Next Article in Journal
Steadying the Ship: Can Export Proceeds Repatriation Policy Stabilize Indonesian Exchange Rates Amid Short-Term Capital Flow Fluctuations?
Previous Article in Journal
Classification of Latin American and Caribbean Countries Based on Multidimensional Development Indicators: A Multivariate Empirical Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Linking R&D and Productivity in South Africa: The Moderating Role of Human Skills

by
Brian Tavonga Mazorodze
*,
Darlington Chizema
and
Phetole Emanuel Ramatsoma
Department of Accounting and Economics, Faculty of Economic and Management Sciences, Sol Plaatje University, Kimberley 8301, South Africa
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2025, 13(6), 179; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13060179
Submission received: 23 April 2025 / Revised: 5 June 2025 / Accepted: 15 June 2025 / Published: 18 June 2025

Abstract

:
This study examines the impact of research and development (R&D) on productivity outcomes across South African industries. Drawing on an industry-level panel dataset covering 66 industries (6 mining, 37 manufacturing, and 23 services) stretching from 1993 to 2023, the study estimates how a change in the initial R&D stock affects labor and capital productivity over a five-year horizon using the Feasible Generalized Least Squares (FGLS) method. The results reveal a positive but weak elasticity of labor productivity to R&D stock (0.01–0.02%), consistent with existing literature. The effects on capital productivity are even lower (0.003–0.005%), suggesting that R&D more directly enhances labor productivity than capital. Sectoral estimations indicate that R&D has no significant effect on labor productivity in mining but a strong productivity effect in manufacturing and services—twice as large in the latter. In contrast, capital productivity gains are only evident in mining. Additionally, the study finds that R&D effects are larger in technology-intensive industries, and the productivity benefits increase with the share of skilled workers, underscoring the importance of absorptive capacity. Overall, the findings suggest that while R&D matters for productivity, its returns are stronger in human capital- and technology-intensive industries.

1. Introduction

Empirical research addressing the productivity effects of research and development (R&D) is more than four decades old. Underpinning this strand of literature is the general understanding that R&D is a major driver of productivity growth, which is, in turn, a crucial driver of economic development (Hall et al., 2010). Despite the plausibility of this proposition, the degree to which R&D results in productivity increases remains contentious among economists. Some have argued that the impact is largely contingent on institutional frameworks, technological intensity, and human capital (Griffith et al., 2004). In this paper, this study joins this literature by examining the moderating role of human capital in the relationship between R&D and productivity growth in South Africa.
The theoretical foundations of the R&D/productivity nexus may be traced back to endogenous growth models, in which technical development driven by innovation is a significant driver of economic development (Romer, 1990; Aghion & Howitt, 1992). Romer (1990) argued that contrary to neoclassical models, economic growth is driven by internal forces of capital, human capital, and innovation. Romer (1990) and Lucas (1988) particularly pioneered the endogenous growth model, which has now become a common framework for examining the effects of innovation on productivity and productivity. Aghion and Howitt (1992) and Grossman and Helpman (1991) also claimed that the benefits of enhanced human capital and more innovation extended beyond the knowledge sectors to other economic sectors. Similarly, You (1979) asserts that the rate of productivity growth that a country’s economy can generate when full employment is in place is contingent upon several factors, including the amount of capital stock, technology, and human capital.
In essence, R&D improves productivity by developing new goods and more efficient manufacturing techniques (Romer, 1990). This is supported by Keller (2009), who emphasizes that technological progress plays a significant role in productivity and that variations in productivity are particularly significant since they account for income disparities across countries. It is against this background that the link between R&D and productivity has been heavily examined, with most empirical evidence supporting a positive but often moderate impact (Mairesse & Sassenou, 1991; Hall et al., 2010). R&D increases productivity at the business and industry levels by encouraging innovation, improving manufacturing processes, and promoting technological adoption (Griffith et al., 2004). However, the degree of this effect varies by sector, with technology-intensive industries often showing higher returns on R&D. Moreover, the evidence from emerging and middle-income economies is more conflicting and often demonstrates less significant impacts (Crespi & Zuniga, 2012).
The extent to which R&D affects productivity differs across sectors. For example, Ortega-Argilés et al. (2015) discovered that R&D investments typically yield more benefits for the manufacturing and services sectors than for primary sectors such as mining. This supports the findings of Sterlacchini and Venturini (2014) and Fernandez (2022), who observed that technology-intensive industries respond more productively to R&D. In contrast, Fan et al. (2017) found no significant relationship between R&D intensity and output per worker in China’s mining industry. These inconclusive findings make it difficult to draw firm conclusions about how R&D affects industries in different sectors.
At a macro level, it has been argued that the productivity gains from R&D are typically less pronounced in emerging and middle-income economies than in advanced ones, in part because of a reduced capability to absorb and effectively utilize outside information (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). This approach has been backed by subsequent research, such as Sterlacchini and Venturini (2014) and Elkomy et al. (2021), which stressed the role of human skills in maximizing R&D benefits. It is against this background that the importance of human capital in moderating the impact of R&D on productivity is becoming more widely acknowledged (Cammeraat et al., 2021; Gerybadze, 2010; Criscuolo et al., 2021). Skilled employees improve absorptive capacity, allowing businesses and industries at large to better use R&D for productivity gains (Roberts & Wolf, 2018). This view is backed by Mason et al.’s (2020) findings, which imply that industries with a higher proportion of skilled people benefit more from R&D. Research conducted in African contexts, including Adeosun et al. (2024), emphasizes that the productivity gains of R&D are often hampered by a lack of human capital and insufficient supplementary investments in skills.
Several studies have been conducted in both developed and emerging economies to examine the relationship between R&D and productivity. Prior studies conducted in South Africa have demonstrated the beneficial effects of research and development on productivity and economic growth, especially in the manufacturing sector (Ledwaba, 2022). Research has particularly demonstrated that while the impacts on capital productivity are often less observed, R&D investments result in innovations that increase labor productivity (Kahn et al., 2022).
Although the significance of human talents has received little attention, several studies have looked at the relationship between innovation and productivity in South Africa. According to Cassim et al. (2020), innovation improves company performance in manufacturing; however, the impacts are somewhat tempered by workforce skill levels. Similarly, Hanlin et al. (2022) contend that to provide long-term productivity gains, innovation policy needs to be in line with the growth of human capital.
The effectiveness of South Africa’s innovative ecosystem is called into question due to the country’s slow productivity growth, even with high spending on R&D. Research in developed economies has consistently shown that R&D and productivity are positively correlated (Hall et al., 2010; Griffith et al., 2004). However, the evidence from middle-income countries, especially those in Africa, is still inconsistent. The industrial structure of South Africa, which is defined by a diminishing manufacturing base, a growing services sector, and a dominant mining industry, creates a special setting where R&D returns can vary greatly amongst industries. Furthermore, ongoing skill shortages and incompatibility may make it more difficult for industries to convert R&D into productivity increases.
In addition, South African literature on R&D and productivity has mostly concentrated on aggregate impacts, often ignoring sectoral heterogeneities and the moderating influence of human capital (Adeosun et al., 2024). For example, mining’s capital-intensive nature may limit its responsiveness to new investments, but manufacturing and services, which depend on knowledge-intensive processes, may gain more from R&D. Furthermore, not enough research has been conducted in the South African setting to determine how much skilled labor boosts the productivity effects of R&D.
To this end, this study contributes by determining the extent to which skilled workers moderate the relationship between R&D investment and productivity across South African industries and understanding the sectoral conditions under which this effect is most pronounced. Drawing on the absorptive capacity framework (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990), the study posits that skilled labor enhances firms’ ability to internalize and apply R&D outputs, thereby amplifying productivity gains. This moderating effect is expected to be stronger in knowledge- and technology-intensive sectors, where innovation processes are more reliant on specialized expertise and learning-by-doing. Conversely, in capital-intensive or low-skill sectors, the productivity effects of R&D may be muted due to limited absorptive capacity. By integrating this theoretical lens with sector-level empirical analysis, the study aims to clarify the mechanisms through which human capital transforms R&D inputs into productivity outcomes, thereby contributing to a more nuanced understanding of South Africa’s innovation productivity dynamics. The findings are intended to inform evidence-based policymaking and guide strategic innovation investments to enhance productivity growth in the South African economy.
The rest of the study is organized as follows. Section 2 is the literature review section. Section 3 provides the methodology. Section 4 presents and interprets empirical findings. Section 5 discusses empirical findings. Lastly, Section 6 provides conclusions and policy recommendations.

