environmental goods and services will likely increase future WTP for environmental goods assuming a negative price elasticity of demand. Nevertheless, the price elasticity of demand for environmental amenities cannot be estimated directly since welfare estimates are usually derived from the indirect utility function. The literature provides several studies that attempt to estimate price elasticities of environmental assets. Not surprisingly, the majority of them deal with environmental resources that can be easily deemed as market goods, e.g., residential or irrigation water (e.g., Thomas and Syme 1988; Hewitt and Hanemann 1995; Pint 1999). Arbués et al. (2003) examine differences in the specification of water demand models and analyze several tariff types and their objectives through an extensive literature review. Worthington and Hoffman (2008) also provide a synoptic survey of empirical residential water demand analyses conducted in the last 25 years. Price elasticity estimates are generally found in the range of 0 to 0.5 in the short run and 0.5 to 1 in the long run (in absolute terms). Borcherding and Deacon (1972) explored the parameters that govern the demand of public services in the U.S. for various public goods, including parks and recreation. The results show price elasticities of demand to be less than one in absolute terms. Bergstrom and Goodman (1973) estimated that the price elasticity of demand for parks and recreation is higher than 1 (~1.13) on absolute terms. Rosenberger and Stanley (2010) conducted a meta-regression analysis of own-price elasticity of recreation demand estimates in the U.S. The raw average elasticity is unitary (−0.997), while the median elasticity is inelastic (−0.567). Finally, Hökby and Söderqvist (2003) found price elasticity of demand equal to −1.86 (95% confidence interval: −2.08, −1.64).

3.1.3. Substitution Elasticity between Natural and Man-Made Capitals

As mentioned by Sterner and Persson (2008), who provide a detailed analysis on the subject, when non-market goods are perfectly substitutable with market goods, non-market damages can be included in consumption directly. However, when there are limits to the substitutability between market and environmental goods (i.e., when elasticity of substitution is less than 1), WTP would be expected to rise with increasing scarcity. Similar results are reported by Hoel and Sterner (2007). In addition, Krysiak and Krysiak (2006) note that for constant nature and capital stocks, an increase in the elasticity of substitution increases the absolute change in the maximal stock of nature at which a further reduction is not sustainable to counter a decrease in the level of sustainability. Hence, they argue that substitution possibilities and uncertainty about future preferences (or production possibilities) are substitutes in the sense that an increase in the uncertainty about future preferences can be compensated by a lower elasticity of substitution, and vice versa. As a result, more uncertainty provides a rationale for more preservation (Fisher and Krutilla 1975).
Although the elasticity of substitution has significant implications with respect to future WTP values, risk aversion and discount rates (Ayong Le Kama and Schubert 2004; Krysiak and Krysiak 2006; Traeger 2007), it is hard to provide good empirical estimates for the elasticity of substitution. The elasticity of substitution varies considerably among environmental goods and services, as well as between individuals (Sterner and Persson 2008).

3.1.4. Changing Preferences

Future WTP values will be affected by the attitude of future generations towards environmental assets. Their attitude may well be different from ours for many reasons, some of which are obvious, and others unpredictable since the formation of preferences involves complex and interlinked economic, social and moral determinants (Ayong Le Kama and Schubert 2004; Grüne-Yanoff and Hansson 2009). This diversification of the perceptions among generations can be considered both conspicuous and unpredictable. A change in preferences may occur in the future unexpectedly, while it can affect the level of utility associated with the level of consumption of the examined environmental goods.
Two different behaviors can be expected due to changes in preferences. Firstly, if both economic growth and environmental quality are considerably low, people will tend to be more provident and conservative. However, in a case where economic growth is high and environmental quality fair, people will increase the existing levels of consumption despite the deterioration of environmental quality adopting a type of insurance behavior against future conditions. As a result, estimating changes in preferences depends on present concerns about the well-being of future generations and requires the estimation of both the living conditions and the corresponding preferences in the future. Therefore, assumptions about the impact of present actions on the future living conditions and the respective changes of preferences are required for the analysis of changing preferences (Krysiak and Krysiak 2006).
There are good reasons to suspect that future people will care more about the natural environment (greening of preferences), leading to higher WTP values. Indisputably, the deterioration of the existing quality of the environment in combination with the upcoming depletion of the natural sources constitutes the main reason for this tendency. Yet, this is not definite. Ayong Le Kama and Schubert (2004) argue that future generations may value environmental goods and services less than the present one. To illustrate this, the authors analyze changes of future preferences which lead to a more conservative utilization of the natural resources, assuming that environmental quality is taken into consideration.
In addition, materialism may result in lower WTP values due to less concern about the effects of environmental damage on other people, ecosystem, and future generations. Materialism constitutes a value orientation, which influences the environmentalism at a significant degree (Kidd and Lee 1997; Kilbourne and Pickett 2008). Hultman et al. (2015) developed a conceptual model to examine the environmental beliefs, attitudes toward ecotourism, behavioral intentions, and WTP in relation to the materialism and tourism motivation. A negative relation between materialism and WTP was detected. Moreover, a negative relation was identified between materialism and environmental beliefs. Finally, consumerism can also affect and shape the preferences of future generations. For instance, Yu et al. (2014) examined the WTP of citizens for purchase of “green food” in China. They found a positive relation between WTP and the frequency of shopping indicating that a potential increase of consumerism in the future could lead to higher WTP values.
According to Krysiak and Krysiak (2006), future preferences cannot be taken into consideration today due to the fact that the respective individuals are not yet in existence. As a result, the estimation of future preferences is characterized by a high degree of uncertainty.

