Effects of Primary, Secondary and Tertiary Education on Conflict Intensity in Africa
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Why Education Matters for Conflict
3. Methodology
3.1. Empirical Model
3.2. Choice of Estimator
3.3. Estimation Strategy
3.4. Variables and Data
Variable | Source |
---|---|
Gross primary Enrolment (PRI) | ADI/World Bank |
Intra-state Conflict Intensity (CIVITOT) | Author’s construction using Uppsala Conflict Dataset |
Gross Secondary Enrolment (SEC) | ADI/World Bank |
Gross Tertiary Enrolment (TER) | ADI/World Bank |
Youth Bulge, Proportion of young men aged 15–24 in total population (YBULGE) | Collier et al. (2006) [51] |
Institutionalized Democracy (DEMOC) | ADI/World Bank |
Urbanization (URBAN) | ADI/World Bank |
Inflation (INFL) | ADI/World Bank |
Total Natural Resource Rents as % of GDP (NRES) | The World Bank |
Income Inequality (GINI) | ADI/World Bank |
Algeria | Central Africa Republic |
Angola | Egypt |
Burundi | Guinea |
Chad | Guinea Bissau |
Congo DRC | Ivory Coast |
Ethiopia | Mali |
Liberia | Morocco |
Mozambique | Niger |
Rwanda | Nigeria |
Senegal | Togo |
Sierra Leone | Congo Republic |
Sudan | Djibouti |
Uganda |
Variable | Obs. | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Conflict Intensity | 207 | 2.947 | 1.795 | −1.172 | 8.155 |
Primary Enrolment | 434 | 4.263 | 0.405 | 3.127 | 5.154 |
Secondary Enrolment | 380 | 2.947 | 0.662 | 1.496 | 4.421 |
Tertiary Enrolment | 336 | 0.85 | 1.131 | −2.346 | 3.56 |
Inflation | 378 | 2.161 | 1.702 | −3.206 | 10.076 |
Urbanization | 494 | 1.3 | 0.481 | −1.605 | 10.076 |
Institutionalized Democracy | 242 | 1.017 | 0.785 | 0 | 2.079 |
Income Inequality | 480 | 3.745 | 0.177 | 3.393 | 4.141 |
Youth Bulge | 499 | 2.978 | 0.066 | 2.856 | 3.314 |
Natural Resource Rents | 499 | 1.899 | 1.467 | −7.271 | 5.388 |
CIVTOT | PRI | SEC | TER | INFL | URBAN | DEMOC | GINI | NRES | YBULGE | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
CIVTOT | 1.00 | |||||||||
PRI | −0.04 | 1.00 | ||||||||
SEC | 0.01 | 0.45*** | 1.00 | |||||||
TER | −0.04 | 0.37*** | 0.84*** | 1.00 | ||||||
INFL | −0.02 | −0.02 | –0.07 | –0.03 | 1.00 | |||||
URBAN | −0.03 | 0.01 | –0.33*** | –0.21*** | 0.02 | 1.00 | ||||
DEMOC | −0.06 | 0.10** | –0.07 | 0.02 | –0.21*** | 0.01 | 1.00 | |||
GINI | 0.03 | 0.02 | –0.34*** | –0.33*** | 0.06 | 0.04 | –0.09** | 1.00 | ||
NRES | 0.10** | 0.30*** | 0.13** | 0.11** | 0.03 | –0.03 | –0.06 | 0.26*** | 1.00 | |
YBULGE | −0.02 | 0.35*** | 0.36*** | 0.33*** | –0.07 | 0.04 | 0.02 | –0.16*** | –0.04 | 1.00 |
3.5. Inferences from the Empirical Data
4. Discussion of the Results
4.1. Analysis of Fixed Effects Estimation Results
Dependent Variable: Conflict Intensity | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 | |
Conflict Intensity (Lagged) | 0.11 [0.113] | −0.15 [0.244] | −0.16 [0.241] | −0.15 [0.254] | −0.25 [0.153] | −0.25 [0.166] |
Primary Enrolment | -0.23 [0.503] | 3.30* [1.251] | 3.82** [1.162] | −0.33 [27.828] | −322.6 [214.032] | −319.73 [221.027] |
High Conflict Dummy | 1.66*** [0.206] | 9.31 [9.188] | 1.66*** [0.217] | 2.31** [0.539] | 2.32** [0.537] | |