2. Literature Review

Understanding the channels through which R&D influences productivity has been subject to empirical inquiry in the last four decades, aided by the emergence of endogenous growth theories. While several studies have documented a positive relationship between R&D and productivity growth, interest in understanding the mechanisms underpinning this relationship continues to shape and define the objectives of most recent related studies. This section draws insights from endogenous growth theory and the literature on absorptive capacity to propose a theoretical framework in which the productivity gains from R&D are conditional on the level of human skills.

2.1. Theoretical Framework

Understanding the sources of productivity growth has occupied the hearts and minds of development economists for decades. In earlier classical theories, productivity growth primarily arises from labor specialization and the division of labor. In these theories, productivity improvements are largely shaped by how production activities are organized within firms, industries, sectors, and countries. This idea was later extended to the theory of comparative advantage, in which productivity differences across industries and countries reflect relative opportunity costs. According to this theory, productivity gains arise when countries specialize in producing goods for which they have a lower opportunity cost and engage in trade in exchange for goods that would be more costly for them to produce domestically. Marxism theories, on the other hand, emphasize the role of surplus value extracted from labor and the structural dynamics of capitalist economies. While these classical insights were rich in scope, they lacked formal mechanisms for isolating and quantifying the sources of productivity gains.
Structuralist models added another dimension by focusing on the dualistic nature of their production systems. Lewis (1954) and Fei and Ranis (1964) argued that productivity growth in such setups depends on structural transformation, the reallocation of labor from low-productivity traditional sectors to higher-productivity modern sectors. Despite providing a plausible explanation that resonated with the experiences of most developing countries at the time, structural models similarly lack explicit mechanisms through which productivity growth could be sustained in the long run.
The emergence of neoclassical growth theory, particularly the Solow growth model, provided what would be an important theoretical framework from which economists could derive testable hypotheses for decades. Within this model, output was modeled as a function of capital and labor, with technological progress treated as an exogenous factor. The so-called Solow residual became a proxy for total factor productivity, and it captures the unexplained portion of output growth not attributable to measured inputs. Despite being the mainstay of earlier studies, the exogeneity of technological progress in this framework left open questions regarding its origins and determinants, inviting further theoretical refinement.
The limitations associated with the neoclassical growth theories gave rise to the endogenous growth theory, in which technology was considered endogenous. Endogenous growth theories particularly viewed innovation as an outcome of domestic R&D efforts that accumulated over time (Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988). In essence, these models suggested that productivity growth could be self-reinforcing, with knowledge spillovers and increasing returns to scale playing an important role. Innovation ceased to be an exogenous outcome but rather became an outcome of deliberate economic choices shaped by institutional, policy, and market environments. Importantly, these theories emphasized the complementarity between R&D and human capital and demonstrated that the benefits of innovation are more fully realized when firms have the skills necessary to adopt, adapt, and diffuse new technologies.
Parallel contributions from institutional economics, particularly those of North (1990) and, later, Acemoglu et al. (2001), highlighted that productivity outcomes are conditioned by the broader governance and incentive structures within which economic activity takes place. Secure property rights, contract enforcement, and effective public institutions influence the return on investments in both physical and intangible capital, including R&D. These perspectives enriched the theoretical landscape by emphasizing that productivity is not merely a technical phenomenon but is deeply embedded in political and institutional setups.
Within the realm of endogenous growth theories, the effectiveness of R&D in enhancing productivity growth is thought to depend on a set of complementary factors, among which human capital, particularly the availability of skilled labor, plays a central role. In particular, the notion that R&D-induced technological progress requires an adequate absorptive capacity is rooted in the seminal work of Cohen and Levinthal (1990), who argue that the capacity of firms to apply new knowledge is strongly influenced by the level of existing human capital. In this framework, skilled workers act as a mechanism through which R&D is translated into productivity gains.
This study is, therefore, theoretically grounded in the work of Cohen and Levinthal (1990), given the specific objective of the analysis and the South African context. It is widely reported that productivity returns to R&D have been relatively modest in South Africa despite considerable investments in innovation infrastructure. One plausible explanation lies in the limited availability and uneven distribution of human skills across the economy. The South African labor market is characterized by structural mismatches, skills shortages, and significant inequalities in educational attainment. These limitations potentially constrain the diffusion and effective utilization of R&D outputs, which consequently limits their contribution to productivity.
Accordingly, this study posits that the productivity-enhancing effects of R&D in South Africa are conditional on the level of human skills. The theoretical expectation is that R&D expenditures yield higher productivity gains in industries and sectors with a higher concentration of skilled workers.

2.2. Empirical Literature

The relationship between technological innovation, human capital, and industrial productivity has garnered considerable empirical attention in recent decades. Within the most recent literature, studies have been particularly interested in examining conditional factors that moderate the impact of R&D and innovation on productivity growth. Among these empirical studies, Awode and Oduola (2025) provide an important contribution to this discussion by examining 36 African countries from 1996 to 2021. Using the generalized method of moments, their study reveals a negative effect of innovation on productivity, while human capital has a significantly positive impact. Importantly, their findings demonstrate the moderating role of human skills on the relationship between innovation and productivity growth. Despite the plausibility of their finding, it is noteworthy that the generalized method of moments applied in their study falls short in handling potential cross-sectional dependence.
Griffith et al. (2004) highlight the role of innovation in enhancing production efficiency and facilitating the diffusion of frontier technologies. Supporting this line of inquiry are cross-sectional studies that reveal significant heterogeneity, with the most pronounced gains observed in technology-intensive industries characterized by high absorptive capacity and innovation potential (Ortega-Argilés et al., 2015; Czarnitzki et al., 2011). Despite the wealth of literature on R&D and productivity, the empirical literature examining the relationship between R&D and productivity in South Africa remains relatively underdeveloped and yields inconclusive findings, particularly at the disaggregated sectoral level. Edwards and Jenkins (2015) attribute this ambiguity to persistent structural constraints, including labor market frictions such as skills mismatches and heterogeneity in firms’ innovation capabilities, which inhibit the diffusion of productivity-enhancing technologies. More recent empirical contributions have begun to shed light on sector-specific dynamics. For instance, Kahn et al. (2022) provide evidence that both product and process innovations are positively correlated with productivity performance in the manufacturing sector, suggesting that innovation can yield efficiency gains.
The complementarity between human capital and innovation documented in theory is observed in broader empirical work. For instance, Kumar et al. (2025), employing a partial least squares/structural equation modeling approach, find that firms benefit from R&D efforts when industry–academic knowledge transfers are robust. Their findings suggest that collaborative linkages with academia not only augment innovation capability but also improve R&D performance, reinforcing the case for multi-sectoral partnerships in fostering innovation ecosystems. Meanwhile, Keller (2009) and Mairesse and Sassenou (1991) provide robust evidence of a positive relationship between R&D intensity and productivity outcomes. Recent contributions by Besiroglu et al. (2024) highlight the disruptive potential of artificial intelligence (AI)-enabled R&D, which is accelerating innovation cycles and enhancing productivity, especially within high-technology sectors. Based on an industry-level analysis, B. T. Mazorodze (2025) advocates for the strategic alignment of industrial policy instruments and R&D subsidies with sector-specific technological efforts. In parallel, Mokgokong and Mukonza (2024) call for a collaborative R&D ecosystem embedded within South Africa’s developmental state paradigm, emphasizing the importance of synergistic partnerships among government, academia, and industry in fostering innovation-led growth. Li (2024) adds further empirical evidence through an analysis of Korean exporters, showing that the “learning-by-exporting” phenomenon, where export activity spurs innovation, is moderated by human capital. Firms employing a more educated and internationally experienced workforce are better positioned to translate export exposure into innovation gains. Their study aligns with the contention that the quality and absorptive capacity of human capital can determine the extent to which technological and market stimuli are internalized and transformed into productive outcomes.
Empirical studies by Sterlacchini and Venturini (2014), Cirera et al. (2022), and Cammeraat et al. (2021) affirm that skilled labor significantly enhances the productivity returns to R&D. In developing economies, Fernandez (2022), Elkomy et al. (2021), Gerybadze (2010), and Criscuolo et al. (2021) similarly find that higher levels of human capital enhance the efficacy of innovation efforts. Curtis et al. (2020) show that the historical link between R&D spending and future profitability has weakened among U.S. public firms, potentially due to saturation in mature technological domains or shifts in the composition of R&D-active firms. These findings raise important questions about the efficiency of current R&D allocation strategies and demonstrate the need to consider contextual and structural factors such as human capital in shaping the productivity outcomes of innovative investments. On the other hand, lack of innovative drive and mindset in resource-based sectors such as mining often exhibit limited or statistically insignificant productivity effects from R&D investment, as evidenced by Fan et al. (2017), reflecting structural constraints and lower innovation intensity in these domains. Ledwaba (2022) finds that R&D investment has contributed to improvements in labor productivity, although gains in capital productivity remain limited, indicating potential inefficiencies in capital utilization or technological absorption.
More recently, Cuevas-Vargas and Cortés-Palacios (2025), analyzing Mexican SMEs, show that capital structure significantly influences technological innovation and, by extension, firm performance. Crucially, firms with higher absorptive capacity are better able to translate innovation efforts into superior performance outcomes. Similarly, Zhu et al. (2020), in the context of Chinese regional innovation systems, find that while both direct R&D investments and grants contribute to innovation performance, the effectiveness of these inputs is conditioned by the absorptive capacity of recipient firms or regions. These insights collectively highlight that innovation is not merely a function of investment but also of institutional and organizational readiness, often encapsulated by human and relational capital. Empirical analyses by Cassim et al. (2020) and Hanlin et al. (2022) demonstrate the critical role of complementary investments in human capital formation, suggesting that R&D-driven productivity improvements are unlikely to be sustained in the absence of a skilled labor force. Further, Mason et al. (2020) and Adeosun et al. (2024) identify structural constraints in the labor market, particularly the shortage of highly skilled workers, as a key impediment to the translation of R&D inputs into measurable productivity outcomes. Haneda and Ono (2022) emphasize the significance of internal R&D governance mechanisms, including project management practices and incentive structures, in shaping innovation performance. Beyond firm-level capabilities, macro-level factors such as interdisciplinarity and digitalization also influence innovation outcomes. Melnychuk and Schultz (2025), examining medical technology firms, identify a trade-off between the breadth of interdisciplinary R&D and the complexity of innovation validation. Their findings emphasize that firms must possess adequate capabilities, financial slack, academic collaborations, and access to scientific networks to harness the benefits of diverse knowledge inputs. Meanwhile, Jorge Ulises and Pablo José (2024), analyzing service sector firms in Peru, demonstrate that digitalization moderates the relationship between human factor management and firm productivity, suggesting that technological readiness enhances productivity returns to human capital investments.
Within the above-reviewed literature, our study contributes by estimating the impact of R&D on productivity with a specific focus on the moderating role of skilled workers. The next section provides the methodology from which the empirical results of the study are based.