3.2. Model Formation

As discussed in previous sections, the evolution of WTP values (i.e., the growth rate α) is influenced mainly by (a) the growth of income (“income growth factor”); (b) the depletion of environmental assets (“depletion factor”); (c) the elasticity of substitution between man-made and environmental goods and services (“substitution factor”); and (d) the changing preferences of future generations (“changing preferences factor”). However, in order to avoid “double-counting” issues, the substitution factor is omitted in the model developed, since:
  • In case of perfect substitution between man-made and environmental assets, the effect of scarcity on WTP values is negligible and the non-market damages are estimated in consumption;
  • In case of weak substitution, the effect on WTP values is captured via the depletion factor, as discussed below.
To consider the effect of income growth it is necessary to consider both the income elasticity of WTP and the growth rate of income, i.e.,
αinc = ω·g
where
  • g is growth rate of income expressed as percentage change from previous year.
  • ω is the income elasticity of WTP.
The environmental depletion (or scarcity) factor (αsc) is given by:
αsc = λ·q
where: q is the depletion rate on an annual basis and expressed as percentage decrease (or increase) from previous year.
λ is the “price” (i.e., WTP) elasticity of demand, estimated as follows:
λ = W T P Q q W T P
When a natural resource is depleted faster than it can be replenished, it is considered as non-renewable. In such cases, an alternative way to estimate the effect of scarcity over future WTP values is to make use of the “Hotelling’s rule”, which predicts that the shadow price of the stock of an exhaustible resource should grow at the rate of interest (Hotelling 1931).
Finally, preferences may evolve in the future and modify in an unknown way the attitude of future generations toward environmental assets. As mentioned, some of the factors associated with these changes are obvious, but others are unpredictable. Thus, it is not possible to foretell whether people will care more about the environment in the future (i.e., green preferences) or less (i.e., materialistic preferences). Since future preferences are unknown, the preferences factor (αpr) works at the proposed model as a “drift” (upwards or downwards) and is defined ad hoc.
Given that each and every of the above-mentioned factors has an independent and additive effect on the evolution of future WTP values, the total growth rate, αtot, of WTP is given by:
W T P ˙ W T P = ω I n c ˙ I n c + λ Q ˙ Q + α p r
When the right-hand expression is constant, the solution is WTPt = WTP0eαt with α given by the right-hand side:
αtot = αinc + αsc + αpr
where
  • αtot is the total growth rate of WTP.
  • αinc is the income growth factor.
  • αsc is the environmental depletion (or scarcity) factor.
  • αpr is the changing preferences factor.
The total growth rate, αtot, is quite uncertain and its value can never be determined exactly. Therefore, simulation functions were constructed using flexible random walk-based stochastic models with and without drift (i.e., with and without change of preferences) to deal with the uncertainties involved. Random walk models are used in finance and economics in understanding and predicting the behavior of stock market prices, e.g., (Fama 1965; Smith 2002; Borges 2011), interest rates, e.g., (Pesando 1979; Newell and Pizer 2003; Bacchetta and van Wincoop 2007), growth and inequality, e.g., (Scalas 2006), etc. The random walk-based stochastic process is equivalent to a Brownian motion, and formally it is a Wiener process, named after Norbert Wiener’s work in the early 1920s (Shafer and Vovk 2001). In general, a Brownian motion is any process S of the form:
S(t) = μt + σW(t)
with μ ∊ R and σ ≧ 0.
Based on the general random walk model, the growth rate α in period (t) is estimated as follows:
αtot(t) = θ(0) + kt + εt
where αtot(t) is the total growth rate of WTP at time t.
  • θ(0) is the sum of αinc + αsc at time 0.
  • k is the drift that reflects future preferences.
  • εt is a random component estimated by σW(t).
Since the growth rate of WTP is a continuous process dependent on its rate of change and time, it can be expressed as dependent on the differential change in the rate, i.e., it has to rewritten as a differential process:
tot(t) = kdt + σdW(t)
Hence, tot(t) is normally distributed with mean kt and standard deviation σ.
In order to implement the model, the following parameters should be empirically established:
  • The income elasticity of WTP (ω)
  • The income or growth rate (g) on an annual basis
  • The WTP elasticity of demand (λ)
  • The environmental depletion rate (q) on an annual basis
  • The preferences factor (αpr), which is expressed by k
  • The volatility (σ) for the stochastic term
The elasticities ω and λ can be obtained from existing non-market valuation studies, while the preferences factor is defined ad hoc (i.e., it depends on the scenario set by the analyst). To facilitate this selection, it is suggested to express the evolution of preferences using the ratio WTPT/WTPT0, i.e., to make an arbitrary selection about the future WTP value (WTPT). Having defined WTPT0 and WTPT, the average preferences factor is estimated as follows:
k = 1 T T 0 l n W T P T 0 W T P T
Similarly, in order to calculate the annual environmental depletion rate, q, the analyst may use the ratio ΔQ = QT/QT0, which expresses the expected decrease (or increase) in the quality or quantity of the environmental good or service under investigation, according to the following equation:
q = 1 T T 0 l n Q T 0 Q T
Finally, the volatility, σ, in similar models, is usually estimated using historical data series, e.g., (Newell and Pizer 2003). Nevertheless, in case of data unavailability, a different approach may be implemented by means of Monte Carlo simulation, as described in Section 4.

4. An Illustrative Example

4.1. Input Parameters

For illustrative purposes, we choose to estimate the effect of growth rate αtot between 2015 and 2050 to the WTP values of European temperate and boreal forests. To this end, the Ecosystem Service Value Database is used (van der Ploeg and de Groot 2010; de Groot et al. 2012). The original estimates of the database (Table 1) are converted into Euros in 2015 prices following Pattanayak et al. (2002) and using the purchasing power parity index (PPPI) and consumer price index (CPI) by the World Bank (2015) and OECD (2015). The mean, minimum and maximum values obtained by the database per ha and per year in Euros2015 are 922, 0.9 and 9345, respectively.
As regards the income elasticity of WTP, based on the results of the literature review discussed in Section 3.1, a central (i.e., likeliest) estimate of 0.7 was adopted. Moreover, for conducting sensitivity and probabilistic analyses the minimum and maximum values were taken equal to 0.1 and 1, correspondingly.
In order to estimate the annual growth rate, estimates from international organizations were taken into consideration, e.g., (OECD 2012a; PricewaterhouseCoopers 2015). For the purposes of our illustrative example, our model assumes an average rate of 2.0% per annum for European countries.
For the “environmental” elasticity of WTP, an average unitary elasticity (−1) was considered as the base value for the estimates according to empirical surveys (see Section 3.1). Furthermore, a minimum value of −2.3 and a maximum value of −0.5 were considered for sensitivity purposes.
The estimation of the environmental depletion rate was performed, taking into consideration the main findings from the study of OECD about the evolution of the biodiversity until 2050 (OECD 2012b). The projection for the case of the mature forests (primary forest) foresees a steady decrease until 2050 in all the examined regions within the framework of the baseline scenario. Specifically, the reduction of the primary forest area in OECD countries is expected to be approximately 14%.
Provided that future preferences are unknown, three different behavioral scenarios were examined, as follows:
  • Scenario A: Unchanged preferences. In this case the ratio WTP2050/WTP2015 equals to 1 and, consequently, the average (annual) preferences factor is zero.
  • Scenario B: Green preferences. In this case the ratio WTP2050/WTP2015 is assumed to be 2 and, consequently, the annual preferences factor is 1.98%.
  • Scenario C: Materialistic preferences. In this case the ratio WTP2050/WTP2015 is assumed to be 0.5 and, consequently, the annual preferences factor is −1.98%.
As mentioned, the volatility factor, σ, is a challenging issue contrary to the volatility of financial options, which is based on available historical information. In our case, the management assumption approach was employed (Mun 2006) using Monte Carlo simulations. In total, 1000 possible future growth rate αtot values were estimated starting in 2015 and extending 35 years into the future, i.e., up to 2050. In order to represent the wider range of uncertainty that affects future growth rate, the Maximum Entropy theory was employed (Shannon 1948; Jaynes 1957; Gay and Estrada 2010). Since minimum, maximum, and mode values were known, the triangular distribution that maximizes the entropy was chosen (Harr 1987; quoted in Mishra 2002). Regarding environmental depletion, a uniform distribution was adopted for the ratio ΔQ = Q2050/Q2015 with min and max values equal to 70% and 110%, respectively. According to the analysis, the volatility σ was estimated at 20%.