Primary × High Conflict | −1.75 [2.071] | |||||
Natural Resource Rents | 0.14 [0.157] | 0.45 [0.425] | 0.12 [0.331] | 0.78* [0.275] | 0.83 [0.368] | |
Democracy | 0.56 [0.430] | 0.62 [0.382] | 0.53 [0.282] | 0.96 [0.502] | 1.01* [0.407] | |
Income Inequality | 11.04* [3.795] | 11.63** [3.279] | 7.08 [27.873] | 10.37** [3.082] | 17.34 [26.647] | |
Urbanization | −0.38 [0.539] | 0.82 [1.786] | −0.35 [0.489] | −5.43 [3.902] | −5.53 [3.814] | |
Inflation | −0.05 [0.148] | 0.04 [0.235] | −0.05 [0.175] | −0.18 [0.165] | −0.18 [0.171] | |
Youth Bulge | 28.61* [9.457] | 3.5 [24.462] | 26.26 [27.664] | −414.12 [294.569] | −414.78 [301.689] | |
Primary × Inequality | 1.01 [8.085] | −1.78 [7.557] | ||||
Primary × Youth Bulge | 113.12 [74.456] | 114.34 [76.197] | ||||
Constant | 2.5 [2.294] | −138.83*** [17.079] | −70.18 [74.914] | −117.41 [177.862] | 1134.73 [841.902] | 1110.99 [879.794] |
Number of Observation | 131 | 45 | 45 | 45 | 45 | 45 |
R-Squared | 0.292 | 0.871 | 0.876 | 0.871 | 0.898 | 0.898 |
Number of Countries | 22 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 |
DEPENDENT VARIABLE: CONFLICT INTENSITY | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 | Model 7 | |
Conflict Intensity (Lagged) | 0.13 [0.126] | 0.24 [0.174] | 0.21 [0.200] | 0.24 [0.199] | 0.31 [0.435] | 0.29 [0.190] | 0.8 [0.552] |
Secondary Enrolment | 1.49** [0.332] | 6.02* [2.408] | 6.02 [2.772] | 18.86** [4.382] | −20.83 [88.961] | −25.99 [13.556] | −141.81 [87.084] |
High Conflict Dummy | 2.50** [0.730] | 3.83*** [0.584] | 2.20** [0.669] | 2.83 [1.795] | 2.53** [0.696] | 3.68 [2.066] | |
Secondary × High Conflict | −0.48 [0.401] | 0.09 [0.895] | |||||
Natural Resource Rents | 0.64 [0.272] | 0.94** [0.245] | 1.04* [0.345] | 0.36 [0.943] | 0.86*** [0.144] | −0.11 [0.921] | |
Urbanization | 6.24* [2.307] | 7.86* [3.252] | 22.62*** [1.594] | 4.52 [8.465] | 7.82* [2.556] | 45.02* [15.836] | |
Income Inequality | 12.71*** [0.757] | 12.95*** [0.991] | 10.53*** [0.952] | −6.78 [65.995] | 12.75*** [1.099] | −30.53 [77.366] | |
Inflation | −0.73 [0.494] | −0.59 [0.653] | −0.76 [0.579] | −0.87 [0.925] | −0.77 [0.553] | −1.77 [1.336] | |
Youth Bulge | −118.98** [36.050] | −150.26*** [21.552] | −117.25* [40.292] | −149.58 [122.439] | −163.12*** [20.348] | −321.95* [110.444] | |
Democracy | 0.97 [1.166] | 0.63 [1.462] | 1.05 [1.246] | 1.29 [2.221] | 1 [1.220] | 3.49 [2.877] | |
Secondary × Resource Rents | |||||||
Secondary × Urbanization | −5.15*** [0.570] | −16.07 [8.143] | |||||
Secondary × Inequality | 7.95 [26.909] | 55.64 [30.983] | |||||
Secondary × Youth Bulge | 11.56* [4.500] | ||||||
Constant | −0.72 [1.676] | 282.94* [100.748] | 372.73*** [62.915] | 245.75 [107.180] | 438.53 [584.977] | 399.48*** [53.576] | 1244.50 [536.418] |
Observations | 116 | 39 | 39 | 39 | 39 | 39 | 39 |
R-Squared | 0.373 | 0.932 | 0.936 | 0.938 | 0.933 | 0.934 | 0.955 |
Number of Countries | 22 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 |
Dependent Variable: Conflict Intensity | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 | Model 7 | |