3. Methodology

Guided by theoretical and empirical literature (Scherer, 1983; Zhang et al., 2012; Ciaffi, 2025), the study considers the following function:
y = f x , z
where y is a productivity measure (labor and capital), x captures the stock of R&D proxying innovation (Kafouros, 2005; Siliverstovs, 2016; Peng et al., 2024; Tetteh, 2024), and z is a vector of controls (export intensity, import penetration, unit labor cost, and capital/labor ratio). The stock of R&D is measured using the perpetual inventory and a deprecation rate of 15% based on the metadata from our data source. Using an industry-level dataset following Bogliacino and Pianta (2011), the estimated model then takes the following form:
y i t = α + δ x i t 5 + θ z i t 5 + γ s i t 5 + β x i t 5 × s i t 5 + ε i t    
where subscripts i   and   t denote industry and year, respectively, y , x , and z are as defined before, s is the share of skilled workers, α , δ , θ ,   γ ,   and β are unknown parameters to be estimated, and ε is the stochastic error term. Parameter β captures the moderating effect of skilled workers. Inclusion of the interactive term is an attempt to capture the potentially important role of skilled workers in ensuring that industries absorb the new knowledge and maximize the benefits of R&D. In this regard, δ > 0 and β > 0 would suggest that the positive effect of R&D on productivity increases with the share of skilled workers.
The study introduces 5 lags to mitigate endogeneity, as productivity levels may influence industrial R&D efforts (Bravo-Ortega & Marín, 2011). In the empirical literature, the use of lags to mitigate endogeneity is a common practice applied in studies such as Bogliacino and Pianta (2011), Blanco et al. (2016), and more recently, Magazzino and Santeramo (2024). By using 5 lags, this study seeks to establish how a change in the current R&D stock influences productivity over a 5-year period. The logic behind this methodological approach is that it is less likely that industries will make their R&D decisions in year t based on future or expected (i.e., year 5) productivity levels. Apart from partially mitigating endogeneity, the use of lags is additionally intuitive as R&D normally takes time to enhance productivity due to learning and the possible retraining of workers (Ravenscraft & Scherer, 1982).
In line with both theoretical expectations and empirical findings in the productivity literature, the study includes a set of control variables in the model to account for additional industry-level characteristics that may influence productivity outcomes. In essence, the study includes controls in a bid to isolate the effect of R&D stock on productivity while accounting for other relevant drivers of industry performance.
Export intensity is included to capture the role of international market exposure in enhancing productivity through competition, knowledge spillovers, and scale economies (Rafique et al., 2025; Casagrande et al., 2024). Theoretical models, such as Melitz (2003), argue that exporting industries are generally more productive due to self-selection and learning-by-exporting mechanisms (Kamal, 2024; Bartoloni et al., 2025). Empirical studies have similarly found positive associations between export intensity and productivity (Nguyen et al., 2024; Ali & Akhtar, 2024; Ünsal, 2024; Van Biesebroeck, 2005; B. Mazorodze, 2020). Import penetration is also considered as a control to reflect the degree of foreign competition faced by domestic industries (Friesenbichler et al., 2024; Unegbu & Ugwunna, 2024). Import competition may compel industries to innovate, reduce inefficiencies, or reallocate resources more effectively, which consequently enhances productivity (Aghion et al., 2009).
Unit labor cost is introduced to control for variations in industrial competitiveness. High unit labor costs can hamper productivity if wage growth outpaces efficiency gains, while declining unit labor costs may signal improvements in labor productivity or cost efficiency (Stundziene & Baliute, 2022; Karlsone & Ozola, 2023).
The capital/labor ratio is used to account for differences in production technology and capital intensity across industries (Chen, 2020; Wu & Chen, 2023). A higher capital/labor ratio often reflects capital deepening, which is generally associated with higher productivity (Chen, 2020; Astutik & Nugroho, 2024).

3.1. Estimation Strategy

The results from Pesaran’s test for cross-sectional dependence indicated strong evidence of correlation across the cross-sectional units in the panel dataset. The t-statistic was found to be 12.763 with a p-value of 0.0000, confirming a high prevalence of cross-sectional dependence at all conventional significance levels. The average absolute value of the off-diagonal elements of the correlation matrix was additionally 0.47, suggesting a moderate to high level of average correlation among the industries. This result implied that standard first-generation panel estimators that assume cross-sectional independence, such as fixed effects or random effects models, would produce biased and inconsistent standard errors (Pesaran, 2021). Compounding the prevalence of cross-sectional dependence was the presence of first-order serial correlation and heteroscedasticity, which, if ignored, distorts statistical inference (Bai et al., 2021). To account for these violations, the study estimated our baseline model using the feasible generalized least squares method, as recommended by Greene (2018). The alternative and commonly applied estimators, such as the system Generalized Method of Moments (GMM), the panel Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares (PDOLS) method, and the Pooled Mean Group (PMG), were inappropriate for this specific analysis. The system GMM is technically designed for small T and large N cases (Roodman, 2009), which makes it less appropriate given our moderate-to-large T of 31 years. In addition, this estimator, although desirable on account of addressing endogeneity explicitly, is inconsistent and less efficient in the presence of cross-sectional dependence. Monte Carlo results in Sarafidis and Robertson (2009) show that the standard moment conditions used by these estimators become invalid in the presence of cross-sectional dependence. In addition, they show that the bias of these estimators can be quite severe to the extent that the traditional within-estimator will not be comparatively inferior anymore (Sarafidis & Robertson, 2009). The PDOLS method suffers the same weakness of assuming cross-cross-sectional independence, an assumption that was strongly violated in our case. It is against this background that the feasible generalized least squares method was preferred for estimation.
Our estimation strategy first estimates the total sample. To account for potential heterogeneities in the way R&D relates to productivity, the study then estimates sub-variants by sector and technology intensiveness. The former categorization acknowledges the possibility that R&D may affect productivity differently across sectors (mining, manufacturing, and services). The latter categorization allows us to crudely test the hypothesis that R&D largely facilitates productivity growth in technology-intensive sectors. Analysis was performed using the Stata 17 package. The study specifically uses the xtgls command, which fits panel-data linear models by using feasible generalized least squares accounting autoregressive (1) autocorrelation within panels, cross-sectional correlation, and heteroskedasticity across panels.

3.2. Data Description and Sources

The study relies on a panel dataset comprising 66 3-digit industries observed annually stretching from 1993 to 2023. The 66 industries and the sampling period were selected based on data availability. In particular, the study dropped industries that did not entirely have data on key control variables such as export intensity and import penetration. This included industries such as water, site preparation, the building of complete constructions, and the renting of construction equipment, among others. The remaining industries comprise 6 mining industries, 37 manufacturing, and 23 services. The total sample, therefore, consists of 2046 observations (i.e., T = 31 and N = 66, 31 × 66 = 2046 ). The use of 5 lags, however, reduced the sample size from 2046 to 1716 observations. Data on all variables are sourced from Quantec. This is a consultancy firm based in South Africa that commercializes statistical software and micro and macro data. Prominent work that has used this data source includes Rodrik (2008) and Edwards and Jenkins (2015). The database categorizes workers into three categories, namely skilled, semi-skilled, and low-skilled workers. Skilled workers comprise professional, semi-professional, and technical occupations, managerial, executive, and administrative occupations, and certain transport occupations, e.g., pilot navigator. Semi-skilled workers comprise clerical occupations, sales occupations, transport, delivery and communications occupations, services occupations, farmer, farm manager, artisan, apprentice and related occupations, production foremen, and production supervisors. Low-skilled workers, on the other hand, include all occupations not classified elsewhere. This study takes skilled workers as a ratio of total employment to proxy each industry’s absorptive capacity. The description of variables is given in Appendix A as Table A4.

4. Results

Summary statistics and the correlation matrix are contained in Appendix A, Table A1 and Table A2, respectively. The key takeaway points from these tables are that the dataset does not appear to be plagued by outliers and that the correlation coefficients are small to moderate, downplaying concerns of perfect and near multicollinearity among our independent variables. The study then proceeds to present formal results. Table 1, particularly, presents preliminary diagnostic tests. Evidently, the null hypotheses of cross-sectional independence, no serial correlation, and groupwise homoscedasticity are strongly rejected, indicating that the model suffers from cross-sectional dependence, first-order serial correlation, and groupwise heteroscedasticity. These results provide strong support for the feasible generalized least squares approach, given its ability to correct the standard errors and provide efficient estimates (Greene, 2018). The time dummies are also jointly significant, necessitating their inclusion to prevent a possible omitted variable bias.
Table 2 presents feasible generalized least squares estimates with time-fixed effects. In all our tables, Log R&D (−5) is the initial stock of R&D in natural logarithm form, Export (−5) is initial export intensity (%), Import (−5) is initial import penetration (%), CLR (−5) represents initial capital/labor ratio, ULC (−5) is the initial labor cost, and SW (−5) is the initial share of skilled workers. Six regression variants were estimated. The study included control variables in a stepwise fashion. The results show a positive, statistically significant but weak association between R&D stock and labor productivity. Raising the R&D stock by 1% at the start of a 5-year window is associated with a 0.01–0.02% increase in labor productivity in the subsequent 5 years, holding constant the initial levels of trade, capital/labor ratio, unit labor cost, and the share of skilled workers. The low elasticity is consistent with the literature as the majority of industry-level studies have found weaker evidence of the R&D/productivity link (Bogliacino & Pianta, 2011). The elasticity of 0.02% is particularly comparable to the 0.024% reported in Lehto (2007).
Table 3 presents regression results in which the dependent variable is now capital productivity. The aim is to determine whether innovation affects labor and capital productivity differently. Interestingly, although the elasticities reported in Table 2 and Table 3 are both low, the elasticity of capital productivity to changes in R&D is weaker (about 0.005%), suggesting that R&D enhances the productivity of workers more than the existing capital stock. There are several explanations for this emerging finding. First, R&D investments often lead to new processes and skill-intensive technologies that are complementary to human capital, which ultimately amplifies the marginal productivity of labor more directly. Second, in many contexts, especially in developing and emerging markets such as South Africa, capital stock tends to be less responsive to innovation due to a combination of technological mismatch, outdated machinery, and underutilization, which limits the extent to which R&D can translate into capital productivity gains (You, 1979). Third, labor may adjust more rapidly to innovation through training and adaptation, while capital adjustments typically involve longer time periods and huge investment costs. Empirically, this result is consistent with Hecht (2018), who finds evidence of labor-saving technical changes from R&D. The absence of capital-saving technical changes in Hecht (2018) supports our result as it implies rapid growth in labor productivity relative to capital productivity.
In Table 4, the study presents regression results in which the analysis groups industries into three sectors, namely mining, manufacturing, and services. In the first three regression variants, in which labor productivity is the dependent variable, we observe two main findings. First, it turns out that R&D does not significantly affect labor productivity in the mining sector. Its positive effect is only statistically significant in the manufacturing and service sectors. This result may reflect the capital-intensive nature of mining activities, where productivity gains are often driven more by capital stock and extraction technologies. This is in line with earlier studies such as Campbell (1980) and, more recently, Fan et al. (2017). The latter, particularly, finds no significant association between R&D intensity and output per worker in China’s mining industry. Second, R&D has a larger effect on labor productivity in the service sector (0.008) compared to manufacturing (0.004) by a factor of 2. This finding underscores the growing prominence of innovation in driving productivity in services. The result is in line with Ortega-Argilés et al. (2015), whose analysis found the coefficient of R&D significantly larger in the R&D-user services compared to non-high-tech manufacturing sectors.
Interestingly, in the last three regression variants, R&D turns out to significantly raise capital productivity in the mining sector. The results, therefore, suggest that R&D only enhances capital productivity in the mining sector. This result is plausible given the capital-intensive nature of mining activities, which limits the scope for labor-specific productivity gains through R&D. The result is particularly supportive of Fernandez’s (2022) proposition that a crucial channel for innovation in the mining sector lies in the acquisition of technologies integrated into the capital equipment.
In addition, the study observes that while R&D enhances labor productivity in the services sector, its impact on capital productivity is significantly negative. This result is consistent with the labor-intensive nature of most services. Unlike manufacturing, where capital inputs such as machinery and infrastructure play a central role in driving output, the services sector relies heavily on human skills, expertise, and interpersonal engagement. Consequently, R&D in services often prioritizes improvements in service delivery methods, digital tools for client engagement, or employee training, which all enhance the effectiveness of labor inputs more than capital.
Table 5 reports estimates examining the relationship between lagged R&D intensity and productivity outcomes, disaggregated by industry technology intensiveness. Our categorization is based on R&D intensities. Given the arbitrariness involved, the study prefers defining industries as technology-intensive and less-technology-intensive. The list of technology-intensive and less-technology-intensive industries is presented in Table A3. The results are not presented here for brevity. As Table 5 shows, the estimates reveal marked differences in how R&D affects labor and capital productivity across technology-intensive and less-technology-intensive industries.
With respect to labor productivity, the results show that R&D has a statistically significant and positive impact in both types of industries, although the magnitude of the effect is notably higher in technology-intensive sectors. Specifically, a 1% increase in R&D at the start of a 5-year period is associated with a 0.0326% increase in labor productivity in technology-intensive industries over a 5-year period, compared to a 0.0105% increase in less-technology-intensive industries. This disparity suggests that technology-intensive industries are better positioned to leverage innovation to enhance human capital productivity. These sectors likely possess stronger absorptive capacities compared to less-technology-intensive industries. This result is in line with previous studies such as Sterlacchini and Venturini (2014) and Elkomy et al. (2021).
In sharp contrast, the results for capital productivity reveal a small but statistically significant negative effect of R&D on capital productivity (−0.00824). This finding may reflect capital obsolescence induced by innovation as newly developed technologies tend to displace or render existing capital stock less productive. Conversely, in less-technology-intensive industries, the impact of R&D on capital productivity is positive, albeit modest (0.00448), suggesting that R&D can enhance capital productivity in industries where the baseline level of technology is lower.
Table 6 extends the baseline analysis by incorporating an interaction term between R&D stock and the share of skilled workers with the objective of examining the role of human capital as an absorptive capacity for innovation. This approach is grounded in the literature that posits that the productivity effects of R&D are contingent on the presence of complementary skilled labor, which enables industries to internalize new knowledge (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990).
The results presented in Columns (1) and (2), where the dependent variable is labor productivity, reveal a statistically significant and positive interaction between R&D and the share of skilled workers. Specifically, the coefficient on the interaction term is 0.0459 in Column (1) and 0.0122 in Column (2), indicating that the productivity-enhancing effects of R&D are magnified in industries with a higher proportion of skilled labor. This finding reinforces the notion that human capital acts as a critical enabler of technological assimilation and adaptation, which is crucial for enhancing the marginal returns to R&D. Interestingly, although the direct effect of skilled workers is negative in both specifications, the positive interaction suggests that R&D and human capital are not independent inputs but complement each other in driving labor productivity. The negative linear effect of skilled workers suggests that industries with highly skilled workers may experience productivity declines if the accumulation of skilled workers is not accompanied by significant investment in R&D.
On the contrary, variants (3) and (4), where the dependent variable is capital productivity, confirm a negative and statistically significant interaction between R&D and skilled labor. The coefficients on the interaction term are −0.0489 and −0.0476, respectively. This inverse relationship suggests that in sectors with higher shares of skilled workers, R&D hampers capital productivity. One plausible explanation is that skilled labor-intensive innovation strategies may lead to automation, which increases labor productivity but renders existing capital partially redundant or underutilized, which ultimately lowers capital productivity. It is also possible that these industries allocated R&D toward human capital enhancement rather than capital-deepening technologies, which may have limited direct gains in capital productivity.
Figure 1 displays the average shares of skilled workers by sector. A quick visual inspection of the graph shows that services (38%) employ most of the skilled workers on average, followed by manufacturing (19%) and mining (9%). Given the important moderating role of skilled workers demonstrated in Table 6 above, Figure 1 may suggest the need for training and development workshops in the mining and manufacturing sectors for industries in these sectors to stand a better chance of benefiting from R&D investments.
With respect to our control variables, exports and imports generally display a negative association with labor productivity, possibly reflecting competitive pressures affecting local industries, as similarly observed in Edwards and Jenkins (2015), although capital productivity shows mixed responses. For capital productivity in particular, the effect is positive in some sectors and negative in others. The capital/labor ratio is positively associated with both labor and capital productivity, indicating that capital deepening contributes to improved productivity during the sampling period. Unit labor costs have a negative effect on labor productivity, suggesting that rising labor costs can hinder performance. In some cases, however, labor costs positively influence capital productivity, suggesting complementary effects. The share of skilled workers has a heterogeneous effect. It positively affects capital productivity across all models but exhibits a negative or insignificant relationship with labor productivity in some sectors, possibly due to skill mismatches.

5. Discussion

The empirical findings of this study contribute to the growing literature on the productivity effects of R&D in developing economies, with a specific focus on South African industries. The results indicate that R&D expenditure exerts a positive and statistically significant impact on labor productivity, albeit with a relatively low elasticity. This is consistent with previous studies that document modest productivity returns to innovation in contexts characterized by structural constraints, institutional inefficiencies, and limited absorptive capacity (Hall et al., 2010; Crespi & Zuniga, 2012).
The effect of R&D on capital productivity is comparatively weaker and less robust across specifications. Sectoral heterogeneity in the productivity effects of R&D is also evident. The lack of significant labor productivity effects in the mining sector is unsurprising given its capital-intensive nature and reliance on physical resource characteristics, which tend to diminish the marginal returns to knowledge-based inputs. In contrast, the positive and statistically significant effects observed in the manufacturing and service sectors are more consistent with international evidence, where such sectors demonstrate higher innovation intensity and stronger integration into global value chains (Griffith et al., 2004). The pronounced effect in the service sector, in particular, may reflect the increasing importance of intangible assets and human capital, which are key complements to innovation in knowledge-intensive services.
Interestingly, while labor productivity gains are not evident in mining, the positive effect of R&D on capital productivity within this sector suggests that process innovation, automation, and equipment efficiency improvements may be the primary channels through which innovation manifests. This observation underscores the importance of aligning innovation strategies with sector-specific characteristics and production technologies. The findings further reveal that the productivity effects of R&D are more pronounced in technology-intensive industries, particularly in relation to labor productivity. This supports the argument that sectors with higher technological intensity possess stronger absorptive capacities and are better equipped to translate innovation inputs into productive outputs (Cohen & Levinthal, 1990). However, the negative relationship between R&D and capital productivity in technology-intensive industries may reflect transitional inefficiencies such as the obsolescence of older capital assets or the misalignment between innovation efforts and capital utilization.
The interaction between R&D and human capital provides additional insights to the analysis. The results suggest that the productivity effects of R&D are conditional on the presence of a sufficiently skilled labor force. This finding is consistent with endogenous growth theory, which posits that human capital enhances the productivity of innovation by facilitating learning, adaptation, and diffusion (Lucas, 1988; Romer, 1990). In the South African case, where skill mismatches and educational inequalities persist, this result highlights the critical role of coordinated policy interventions that promote both innovation investment and human capital development.
Overall, the findings underscore that R&D can be a meaningful driver of productivity growth in South Africa, but the extent of its impact is mediated by structural conditions, sectoral dynamics, and the quality of the labor force. The evidence supports the view that innovation policy must be sector-specific, complemented by investments in skills, and attentive to the broader institutional and technological ecosystem. Enhancing the productivity returns to R&D will require not only increased expenditure but also improved alignment between innovation, education, and industrial policy.

6. Conclusions

This study concludes that R&D investment positively influences labor productivity in South African industries, particularly within the manufacturing and services sectors and in technology-intensive activities. The effect on capital productivity is marginal and, in some instances, negative. The analysis additionally concludes that skilled workers are critical in ensuring that industries record productivity gains from R&D.
In light of our conclusion, policy recommendations should be carefully tailored and combined with complementary interventions to maximize their impact. Specifically, the following measures are proposed.

6.1. Targeted Skill Development

To enhance labor productivity effectively, it is imperative to implement industry-specific training programs that address the unique skill demands of each industry. In addition, improving the quality and relevance of education and training, particularly in science, technology, engineering, and mathematics (STEM), will impart workers with the skills needed to translate R&D into productivity improvements.

6.2. Technology Adoption Incentives

Fiscal incentives or subsidies should be provided to encourage industries to invest in modern technologies and equipment that boost productivity. To encourage technological upgrading and digital transformation, the government may implement fiscal policy instruments such as targeted tax incentives. Specifically, tax credits could be extended to small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) that invest in approved digital technologies, including automation, data analytics, and cloud-based systems. Such incentives may aim to lower the effective cost of capital for technology adoption, thereby enhancing firms’ innovation capacity and productivity potential. In addition, public procurement policy can be strategically leveraged to stimulate technology diffusion. By introducing preferential procurement criteria that prioritize firms demonstrating the integration of advanced technologies, particularly in sectors such as infrastructure, education, and logistics, the state can create demand-side incentives for digital adoption. This approach not only fosters innovation among suppliers but also aligns public expenditure with broader industrial policy objectives aimed at digital transformation and competitiveness enhancement.

6.3. Access to Finance

Enhancing access to affordable credit and financial services is critical to enhancing investment in R&D, which is often constrained by limited financial resources. SMEs, for instance, typically face higher borrowing costs, stricter collateral requirements, and limited credit history compared to larger firms, which restrict their ability to finance innovation activities. By implementing targeted financial instruments such as low-interest loans, credit guarantees, and innovation grants, policymakers can lower the cost of capital and reduce the financial risks associated with R&D investments. Additionally, establishing specialized venture capital funds and public/private partnerships can provide alternative funding avenues that support early-stage innovation projects.

6.4. Design of Innovation Policy

Second, the design of innovation policy must account for sectoral heterogeneity and the varying degrees of technology intensiveness across industries. Different sectors face distinct innovation challenges and opportunities, which require tailored policy instruments. For example, high-technology sectors such as information and communication technology (ICT) and pharmaceuticals often demand substantial R&D investments, advanced infrastructure, and strong intellectual property protections to foster breakthrough innovations. Conversely, traditional manufacturing and agriculture may benefit more from incremental innovations, process improvements, and technology adoption support, such as extension services and subsidies for equipment modernization. Moreover, policies promoting collaboration between universities, research institutions, and firms should be customized to reflect sector-specific innovation ecosystems, recognizing that the pathways to innovation differ markedly between capital-intensive industries and labor-intensive ones.
In closing, it is important to acknowledge the limitations of our study. First, our study relies on the FGLS estimation approach to correct for the presence of cross-sectional dependence, serial correlation, and groupwise heteroskedasticity. While this technique is robust under the identified violations of classical assumptions, it does not fully address potential endogeneity issues related to the R&D variable. Although lagging the regressors helps in reducing simultaneity bias, the absence of strong external instruments means the causal interpretation of the R&D/productivity relationship should be made cautiously.
Second, the empirical specification controls for key production-side variables (trade intensity, capital/labor ratio, labor costs, and skills). Demand-side dynamics and institutional variables are not adequately incorporated. These omitted factors may interact with R&D in shaping productivity dynamics.
Lastly, the study does not differentiate between public and private R&D or between basic and applied research, which may have distinct impacts on productivity. The heterogeneity in R&D type, funding source, and purpose could moderate its effectiveness but is not explored due to data constraints.
Future research may build on these findings by conducting firm-level analyses that explore heterogeneity in innovation and productivity responses across different types of enterprises. Such studies could reveal how firm size, ownership structure, and export orientation mediate the impact of R&D investments.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, P.E.R. and D.C.; methodology, B.T.M.; software, B.T.M.; validation, P.E.R.; formal analysis, B.T.M.; investigation, B.T.M.; data curation, B.T.M.; writing—original draft preparation, B.T.M.; writing—review and editing, B.T.M., D.C. and P.E.R.; supervision, B.T.M.; Literature review, P.E.R. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

The datasets used and/or analyzed during the current study are available from the author upon reasonable request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Summary Statistics.
Table A1. Summary Statistics.
VariableObsMeanStd. Dev.MinMax
loglp20464.4710.3992.3075.277
logcp20464.730.2584.237.729
logrnd20465.8022.64−2.16810.633
Export (%)204619.66418.5520.16197.008
Import (%)204625.25435.6460371.423
Clr (%)20460.090.14701.836
Ulc2046108.66538.88522.194516.405
skilled share20460.2480.1670.0230.846
Table A2. Correlation Matrix.
Table A2. Correlation Matrix.
Variables−1−2−3−4−5−6−7−8
(1) loglp1.000
(2) logcp−0.0931.000
(3) logrnd0.1870.0131.000
(4) export−0.200−0.090−0.0361.000
(5) import−0.221−0.053−0.1080.5971.000
(6) clr0.2140.0750.1300.030−0.1351.000
(7) ulc−0.3170.199−0.149−0.0280.109−0.1171.000
(8) skilled_share−0.0580.2200.078−0.167−0.034−0.1090.1811.000
Table A3. Technology Intensiveness.
Table A3. Technology Intensiveness.
Technology IntensiveLess Technology Intensive
General purpose machinery Coal
Special purpose machineryIron ore
Office, accounting, computing machineryCopper
Electric motors, generators, transformersManganese ore
Other electrical equipmentOther metallic minerals
Radio, television, and communication apparatus Other mining and quarrying
Professional equipment Meat, fish, fruit, etc.
Motor vehiclesDairy products
Other transport equipment Grain mill products
Sale, maintenance, and repair of motor vehicles Other food products
TelecommunicationBeverages
Renting machinery and equipment, without operator and of personal and household goods Tobacco
Computer and related activitiesOther textile products
Research and development Wearing apparel
Architectural, engineering, and other technical activities Footwear
Products of wood
Paper and paper products
Printing, recorded media
Coke, petroleum products, and nuclear fuel
Basic chemicals
Rubber products
Plastic products
Glass and glass products
Non-metallic mineral products
Basic iron and steel products
Non-ferrous metal products
Structural metal products
Other fabricated metal products
Household appliances
Electricity distribution and control apparatus
Insulated wire and cables
Parts and accessories
Furniture
Other manufacturing groups
Electricity and gas
Wholesale trade, commission trade
Retail trade
Catering and accommodation services
Land transport, transport via pipelines
Air transport
Financial intermediation, except for insurance and pension funding
Insurance and pension funding
Legal, accounting, bookkeeping, and auditing activities
Advertising
Business activities n.e.c.
National departments
Provincial departments
Local government
Education
Recreation, cultural, and sport activities
Other activities
Table A4. Variable Description.
Table A4. Variable Description.
VariableNameUnit of Measurement
loglpReal Labor productivityLog units
logcpReal Capital productivityLog units
logrndResearch and Development StockLog units
ExportExport intensityPercent
ImportImport penetrationPercent
ClrCapital/labor ratioPercent
UlcUnit labor costsIndex
skilled shareSkilled workersRatio

References

  1. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Adeosun, O. T., Odior, E. S., & Shitu, A. I. (2024). Human capital development, innovation, and industrial sector performance in sub-Saharan Africa. Available online: https://aec.afdb.org/sites/default/files/papers/human_capital_development_innovation_and_industrial_sector_performance_in_sub-saharan_africa.pdf (accessed on 20 April 2025).
  3. Aghion, P., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, P., & Prantl, S. (2009). The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(1), 20–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Ali, L., & Akhtar, N. (2024). The effectiveness of export, FDI, human capital, and R&D on total factor productivity growth: The case of Pakistan. Journal of the Knowledge Economy, 15(1), 3085–3099. [Google Scholar]
  6. Astutik, Y., & Nugroho, R. Y. Y. (2024). The effect of financial deepening on economic growth in Indonesia. Signifikan Jurnal Ilmu Ekonomi, 13(2), 327–346. [Google Scholar]
  7. Awode, S. S., & Oduola, M. O. (2025). The interplay between technological innovation and human capital development in driving industrial productivity and competitiveness in Africa. Journal of Economics and Development, 27(1), 56–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bai, J., Choi, S. H., & Liao, Y. (2021). Feasible generalized least squares for panel data with cross-sectional and serial correlations. Empirical Economics, 60, 309–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Bartoloni, E., Baussola, M., Marino, A., & Romaniello, D. (2025). The efficient triangle: Export persistence, human capital, and productivity. Review of Political Economy, 37(2), 431–455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Besiroglu, T., Emery-Xu, N., & Thompson, N. (2024). Economic impacts of AI-augmented R&D. Research Policy, 53(7), 105037. [Google Scholar]
  11. Blanco, L. R., Gu, J., & Prieger, J. E. (2016). The impact of research and development on economic growth and productivity in the US States. Southern Economic Journal, 82(3), 914–934. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Bogliacino, F., & Pianta, M. (2011). Engines of growth. Innovation and productivity in industry groups. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 22(1), 41–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bravo-Ortega, C., & Marín, Á. G. (2011). R&D and productivity: A two way avenue? World Development, 39(7), 1090–1107. [Google Scholar]
  14. Cammeraat, E., Samek, L., & Squicciarini, M. (2021). The role of innovation and human capital for the productivity of industries. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Policy Papers. No. 103. OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Campbell, H. F. (1980). The effect of capital intensity on the optimal rate of extraction of a mineral deposit. The Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’Economique, 13(2), 349–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Casagrande, D., Hidalgo, Á., & Feistel, P. (2024). Exports, productivity and capital intensity: Evidence for Brazilian firms. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 70, 279–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Cassim, Z., Handjiski, B., Schubert, J., & Zouaoui, Y. (2020). The $10 trillion rescue: How governments can deliver impact. McKinsey & Company. [Google Scholar]
  18. Chen, C. (2020). Technology adoption, capital deepening, and international productivity differences. Journal of Development Economics, 143, 102388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ciaffi, G. (2025). Innovation and demand as drivers of labour productivity: An integrated analysis for OECD countries. Review of Political Economy, 37(2), 369–391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Cirera, X., Comin, D., & Cruz, M. (2022). Bridging the technological divide: Technology adoption by firms in developing countries. World Bank Publications. [Google Scholar]
  21. Cohen, W. M., & Levinthal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35(1), 128–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Crespi, G., & Zuniga, P. (2012). Innovation and productivity: Evidence from six Latin American countries. World Development, 40(2), 273–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Criscuolo, C., Gal, P., Leidecker, T., & Nicoletti, G. (2021). The human side of productivity: Uncovering the role of skills and diversity for firm productivity. OECD Productivity Working Papers, No. 29. OECD Publishing. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Cuevas-Vargas, H., & Cortés-Palacios, H. A. (2025). The influence of capital structure on technological innovation and business performance: Examining the moderating role of absorptive capacity. Journal of Manufacturing Technology Management. Ahead-of-print. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Curtis, A., McVay, S., & Toynbee, S. (2020). The changing implications of research and development expenditures for future profitability. Review of Accounting Studies, 25, 405–437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Czarnitzki, D., Hanel, P., & Rosa, J. M. (2011). Evaluating the impact of R&D tax credits on innovation: A microeconometric study on Canadian firms. Research Policy, 40(2), 217–229. [Google Scholar]
  27. Edwards, L., & Jenkins, R. (2015). The impact of Chinese import penetration on the South African manufacturing sector. The Journal of Development Studies, 51(4), 447–463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Elkomy, S., Ingham, H., & Read, R. (2021). The impact of foreign technology and embodied R&D on productivity in internationally oriented and high-technology industries in Egypt, 2006–2009. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 21(2), 171–192. [Google Scholar]
  29. Fan, S., Yan, J., & Sha, J. (2017). Innovation and economic growth in the mining industry: Evidence from China’s listed companies. Resources Policy, 54, 25–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Fei, J. C., & Ranis, G. (1964). Capital-labor ratios in theory and in history: Reply. The American Economic Review, 54, 1063–1069. [Google Scholar]
  31. Fernandez, V. (2022). Innovative intensity in the mining industry: Evidence from patent families. Resources Policy, 78, 102805. [Google Scholar]
  32. Friesenbichler, K. S., Kügler, A., & Reinstaller, A. (2024). The impact of import competition from China on firm-level productivity growth in the European Union. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 86(2), 236–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Gerybadze, A. (2010). R&D, innovation and growth: Performance of the world’s leading technology corporations. In A. Gerybadze, U. Hommel, H. Reiners, & D. Thomaschewski (Eds.), Innovation and international corporate growth. Springer. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Greene, W. H. (2018). Econometric analysis (8th ed.). Pearson. [Google Scholar]
  35. Griffith, R., Redding, S., & Reenen, J. V. (2004). Mapping the two faces of R&D: Productivity growth in a panel of OECD industries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(4), 883–895. [Google Scholar]
  36. Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1991). Trade, knowledge spillovers, and growth. European Economic Review, 35(2–3), 517–526. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Hall, B. H., Mairesse, J., & Mohnen, P. (2010). Measuring the returns to R&D. In Handbook of the economics of innovation (Vol. 2, pp. 1033–1082). North-Holland. [Google Scholar]
  38. Haneda, S., & Ono, A. (2022). R&D management practices and innovation: Evidence from a firm survey (p. 99). Springer Nature. [Google Scholar]
  39. Hanlin, R., Kruss, G., Petersen, I., & Kraemer-Mbula, E. (2022). Giving direction to innovation policy: A transformative innovation policy approach. Available online: https://repository.hsrc.ac.za/handle/20.500.11910/22715 (accessed on 5 June 2025).
  40. Hecht, J. (2018). Research and development and labour productivity: Do high-tech firms exhibit labour-or capital-saving technical change? Applied Economics, 50(16), 1790–1811. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Jorge Ulises, K. R., & Pablo José, A. B. (2024). Impact of human factor management on company productivity: The moderating effect of digitalization. Cogent Business & Management, 11(1), 2371064. [Google Scholar]
  42. Kafouros, M. I. (2005). R&D and productivity growth: Evidence from the UK. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 14(6), 479–497. [Google Scholar]
  43. Kahn, A., Sithole, M., & Buchana, Y. (2022). An analysis of the impact of technological innovation on productivity in South African manufacturing firms using direct measures of innovation. South African Journal of Economics, 90(1), 37–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Kamal, Y. (2024). The effects of trade participation on labor productivity, wages and female employment. Journal of Economic Integration, 39(1), 151–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Karlsone, K., & Ozola, A. (2023). Factors affecting labour productivity in the construction sector. Rural Environment. Education. Personality, 16, 56–62. [Google Scholar]
  46. Keller, W. (2009). International trade, foreign direct investment, and technology spillovers. NBER Working Paper 15442. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. [Google Scholar]
  47. Kumar, V., Kumar, S., Chaudhuri, R., Chatterjee, S., Vrontis, D., & Rezaee Vessal, S. (2025). Innovation capability and R&D performance of organizations: Moderating role of industry–academic knowledge transfer. Journal of Knowledge Management, 29(3), 891–914. [Google Scholar]
  48. Ledwaba, N. A. (2022). Growth through innovation and productivity: The case of South Africa [Doctoral dissertation, University of Limpopo]. Available online: http://ul.netd.ac.za/handle/10386/4126 (accessed on 19 April 2025).
  49. Lehto, E. (2007). Regional impact of research and development on productivity. Regional Studies, 41(5), 623–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour (pp. 139–191). Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  51. Li, X. (2024). Learning by exporting: The moderating role of employee human capital. International Marketing Review, 41(6), 1560–1576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Magazzino, C., & Santeramo, F. G. (2024). Financial development, growth and productivity. Journal of Economic Studies, 51(9), 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Mairesse, J., & Sassenou, M. (1991). R&D productivity: A survey of econometric studies at the firm level. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Series (w3666). National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  55. Mason, G., Rincon-Aznar, A., & Venturini, F. (2020). Which skills contribute most to absorptive capacity, innovation and productivity performance? Evidence from the US and Western Europe. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 29(3), 223–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Mazorodze, B. (2020). Trade and efficiency of manufacturing industries in South Africa. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 29(1), 89–118. [Google Scholar]
  57. Mazorodze, B. T. (2025). Government subsidies and industrial productivity in South Africa: A focus on the channels. Econometrics, 13(2), 20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Melitz, M. J. (2003). The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica, 71(6), 1695–1725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Melnychuk, T., & Schultz, C. (2025). Direct and indirect effects of degree of interdisciplinarity on firms’ innovation performance: The moderating role of firms’ capabilities. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 42(2), 417–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Mokgokong, M. J., & Mukonza, R. M. (2024). Research and development collaborations within the context of a South African developmental state. Journal of Asian and African Studies, 00219096241257693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Nguyen, A. T., Hoang, V. H., Le, P. T., Nguyen, T. T. H., & Pham, T. T. V. (2024). The spillover effect of export on total factor productivity of enterprises: Panel data approach in Vietnam. International Journal of Social Economics, 51(12), 1585–1601. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University. [Google Scholar]
  63. Ortega-Argilés, R., Piva, M., & Vivarelli, M. (2015). The productivity impact of R&D investment: Are high-tech sectors still ahead? Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 24(3), 204–222. [Google Scholar]
  64. Peng, X. Y., Lin, C. Y., & Mai, T. K. (2024). Unraveling the dynamics of R&D and firm productivity: Empirical insights from 27 Chinese industries with regional and ownership differences. Finance Research Letters, 59, 104705. [Google Scholar]
  65. Pesaran, M. H. (2021). General diagnostic tests for cross-sectional dependence in panels. Empirical Economics, 60(1), 13–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Rafique, K., Qi, Y., & Abbas, S. (2025). The impacts of exporting to China: Assessing the productivity gains of developing countries using an instrumental variable approach. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies, 23(1), 123–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Ravenscraft, D., & Scherer, F. M. (1982). The lag structure of returns to research and development. Applied Economics, 14(6), 603–620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Roberts, B., & Wolf, M. (2018). High-tech industries: An analysis of employment, wages, and output. Beyond the Numbers, 7(7), 1–11. [Google Scholar]
  69. Rodrik, D. (2008). Understanding South Africa’s economic puzzles. Economics of Transition, 16(4), 769–797. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Roodman, D. (2009). How to do xtabond2: An introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. The Stata Journal, 9(1), 86–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Sarafidis, V., & Robertson, D. (2009). On the impact of error cross-sectional dependence in short dynamic panel estimation. The Econometrics Journal, 12(1), 62–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Scherer, F. M. (1983). R & D and declining productivity growth. The American Economic Review, 73(2), 215–218. [Google Scholar]
  75. Siliverstovs, B. (2016). R&D and non-linear productivity growth. Research Policy, 45(3), 634–646. [Google Scholar]
  76. Sterlacchini, A., & Venturini, F. (2014). R&D and productivity in high-tech manufacturing: A comparison between Italy and Spain. Industry and Innovation, 21(5), 359–379. [Google Scholar]
  77. Stundziene, A., & Baliute, A. (2022). Personnel costs and labour productivity: The case of European manufacturing industry. Economies, 10(2), 31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Tetteh, C. K. (2024). R&D, innovation and labour productivity: Evidence from the manufacturing sector in Ghana. Scientific African, 24, e02136. [Google Scholar]
  79. Unegbu, P. I., & Ugwunna, O. T. (2024). Importation and manufacturing sector performance in Nigeria: An empirical analysis. ANSU Journal of Arts and Social Sciences, 11(2), 43–60. [Google Scholar]
  80. Ünsal, M. E. (2024). Causalities between exports, imports, and total factor productivity in developing countries: The case of Türkiye, Brazil, India, and South Africa. Journal of Economic Policy Researches, 11(2), 186–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Van Biesebroeck, J. (2005). Exporting raises productivity in sub-Saharan African manufacturing firms. Journal of International Economics, 67(2), 373–391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Wu, D., & Chen, Y. (2023). Digital inclusive finance development and labor productivity: Based on a capital-deepening perspective. Sustainability, 15(12), 9243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. You, J. K. (1979). Capital utilization, productivity, and output gap. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 61(1), 91–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Zhang, R., Sun, K., Delgado, M. S., & Kumbhakar, S. C. (2012). Productivity in China’s high technology industry: Regional heterogeneity and R&D. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 79(1), 127–141. [Google Scholar]
  85. Zhu, H., Zhao, S., & Abbas, A. (2020). Relationship between R&D grants, R&D investment, and innovation performance: The moderating effect of absorptive capacity. Journal of Public Affairs, 20(1), e1973. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Average Share of Skilled Workers by Sector. Source: Own computation.
Figure 1. Average Share of Skilled Workers by Sector. Source: Own computation.
Economies 13 00179 g001
Table 1. Preliminary Diagnostic Tests.
Table 1. Preliminary Diagnostic Tests.
TestTest Statisticp-Value
Pesaran’s test12.7630.0000
Wooldridge test428.8120.0000
Groupwise heteroskedasticity test30,839.110.0000
Time dummies (Wald test)10,035.850.0000
Note: Average absolute value of the off-diagonal elements = 0.471.
Table 2. R&D and Labor Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates.
Table 2. R&D and Labor Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates.
Dependent Variable = log Labor Productivity(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Log R&D (−5)0.0157 ***0.0145 ***0.0144 ***0.0133 ***0.00978 ***0.0104 ***
(0.000653)(0.000828)(0.000396)(0.000388)(0.000695)(0.000698)
Export (−5) −0.00391 ***−0.00340 ***−0.00360 ***−0.00384 ***−0.00397 ***
(0.000142)(6.36 × 10−5)(6.57 × 10−5)(7.74 × 10−5)(8.59 × 10−5)
Import (−5) −0.000492 ***−0.000328 ***−0.000141 **−0.000124 *
(4.22 × 10−5)(4.35 × 10−5)(6.50 × 10−5)(6.63 × 10−5)
CLR (−5) 0.203 ***0.187 ***0.174 ***
(0.0173)(0.0156)(0.0179)
ULC (−5) −0.00151 ***−0.00142 ***
(3.84 × 10−5)(3.88 × 10−5)
SW (−5) −0.0863 ***
(0.0132)
Constant4.171 ***4.228 ***4.239 ***4.237 ***4.471 ***4.477 ***
(0.00462)(0.00545)(0.00475)(0.00513)(0.00778)(0.00805)
Time-fixed effectsyesyesyesyesyesyes
Observations171617161716171617161716
No. of industries666666666666
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. GLS denotes generalized least squares.
Table 3. R&D and Capital Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates.
Table 3. R&D and Capital Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates.
Dependent Variable = log Capital Productivity(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Log R&D (−5)0.00522 ***0.00522 ***0.00505 ***0.00427 ***0.00468 ***0.00298 ***
(0.000192)(0.000160)(0.000108)(4.47 × 10−5)(9.12 × 10−5)(7.54 × 10−5)
Export (−5) −0.000137 ***0.000187 ***3.71 × 10−5 ***5.60 × 10−5 ***0.000454 ***
(5.62 × 10−6)(4.90 × 10−6)(6.40 × 10−6)(6.91 × 10−6)(7.61 × 10−6)
Import (−5) −0.000261 ***−0.000147 ***−0.000166 ***−0.000241 ***
(3.39 × 10−6)(2.09 × 10−6)(2.23 × 10−6)(2.64 × 10−6)
CLR (−5) 0.147 ***0.148 ***0.170 ***
(0.00147)(0.00170)(0.00190)
ULC (−5) 0.000181 ***−4.40 × 10−5 ***
(2.54 × 10−6)(3.52 × 10−6)
SW (−5) 0.219 ***
(0.00255)
Constant4.841 ***4.842 ***4.846 ***4.843 ***4.815 ***4.800 ***
(0.00107)(0.000901)(0.000686)(0.000387)(0.000554)(0.00110)
Time-fixed effectsyesyesyesyesyesyes
Observations171617161716171617161716
No. of industries666666666666
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01
Table 4. R&D and Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates—Sectoral Comparisons.
Table 4. R&D and Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates—Sectoral Comparisons.
Dependent Variable Loglabor Productivity Logcapital Productivity
MiningManufacturingServicesMiningManufacturingServices
Log R&D (−5)0.02760.00403 ***0.00810 ***0.0345 ***0.00183 ***−0.00739 ***
(0.0335)(0.000490)(0.000530)(0.00650)(1.68 × 10−5)(8.73 × 10−5)
Export (−5)−0.000356−0.00364 ***−0.00653 ***0.000708 *−0.000146 ***−0.00168 ***
(0.00201)(0.000142)(0.000177)(0.000379)(2.34 × 10−6)(1.48 × 10−5)
Import (−5)−0.00114 ***−0.000327 ***0.00429 ***0.000228 ***0.000374 ***−0.00142 ***
(0.000424)(5.55 × 10−5)(0.000261)(7.67 × 10−5)(1.93 × 10−6)(1.44 × 10−5)
CLR (−5)−0.3840.527 ***0.0322 ***0.00422−0.0292 ***0.0829 ***
(0.340)(0.0233)(0.00502)(0.0635)(0.000510)(0.00187)
ULC (−5)−0.000289−0.000401 ***−0.00218 ***−0.000275 **1.55 × 10−5 ***0.000120 ***
(0.000689)(3.38 × 10−5)(5.01 × 10−5)(0.000117)(1.08 × 10−6)(2.76 × 10−6)
SW (−5)2.623 **−0.238 ***−0.0680 ***−0.545 ***0.0400 ***0.0900 ***
(1.167)(0.0232)(0.00905)(0.192)(0.000803)(0.00134)
Constant4.519 ***4.230 ***4.725 ***4.890 ***4.679 ***5.066 ***
(0.186)(0.00593)(0.00936)(0.0398)(0.000249)(0.000473)
Time-fixed effectsyesyesyesyesyesyes
Observations156962598156962598
No. of industries6372363723
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1.
Table 5. R&D and Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates—Technology intensiveness.
Table 5. R&D and Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates—Technology intensiveness.
Dependent VariableLog Labor ProductivityLog Labor ProductivityLog Capital Productivity Log Capital Productivity
Technology-Intensive IndustriesLess-Technology IndustriesTechnology-Intensive IndustriesLess-Technology Industries
Log R&D (−5)0.0326 ***0.0105 ***−0.00824 ***0.00448 ***
(0.00231)(0.000661)(0.000531)(9.12 × 10−5)
Export (−5)−0.00477 ***−0.00363 ***−0.000117 ***0.000745 ***
(0.000222)(0.000119)(3.25 × 10−5)(1.36 × 10−5)
Import (−5)0.000404 ***2.75 × 10−5−0.000417 ***0.000113 ***
(0.000121)(4.21 × 10−5)(1.88 × 10−5)(7.27 × 10−6)
CLR (−5)1.443 ***0.156 ***−0.541 ***0.157 ***
(0.103)(0.00985)(0.0183)(0.00207)
ULC (−5)−0.00145 ***−0.00119 ***0.000510 ***−9.47 × 10−5 ***
(0.000131)(2.81 × 10−5)(1.82 × 10−5)(5.50 × 10−6)
SW (−5)0.354 ***−0.120 ***0.170 ***0.238 ***
(0.0299)(0.00806)(0.00928)(0.00373)
Constant4.034 ***4.487 ***4.807 ***4.789 ***
(0.0253)(0.00626)(0.00453)(0.00137)
Time-fixed effectsyesyesyesyes
Observations39013263901326
No. of industries15511551
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01
Table 6. R&D and Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates—Absorptive Capacity.
Table 6. R&D and Productivity Feasible GLS Estimates—Absorptive Capacity.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Dependent VariableLog Labor ProductivityLog Labor ProductivityLog Capital ProductivityLog Capital Productivity
Log R&D (−5)0.00309 ***0.00694 ***0.0182 ***0.0163 ***
(0.000886)(0.00101)(0.000456)(0.000166)
Export (−5) −0.00379 *** 3.80 × 10−5 ***
(0.000120) (9.73 × 10−6)
Import (−5) −0.000170 *** −0.000136 ***
(6.13 × 10−5) (2.69 × 10−6)
CLR (−5) 0.178 *** 0.168 ***
(0.0185) (0.00159)
ULC (−5) −0.00139 *** −7.52 × 10−5 ***
(3.92 × 10−5) (2.76 × 10−6)
SW (−5)−0.379 ***−0.155 ***0.488 ***0.501 ***
(0.0198)(0.0328)(0.0118)(0.00463)
Log R&D × SW (−5)0.0459 ***0.0122 **−0.0489 ***−0.0476 ***
(0.00209)(0.00513)(0.00121)(0.000458)
Constant4.271 ***4.488 ***4.717 ***4.729 ***
(0.00916)(0.00960)(0.00377)(0.00152)
Time-fixed effectsyesyesyesyes
Observations1716171617161716
No. of industries66666666
Standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01 & ** p < 0.05
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Mazorodze, B.T.; Chizema, D.; Ramatsoma, P.E. Linking R&D and Productivity in South Africa: The Moderating Role of Human Skills. Economies 2025, 13, 179. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13060179

AMA Style

Mazorodze BT, Chizema D, Ramatsoma PE. Linking R&D and Productivity in South Africa: The Moderating Role of Human Skills. Economies. 2025; 13(6):179. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13060179

Chicago/Turabian Style

Mazorodze, Brian Tavonga, Darlington Chizema, and Phetole Emanuel Ramatsoma. 2025. "Linking R&D and Productivity in South Africa: The Moderating Role of Human Skills" Economies 13, no. 6: 179. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13060179

APA Style

Mazorodze, B. T., Chizema, D., & Ramatsoma, P. E. (2025). Linking R&D and Productivity in South Africa: The Moderating Role of Human Skills. Economies, 13(6), 179. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13060179

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop