Economic Freedom and Income Inequality: Does Political Regime Matter?
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Review of Literature on Income Inequality Links to Liberalization and Democracy
2.1. Inequality and Economic Liberalization
- Size of government: This component measures government size via indicators like government consumption and transfers as a share of GDP, state-owned enterprises, and top marginal tax-rates. It is coded in a way that larger size of government received less freedom score. Thus, a positive relationship to income inequality is expected since larger government normally leads to lower inequality. In other words, larger government size as a result of greater welfare spending and increased public sector transfers is expected to reduce income gap as such spending and transfers are meant for various income-equalizing policies like child benefits, free education and healthcare etc.
- Legal system and property rights: This component focuses on the protection of property rights via rule of law, independent and unbiased judiciary, and impartial and effective enforcement of the law. Intuitively, protection of property rights is thought to mainly benefit those with properties which are normally the high income earners. Protection increases the value of the properties leading to rising earnings of this group, and consequently creating a larger gap with the low income earners in the country. Thus, we may expect a positive relationship of this component to inequality.
- Access to sound money: Economic exchanges require money. This component receives low scores when the value of money is volatile due to inflationary pressure and unpredictable monetary policy. Thus, a negative association with income inequality is expected since the cost of inflation in term of returns to capital and lending rates are expected to be relatively more detrimental to low income earners whose assets are less protected against inflation. This leads to wider gap between the top and bottom earners within a population.
- Freedom to trade internationally: This component captures various protectionist measures like trade taxes, tariff rates and trade barriers and capital market controls. According to Heckscher-Ohlin theory, openness to international trade is expected to reduce (increase) income inequality in developing (developed) countries. This is because increased demand for low skilled workers that are abundant in developing countries is expected to exert a downward pressure on the wage gap between skilled-unskilled labors. Nevertheless, this proposition is still debatable due to differing theoretical approximations taking into account degrees of openness, different assumptions in term of factors supply and mobility, and unequal level of technology between the trading countries.
- Regulation of credit, labor and business: The final component of EFW focuses on the regulatory constraints that limit the freedom of exchange in credit, labor and product markets. Deregulation provides greater access to credit to all population segments including the low income earners to support their economic ventures and this subsequently may improve their incomes. Nevertheless, positive distributive effect of deregulation may not be realized in a situation when political elites can influence the deregulation policy. Therefore, there is no clear indication in the direction of inequality-effect of this component.
2.2. Inequality and Democracy
- Median voter theory: This theory argues that, based on rational choice of redistribution, the median voters would choose redistribution and higher taxation for rich people if the median income lies below the mean income. This theory thus predicts that income inequality is lower in a democracy than an autocracy.
- Political participation mechanism: Via this mechanism, democracy is expected to lower the costs of political participation, giving rise to strong and organized labor unions, political parties and interest groups representing the low and middle income groups. These groups would then push for more welfare-augmenting policies such as minimum wage that reduce wage dispersion.
- Political competition mechanism: This mechanism highlights the importance of electoral connection. Reelection-oriented democratic leaders would compete for citizen support, and consequently invest more in meeting the needs of the larger segments of suffrage who are normally the low and middle income earners. To win the voters’ support, they would adopt various redistributive measures such as welfare spendings and benefits, greater access to education and healthcare, price subsidies, and other public services provisions.
3. Data, Econometric Specification and Empirical Strategy
3.1. Data
- (a)
- size of government (henceforth denoted EFW1),
- (b)
- legal system and property rights (EFW2),
- (c)
- access to sound money (EFW3),
- (d)
- freedom to trade internationally (EFW4), and
- (e)
- regulation of credit, labor, and business (EFW5).
3.2. Econometric Specification
3.3. Empirical Strategy
4. Results and Discussion
4.1. Baseline Results
4.2. Summary of Baseline Results
4.3. Sensitivity Analysis
4.4. Economic Freedom-Inequality Relationship in Different Regimes
5. Conclusions and Policy Implications
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Variable | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min | Max | Total no. of obs. | No. of Countries | No. of Periods (avg) | Data Sources |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gini net | 36.93 | 9.58 | 16.11 | 65.72 | 789 | 115 | 6.9 | SWIID5.0 (Solt 2014) |
Gini gross | 45.26 | 7.96 | 20.13 | 75.29 | 789 | 115 | 6.9 | SWIID5.0 (Solt 2014) |
EHII Gini | 41.44 | 6.97 | 22.34 | 56.38 | 531 | 104 | 5.1 | UTIP (Galbraith et al. 2014) |
EFW | 6.26 | 1.25 | 2.5 | 8.9 | 726 | 115 | 6.3 | Economic Freedom in The World (Gwartney et al. 2010) |
EFW1 | 5.78 | 1.53 | 1.2 | 9.3 | 742 | 115 | 6.5 | |
EFW2 | 5.66 | 1.80 | 1.1 | 9.3 | 715 | 115 | 6.2 | |
EFW3 | 7.18 | 2.18 | 0 | 9.8 | 755 | 115 | 6.6 | |
EFW4 | 6.42 | 2.08 | 0 | 10.0 | 726 | 115 | 6.3 | |
EFW5 | 6.14 | 1.30 | 1.0 | 9.0 | 721 | 115 | 6.3 | |
IP2 | 0.74 | 0.44 | 0 | 1 | 769 | 115 | 6.7 | Hadenius and Teorell (2007) |
ANRR | 0.74 | 0.44 | 0 | 1 | 769 | 115 | 6.7 | Acemoglu et al. (2015) |
BMR | 0.66 | 0.47 | 0 | 1 | 769 | 115 | 6.7 | Boix et al. (2013) |
CGV | 0.67 | 0.47 | 0 | 1 | 769 | 115 | 6.7 | Cheibub et al. (2010) |
Real GDP per capita | 13,597.06 | 13,313.61 | 436.55 | 90,604.64 | 762 | 113 | 6.7 | PWT9.0, Feenstra et al. (2015) |
Education | 6.99 | 6.26 | 0 | 30.9 | 750 | 109 | 6.9 | Barro and Lee (2013) |
Age dependency ratio | 64.91 | 18.18 | 34.96 | 112.84 | 747 | 113 | 6.6 | World Development Indicator (WDI) World Bank (2016) |
Urban population | 56.49 | 23.05 | 5.2 | 100.0 | 747 | 113 | 6.6 | |
Emp. in industry | 23.90 | 8.29 | 2.2 | 45.6 | 544 | 110 | 4.9 | |
Emp. in service | 53.47 | 16.78 | 5.6 | 83.6 | 544 | 110 | 4.9 |
Gini Net | Gini Gross | EHII Gini | Real GDPpc | Education | Agedep | Urbanpop | Empind | Empserve | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gini gross | 0.709 | ||||||||
EHII Gini | 0.765 | 0.419 | |||||||
Real GDP pc | −0.556 | −0.130 | −0.706 | ||||||
Education | −0.426 | −0.081 | −0.405 | 0.729 | |||||
Agedep | 0.540 | 0.248 | 0.622 | −0.771 | −0.681 | ||||
Urbanpop | −0.390 | −0.079 | −0.530 | 0.779 | 0.725 | −0.576 | |||
Empind | −0.434 | −0.239 | −0.578 | 0.462 | 0.213 | −0.539 | 0.346 | ||
Empser | −0.277 | 0.113 | −0.336 | 0.767 | 0.620 | −0.382 | 0.766 | 0.263 | |
IP2 | −0.179 | 0.039 | −0.230 | 0.428 | 0.404 | −0.348 | 0.299 | 0.066 | 0.269 |
ANRR | −0.161 | 0.069 | −0.241 | 0.427 | 0.412 | −0.344 | 0.307 | 0.082 | 0.283 |
BMR | −0.248 | 0.008 | −0.273 | 0.488 | 0.431 | −0.383 | 0.365 | 0.168 | 0.339 |
CGV | −0.278 | −0.025 | −0.290 | 0.465 | 0.494 | −0.401 | 0.371 | 0.135 | 0.326 |
EFW | −0.318 | −0.002 | −0.411 | 0.689 | 0.589 | −0.600 | 0.512 | 0.091 | 0.562 |
EFW 1 | 0.418 | 0.135 | 0.418 | −0.214 | −0.005 | 0.054 | −0.117 | −0.331 | −0.154 |
EFW 2 | −0.583 | −0.190 | −0.685 | 0.785 | 0.528 | −0.632 | 0.578 | 0.388 | 0.557 |
EFW 3 | −0.310 | 0.009 | −0.335 | 0.583 | 0.476 | −0.457 | 0.397 | 0.057 | 0.471 |
EFW 4 | −0.347 | 0.038 | −0.483 | 0.700 | 0.586 | −0.592 | 0.595 | 0.238 | 0.577 |
EFW 5 | −0.126 | 0.083 | −0.217 | 0.503 | 0.447 | −0.427 | 0.314 | −0.063 | 0.431 |
|
High Income (42 Countries) | Upper Middle Income (31 Countries) | Lower Middle Income (26 Countries) | Lower Income (16 Countries) |
---|---|---|---|
Australia | Albania | Armenia | Burundi |
Austria | Algeria | Bangladesh | Central African Republic |
Barbados | Argentina | Bolivia | Guinea-Bissau |
Belgium | Botswana | Cameroon | Haiti |
Canada | Brazil | Cote d’Ivoire | Madagascar |
Chile | Bulgaria | Egypt | Malawi |
Croatia | China | El Salvador | Mali |
Cyprus | Colombia | Ghana | Mozambique |
Czech Republic | Costa Rica | Guatemala | Nepal |
Denmark | Dominican Republic | Honduras | Niger |
Estonia | Ecuador | India | Rwanda |
Finland | Fiji | Indonesia | Senegal |
France | Georgia | Kenya | Sierra Leone |
Germany | Guyana | Mongolia | Tanzania |
Greece | Iran | Morocco | Uganda |
Hungary | Jamaica | Nicaragua | Zimbabwe |
Iceland | Jordan | Nigeria | |
Ireland | Macedonia | Pakistan | |
Israel | Malaysia | Papua New Guinea | |
Italy | Mauritius | Philippines | |
Japan | Mexico | Sri Lanka | |
Korea, Republic of | Namibia | Syria | |
Latvia | Panama | Tunisia | |
Lithuania | Paraguay | Ukraine | |
Luxembourg | Peru | Vietnam | |
Malta | Romania | Zambia | |
Netherlands | Russia | ||
New Zealand | South Africa | ||
Norway | Thailand | ||
Poland | Turkey | ||
Portugal | Venezuela | ||
Singapore | |||
Slovakia | |||
Slovenia | |||
Spain | |||
Sweden | |||
Switzerland | |||
Taiwan | |||
Trinidad and Tobago | |||
United Kingdom | |||
United States | |||
Uruguay |
References
- Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth. In Handbook of Economic Growth. Edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V., vol. 1A, pp. 386–471. [Google Scholar]
- Acemoglu, Daron, Suresh Naidu, Pascual Restrepo, and James A. Robinson. 2015. Democracy, redistribution, and inequality. In Handbook of Income Distribution. Edited by Anthony B. Atkinson and François Bourguignon. Amsterdam: Elsevier Ltd., vol. 2, pp. 1885–966. [Google Scholar]
- Ahmad, Mahyudin. 2016. Middle Income Trap and Income Inequality: Empirical Evidence on the Distributional Effect of Economic Liberalization and Political Regime. MPRA Working Paper Series; WP No. 764. Munich: University Library of Munich, pp. 1–34. [Google Scholar]
- Amendola, Adalgiso, Joshy Easaw, and Antonio Savoia. 2013. Inequality in developing economies: The role of institutional development. Public Choice 155: 43–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Apergis, Nicholas, and Arusha Cooray. 2015. Economic Freedom and Income Inequality: Evidence from a Panel of Global Economies—A Linear and a Non-Linear Long-Run Analysis. Manchester School 85: 88–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arellano, Manuel, and Olympia Bover. 1995. Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Babones, Salvatore J., and María José Alvarez-Rivadulla. 2007. Standardized Income Inequality Data for Use in Cross-National Research. Sociological Inquiry 77: 3–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Balcázar, Carlos F. 2015. Long-Run Effects of Democracy on Income Inequality: Evidence from Repeated cross-Sections. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper. Washington: World Bank, vol. 7153. [Google Scholar]
- Balcázar, Carlos F. 2016. Long-run effects of democracy on income inequality in Latin America. Journal of Economic Inequality 14: 289–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barro, Robert J., and Jong-Wha Lee. 2013. A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics 104: 184–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bennett, Daniel L., and Richard J. Cebula. 2016. Misperceptions about capitalism, government and inequality. In Economic Behavior, Economic Freedom, and Entrepreneurship. Edited by Richard J. Cebula, Joshua C. Hall, Franklin G. Mixon and James E. Payne. Northampton: Edward Elgar, pp. 1–20. [Google Scholar]
- Bennett, Daniel L., and Boris Nikolaev. 2016. On the ambiguous economic freedom-inequality relationship. Empirical Economics, 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bennett, Daniel L., and Richard K. Vedder. 2013. A Dynamic Analysis of Economic Freedom and Income Inequality in the 50 U.S. States: Evidence of a Parabolic Relationship. The Journal of Regional Analysis and Policy 43: 42–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berggren, Niclas. 1999. Economic freedom and equality: Friends or foes? Public Choice 100: 203–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bergh, Andreas, and Therese Nilsson. 2010. Do liberalization and globalization increase income inequality? European Journal of Political Economy 26: 488–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boix, Carles, Michael K. Miller, and Sebastian Rosato. 2013. A Complete Data Set of Political Regimes, 1800–2007. Comparative Political Studies 46: 1523–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Calderón, César, and Alberto Chong. 2009. Labor market institutions and income inequality: An empirical exploration. Public Choice 138: 65–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carter, John R. 2006. An empirical note on economic freedom and income inequality. Public Choice 130: 163–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cheibub, José Antonio, Jennifer Gandhi, and James Raymond Vreeland. 2010. Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice 143: 67–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clark, J. R., and Robert A. Lawson. 2008. The Impact of Economic Growth, Tax Policy and Economic Freedom on Income Inequality. The Journal of Private Enterprise 24: 23–31. [Google Scholar]
- Doucouliagos, Hristos, and Mehmet Ali Ulubasoglu. 2008. Democracy and Economic Growth: A Meta-Analysis. American Journal of Political Science 52: 61–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feenstra, Robert, Robert Inklaar, and Marcel Timmer. 2015. the Next Generation of the Penn World Table. National Bureau of Economic Research 105: 3150–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Galbraith, James K., Béatrice Halbach, Aleksandra Malinowska, Amin Shams, and Wenjie Zhang. 2014. UTIP Global Inequality Data Sets 1963–2008:Updates, Revisions and Quality Checks. Austin: The University of Texas at Austin. [Google Scholar]
- Gerry, Christopher J., and Tomasz M. Mickiewicz. 2008. Inequality, democracy and taxation: Lessons from the post-communist transition. Europe-Asia Studies 60: 89–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gradstein, Mark, and Branco Milanovic. 2004. Does libertè=egalité? A survey of the empirical links between democracy and inequality with some evidence on the transition economies. Journal of Economic Surveys 18: 515–537. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gwartney, James, Joshua Hall, and Robert Lawson. 2010. Economic Freedom in the World: 2010 Annual Report. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute. [Google Scholar]
- Hadenius, Axel, and Jan Teorell. 2007. Pathways from Authoritarianism. Journal of Democracy 18: 143–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Holcombe, Randall G., and Christopher J. Boudreaux. 2016. Market institutions and income inequality. Journal of Institutional Economics 12: 263–276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Islam, Muhammed N. 2016. Does democracy reduce income inequality? Empirical Economics 51: 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jenkins, Stephen P. 2015. World income inequality databases: An assessment of WIID and SWIID. Journal of Economic Inequality 13: 629–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, Cheol-Sung. 2005. Income Inequality, Democracy, and Public Sector Size. American Economic Review 70: 158–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Marshall, Monty G., and Keith Jaggers. 2014. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions 1800–2014. Available online: http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm (accessed on 20 March 2016).
- Meschi, Elena, and Marco Vivarelli. 2009. Trade and Income Inequality in Developing Countries. World Development 37: 287–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Reuveny, Rafael, and Quan Li. 2003. Economic openness, democracy, and income inequality - An empirical analysis. Comparative Political Studies 36: 575–601. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roodman, David. 2009. A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 71: 135–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Savoia, Antonio, Joshy Easaw, and Andrew Mckay. 2010. Inequality, Democracy, and Institutions: A Critical Review of Recent Research. World Development 38: 142–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scully, Gerald W. 2002. Economic Freedom, Government Policy and the Trade-Off Between Equity and Economic Growth. Public Choice 113: 77–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Solt, Frederick. 2014. The Standardized World Income Inequality Database. University of Iowa Working Paper, SWIID Version 5.0. Iowa City: University of Iowa. [Google Scholar]
- Sturm, Jan-Egbert, and Jakob De Haan. 2015. Income Inequality, Capitalism, and Ethno-Linguistic Fractionalization. American Economic Review 105: 593–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Timmons, Jeffrey F. 2010. Does Democracy Reduce Economic Inequality. British Journal of Political Science 40: 741–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Windmeijer, Frank. 2005. A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics 126: 25–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- World Bank. 2016. World Development Indicators. Washington: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
1 | |
2 | A necessary caveat is required when interpreting the inequality-effect of democracy, and it is discussed more in the results section. |
3 | See https://www.fraserinstitute.org for more information on the economic freedom index definition, areas and methodology to compute the index. For a more detailed discussion on the theoretical links and empirical evidence of five areas of economic freedom to inequality, see Bergh and Nilsson (2010). |
4 | For more details, see https://freedomhouse.org/report/methodology-freedom-world-2017. |
5 | The summary is briefly extracted from a longer discussion found in Acemoglu et al. (2015), Balcázar (2015), Reuveny and Li (2003) and Timmons (2010). |
6 | For detail discussion on the empirical heterogeneity of democracy–inequality studies, see Acemoglu et al. (2015) and Balcázar (2016). |
7 | See Bergh and Nilsson (2010) for discussion on the superiority of Gini coefficient from SWIID as compared to World Income Inequality Database (WIID) of UNU-WIDER, Standardized Income Distribution Database (SIDD) created by Babones and Alvarez-Rivadulla (2007) or Luxembourg Income Study (LIS) etc. On the other hand, Jenkins (2015) recommends the use of WIID over SWIID although his recommendation is conditional. It is noteworthy that Jenkins, in discussing his concern regarding SWIID imputation exercise that may lead to the risk of bias estimates, refers to SWIID version 4.0, and this paper uses the latest SWIID version 5.0. |
8 | EHII dataset is downloadable at http://utip.gov.utexas.edu and available up until to 2008 only. |
9 | |
10 | Specifically, the average score of political rights and civil liberties is transformed to a scale 0–10, as is Polity2 score of −10 to 10. Subsequently these transformed scores are averaged into an imputed version of Polity 2 with final score between 0–10. In the event that data on Polity 2 is missing, this imputed version generate imputed values for countries by regressing Polity 2 scores on the average Freedom House measure. |
11 | Venezuela status as a “partly free” country is remarked as trending down after the election of new president following the death of Chavez in 2012—see the country’s detailed report especially in year 2014 onwards on the Freedom House website here: https://freedomhouse.org/report/freedom-world/2014/venezuela. In the latest 2017 report, Venezuela however is now classed as “not free.” Meanwhile Russia has been classed as “not free” since 2005, prior to that year was classed “partly free.” |
12 | The other partial derivative is when we take which examines the inequality-effect of democratization for a given level of economic freedom in the country under study. Nevertheless, our interpretation on the effect of democratization always assume economic freedom to be constant. This is since the focus of the study is to examine the role of democracy in the economic freedom-inequality nexus, which is captured by Equation (2). |
13 | Ordinary Least Square (OLS) estimation therefore is straightforward biased since the estimation does not allow for the presence of fixed effects in the model. Furthermore, we follow Acemoglu et al. (2015) in not using Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998) System GMM estimation. System GMM is an estimation that combines the difference equation with a level equation. Lagged levels are used as instruments for the endogenous variables in the differenced equation, whereas in level equation lagged first differences of the endogenous regressors are used as instruments. For consistency, System GMM estimator requires that the initial value of democracy and economic freedom variables to be uncorrelated with the fixed effects, however this is unlikely to be a good assumption given the historically determined nature of democracy and free market-oriented institutions. |
14 | By construction, the differenced error term is probably serially correlated at first-order even if the original error is not. While most studies employing GMM estimation report the test for first order serial correlation, some do not. |
15 | Note that one-period lag of the
variable of interests in Equation (1) always means a 5-year lag, since the data
are 5-year average across the sample year 1970–2014. The practice to predate
endogenous regressors as a way to handle endogeneity has also been done by Berggren (1999), Bergh and Nilsson (2010), and Acemoglu et al. (2015). |
16 | Various instrument lags are experimented and the decision to set this lag restriction is made because the estimation results fulfill the necessary requirements i.e., successfully pass the instrument’s exogeneity (Hansen) and second order serial correlation (AR2) tests. |
17 | Specifically, the calculations are as follows: (1) to determine the size of effect of economic freedom on inequality, we first set the baseline Gini value using this equation: (based on the partial derivative and holding other factors constant), then we raise 1 standard deviation in the efw variable above its mean, and recalculate the new Gini value to see the size of change in Gini from its baseline value, (2) to determine the size of effect of democracy on inequality, we set the baseline Gini value using this equation: (based on the partial derivative and holding another factors constant), then we raise dem variable by 1 standard deviation above its mean, and recalculate the new Gini value to see the size of change in Gini from its baseline value, and finally (3) to determine the size of effect of economic freedom in a democratic regime, we set the baseline Gini value using this formula: (based on the partial derivative setting dem = 1 and holding other factors including individual dem constant), then we concurrently raise efw and dem by 1 standard
deviation above their means, and recalculate the new Gini value to see the size of change in Gini from its baseline value. Please see also discussion on the partial effect the of variables of interest in Equation (2) in econometric specification section. |
18 | To obtain the long term effect, we first need to set giniit = giniit−1 so that the dynamics in the dependent variable would converge to a new steady state level. Consequently, the long run effect of freedom to international trade EFW4 is given by: , long run effect of democracy is , and the long run effect of the interaction between EFW4*Democracy is , holding other variables constant. |
19 | According to the latest classification by the World Bank, a middle income country is an economy whose Gross National Income (GNI) between $1026–12475 threshold; with lower middle income GNI between $1026–$4035, and upper middle income GNI between $4036–$12,475. Note the skewed range of GNI for the upper middle income group. The range of GNI between $0–$1025 for low income group is thus naturally closer to the lower middle income group GNI range. |
20 | By omitting dem variable we are assuming the effect of regime types are fully captured by the country fixed effects term. |
21 | This is an average effect, since the average values for the coefficient, the mean, and the standard deviation of EFW4 variable are used since there are four sources for democracy classification. Specifically, for each regime type, the average of the four means and standard deviations are obtained from the variable’s summary statistics according to four difference democracy sources. Similarly, the average of the EFW4 coefficients used is the one reported in Table 6 according to regime classification based on the four different democracy sources. |
Country Sample | Mean | Std. Dev. | Minimum | Maximum | Obs. | No. of Countries |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gini of Net Income | ||||||
Overall sample | 36.93 | 9.58 | 16.11 (Bulgaria) | 65.72 (Namibia) | 789 | 115 |
Always democracy | 34.29 | 10.26 | 17.29 (Slovakia) | 65.72 (Namibia) | 376 | 55 |
In-transition | 39.00 | 8.60 | 16.11 (Bulgaria) | 61.47 (Sierra Leone) | 326 | 46 |
Always non-democracy | 40.57 | 6.45 | 25.35 (Rwanda) | 58.21 (Egypt) | 87 | 14 |
High income | 30.02 | 6.51 | 17.29 (Slovakia) | 51.07 (Chile) | 323 | 42 |
Upper middle income | 42.12 | 9.11 | 16.11 (Bulgaria) | 65.72 (Namibia) | 216 | 31 |
Lower middle income | 40.97 | 7.79 | 19.99 (Ukraine) | 61.25 (Kenya) | 170 | 26 |
Low income | 42.19 | 7.35 | 25.35 (Rwanda) | 61.47 (Sierra Leone) | 80 | 16 |
Economic Freedom Overall Index, EFW | ||||||
Overall sample | 6.26 | 1.25 | 2.5 (Peru) | 8.9 (Singapore) | 726 | 115 |
Always democracy | 6.78 | 1.04 | 2.9 (Nicaragua) | 8.8 (New Zealand) | 340 | 55 |
In-transition | 5.82 | 1.19 | 2.5 (Peru) | 7.9 (Chile) | 305 | 46 |
Always non-democracy | 5.70 | 1.39 | 2.8 (Uganda) | 8.9 (Singapore) | 81 | 14 |
High income | 7.00 | 1.00 | 3.5 (Poland) | 8.9 (Singapore) | 300 | 42 |
Upper middle income | 5.93 | 1.16 | 2.5 (Peru) | 7.8 (Jordan) | 195 | 31 |
Lower middle income | 5.73 | 1.12 | 2.9 (Nicaragua) | 7.7 (Armenia) | 154 | 26 |
Low income | 5.26 | 1.01 | 2.8 (Uganda) | 7.4 (Rwanda) | 77 | 16 |
EFW | EFW1 | EFW2 | EFW3 | EFW4 | EFW5 | IP2 | ANRR | BMR | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
EFW1 | 0.236 | ||||||||
EFW2 | 0.686 | −0.268 | |||||||
EFW3 | 0.843 | 0.056 | 0.514 | ||||||
EFW4 | 0.868 | 0.030 | 0.637 | 0.695 | |||||
EFW5 | 0.792 | 0.219 | 0.456 | 0.587 | 0.598 | ||||
IP2 | 0.395 | 0.019 | 0.292 | 0.270 | 0.445 | 0.379 | |||
ANRR | 0.384 | 0.015 | 0.282 | 0.263 | 0.442 | 0.370 | 0.963 | ||
BMR | 0.392 | −0.032 | 0.330 | 0.305 | 0.448 | 0.336 | 0.806 | 0.809 | |
CGV | 0.388 | 0.028 | 0.293 | 0.299 | 0.436 | 0.318 | 0.787 | 0.796 | 0.875 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Lagged Gini | 0.473 *** | |||||
(0.051) | ||||||
EFW | 0.006 | 0.006 | 0.036 * | 0.005 | 0.027 * | |
(0.011) | (0.011) | (0.020) | (0.053) | (0.014) | ||
Democracy | 0.041 | 0.025 | 0.209 ** | 0.225 ** | 0.130 * | |
(0.033) | (0.032) | (0.099) | (0.099) | (0.073) | ||
EFW*Democracy | −0.035 * | −0.038 * | −0.024 * | |||
(0.020) | (0.020) | (0.014) | ||||
EFW squared | 0.003 | |||||
(0.004) | ||||||
Observations | 463 | 483 | 463 | 463 | 463 | 463 |
Number of countries | 103 | 104 | 103 | 103 | 103 | 103 |
Adj. R-squared | 0.244 | 0.253 | 0.245 | 0.257 | 0.256 | 0.457 |
Estimation Method | Fixed Effect Estimation | Difference GMM Estimation | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | (12) | (13) | (14) | (15) | (16) | (17) | (18) | |
Lagged Gini | 0.473 *** | 0.480 *** | 0.438 *** | 0.472 *** | 0.460 *** | 0.458 *** | 0.152 | 0.251 ** | 0.370 *** | 0.239 ** | 0.178 * | 0.122 |
(0.051) | (0.052) | (0.049) | (0.050) | (0.051) | (0.049) | (0.108) | (0.099) | (0.089) | (0.093) | (0.095) | (0.099) | |
Democracy | 0.130 * | 0.093 | 0.053 | −0.005 | 0.053 | 0.190 *** | 0.419 * | 0.104 | −0.037 | 0.168 | 0.237 *** | 0.358 ** |
(0.073) | (0.099) | (0.072) | (0.042) | (0.040) | (0.065) | (0.233) | (0.128) | (0.100) | (0.121) | (0.054) | (0.144) | |
EFW | 0.027 * | 0.088 * | ||||||||||
(0.014) | (0.049) | |||||||||||
EFW*Democracy | −0.024 * | −0.058 | ||||||||||
(0.014) | (0.045) | |||||||||||
EFW1 | 0.009 | 0.014 | ||||||||||
(0.017) | (0.024) | |||||||||||
EFW1*Democracy | −0.014 | 0.003 | ||||||||||
(0.017) | (0.024) | |||||||||||
EFW2 | 0.021 ** | 0.011 | ||||||||||
(0.010) | (0.024) | |||||||||||
EFW2*Democracy | −0.010 | 0.025 | ||||||||||
(0.012) | (0.023) | |||||||||||
EFW3 | −0.005 | 0.002 | ||||||||||
(0.007) | (0.023) | |||||||||||
EFW3*Democracy | 0.003 | −0.007 | ||||||||||
(0.007) | (0.022) | |||||||||||
EFW4 | 0.011 * | 0.055 *** | ||||||||||
(0.007) | (0.019) | |||||||||||
EFW4*Democracy | −0.011 * | −0.029 * | ||||||||||
(0.007) | (0.016) | |||||||||||
EFW5 | 0.034 *** | 0.081 *** | ||||||||||
(0.012) | (0.030) | |||||||||||
EFW5*Democracy | −0.034 *** | −0.054 * | ||||||||||
(0.011) | (0.030) | |||||||||||
No. of observations | 463 | 467 | 458 | 473 | 463 | 464 | 368 | 369 | 368 | 372 | 368 | 370 |
No. of countries | 103 | 103 | 103 | 103 | 103 | 103 | 95 | 95 | 95 | 95 | 94 | 95 |
Adj. R2 | 0.457 | 0.461 | 0.411 | 0.462 | 0.441 | 0.452 | ||||||
No. of instruments | 82 | 82 | 82 | 82 | 82 | 82 | ||||||
AR2 p-value | 0.191 | 0.029 | 0.027 | 0.031 | 0.316 | 0.229 | ||||||
Hansen p-value | 0.546 | 0.264 | 0.397 | 0.397 | 0.556 | 0.479 |
1. Alternative Gini | 2. Alternative Democracy Variable | 3.Control Variables | 4. Level of Development | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gini Net (Bounded) | Gini Gross | EHII Gini | ANRR | BMR | CGV | Set 1 | Set 2 | High Income | Middle Income | HI & Upper MI | LI & Lower MI | ||
Estimation | (19–24) | (25–30) | (31–36) | (37–42) | (43–48) | (49–54) | (55–60) | (61–66) | (67–72) | (73–78) | (79–84) | (85–90) | |
A | EFW | 0.058 ** | 0.115 * | 0.006 | 0.162 ** | 0.100 *** | 0.072 *** | 0.095 ** | 0.108 *** | 0.074 | −0.001 | 0.120 *** | 0.020 |
Democracy | 0.266 * | 0.561 * | 0.173 | 0.717 ** | 0.434 *** | 0.270 * | 0.427 * | 0.433 ** | 0.278 | 0.000 | 0.541 *** | −0.142 | |
EFW*Democracy | −0.037 | −0.083 | −0.018 | −0.124 * | −0.073 ** | −0.040 | −0.076* | −0.084 ** | −0.047 | 0.018 | −0.095 *** | 0.028 | |
AR2 p-value | 0.126 | 0.534 | 0.568 | 0.250 | 0.100 | 0.100 | 0.046 | 0.034 | 0.007 | 0.724 | 0.053 | 0.520 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.495 | 0.461 | 0.250 | 0.275 | 0.487 | 0.531 | 0.386 | 0.307 | 1.000 | 0.997 | 0.902 | 1.000 | |
B | EFW 1 | −0.010 | 0.031 | −0.005 | 0.008 | 0.033 ** | 0.031 * | 0.045 * | 0.050 ** | −0.012 | −0.001 | −0.016 | −0.030 |
Democracy | 0.016 | 0.310 * | 0.137* | 0.075 | 0.202 * | 0.162 | 0.362 ** | 0.390 *** | 0.045 | 0.056 | 0.010 | −0.141 | |
EFW1*Democracy | 0.015 | −0.031 | −0.011 | 0.005 | −0.021 | −0.013 | −0.053 ** | −0.060 ** | 0.007 | 0.003 | 0.022 | 0.028 | |
AR2 p-value | 0.054 | 0.413 | 0.509 | 0.025 | 0.046 | 0.044 | 0.017 | 0.012 | 0.010 | 0.792 | 0.027 | 0.198 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.201 | 0.215 | 0.419 | 0.299 | 0.316 | 0.210 | 0.296 | 0.234 | 1.000 | 0.999 | 0.762 | 1.000 | |
C | EFW2 | −0.002 | −0.032 | −0.033 ** | 0.015 | 0.022 | 0.020 | 0.000 | 0.010 | 0.006 | 0.010 | −0.038 | 0.017 |
Democracy | −0.051 | −0.172 | −0.025 | −0.024 | 0.015 | 0.029 | −0.130 | −0.095 | −0.191 | 0.114 | −0.265 | −0.107 | |
EFW2*Democracy | 0.024 * | 0.064 * | 0.025 * | 0.019 | 0.012 | 0.014 | 0.038 * | 0.030 | 0.037 | −0.005 | 0.066 ** | 0.028 | |
AR2 p-value | 0.023 | 0.523 | 0.662 | 0.025 | 0.025 | 0.033 | 0.081 | 0.085 | 0.002 | 0.634 | 0.017 | 0.627 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.331 | 0.465 | 0.392 | 0.319 | 0.536 | 0.450 | 0.245 | 0.231 | 1.000 | 0.998 | 0.948 | 1.000 | |
D | EFW3 | −0.012 | −0.013 | −0.006 | 0.015 | −0.001 | −0.009 | −0.010 | −0.009 | −0.031 | −0.009 | 0.013 | 0.002 |
Democracy | 0.035 | 0.089 | 0.096 | 0.228 ** | 0.099 | 0.076 | 0.103 | 0.086 | −0.084 | 0.067 ** | 0.163 * | −0.021 | |
EFW3*Democracy | 0.012 | 0.012 | 0.001 | −0.021 | −0.002 | 0.007 | 0.003 | 0.003 | 0.027 | 0.005 | −0.015 | 0.005 | |
AR2 p-value | 0.033 | 0.483 | 0.947 | 0.020 | 0.018 | 0.022 | 0.015 | 0.020 | 0.003 | 0.697 | 0.010 | 0.343 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.414 | 0.446 | 0.272 | 0.407 | 0.364 | 0.423 | 0.223 | 0.272 | 1.000 | 0.997 | 0.903 | 1.000 | |
E | EFW4 | 0.036 * | 0.081 *** | 0.021 * | 0.067 *** | 0.062 *** | 0.063 *** | 0.060 *** | 0.080 *** | 0.098 * | 0.032 ** | 0.057 ** | 0.038 |
Democracy | 0.163 *** | 0.352 *** | 0.166 *** | 0.252 *** | 0.252 *** | 0.242 *** | 0.175 * | 0.224 *** | 0.264 | 0.128 * | 0.230 *** | −0.024 | |
EFW4*Democracy | −0.021 | −0.050 * | −0.019 * | −0.042 ** | −0.039 *** | −0.038 *** | −0.039 * | −0.054 *** | −0.076 | −0.008 | −0.038 * | 0.012 | |
AR2 p-value | 0.239 | 0.776 | 0.279 | 0.315 | 0.339 | 0.149 | 0.088 | 0.099 | 0.026 | 0.488 | 0.136 | 0.562 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.683 | 0.491 | 0.328 | 0.368 | 0.585 | 0.588 | 0.447 | 0.681 | 1.000 | 0.996 | 0.861 | 1.000 | |
F | EFW5 | 0.047 ** | 0.150 *** | 0.028 | 0.113 *** | 0.094 *** | 0.079 *** | 0.063 ** | 0.061 ** | 0.002 | 0.019 | 0.050 * | −0.053 |
Democracy | 0.236 ** | 0.715 *** | 0.207 *** | 0.469 *** | 0.419 ** | 0.328 ** | 0.297 * | 0.264 | 0.080 | 0.124 | 0.263 ** | −0.040 | |
EFW5*Democracy | −0.035 * | −0.125 *** | −0.031 * | −0.084 ** | −0.075 ** | −0.054 * | −0.054 | −0.050 | 0.008 | −0.012 | −0.038 | 0.012 | |
AR2 p-value | 0.190 | 0.696 | 0.544 | 0.241 | 0.128 | 0.250 | 0.015 | 0.013 | 0.011 | 0.756 | 0.147 | 0.105 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.418 | 0.464 | 0.417 | 0.330 | 0.248 | 0.348 | 0.446 | 0.380 | 1.000 | 0.997 | 0.856 | 1.000 | |
No. of observations | 368–372 | 368–372 | 226–227 | 368–372 | 368–372 | 368–372 | 466–483 | 456–473 | 184–187 | 172–173 | 288–292 | 79–80 | |
No. of countries | 95 | 95 | 73 | 95 | 95 | 95 | 107 | 106 | 39 | 48 | 66 | 29 | |
No. of instruments | 82 | 82 | 69 | 82 | 82 | 82 | 85 | 87 | 80 | 79 | 82 | 61 |
1. Always Democracy | 2. In Transition | 3. Always Non-Democracy | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
IP2 | ANRR | BMR | CGV | IP2 | ANRR | BMR | CGV | IP2 | ANRR | BMR | CGV | ||
Estimation | (91–96) | (97–102) | (103–108) | (109–114) | (115–120) | (121–126) | (127–132) | (133–138) | (139–144) | (145–150) | (151–156) | (157–162) | |
A | EFW | 0.035 * | 0.038 * | 0.030 | 0.026 | 0.006 | −0.003 | 0.013 | 0.001 | −0.064 | 0.065 | 0.036 | 0.032 |
(0.019) | (0.020) | (0.022) | (0.018) | (0.030) | (0.028) | (0.028) | (0.028) | (0.204) | (0.211) | (0.085) | (0.051) | ||
AR2 p-value | 0.059 | 0.070 | 0.053 | 0.031 | 0.106 | 0.120 | 0.220 | 0.217 | - | 0.538 | 0.668 | 0.073 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.870 | 0.783 | 0.954 | 0.907 | 0.998 | 0.997 | 0.980 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | |
B | EFW1 | 0.013 | 0.013 | 0.008 | 0.020 | −0.011 | −0.015 | −0.011 | −0.008 | −0.049 | −0.074 | −0.023 | −0.038 |
(0.014) | (0.013) | (0.018) | (0.015) | (0.020) | (0.021) | (0.024) | (0.022) | (0.191) | (0.127) | (0.049) | (0.057) | ||
AR2 p-value | 0.039 | 0.049 | 0.048 | 0.013 | 0.208 | 0.269 | 0.340 | 0.243 | 0.114 | 0.373 | 0.839 | 0.931 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.818 | 0.756 | 0.897 | 0.713 | 0.997 | 0.997 | 0.985 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 0.999 | 0.999 | |
C | EFW2 | 0.028 * | 0.026 * | 0.013 | 0.015 | 0.023 | 0.022 | 0.028 * | 0.026 * | −0.047 | −0.012 | 0.009 | 0.009 |
(0.014) | (0.014) | (0.008) | (0.012) | (0.015) | (0.014) | (0.014) | (0.015) | (0.049) | (0.083) | (0.044) | (0.029) | ||
AR2 p-value | 0.028 | 0.029 | 0.033 | 0.013 | 0.143 | 0.118 | 0.194 | 0.186 | 0.717 | 0.787 | 0.720 | 0.998 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.779 | 0.820 | 0.969 | 0.860 | 0.993 | 0.998 | 0.990 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | |
D | EFW3 | 0.006 | 0.010 | 0.003 | 0.006 | −0.012 | −0.011 | −0.013 | −0.010 | 0.028 | 0.029 | 0.009 | −0.014 |
(0.009) | (0.008) | (0.010) | (0.011) | (0.007) | (0.007) | (0.009) | (0.007) | (0.071) | (0.056) | (0.028) | (0.017) | ||
AR2 p-value | 0.037 | 0.039 | 0.017 | 0.011 | 0.150 | 0.134 | 0.179 | 0.196 | 0.482 | 0.533 | 0.554 | 0.177 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.778 | 0.714 | 0.900 | 0.844 | 0.991 | 0.996 | 0.990 | 0.999 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | |
E | EFW4 | 0.036 *** | 0.039 *** | 0.028 *** | 0.028 *** | 0.039 *** | 0.040 *** | 0.037 *** | 0.035 ** | −0.011 | 0.022 | 0.017 | 0.049 |
(0.011) | (0.012) | (0.010) | (0.010) | (0.013) | (0.012) | (0.011) | (0.015) | (0.078) | (0.100) | (0.032) | (0.045) | ||
AR2 p-value | 0.100 | 0.100 | 0.055 | 0.036 | 0.276 | 0.368 | 0.303 | 0.435 | 0.478 | 0.798 | 0.438 | 0.296 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.728 | 0.739 | 0.925 | 0.926 | 0.999 | 1.000 | 0.999 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 0.999 | 0.999 | 1.000 | |
F | EFW5 | 0.010 | 0.011 | 0.016 | 0.017 | 0.030 | 0.022 | 0.008 | 0.028 | −0.032 | −0.003 | 0.009 | 0.025 |
(0.016) | (0.017) | (0.020) | (0.016) | (0.026) | (0.023) | (0.023) | (0.023) | (0.139) | (0.169) | (0.043) | (0.015) | ||
AR2 p-value | 0.067 | 0.064 | 0.053 | 0.023 | 0.255 | 0.299 | 0.308 | 0.273 | 0.994 | 0.906 | 0.770 | 0.076 | |
Hansen p-value | 0.641 | 0.842 | 0.967 | 0.920 | 0.986 | 0.996 | 0.980 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | 1.000 | |
No. of observations | 198–201 | 200–203 | 178–180 | 188–191 | 141–143 | 137–140 | 145–148 | 130–132 | 27 | 29 | 43 | 47–49 | |
No. of countries | 49 | 50 | 44 | 47 | 35 | 33 | 34 | 29 | 11 | 12 | 17 | 19 | |
No. of instruments | 58 | 58 | 58 | 58 | 58 | 58 | 58 | 58 | 27 | 29 | 40 | 42 |
© 2017 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Ahmad, M. Economic Freedom and Income Inequality: Does Political Regime Matter? Economies 2017, 5, 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5020018
Ahmad M. Economic Freedom and Income Inequality: Does Political Regime Matter? Economies. 2017; 5(2):18. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5020018
Chicago/Turabian StyleAhmad, Mahyudin. 2017. "Economic Freedom and Income Inequality: Does Political Regime Matter?" Economies 5, no. 2: 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5020018
APA StyleAhmad, M. (2017). Economic Freedom and Income Inequality: Does Political Regime Matter? Economies, 5(2), 18. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies5020018