Conflict Intensity (Lagged) | 0.20** [0.061] | −0.51** [0.113] | −0.70*** [0.038] | −0.51** [0.113] | −0.52** [0.097] | −0.50** [0.111] | −0.52** [0.105] |
Tertiary Enrolment | 0.14 [0.327] | 0.16 [0.515] | 43.44* [14.826] | 0.13 [0.376] | 3.32 [6.462] | −0.01 [0.299] | 0.2 [0.497] |
High Conflict Dummy | 0.15 [0.104] | 0.1 [0.047] | 0.15 [0.120] | 0.12 [0.152] | 0.16 [0.103] | 0.21* [0.074] | |
Tertiary × Inequality | −12.78* [4.292] | ||||||
Natural Resource Rents | 0.06 [0.030] | 0.60** [0.184] | 0.04 [0.053] | 0.04* [0.016] | 0.07 [0.036] | −0.01 [0.010] | |
Urbanization | 8.97*** [0.449] | 12.14*** [0.781] | 8.91*** [0.828] | 8.77*** [0.823] | 8.81*** [0.665] | 8.18*** [0.766] | |
Income Inequality | 5.13** [1.181] | 2.16** [0.532] | 5.16** [1.372] | 5.21** [1.314] | 5.39** [1.452] | 5.16** [1.165] | |
Youth Bulge | 115.58*** [6.792] | 179.26*** [17.569] | 115.49*** [7.477] | 114.61*** [8.553] | 108.40*** [16.383] | 120.36*** [4.615] | |
Inflation | 0.23** [0.069] | 0.38*** [0.009] | 0.23** [0.072] | 0.24** [0.053] | 0.22* [0.073] | 0.26** [0.058] | |
Democracy | −1.27*** [0.150] | −1.42*** [0.065] | −1.26** [0.217] | −1.25*** [0.185] | −1.27*** [0.139] | −1.02** [0.257] | |
Tertiary × Urbanization | 0 [0.025] | ||||||
Tertiary × Youth Bulge | −1.11 [2.102] | ||||||
Tertiary × Inflation | 0.03 [0.036] | ||||||
Tertiary × Democracy | −0.11 [0.049] | ||||||
Constant | 1.20* [0.474] | −370.03*** [15.833] | −551.48*** [51.824] | −369.68*** [18.242] | −367.01*** [21.477] | −353.66*** [44.080] | −384.53*** [10.053] |
Observations | 98 | 37 | 37 | 37 | 37 | 37 | 37 |
R-Squared | 0.399 | 0.994 | 0.995 | 0.994 | 0.994 | 0.994 | 0.994 |
Number of Countries | 17 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 |
4.2. Robustness Checks Using GMM Estimation
Dependent Variable: Conflict Intensity | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | |
Conflict Intensity (Lagged) | 0.28*** [0.017] | 0.30*** [0.007] | 0.32*** [0.010] | 0.30*** [0.007] | 0.32*** [0.011] |
Primary Enrolment | −0.13 [0.578] | −0.13 [0.527] | −0.66 [0.516] | −0.03 [0.533] | −0.59 [0.548] |
Primary × Resource Rents | 0.03*** [0.010] | 0.03*** [0.011] | |||
Natural Resource Rents | 0.53* [0.308] | −2.00** [0.952] | 0.53* [0.311] | −1.96* [1.007] | |
Democracy | −0.03 [0.187] | −0.03 [0.186] | −0.04 [0.177] | −0.04 [0.175] | |
Income inequality | 1.33 [0.867] | 1.21 [0.873] | 1.28 [0.853] | 1.15 [0.861] | |
Urbanization | 1.29 [2.004] | 0.16 [1.760] | 1.25 [1.998] | 0.15 [1.753] | |
Inflation | 0 [0.001] | 0 [0.001] | 0 [0.001] | 0 [0.001] | |
Youth Bulge | 15.39 [18.991] | 16.38 [18.633] | 15.82 [19.936] | 16.62 [19.567] | |
High Conflict Dummy | 22.50* [11.849] | 24.15** [11.810] | 32.67 [31.868] | 31.25 [31.945] | |
Primary × High Conflict | −0.12 [0.260] | −0.09 [0.260] | |||
Constant | 43.02 [45.154] | −359.04 [390.881] | −325.89 [380.529] | −373.4 [424.232] | −345.83 [415.542] |
Observations | 359 | 309 | 309 | 309 | 309 |
Number of Countries | 25 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 |
Dependent Variable: Conflict Intensity | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | |
Conflict Intensity (Lagged) | 0.30*** [0.034] | 0.34*** [0.012] | 0.34*** [0.011] | 0.33*** [0.014] | 0.33*** [0.014] |
Secondary Enrolment | 3.75 [2.992] | −0.55 [0.949] | −0.51 [0.954] | 1.08 [2.691] | 1.11 [2.715] |
Secondary × High Conflict | −0.12 [0.186] | −0.11 [0.178] | |||
High Conflict Dummy | 12.96** [6.484] | 15.58 [9.487] | 12.86** [6.478] | 15.21 [9.306] | |
Natural Resource Rents | 0.33 [0.311] | 0.33 [0.312] | 0.33 [0.323] | 0.34 [0.324] | |
Urbanization | 2.11** [0.958] | 2.09** [0.955] | 6.58 [6.481] | 6.53 [6.454] | |
Income Inequality | 1.08 [0.728] | 1.08 [0.726] | 1.02 [0.732] | 1.03 [0.729] | |
Inflation | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | |
Youth Bulge | 11.86 [21.078] | 11.56 [21.021] | 13.84 [20.118] | 13.58 [20.021] | |
Democracy | −0.15 [0.109] | −0.15 [0.110] | −0.14 [0.103] | −0.15 [0.104] | |
Secondary × Urbanization | −0.43 [0.608] | −0.43 [0.607] | |||
Constant | −46.8 [58.960] | −265.55 [400.265] | −260.81 [399.141] | −324.7 [375.516] | −320.42 [373.748] |
Observations | 286 | 244 | 244 | 244 | 244 |
Number of Countries | 25 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 |
Dependent Variable: Conflict Intensity | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 | |
Conflict Intensity (Lagged) | 0.29*** [0.014] | 0.31*** [0.004] | 0.31*** [0.004] | 0.31*** [0.006] | 0.31*** [0.005] | 0.31*** [0.007] |
Tertiary Enrolment | 12.46*** [4.837] | −2.78 [3.172] | −4.23* [2.491] | 6.58 [10.278] | 19.28 [16.957] | 19.38 [18.760] |
Tertiary × High Conflict | −2.20** [1.123] | −1.60** [0.712] | ||||
Tertiary × Urbanization | −3.49 [3.530] | −2.81 [3.074] | ||||
Tertiary × Inequality | −0.58 [0.431] | −0.4 [0.358] | ||||
Tertiary × Democracy | 0.03 [0.038] | |||||
High Conflict Dummy | 13.07** [5.723] | 21.71*** [8.113] | 13.11** [5.308] | 14.25** [6.050] | 20.50*** [7.344] | |
Natural Resource Rents | 0.02 [0.349] | 0.06 [0.350] | −0.14 [0.456] | −0.04 [0.385] | −0.18 [0.492] | |
Urbanization | 4.78** [2.140] | 4.54** [2.113] | 7.31*** [2.062] | 3.9 [2.384] | 6.05*** [1.655] | |
Income Inequality | 2.31* [1.263] | 2.27* [1.235] | 1.86* [0.982] | 3.52* [2.010] | 2.74* [1.588] | |
Inflation | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | 0 [0.000] | |
Youth Bulge | 24.14 [16.295] | 26.27 [16.808] | 19.24 [13.505] | 25.91 [17.074] | 23.41 [15.039] | |
Democracy | −0.15* [0.087] | −0.18** [0.088] | −0.17* [0.100] | −0.16* [0.088] | −0.27* [0.160] | |
Constant | −12.35 [29.790] | −584.09* [331.295] | −616.54* [337.724] | −476.12* [265.168] | −665.97* [371.147] | −577.35* [306.530] |
Observations | 233 | 196 | 196 | 196 | 196 | 196 |
Number of Countries | 25 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
5. Summary and Conclusion
- 1
- Primary schooling broadly mitigates conflicts in Africa. However, in environments with high natural resource rents, it could ignite conflicts. This finding is consistent with prior empirical evidence notably by Barakat and Urdal (2009) [3] which suggests that the risk of conflict is higher in countries where low education levels coincide with the presence of abundant natural resources rents.
- 2
- There is evidence, although not overwhelming, that secondary schooling drives conflicts in Africa. There is also evidence that urbanization drives conflicts in Africa. However, although secondary schooling and urbanization potentially drives conflicts, in environments where secondary schooling (urbanization) is high, urbanization (secondary schooling) mitigates conflicts. The likely policy implication of this for African governments is that, in countries with a high level of urbanization, they should try to foster secondary education in order to reduce conflict.
- 3
- There is no evidence of a strong direct positive impact of tertiary education on conflicts in Africa, which is also consistent with Thyne (2006) [5]. Conditioning on tertiary schooling, income inequality appears to be a significant driver of conflicts in African states. However, in contexts where income inequality (tertiary schooling) is high, tertiary schooling (inequality) mitigates conflict. This finding somewhat contradicts the recommendations from Thyne (2006) [5] which cautions against disproportionate public investment in favor of tertiary education suggesting that this would likely ignite conflicts by widening the inequality gap between the rich and the poor. We argue that more investment in tertiary education (or more tertiary schooling to be more direct) is warranted in contexts where inequality levels are high, as this would enable folks to peacefully resolve their grievances or differences using formal institutional channels rather than by resorting to violence. The evidence in this study also lends partial support for African governments faced with high urbanization rates to continue investing in tertiary education as a conflict mitigation strategy.
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- World Bank. Lifelong Learning in the Global Knowledge Economy. Challenges for Developing Countries (Draft). Washington, D.C., USA: World Bank, 2002. [Google Scholar]
- G. Østby, and H. Urdal. “Education and Civil Conflict: A Review of the Quantitative Empirical Literature. Paper commissioned for the EFA Global Monitoring Report 2011, The Hidden Crisis: Armed Conflict and Education.” Available online: http://unesdoc.unesco.org/images/0019/001907/190777e.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- B. Barakat, and U. Henrik. “Breaking the Waves? ” In Does Education Mediate the Relationship Between Youth Bulges and Political Violence? Policy Research Working Paper 5114; Washington, DC, USA: The World Bank, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- A.B. Krueger, and J. Maleckova. “Education, Poverty and Terrorism: Is There a Causal Connection? ” J. Econ. Perspect. 17 (2003): 119–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- C. Thyne. “ABC’s, 123’s, and the Golden Rule: The Pacifying Effect of Education on Civil War, 1980–1999.” Int. Stud. Q. 50 (2006): 733–754. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- C. Berrebi. “Evidence about the Link Between Education, Poverty and Terrorism among Palestinians.” Peace Econ. Peace Sci. Public Policy 13 (2007): 1–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- C. Fair. “The Educated Militants of Pakistan: Implications for Pakistan’s Domestic Security.” Contemp. South Asia 16 (2008): 93–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- A. Oyefusi. “Education, Studentship, and the Disposition to Civil Unrest among Youths in Resource-Abundant Regions: Evidence from Nigeria’s Delta.” In Presented at the Conference on ‘Youth Exclusion and Political Violence: Breaking the Link and Engaging Young People Positively in Development’, Centre for the Study of Civil War (CSCW) at the Peace Research Institute, Oslo (PRIO), Norway, 4–6 December 2008.
- M. Shayo. “Education, Militarism and Civil Wars. Discussion Paper 07.03. Jerusalem: The Maurice Falk Institute for Economic Research in Israel.” Available online: http://pluto.huji.ac.il/~mshayo/Education_and_Militarism.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- H. Urdal. “Population, Resources and Violent Conflict: A Sub-National Study of India 1956–2002.” J. Confl. Resolut. 52 (2008): 590–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- M. Bussmann. “Gender Equality, Good Governance, and Peace.” In Presented at the General Polarization and Conflict (PAC) Meeting, Gaillac, France, 7–9 June 2007.
- M.L. Besançon. “Relative Resources: Inequality in Ethnic Wars, Revolutions, and Genocides.” J. Peace Res. 42 (2005): 393–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- H. Hegre. “2003. Disentangling Democracy and Development as Determinants of Armed Conflict.” In Presented at the Annual Meeting of International Studies Association, Portland, OR, USA, 27 February 2003.
- E. Aryeetey, and A. Fosu. “Explaining African Economic Growth Performance: The Case of Ghana. AERC Growth Working Paper, 7.” Available online: http://www.researchgate.net/publication/265074393_Explaining_African_Economic_Growth_Performance_The_Case_of_Ghana (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- S.B. Blomberg, G.D. Hess, and S. Thacker. “On the Conflict-Poverty Nexus.” Econ. Politics 18 (2006): 237–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J.A. Agbor. “2011. Does School Education Reduce the Likelihood of Societal Conflicts in Africa. Economic Research Southern Africa Working Paper No. 218.” Available online: http://www.econrsa.org/system/files/publications/working_papers/wp218.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- N.P. Gleditsch, P. Wallensteen, M. Eriksson, M. Sollenberg, and H. Strand. “Armed Conflict 1946–2001: A New Dataset.” J. Peace Res. 39 (2002): 615–637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- D. Acemoglu, and J.A. Robinson. “A Theory of Political Transitions.” Am. Econ. Rev. 91 (2001): 938–963. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- P. Collier, and A. Hoeffler. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War.” Oxf. Econ. Papers 56 (2004): 563–595. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- A. Akoki, B. Barbara, D. Micheal, M. Mmantetsa, M. Alain, M. Peter, M. Patrick, P. Pirella, P. Harry, T. Jee-Peng, and et al. “Chapter 19: Education.” Available online: http://info.worldbank.org/etools/docs/library/81136/Nairobi2004/readings/ed/edprspsourcebookeng.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- A. Alesina, and R. Perotti. “Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment.” Eur. Econ. Rev. 40 (1996): 1203–1228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- D. Hibbs. Mass Political Violence: A Cross-National Causal Analysis. New York, NY, USA: Wiley, 1973. [Google Scholar]
- S.P. Huntington. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT, USA: Yale University Press, 1968. [Google Scholar]
- G. Becker, and C. Mulligan. “On the Endogenous Determination of Time Preference.” Q. J. Econ. 112 (1997): 729–758. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- G. Becker. Accounting for Tastes. Cambridge, MA, USA: Harvard University Press, 1996. [Google Scholar]
- K. Arrow. “The Benefits of Education and the Formation of Preferences.” In The Social Benefits of Education. Edited by J. Behrman and N. Stacey. Ann Arbor, MI, USA: The Univeristy of Michigan Press, 1997, pp. 11–16. [Google Scholar]
- O. Galor, and O. Moav. “Das Human Kapital: A Theory of the Demise of the Class Structure.” J. Rev. Econ. Stud. 73 (2006): 85–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J.W. Fedderke, and C. Kularatne. “Characterizing Conflict Forms. Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics Working Paper.” Available online: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DEC/Resources/84797–1284144259233/7386294–1284385904490/JohannesFedderke.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- F. Bourguignon, and T. Verdier. “The Political Economy of Education and Development in an Open Economy. Center of Economic Policy Research Working Paper 3075.” Available online: http://www.cepr.org/active/publications/discussion_papers/dp.php?dpno=3075 (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- D.E. Apter. The Gold Coast in Transition. Princeton, NJ, USA: Princeton University Press, 1955. [Google Scholar]
- J.P. Foster. Education and Social Change in Ghana. London, UK: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1965. [Google Scholar]
- H.O.A. McWilliam, and M.A. Kwamena-Poh. The Development of Education in Ghana: An Outline. London, UK: Longman Group Limited, 1978. [Google Scholar]
- J. Hirshleifer. “Anarchy and its Breakdown.” J. Polit. Econ. 103 (1995): 26–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- R. Bates, A. Greif, and S. Singh. “Organising Violence.” J. Confl. Resolut. 46 (2007): 599–628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- L. Davies. Education and Conflict: Complexity and Chaos. New York, NY, USA: Routledge, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- L. Vriens. Responsibility for the Future: The Key to Peace Education. City, Country: Publisher, 2003, pp. 71–83. [Google Scholar]
- K. Bush, and D. Saltarelli. The Two Faces of Education in Ethnic Conflict: Towards a Peace Building Education for Children. Florence, Italy: UNICEF Innocenti Research Centre, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- A. Smith, and T. Vaux. Education, Conflict and International Development. London, UK: Department for International Development, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- H. Urdal. “A Clash of Generations? Youth Bulges and Political Violence.” Int. Stud. Q. 50 (2006): 607–630. [Google Scholar]
- N. Choucri. “Population Dynamics and International Violence: Propositions, Insights and Evidence.” Lexington, MA, USA: DC Health, 1974. [Google Scholar]
- J.A. Goldstone. Demography, Environment, and Security. Edited by P.F. Diehl and N.P. Gleditsch. Boulder, CO, USA: Westview, 2001. [Google Scholar]
- B. Lia. Globalisation and the Future of Terrorism: Patterns and Predictions. London, UK: Routledge, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- J. Boyden, and P. Ryder. “Implementing the Right to Education in Areas of Armed Conflict.” Available online: http://www.essex.ac.uk/armedcon/story_id/000454.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- R. Lange. “Promoting Livelihood and Employment in Post-conflict situations.” Available online: www.enterprise-development.org/download.ashx?id=2091 (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- M. Sommers. Youth: Care and Protection of Children in Emergencies: A Field Guide. Washington, DC, USA: Save the Children US, 2001. [Google Scholar]
- D. Senghaas. Zivilisierung wider Willen. Der Konflikt der Kulturen mit sich selbst. Frankfurt, Germany: Suhrkamp, 1998. [Google Scholar]
- S. Klaus. “ìWeltweite Bildung und soziale Ungleichheit.” In Marianne Heimbach-Steins und Gerhard Kruip (Hg.). Bielefeld, Germany: Bildung und Beteiligungsgerechtigkeit, 2003, pp. 75–96. [Google Scholar]
- P. Aguilar, and M. Richmond. “Emergency Educational Response in the Rwandan Crisis.” In Retamal and Aedo-Richmond. Geneva, Switzerland: International Bureau of Education, 1998, pp. 119–141. [Google Scholar]
- M. Arellano, and R. Carrasco. “Binary Choice Panel Data Models with Predetermined Variables.” J. Econom. 115 (2003): 125–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- R.H. Bates. Markets and States in Tropical Africa. Berkeley, CA, USA: University of California Press, 1981. [Google Scholar]
- P. Collier, A. Hoeffler, and D. Rohner. “Beyond Greed and Grievance: Feasibility and Civil War. CSAE WPS/2006/-10.” Available online: http://www.csae.ox.ac.uk/workingpapers/pdfs/2006–10text.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- J. Auvinen. “Political Instability Conflict in Less Developed Countries: Further Evidence.” J. Peace Res. 34 (1997): 267–290. [Google Scholar]
- A. Annett. “Social Fractionalization, Political Instability and the Size of Government.” Available online: http://www.imf.org/External/Pubs/FT/staffp/2001/03/pdf/annett.pdf pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- M. Duffield. Global Governance and the New Wars. London, UK: Zed Books, 2001. [Google Scholar]
- S.M. Murshed. “Conflict, Civil War and Underdevelopment: An Introduction.” J. Peace Res. 39 (2002): 387–393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- E. Elbadawi, and N. Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa? Understanding and preventing violent conflict.” J. Afr. Econ. 9 (2000): 244–269. [Google Scholar]
- M.L. Ross. “What Do We Know about Natural Resources and Civil War? ” J. Peace Res. 41 (2004): 337–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J.D. Fearon, and D.D. Laitin. “Ethnicity, Insurgency and Civil War.” Am. Political Sci. Rev. 97 (2003): 75–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- M. Bleaney, and A. Dimico. “Ethnic Diversity and Local Conflicts.” Available online: http://www.csae.ox.ac.uk/conferences/2009-EDiA/papers/461-BleaneyDimico.pdf (accessed on 3 October 2015).
- 1The World Bank has unequivocally stressed its faith in the key significance of education and lifelong learning in reinforcing social cohesion: “by improving people’s ability to function as members of their communities, education and training increase social cohesion, reduce crime and improve income distribution”, World Bank (2002) [1].
- 2While Thyne (2006) [5] finds no significant effect of higher education on conflict, Besançon (2005) [12] finds that higher tertiary education levels increase the risk of ethnic wars and genocides, whereas they lower the risk of revolutions. Bussmann (2007) [11] on his part finds that tertiary education has an overall pacifying effect. The underlying message behind all these studies is that education does not necessarily have the same pacifying effect on all kinds of conflict.
- 3For example, Barakat and Urdal (2009) [3] find that low rates of male secondary education are more likely to cause conflict in societies with large young male population bulges, particularly in poor countries, and particularly in Sub-Saharan Africa.
- 4Investigating the context of youth bulges in natural resource dependent economies, Barakat and Urdal (2009) [3] find some evidence indicating that the presence of large youth cohorts with low education significantly increases the risk of conflict in countries with high dependence on natural resource.
- 5Hegre (2003) [13] find that increasing literacy rates decrease the risk of armed conflict in countries with functional democracies, but the relation is not verified in the context of non-functional democracies.
- 8See Galor and Moav (2006) [27].
- 10In Hirshleifer’s model, more knowledge acquired from schooling means a better technology of fighting and an increasing number of unemployed graduates implies an increased number of potential belligerents.
- 15Huntington (1968) [23], for instance, argues that: “Social and economic change. … extends political consciousness, multiply political demands, broaden political participation… These changes undermine traditional sources of political authority and traditional political institutions… The result are political instability and disorder…”.
- 16Senghaas (1998) [46], also argues that education is capable of unleashing and multiplying conflicts: “Development (…) is inevitably conflictual, destabilizing and subversive because it challenges the established power structures that prevent individuals and groups from reaching their full potential”.
- 17The UCDP database defines battle-related deaths as conflict behavior between warring parties in the conflict dyad, which is directly related to some known incompatibility, i.e., carried out with the purpose of realizing the goal of the incompatibility and results in deaths. This includes traditional battlefield fighting, guerrilla activities (e.g., hit-and-run attacks/ambushes) and all kinds of bombardments of military bases, cities and villages. Although urban warfare (bombs, explosions, and assassinations) does not resemble what happens on a battlefield, deaths resulting from such are considered as battle-related. In same wise, all fatalities—military as well as civilian—incurred from attacks on military forces or representatives for the parties are counted as battle-related deaths.
- 18Due to data unavailability, these episodes ignore any foreign involvement in the domestic conflict. Although, the specific aspect of the conflict investigated that is, its intensity, is likely to increase with foreign involvement, the influence of foreign involvement is likely to under-estimate, rather than overestimate the impact of education on conflict intensity, assuming that in highly intense conflict situations educational outcomes are negatively affected.
- 19HIGHCON takes on the value 1 for CIVTOT > 2.95 (which is the mean value for CIVTOT) and 0 otherwise.
- 21See the evidence notably by Fearon and Laitin (2003) [58], and Bleaney and Dimico (2002) [59]. Elbadawi and Sambanis (2000) [56] however hold the opposite view that the relatively higher incidence of war in Africa is not due to the ethno-linguistic fragmentation of its countries, but rather to high levels of poverty, failed political institutions and economic dependence on natural resources.
© 2015 by the authors; licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Agbor, J.A. Effects of Primary, Secondary and Tertiary Education on Conflict Intensity in Africa. Economies 2015, 3, 161-185. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies3040161
Agbor JA. Effects of Primary, Secondary and Tertiary Education on Conflict Intensity in Africa. Economies. 2015; 3(4):161-185. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies3040161
Chicago/Turabian StyleAgbor, Julius A. 2015. "Effects of Primary, Secondary and Tertiary Education on Conflict Intensity in Africa" Economies 3, no. 4: 161-185. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies3040161
APA StyleAgbor, J. A. (2015). Effects of Primary, Secondary and Tertiary Education on Conflict Intensity in Africa. Economies, 3(4), 161-185. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies3040161