4.2. Present Value of WTP Ignoring αtot

As a first step toward highlighting the effect of growth rate αtot on future WTP values, the present value (PV) of the recreational value of 1 ha of forestland for the period 2015–2050 is estimated. To this direction, the original (i.e., today’s) value remains constant (i.e., the estimates are in constant prices) and equals to 922 €2015. The PV of annual WTP recreational values per ha of forest land is estimated according to the following equation:
P V t o t = t = 0 35 W T P t ( 1 + s ) t
where
  • PVtot is the total present value of WTP for recreation per ha of forest land (i.e., 922 €2015).
  • WTPt is the annual WTP for recreation per ha of forest land at time t.
  • s is the social discount rate.
  • t is the time in years.
An extensive discussion around the selection of the social discount rate is beyond the scope of this report. For illustrative purposes, a discount rate of 3.5% is adopted, as suggested by UK Treasury (H.M. Treasury 2003). Using the central estimate of 922 €2015, the PVtot for recreation per ha of forestland is estimated at19,360 €2015.
Furthermore, in order to quantify variability due to the range of existing WTP estimates, a typical approach to probabilistic modeling, i.e., Monte Carlo simulation, is used. In this Monte Carlo simulation, a model is run repeatedly 1000 times, using WTP2015 as input parameter. The triangular probability distribution is constructed again according to the Maximum Entropy approach using likeliest, minimum, and maximum WTP values equal to 922, 0.9 and 9.45 €2015 per ha and per year, respectively.
According to the probabilistic simulation, the mean PV of WTP, ignoring the growth rate αtot, is approximately 72,200 €2015, ranging between 1550 and 194,600 €2015. Detailed results are presented in Table 2 and Table 3.

4.3. Present Value of WTP Considering αtot

4.3.1. Scenario A: Unchanged Preferences

According to Scenario A, the preferences remain unchanged during the time period considered. Nevertheless, WTP values are influenced by the growth of income and decrease in the area of primary forests. The former is captured in the model by αinc and the latter is expressed by αsc. In this particular Scenario, αpr is zero. The values used in the base-case estimates are WTP2015 = 922 €; αinc = 1.40% (which is estimated assuming an average growth rate of 2% per year and income elasticity of 0.7); and αsc = 0.46% (which is estimated assuming an average depletion rate of 0.46% per year and ‘environmental’ elasticity of WTP of −1).
Given that the model is based on a stochastic random walk process, 100 repetitions were made to estimate the mean PV. It is noted that in this case, contrary to the Monte Carlo simulation, the values of WTP, αinc and αsc remain constant. Thus, the results are only affected by the random component of the model, which is estimated by σW(t). Figure 1a illustrates 10 of the 100 random walks conducted during the modeling process for αtot and Figure 1b illustrates the corresponding WTP values.
The mean random walk-based PV of WTP for the Scenario A is around 26,190 €2015. The minimum and maximum PV of WTP estimates are 20,500 and 54,800 €2015, respectively. In order to consider simultaneously the variability due to the range of WTP2015 estimates and the uncertainty related to αtot, 1000 Monte Carlo simulations were run for WTP2015, ω and λ. The results of the Monte Carlo simulation are presented in Table 2 and Table 3.
In addition, a sensitivity analysis was carried out to explore the influence of input parameters on the PV of WTP. According to the sensitivity analysis, the most critical parameter is the WTP2015 value, followed by the ω.

4.3.2. Scenario B: Green Preferences

According to Scenario B, the preferences become greener during the coming decades. Thus, WTP values are influenced by the growth of income, the decrease in the area of primary forests, and the green preferences of the individuals, which are captured in the model by αinc, αsc and αpr. The values used in the base-case estimates are WTP2015 = 922 €; αinc = 1.40%; αsc =0.46%; and αpr = 1.98% (this value is estimated assuming a ratio of WTP2050/WTP2015 equal to 2).
Similar to the process followed in the case of the Scenario A, 100 repetitions were made to estimate the mean PV, keeping the values of WTP, αinc, αsc and αpr constant; thus, the estimates are only affected by the random component of the model. Figure 2a,b illustrate ten of the random walks for the αtot and the corresponding WTP values for Scenario B, respectively.
The mean PV of WTP for Scenario B, derived by the random walk model, is around 41,830 €2015, and the minimum and maximum estimates are 22,700 and 230,300 €2015, respectively. Again, Monte Carlo simulation was used to quantify the variability due to the range of exiting WTP estimates and the uncertainty related to αtot model parameters, i.e., WTP2015, ω, λ, and the WTP2050/WTP2015 ratio. The results of the Monte Carlo simulation are presented in Table 2 and Table 3.
According to the sensitivity analysis results, the most critical parameter is the WTP2015 value, followed by the WTP2050/WTP2015 ratio, and the ω.

4.3.3. Scenario C: Materialistic Preferences

According to Scenario C, society becomes more materialistic up to 2050. In this scenario, the values used in the base-case estimates are: WTP2015 = 922 €; αinc = 1.40%; αsc = 0.46%; and αpr = −1.98% (this value is estimated assuming ratio WTP2050/WTP2015 equal to 0.5).
Similarly to the process followed in the case of Scenarios A and B, the mean random walk-based PV of WTP for the Scenario C is around 19,050 Euros2015, and the minimum and maximum estimates are 18,500 and 19,300 €2015, respectively. Figure 3a presents ten random walks for αtot and Figure 3b shows the corresponding WTP values for Scenario C.
Monte Carlo simulations and sensitivity analyses were carried out to investigate the effect of WTP2015, ω, λ, and WTP2050/WTP2015 ratio. Detailed results are illustrated in Table 2 and Table 3. Similar to the sensitivity analysis results for Scenario B, the most critical parameter is the WTP2015 value, followed by the WTP2050/WTP2015 ratio and the ω.

4.4. Discussion of Results

Table 2 and Table 3 present results of the analysis with and without the effect of growth rate αtot.
In all scenarios studied, the probabilistic assessment results in higher estimates than the deterministic analysis. The disparities between the deterministic estimates and the probabilistic simulations are attributed primarily to the wide range of WTP2015 values, i.e., between 0.9 and 9345 €2015 per ha/per year, which may be attributed to the preference uncertainty of the current generation.
The effect of total growth rate αtot on the estimated PV of WTP is significant, even when preferences are assumed to remain constant. This is evident when comparing the results presented in Section 4.2 with those of obtained in Section 4.3.1 (i.e., the Scenario A). The mean (probabilistic) PV of WTP for Scenario A (i.e., 94,000 €2015) is 30% higher than the one estimated when ignoring the growth rate αtot (i.e., around 72,200 €2015). The effect of total growth rate αtot is even more apparent when changes in the preferences of individuals are involved in the stochastic model. For instance, in the case of green preferences (i.e., Scenario B), the mean (probabilistic) PV of WTP is around 132,000 €2015, which is almost twice the PV estimated when ignoring the growth rate αtot.
The comparison of the estimates for the three Scenarios A, B, and C reveals the importance of considering the effect of evolving preferences, especially in long-term analyses. In fact, all other parameters being equal, the estimated PV of WTP is quite different for constant preferences, green preferences, and materialistic preferences. More specifically, the PV of WTP for the scenario of constant preferences (i.e., Scenario A) is about 35% higher than the estimated PV for the case of materialistic preferences (i.e., Scenario C), and about 30% lower than the PV estimated for the case of green preferences (i.e., Scenario B). More importantly, the comparison between the estimates of Scenarios B and C highlights the significance of the assumptions adopted regarding the evolution of preferences in the next decades. To wit, the PV estimated for Scenario B is around 85% higher than the corresponding value of Scenario C. This finding is worrisome considering future preferences are unknown. Therefore, potential behavioral patterns should be considered in climate change policy analyses, at least for sensitivity purposes.

5. Conclusions

Current methodological tools assume that there exists a perfect substitutability between market and non-market goods and that values related to environment remain unchanged. Consequently, in almost all IAMs assessments and “bottom-up” cost-benefit studies related to climate change policies, analysts take for granted that the preferences of current and future generations are fixed and given. However, this is far from the truth, especially when it comes to the valuation of environmental amenities. Ignoring changes in non-market values could (a) result in logical inconsistencies between the assumptions on future emissions and climate conditions, and the inputs of policy evaluation and optimization models; (b) lead to failure to recognize the influence of socioeconomic parameters in climate change policy; and finally (c) hinder the implementation of effective policies by distorting the damage assessment results. These issues are critical for accurate climate change economic assessments and timely policy responses.
As a first step toward handling the uncertainty in preferences with a focus on the value of non-market environmental goods and services, a robust methodology is proposed. More explicitly, a number of parameters, such as the growth of income, the depletion of environmental assets, the elasticity of income and demand, and the change in preferences towards the environment, are combined to a general random walk-based stochastic process that simulates uncertainty in the growth rate of the WTP values for environmental goods or services. By doing so, the model allows the analyst to visualize future paths of preference evolutions and to bring future values of damaged non-market assets realistically to the fore. For instance, the illustrative comparisons between Scenarios B and C show that—depending on the specific evolution of preferences—the resulting estimates may differ substantially (more than 80%). Thus, at least for sensitivity purposes, it is crucial to consider the change in behavioral patterns over time.
Nevertheless, much work needs to be done in future research. Embedding the model into Share Socioeconomic Pathways (SSPs) would add to the completeness and reliability of climate change economic assessments. This, of course, means that linkages between climate scenarios and the parameters of α should be created by developing separate modules in existing IAMs or other models, considering socioeconomic and environmental drivers of climate change. For instance, Drupp and Hänsel (2018) examined the effect of the scarcity of non-market on the economic appraisal of climate policy by calibrating DICE based on empirical evidence and performed a comprehensive analysis of the change in relative prices of non-market goods. They showed that neglecting relative prices changes leads to an underestimation of the social cost of carbon, in 2020, of more than 40%, which is equivalent to a decrease in pure time preference by more than a half percentage point. The proposed random-walk model of growth rate, α, could be also incorporated in modern valuation tools offering flexibility in decision making, such as Real Options. Recently, Real Options analysis (ROA) is recognized as a promising approach for assessing climate change adaptation strategies, e.g., (H.M. Treasury 2009; World Bank 2009, 2011). The use of ROA, however, to appraise adaptation actions is so far limited, e.g., (Hertzler 2007; Woodward et al. 2011; Linquiti and Vonortas 2012; Kontogianni et al. 2013). In a more theoretical context, the social discount rate, say s, could be replaced by the “environmental” discount rate (sα) proposed by Fisher and Krutilla (1975). In fact, it is important to examine which existing discounting practices could implicitly cover some of the ground that the paper proposes, e.g., choosing discount parameters according to reasonable assumptions of increased scarcity of environmental assets, e.g., (Gollier and Weitzman 2010; Hoel and Sterner 2007; Traeger 2011). For example, Baumgärtner et al. (2015) using empirical data for ten ecosystem services across five countries, estimated the difference between the discount rates for ecosystem services and for manufactured consumption goods. They concluded that, on global average, ecosystem services should be discounted at a rate that is 0.9 ± 0.3%-points lower than the one for manufactured consumption goods. To the same direction, Gollier (2017) mentions that uncertainty related to the substitutability of ecosystem services in the future makes the investment in natural capital risky and tends to raise this discount rate. Yet, he concludes that this result is misleading because the uncertainty affects the growth rate of expected benefits, as well. The latter issue dominates the negative discounting effect, so that the economic value of natural capital is always increased. Finally, future work could also focus on refining the proposed model for market goods, as well. In this way, the model could be used in different application domains where it is required to explore possible futures.
The reliability of the model depends on the reliability of input data (elasticities of demand and income, projected growth rate of world economies, etc.), which means that the uncertainties do not vanish. But, to quote Keynes “it is better to be roughly right than precisely wrong”.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.S.; Data curation, A.K. and C.T.; Methodology, D.D.; Writing—original draft, M.S., D.D. and A.H.; Writing—review & editing, M.S., A.K., C.T. and A.H.

Funding

This research was funded by the Seventh Framework Programme of the European Commission through the ECONADAPT Collaborative Project (Economics of climate change adaptation in Europe) (Contract No. 603906).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Ackerman, Frank, and Elizabeth A. Stanton. 2013. Climate Economics. The State of the Art. Oxford and New York: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  2. Anderson, Mark W., Mario Teisl, and Caroline Noblet. 2012. Giving voice to the future in sustainability: Retrospective assessment to learn prospective stakeholder engagement. Ecological Economics 84: 1–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Arbués, Fernando, María Ángeles García-Valiñas, and Roberto Martínez-Espiñeira. 2003. Estimation of residential water demand: A state-of-the-art review. Journal of Socio-Economics 32: 81–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Arrow, Kenneth J., William R. Cline, Karl-Goran Maler, Mohan Munasinghe, Ray Squitier, and Joseph E. Stiglitz. 1996. Intertemporal equity, discounting, and economic efficiency. In Climate Change 1995: Economic and Social Dimensions of Climate Change, Contribution of Working Group III to the Second Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Edited by James P. Bruce, Hoesung Lee and Erik F. Haites. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  5. Le Kama, Alain Ayong, and Katheline Schubert. 2004. Growth, Environment and Uncertain Future Preferences. Environmental and Resource Economics 28: 31–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric Van Wincoop. 2007. Random walk expectations and the forward discount puzzle. American Economic Review 97: 346–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Balint, Tomas, Francesco Lamperti, Antoine Mandel, Mauro Napoletano, Andrea Roventini, and Alessandro Sapio. 2017. Complexity and the Economics of Climate Change: A Survey and a Look Forward. Ecological Economics 138: 252–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Barbier, Edward B., Stefan Baumgärtner, Kanchan Chopra, Christopher Costello, Anantha Duraiappah, Rashid Hassan, Ann Kinzig, Markus Lehman, Unai Pascual, Stephen Polasky, and et al. 2009. The valuation of ecosystem services, Chapter 18. In Biodiversity, Ecosystem Functioning, and Human Wellbeing: An Ecological and Economic Perspective. Edited by Shahid Naeem, Daniel E. Bunker, Andy Hector, Michel Loreau and Charles Perrings. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 248–62. [Google Scholar]
  9. Baum, Seth D., and William E. Easterling. 2010. Space-time discounting in climate change adaptation. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 15: 591–609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Baumgärtner, Stefan, Alexandra Klein, Denise Thiel, and Klara Winkler. 2015. Ramsey Discounting of Ecosystem Services. Environmental and Resource Economics 61: 273–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bergstrom, Theodore C., and Robert P. Goodman. 1973. Private demands for public goods. American Economic Review 63: 280–96. [Google Scholar]
  12. Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson. 2019. The Dynamics of Environmental Politics and Values. Journal of the European Economics Association 17: 993–1024. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Borcherding, Thomas, and Robert Deacon. 1972. Demand for services of non-federal governments. American Economic Review 62: 891–901. [Google Scholar]
  14. Borges, Maria Rosa. 2011. Random walk tests for the Lisbon stock market. Applied Economics 43: 631–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Bosello, Francesco. 2014. The role of economic modelling for climate change mitigation and adaptation strategies. In Routledge Handbook of the Economics of Climate Change Adaptation. Edited by Anil Markandya, Ibon Galarraga and Elisa Sainz de Murieta. Abingdon: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  16. Boyd, James, and Spencer Banzhaf. 2007. What are ecosystem services? The need for standardized environmental accounting units. Ecological Economics 63: 616–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Cline, William R. 1992. The Economics of Global Warming. Washington: Institute for International Economics. [Google Scholar]
  18. Dalhuisen, Jasper M., Raymond J. G. M. Florax, Henri L. F. de Groot, and Peter Nijkamp. 2003. Price and income elasticities of residential water demand: A meta-analysis. Land Economics 79: 292–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Dasgupta, Partha. 2008. Discounting climate change. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 37: 141–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Dasgupta, Partha, and Eric Maskin. 2005. Uncertainty and hyperbolic discounting. American Economic Review 95: 1290–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Dasgupta, Partha, Karl-Göran Mäler, and Scott Barrett. 1999. Intergenerational equity, social discount rates, and global warming. In Discounting and Intergenerational Equity. Edited by Paul R. Portney and John P. Weyant. Washington: Resources for the Future. [Google Scholar]
  22. de Groot, Rudolf, Luke Brander, Sander van der Ploeg, Robert Costanza, Florence Bernard, Leon Braat, Mike Christie, Neville Crossman, Andrea Ghermandi, Lars Hein, and et al. 2012. Global estimates of the value of ecosystems and their services in monetary units. Ecosystem Services 1: 50–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Drupp, Moritz A., and Martin C. Hänsel. 2018. Relative Prices and Climate Policy: How the Scarcity of Non-Market Goods Drives Policy Evaluation. Economics Working Papers 2018-01. Kiel: Christian-Albrechts-University of Kiel, Department of Economics, Available online: https://www.econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/174361/1/1012760782.pdf (accessed on 15 December 2015).
  24. Fama, Elugene F. 1965. Random walks in stock market prices. Financial Analysts Journal 21: 55–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Fisher, Anthony C., and John V. Krutilla. 1975. Resource conservation, environmental preservation, and the rate of discount. Quarterly Journal of Economics 89: 358–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Fisher, Brendan, R. Kerry Turner, and Paul Morling. 2009. Defining and classifying ecosystem services for decision making. Ecological Economics 68: 643–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Flores, Nicholas E., and Richard T. Carson. 1997. The Relationship between the Income Elasticities of Demand and Willingness to Pay. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 33: 287–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Freeman, Myrick, III. 2003. The Measurement of Environmental and Resource Values: Theory and Methods, 2nd ed.Washington: Resources for the Future. [Google Scholar]
  29. Gay, Carlos, and Francisco Estrada. 2010. Objective probabilities about future climate are a matter of opinion. Climatic Change 99: 27–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Gollier, Christian. 2007. Comment intégrer le risque dans le calcul économique. Revue d’ Économie Politique 117: 209–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Gollier, Christian. 2008. Discounting with fat-tailed economic growth. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 37: 171–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Gollier, Christian. 2017. Valuation of Natural Capital Under Uncertain Substitutability. TSE Working Paper No. TSE−813. Available online: http://publications.ut-capitole.fr/24094/1/Gollier_24094.pdf (accessed on 12 December 2015).
  33. Gollier, Christian, and Martin L. Weitzman. 2010. How Should the Distant Future be Discounted When Discount Rates are Uncertain? Economics Letters 107: 350–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Goulder, Lawrence H., and Donald Kennedy. 1997. Valuing ecosystem: Philosophical bases and empirical methods. In Nature’s Services: Societal Dependence on Natural Ecosystems. Edited by Gretchen. C. Daily. Washington: Island Press, pp. 23–48. [Google Scholar]
  35. Gravelle, Hugh, and Dave Smith. 2000. Discounting for Health Effects in Cost Benefit and Cost Effectiveness Analysis. Centre for Health Economics Technical Paper Series 20. York: University of York. [Google Scholar]
  36. Groom, Ben, Cameron Hepburn, Phoebe Koundouri, and David Pearce. 2005. Declining discount rates: The long and the short of it. Environmental and Resource Economics 32: 445–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Grüne-Yanoff, Till, and Sven Ove Hansson. 2009. Preference Change. Approaches from Philosophy, Economics and Psychology. Heidelber: Springer. [Google Scholar]
  38. H.M. Treasury. 2003. The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government. London: The Stationery Office. [Google Scholar]
  39. H.M. Treasury. 2009. Accounting for the Effects of Climate Change: Supplementary Green Book Guidance. Available online: https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/ system/uploads/attachment_data/file/191501/Accounting_for_the_effects_of_climate_change.pdf (accessed on 17 December 2015).
  40. Harr, Milton E. 1987. Reliability-Based Design in Civil Engineering. New York: McGraw-Hill. [Google Scholar]
  41. Heal, G. 2009. The economics of climate change: A post-Stern perspective. Climatic Change 96: 275–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hein, Lars, Kris van Koppen, Rudolf S. de Groot, and Ekko C. van Ierland. 2006. Spatial scales, stakeholders and the valuation of ecosystem services. Ecological Economics 57: 209–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hertzler, Greg. 2007. Adapting to Climate Change and Managing Climate Risks by Using Real Options. Australian Journal of Agricultural Research 58: 985–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Hewitt, Julie A., and W. Michael Hanemann. 1995. A Discrete-continuous Choice Approach to Residential Water Demand under Block Rate Pricing. Land Economics 71: 173–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Hoel, Michael, and Thomas Sterner. 2007. Discounting and relative prices. Climatic Change 84: 265–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Hof, Andries F., Chris W. Hope, Jason Lowe, Michael D. Mastrandrea, Malte Meinshausen, and Detlef P. van Vuuren. 2012. The benefits of climate change mitigation in integrated assessment models: The role of the carbon cycle and climate component. Climatic Change 113: 897–917. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Hökby, Stina, and Tore Söderqvist. 2003. Elasticities of Demand and Willingness to Pay for Environmental Services in Sweden. Environmental and Resource Economics 26: 361–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Horowitz, John K. 2002. Preferences in the future. Environmental and Resource Economics 21: 241–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Hotelling, Harold. 1931. The Economics of Exhaustible Resources. Journal of Political Economy 39: 139–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Hultman, Magnus, Azadeh Kazeminia, and Vahid Ghasemi. 2015. Intention to visit and willingness to pay premium for ecotourism: The impact of attitude, materialism, and motivation. Journal of Business Research 68: 1854–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Jacobsen, Jette Bredahl, and Nick Hanley. 2009. Are there income effects on global willingness to pay for biodiversity conservation? Environmental and Resource Economics 43: 137–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Jacobsen, Jette Bredahl, Thomas Hedemark Lundhede, and Bo Jellesmark Thorsen. 2013. The effects of current income and expected change in future income on stated preferences for environmental improvements. Journal of Forest Economics 19: 206–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Janssen, Marco A., and Wander Jager. 2001. Fashions, habits and changing preferences: Simulation of psychological factors affecting market dynamics. Journal of Economic Psychology 22: 745–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Jaynes, Edwin T. 1957. Information theory and statistical mechanics. The Physical Review 106: 620–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Kaplow, Louis, and David Weisbach. 2011. Discount rates, social judgments, individuals’ risk preferences, and uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 42: 125–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Kidd, Quentin, and Aie-Rie Lee. 1997. Postmaterialist values and the environment: A critique and reappraisal. Social Science Quarterly 78: 1–15. [Google Scholar]
  57. Kilbourne, William, and Gregory Pickett. 2008. How materialism affects environmental beliefs, concern, and environmentally responsible behavior. Journal of Business Research 61: 885–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Kontogianni, Areti, Gary W. Luck, and Michalis Skourtos. 2010. Valuing ecosystem services on the basis of service-providing units: A promising solution to the ‘endpoint problem’ in stated preference approaches. Ecological Economics 69: 1479–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Kontogianni, Areti, Christos H. Tourkolias, Dimitris Damigos, and Michalis Skourtos. 2013. Assessing sea level rise costs and adaptation benefits under uncertainty in Greece. Environmental Science & Policy 37: 61–78. [Google Scholar]
  60. Kopp, Robert E., and Bryan K. Mignone. 2012. The U.S. government’s social cost of carbon estimates after their first two years: Pathways for improvement. Economics 6: 2012–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Kriström, Bengt, and Pere Riera. 1996. Is the income elasticity of environmental improvements less than one? Environmental & Resource Economics 7: 45–55. [Google Scholar]
  62. Krysiak, Frank C., and Daniela Krysiak. 2006. Sustainability with Uncertain Future Preferences. Environmental & Resource Economics 33: 511–31. [Google Scholar]
  63. Lamb, Laura. 2019. Changing preferences for environmental protection: Evidence from volunteer behaviour. International Review of Applied Economics 33: 384–401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Lebègue, Danièl, Philippe Hirtzman, and Luc. Baumstark. 2005. Commissariat Général du Plan, Le prix du Temps et la Décision Publique: Révision du Taux d’Actualisation Public. Paris: Documentation Française. [Google Scholar]
  65. Lee, Christine, Claire Schlemme, Jessica Murray, and Robert Unsworth. 2015. The cost of climate change: Ecosystem services and wildland fires. Ecological Economics 116: 261–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Linquiti, Peter, and Nicholas Vonortas. 2012. The value of flexibility in adapting to climate change: A real options analysis of investments in coastal defense. Climate Change Economics 3: 1250008-1/28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Loewenstein, George, and David Schkade. 2003. Wouldn’t it be nice? Predicting future feelings. In Foundations of Hedonic Psychology: Scientific Perspectives on Enjoyment and Suffering. Edited by Daniel Kahneman, Ed Diener and Norbert Schwarz. New York: Russell Sage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
  68. MacInnis, Deborah J., Vanessa M. Patrick, and Choong Whan Park. 2005. Looking through the crystal ball: The role of affective forecasting and misforecasting in consumer behaviour. Review of Marketing Research 2: 43–79. [Google Scholar]
  69. Martini, Chiara, and Silvia Tiezzi. 2014. Is the environment a luxury? An empirical investigation using revealed preferences and household production. Resource and Energy Economics 37: 147–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Masur, Jonathan S., and Eric A. Posner. 2011. Climate regulation and the limits of cost-benefit analysis. California Law Review 99: 1557–600. [Google Scholar]
  71. Metcalf, Gilbert, and James Stock. 2015. The Role of Integrated Assessment Models in Climate Policy: A User’s Guide and Assessment; Discussion Paper 2015-68. Cambridge: Harvard Project on Climate Agreements. Available online: http://belfercenter.ksg.harvard.edu/files/dp68_metcalf-stock.pdf (accessed on 5 January 2016).
  72. Mishra, Srikanta. 2002. Assigning Probability Distributions to Input Parameters of Performance Assessment Models. SKB Technical Report TR-02-11. Stockholm: Svensk Kärnbränslehantering AB. [Google Scholar]
  73. Mun, Johnathan. 2006. Real Options Analysis—Tools and Techniques for Valuing Strategic Investments and Decisions, 2nd ed.Hoboken: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. [Google Scholar]
  74. Neumayer, Eric. 1999. Global warming: Discounting is not the issue, but substitutability is. Energy Policy 27: 33–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Newell, Richard G., and William A. Pizer. 2003. Discounting the distant future: How much do uncertain rates increase valuations? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 46: 52–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Noblet, Caroline L., Mark W. Anderson, and Mario F. Teisl. 2015. Thinking past and thinking future: An empirical test of the effects of retrospective assessment on future preferences. Ecological Economics 114: 180–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Nordhaus, William D. 1997. Discounting in economics and climatic change: An editorial comment. Climate Change 37: 315–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Nordhaus, William D. 2007. The Stern Review on the economics of climate change. Journal of Economic Literature 45: 686–702. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Nunes, Paulo A. L. D., and Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh. 2001. Economic Valuation of Biodiversity: Sense or Nonsense? Ecological Economics 39: 203–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. O’Neill, Brian. 2010. Multi-century scenario development and socioeconomic uncertainty. In Improving the Assessment and Valuation of Climate Change Impacts for Policy and Regulatory Analysis: Modeling Climate Change Impacts and Associated Economic Damages; Washington: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency and U.S. Department of Energy. Available online: https://yosemite.epa.gov/ee/epa/eerm.nsf/vwAN/EE-0564-115.pdf/$file/EE-0564-115.pdf (accessed on 30 November 2015).
  81. OECD. 2012a. Medium and Long-Term Scenarios for Global Growth and Imbalances; OECD Economic Outlook 2012. Paris: OECD. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/berlin/50405107.pdf (accessed on 5 December 2015).
  82. OECD. 2012b. Environmental Outlook to 2050: The Consequences of Inaction. Key Findings on Biodiversity; Paris: OECD. Available online: http://www.oecd.org/env/indicators-modelling-outlooks/biodiversitychapteroftheoecdenvironmentaloutlookto2050theconsequencesofinaction.htm (accessed on 5 December 2015).
  83. OECD. 2015. Inflation (CPI). Paris: OECD, Available online: https://data.oecd.org/price/inflation-cpi.htm (accessed on 5 December 2015).
  84. Parry, Martin, Nigel Arnell, Tony McMichael, Robert Nicholls, Pim Martens, Sari Kovats, Matthew Livermore, Cynthia Rosenzweig, Ana Iglesias, and Gunther Fischer. 2001. Millions at risk: Defining critical climate change threats and targets. Global Environmental Change-Human and Policy Dimensions 11: 181–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Pattanayak, Subhrendu K., Julia M. Wing, Brooks M. Depro, George Van Houtven, Paul De Civita, David M. Stieb, and Bryan Hubbell. 2002. International Health Benefits Transfer Application Tool: The Use of PPP and Inflation Indices. Final Report, Prepared for Economic Analysis and Evaluation Division, Office of Policy Coordination and Economic Analysis Policy and Planning Directorate, Healthy Environments and Consumer Safety Branch. Ottawa: Health Canada. [Google Scholar]
  86. Pearce, David. 2003. Conceptual Framework for Analysing the Distributive Impacts of Environmental Policies. Paper presented at the OECD Environment Directorate Workshop on the Distribution of Benefits and Costs of Environmental Policies, Paris, France, March 4–5. [Google Scholar]
  87. Pesando, James. 1979. On the random walk characteristics of short- and long-term interest rates in an efficient market. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 11: 457–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Pindyck, Robert S. 2013. Climate Change Policy: What Do the Models Tell Us? Journal of Economic Literature 51: 860–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Pingali, Prabhu, Anaka Aiyar, Mathew Abraham, and Andaleeb Rahman. 2019. Managing climate change risks in food systems. In Transforming Food Systems for a Rising India. Palgrave Studies in Agricultural Economics and Food Policy. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan. [Google Scholar]
  90. Pint, Ellen M. 1999. Household Responses to Increased Water Rates during the California Drought. Land Economics 75: 246–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. PricewaterhouseCoopers. 2015. The World in 2050—Will the Shift in Global Economic Power Continue? Available online: https://www.pwc.com/gx/en/issues/the-economy/assets/world-in-2050-february-2015.pdf (accessed on 15 December 2015).
  92. Rosenberger, R. Randall S., and Tom D. Stanley. 2010. Publication Selection of Recreation Demand Price Elasticity: A Meta-Analysis. Available online: https://www.hendrix.edu/uploadedFiles/Departments_and_Programs/Business_and_Economics/AMAES/MAER%202010%20AR%20Rosenberger%20Stanley%20090110.pdf (accessed on 17 December 2015).
  93. Scalas, Enrico. 2006. The application of continuous-time random walks in finance and economics. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 362: 225–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Scarborough, Helen. 2010. Decomposing the social discount rate. Paper presented at the AARES Conference, Adelaide, Australia, February 10–12; Available online: http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/59156/2/Scarborough,%20Helen.pdf (accessed on 30 November 2015).
  95. Shafer, Glenn, and Vladimir Vovk. 2001. Game Theoretic Probability in Finance. In Probability and Finance: It’s Only a Game! New York: Wiley, pp. 201–36. [Google Scholar]
  96. Shannon, Claude E. 1948. A mathematical theory of communication. The Bell System Technical Journal 27: 379–423, 623–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Smith, Graham. 2002. Tests of the Random Walk Hypothesis for London Gold Prices. Applied Economics Letters 9: 671–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Stern, Nicholas H. 2008. The economics of climate change. American Economic Review 98: 1–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. Stern, Nicholas H., and Cabinet Office—HM Treasury. 2007. The Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  100. Sterner, Thomas, and U. Martin Persson. 2008. An Even Sterner Review: Introducing Relative Prices into the Discounting Debate. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 2: 61–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  101. Summers, Lawrence, and Richard Zeckhauser. 2008. Policymaking for posterity. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 37: 115–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. TEEB. 2010. The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity: Ecological and Economic Foundation. London: Earthscan. [Google Scholar]
  103. Thomas, John F., and Geoffrey J. Syme. 1988. Estimating residential price elasticity of demand for water: A contingent valuation approach. Water Resources Research 24: 1847–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Thunström, Linda, Jonas Nordström, and Jason F. Shogren. 2015. Certainty and overconfidence in future preferences for food. Journal of Economic Psychology 51: 101–13. [Google Scholar]
  105. Traeger, Christian P. 2007. Theoretical Aspects of Long-Term Evaluation in Environmental Economics. Ph.D. thesis, University of Heidelberg, Heidelberg, Germany, October 27. Available online: http://www.ub.uni-heidelberg.de/archiv/7049 (accessed on 12 December 2015).
  106. Traeger, Christian P. 2011. Sustainability, limited substitutability, and non-constant social discount rates. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 62: 215–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Vale, Petterson Molina. 2016. The changing climate of climate change economics. Ecological Economics 121: 12–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. van der Ploeg, Sander, and Rudolf S. de Groot. 2010. The TEEB Valuation Database—A Searchable Database of 1310 Estimates of Monetary Values of Ecosystem Services. Wageningen: Foundation for Sustainable Development. [Google Scholar]
  109. van Vuuren, Detlef P., Jason Lowe, Elke Stehfest, Laila Gohar, Andries F. Hof, Chris Hope, Rachel Warren, Malte Meinshausen, and Gian-Kasper Plattner. 2011. How well do integrated assessment models simulate climate change? Climatic Change 104: 255–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  110. Warren, Rachel, Michael Mastrandrea, Chris Hope, and Andries Hof. 2010. Variation in the climatic response to SRES emissions scenarios in integrated assessment models. Climatic Change 102: 671–785. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Watkiss, Paul, and Chris Hope. 2011. Using the social cost of carbon in regulatory deliberations. WIREs Climate Change 2: 886–901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Weisbach, David A., and Cass R. Sunstein. 2008. Climate Change and Discounting the Future: A Guide for the Perplexed. Harvard Law School Program on Risk Regulation Research Paper No. 08-12. Washington: AEI Center for Regulatory and Market Studies. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Weitzman, Martin L. 2007. A Review of the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change. Journal of Economic Literature 45: 703–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Woodward, Merrilyn, Ben Gouldby, Zoran Kapelan, Soon-Thiam Khu, and Ian Townend. 2011. Real options in flood risk management decision making. Journal of Flood Risk Management 4: 339–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. World Bank. 2009. Mainstreaming Adaptation to Climate Change in Agriculture and Natural Resources Management Projects, Guidance Note 7, Annex 12. Environment Department. Available online: http://climatechange.worldbank.org/climatechange/content/note-7-evaluate-adaptation-economic-analysis (accessed on 5 December 2015).
  116. World Bank. 2011. Climate Change and Fiscal Policy: A Report for APEC, Office of the Chief Economist, East Asia and Pacific Region. Available online: http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2011/02/01/000333038_20110201000150/Rendered/PDF/565630REV0ESW010Policy01Jan13112011.pdf (accessed on 5 December 2015).
  117. World Bank. 2015. PPP Conversion Factor, GDP (LCU per International $). Available online: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/PA.NUS.PPP?page=4 (accessed on 5 January 2016).
  118. Worthington, Andrew C., and Mark Hoffman. 2008. An empirical survey of residential water demand modelling. Journal of Economic Surveys 22: 842–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  119. Yoo, James, Silvio Simonit, Ann Kinzig, and Charles Perrings. 2014. Estimating the Price Elasticity of Residential Water Demand: The Case of Phoenix, Arizona. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 36: 333–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Yu, Xiaohua, Zhifeng Gao, and Yinchu Zeng. 2014. Willingness to pay for the “Green Food” in China. Food Policy 45: 80–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Ten random walks of αtot (a) and of future WTP values (b) for Scenario A.
Figure 1. Ten random walks of αtot (a) and of future WTP values (b) for Scenario A.
Economies 07 00107 g001
Figure 2. Ten random walks of αtot (a) and of future WTP values (b) for Scenario B.
Figure 2. Ten random walks of αtot (a) and of future WTP values (b) for Scenario B.
Economies 07 00107 g002
Figure 3. Ten random walks of αtot (a) and of future WTP values (b) for Scenario C.
Figure 3. Ten random walks of αtot (a) and of future WTP values (b) for Scenario C.
Economies 07 00107 g003
Table 1. Monetary value of services provided by Temperate and Boreal Forests (in Int. $/ha/year-2007 values).
Table 1. Monetary value of services provided by Temperate and Boreal Forests (in Int. $/ha/year-2007 values).
No. of EstimatesMean Median St.Dev.Min Max
Provisioning services96714508671211593
1 Food22992994220597
2 Water3191121123118333
3 Raw materials4181313222662
4 Genetic resources
5 Medicinal resources
6 Ornamental resources
Regulating services134913675841051212
7 Air quality regulation
8 Climate regulation6152342417624
9 Disturbance moderation
10 Regulation of water flows
11 Waste treatment37013022
12 Erosion prevention155 55
13 Nutrient cycling19393 9393
14 Pollination
15 Biological control22352353301469
Habitat services108621711342513573
16 Nursery service
17 Genetic diversity108621711342513573
Cultural services269901392644110028
18 Esthetic information
19 Recreation259891382644110027
20 Inspiration
21 Spiritual experience
22 Cognitive development111 11
TOTAL5830131127543727816406
Table 2. Monte Carlo simulation summary statistics for the PV of WTP.
Table 2. Monte Carlo simulation summary statistics for the PV of WTP.
StatisticsPV Ignoring αtotScenario AScenario BScenario C
Mean72,20093,950131,07070,300
Median64,48085,850116,02064,120
St. Dev.44,32056,16081,48043,820
Minimum155024405150210
Maximum194,610278,180392,360209,340
Mean Std. Error1400178025801390
Table 3. Monte Carlo simulation percentiles for the PV of WTP.
Table 3. Monte Carlo simulation percentiles for the PV of WTP.
PercentilesPV Ignoring αtotScenario AScenario BScenario C
100%155024405150210
90%18,74026,83034,28017,820
80%29,95041,61054,29028,830
70%40,53054,97073,03039,480
60%52,47069,84093,27052,120
50%64,47085,840115,94064,120
40%78,710101,450142,83076,170
30%95,220122,910170,35089,940
20%113,400144,690205,080107,210
10%136,680173,690250,550134,890
0%194,610278,180392,360209,340

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Skourtos, M.; Damigos, D.; Kontogianni, A.; Tourkolias, C.; Hunt, A. Embedding Preference Uncertainty for Environmental Amenities in Climate Change Economic Assessments: A “Random” Step Forward. Economies 2019, 7, 107. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7040107

AMA Style

Skourtos M, Damigos D, Kontogianni A, Tourkolias C, Hunt A. Embedding Preference Uncertainty for Environmental Amenities in Climate Change Economic Assessments: A “Random” Step Forward. Economies. 2019; 7(4):107. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7040107

Chicago/Turabian Style

Skourtos, Michalis, Dimitris Damigos, Areti Kontogianni, Christos Tourkolias, and Alistair Hunt. 2019. "Embedding Preference Uncertainty for Environmental Amenities in Climate Change Economic Assessments: A “Random” Step Forward" Economies 7, no. 4: 107. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7040107

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop