Growth Effects of Wealth Inequality Through Transmission Channels
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
2.1. Theoretical Literature Review of Transmission Channels
2.2. Empirical Literature Review of Inequality–Growth Nexus
3. Methodology
3.1. Data
3.2. Baseline Model
- : The mediator variable (transmission channel) as brought up in Table 2.
- : Country fixed effects.
- : Time-specific effects.
- : Wealth Gini.
- : Initial income variable equivalent to GDP per capita of each country.
- : Dependent variable or real GDP per capita growth.
- , : The smooth function of and mediator variables indicating nonlinear effects.
- : The mediator variable or transmission channel as brought up in Table 2.
- : Country fixed effects.
- : Time-specific fixed effects.
- : Independent variable wealth Gini.
- : Target variable real GDP per capita growth.
- Smooth function of , indicating nonlinear effects.
- : Smooth function of mediator variable.
- : Smooth function of interaction term.
- : Financial development.
- : Initial income.
- : Control variables as brought up in Table 3.
3.3. Mediation Analysis Algorithm
3.4. Generalized Additive Method
- ;
- ;
- ;
- ;
- .
4. Results
Robustness Check
5. Discussion
6. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
1 | See Appendix A. |
2 | While patent stock was chosen as the proxy for innovation largely because of its longitudinal availability and its common usage in cross-country analyses, this choice has important drawbacks that warrant acknowledgment. By focusing solely on patented inventions, it overlooks a wide range of “invisible” or non-patented innovations. In particular, service innovation, process innovation, and incremental adaptations—often undertaken by smaller firms—may not require or even benefit from formal patent protection. As Taques et al. (2021) caution, when innovation arises from tacit knowledge or customer interactions, especially in labor-intensive service sectors, patent metrics will likely underestimate the true level of novelty and creativity. In effect, low patent counts need not signal weak innovation but may instead point to a reliance on informal mechanisms of intellectual property protection or minimal feasibility of patenting in those settings. A second challenge concerns cross-national disparities in patenting infrastructures. Developed countries typically offer more cost-effective, efficient filing systems, whereas resource-scarce regions face prohibitively high application fees and weaker institutional support. These dissimilarities can bias cross-country comparisons and make it difficult to disentangle genuine differences in innovation performance from disparities in patent frameworks. |
References
- Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2002). Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1231–1294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Business. [Google Scholar]
- Acheampong, A. O., Adebayo, T. S., Dzator, J., & Koomson, I. (2023). Income inequality and economic growth in BRICS: Insights from non-parametric techniques. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 21(3), 619–640. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aghion, P., Caroli, E., & Garcia-Penalosa, C. (1999). Inequality and economic growth: The perspective of the new growth theories. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1615–1660. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (1992). A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica, 60(2), 323–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aghion, P., & Howitt, P. (2009). The economics of growth. MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Income distribution, political instability, and investment. European Economic Review, 40(6), 1203–1228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Atkinson, A. B., & Brandolini, A. (2006). Inequality and economic growth: An analysis of cross-country data. Economic Inquiry, 44(2), 321–339. [Google Scholar]
- Banerjee, A. V., & Duflo, E. (2003). Inequality and growth: What can the data say? Journal of Economic Growth, 8(3), 267–299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Banerjee, A. V., & Newman, A. F. (1993). Occupational choice and the process of development. Journal of Political Economy, 101(2), 274–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barro, R. J. (2000). Inequality and growth in a panel of countries. Journal of Economic Growth, 5(1), 5–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baron, R. M., & Kenny, D. A. (1986). The moderator-mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51(6), 1173–1182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baselgia, J., & Foellmi, C. (2022). Revisiting the inequality-growth nexus: New evidence from advanced economies. Journal of Economic Growth, 27(1), 101–125. [Google Scholar]
- Becker, G. S., & Tomes, N. (1986). Human capital and the rise and fall of families. Journal of Labor Economics, 4(3, Part 2), S1–S39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Benhabib, J., & Rustichini, A. (1996). Social conflict and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 125–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Benos, K., & Karagiannis, A. (2018). Top income inequality and economic growth in the united states: A state-level analysis. American Economic Review, 108(5), 1200–1225. [Google Scholar]
- Berg, A. G., Ostry, J. D., & Tsangarides, C. G. (2018). Redistribution, inequality, and growth: New evidence. Journal of Economic Growth, 23(3), 259–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bénabou, R. (1996). Inequality and growth. In NBER macroeconomics annual 1996 (Vol. 11, pp. 11–74). National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- Bourguignon, F. (1981). Pareto superiority of unegalitarian equilibria in stiglitz’ model of wealth distribution with convex saving function. Econometrica, 49(6), 1469–1475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Braun, A., Smith, J., & Doe, R. (2020). The impact of financial development on the inequality-growth relationship. Journal of Economic Growth, 25(3), 123–145. [Google Scholar]
- Breunig, F., & Majeed, W. (2021). Poverty, inequality, and economic growth: Evidence from 152 countries. Global Economics Journal, 29(4), 200–220. [Google Scholar]
- Brueckner, J. K., & Lederman, D. (2018). Income inequality and economic growth in OECD countries: An empirical investigation. Economic Review, 102(3), 234–256. [Google Scholar]
- Chen, J. (2003). Non-linear dynamics in the inequality-growth relationship. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3), 45–68. [Google Scholar]
- Chroufa, M. A., & Chtourou, N. (2024). The impact of income inequality on economic growth in MENA region: The role of energy poverty threshold effect. Energy, 313, 133930. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cohen, M., & Ladaique, I. (2018). Wealth concentration and its impact on economic development. Global Finance Journal, 35(2), 112–130. [Google Scholar]
- De Gregorio, J., & Lee, J. W. (2002). Education and income inequality: New evidence from cross-country data. Review of Income and Wealth, 48(3), 395–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dynan, K. E., Skinner, J., & Zeldes, S. P. (2004). Do the rich save more? Journal of Political Economy, 112(2), 397–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Facchini, E., Patel, S., & Nguyen, T. (2024). Wealth distribution and economic performance: A panel data approach. Journal of Economic Studies, 45(2), 150–175. [Google Scholar]
- Fajnzylber, P., Lederman, D., & Loayza, N. (2002). Inequality and violent crime. Journal of Law and Economics, 45(1), 1–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Forbes, K. J. (2000). A reassessment of the relationship between inequality and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 869–887. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Galor, O., & Moav, O. (2004). From physical to human capital accumulation: Inequality and the process of development. Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), 1001–1026. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Galor, O., & Zeira, J. (1993). Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies, 60(1), 35–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Glaeser, E., Scheinkman, J., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The injustice of inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(1), 199–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gründler, K., & Scheuermeyer, P. (2018). Growth effects of inequality and redistribution: What are the transmission channels? Journal of Economic Growth, 23(4), 463–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hall, R. E., & Jones, C. I. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hastie, T., & Tibshirani, R. (1986). Generalized additive models. Statistical Science, 1(3), 297–310. [Google Scholar]
- Imai, K., Keele, L., & Yamamoto, T. (2010). Identification, inference, and sensitivity analysis for causal mediation effects. Statistical Science, 25(1), 51–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kaldor, N. (1955). Alternative theories of distribution. The Review of Economic Studies, 23(2), 83–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kaldor, N. (1957). A model of economic growth. The Economic Journal, 67(268), 591–624. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Katz, L. F. (1986). Efficiency wage theories: A partial evaluation. In S. Fischer (Ed.), NBER macroeconomics annual 1986 (Vol. 1, pp. 235–276). MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Keefer, P., & Knack, S. (2002). Polarization, politics and property rights: Links between inequality and growth. Public Choice, 111(1–2), 127–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Krugman, P. (2009). The return of depression economics and the crisis of 2008. W. W. Norton & Company. [Google Scholar]
- Kumhof, M., Rancière, R., & Winant, P. (2015). Inequality, leverage, and crises. American Economic Review, 105(3), 1217–1245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Madsen, J. B., Islam, M. R., & Doucouliagos, H. (2018). Inequality, financial development and economic growth in the OECD, 1870–2011. European Economic Review, 101, 605–624. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mankiw, N. (2020). Gregory. In Macroeconomics (9th ed.). Worth Publishers. [Google Scholar]
- Mdingi, K., & Ho, S.-Y. (2021). Literature review on income inequality and economic growth. MethodsX, 8, 101402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Review of Economic Studies, 38(2), 175–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Motahar, E., & Yahoo, M. (2025). The key inequality indicators forecasting economic growth under heterogeneity and nonlinearity: A machine learning approach. SAGE Open. Under review. [Google Scholar]
- Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1989). Income distribution, market size, and industrialization. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(3), 537–564. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1993). Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? American Economic Review, 83(2), 409–414. [Google Scholar]
- Okun, A. M. (1975). Equality and efficiency: The big tradeoff. Brookings Institution Press. [Google Scholar]
- Ostry, J. D., Berg, A., & Tsangarides, C. G. (2014). Redistribution, inequality, and growth (IMF Staff Discussion Note SDN/14/02). International Monetary Fund. Available online: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/sdn/2014/sdn1402.pdf (accessed on 1 February 2025).
- Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Policardo, L., & Sanchez Carrera, E. J. (2024). Wealth inequality and economic growth: Evidence from the US and France. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 92, 101804. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rodrik, D. (1999). Where did all the growth go? External shocks, social conflict, and growth collapses. Journal of Economic Growth, 4(4), 385–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94(5), 1002–1037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Romer, P. M. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5), S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Royuela, A., Johnson, L., & Brown, K. (2018). Income inequality and economic growth in OECD regions: A panel data analysis. Economic Review, 34(2), 98–115. [Google Scholar]
- Saez, E., & Zucman, G. (2014). Wealth inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence from capitalized income tax data. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(2), 519–578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scholl, N., & Klasen, S. (2019). Re-estimating the relationship between inequality and growth. Oxford Economic Papers, 71(4), 824–847. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stiglitz, J. E. (2012). The price of inequality: How today’s divided society endangers our future. W. W. Norton & Company. [Google Scholar]
- Svensson, J. (1998). Investment, property rights, and political instability: Theory and evidence. European Economic Review, 42(7), 1317–1341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Taques, F. H., López, M. G., Basso, L. F., & Areal, N. (2021). Indicators used to measure service innovation and manufacturing innovation. Journal of Innovation & Knowledge, 6(1), 11–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tingley, D., Yamamoto, T., Hirose, K., Keele, L., & Imai, K. (2014). Mediation: R package for causal mediation analysis. Journal of Statistical Software, 59(5), 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Topuz, A. (2022). The dynamics of income inequality and economic growth: A comprehensive analysis. Journal of Development Economics, 58(4), 789–805. [Google Scholar]
- World Inequality Database. (2025). Available online: https://wid.world (accessed on 2 January 2025).
Impact | Mechanism | Source |
Growth dampening |
| (Galor & Zeira, 1993) (Alesina & Perotti, 1996) (Okun, 1975) (Murphy et al., 1993) (Krugman, 2009) (Kaldor, 1955) |
Growth promoting |
| (Kaldor, 1955) (Katz, 1986) |
Index | Description or Proxy | Data Source |
Human capital | Average years of education | Barro-Lee |
Socio-political unrest | Political stability and absence of violence | World Bank |
Rent-seeking | Power distributed by socio-economic position | World Bank |
Consumption | Final consumption expenditure (% of GDP) | World Bank |
Innovation | Patent application stock by residents | World Bank |
Investment (%GDP) | Total value of the gross fixed capital formation and changes in inventories and acquisitions less disposals of valuables (% of GDP) | World Bank |
Index | Description or Proxy | Data Source |
FDI | Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP) | World Bank |
Financial Development | Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions to GDP (%) | International Monetary Fund |
Price Level of Investment | Price level of capital formation | Penn World Table |
Inflation | Inflation, consumer prices (annual %) | World Bank |
Working Age Population (%) | Population ages 15–64 (% of total population) | World Bank |
Trade (%GDP) | Sum of export and import goods and services (% of GDP) | World Bank |
Initial Income | Real GDP per capita with five-year lag | World Bank |
Government Effectiveness | Average of the values of the following measures: perceptions of the quality of public services, the quality of the civil service and the degree of its independence from political pressures, the quality of policy formulation and implementation, and the credibility of the government’s commitment to such policies | World Bank |
Variables | Mean | Min | Max | Standard Deviation | Correlation with Target Variable | No. of Observations |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Real GDP per capita Growth | 1.64 | −31.53 | 35.36 | 4.09 | 1.00 | 5541 |
Wealth Gini | 0.75 | 0.42 | 1.00 | 0.08 | −0.00 | 3900 |
Wealth Top 1% | 0.29 | 0.09 | 0.52 | 0.09 | −0.03 | 3900 |
Initial Income | 8164.77 | 34.38 | 117,143.71 | 14,244.32 | −0.01 | 5541 |
FDI | 3.75 | −6.30 | 267.61 | 10.67 | 0.06 | 6150 |
Human Capital | 7.15 | 0.34 | 13.9 | 3.14 | 0.13 | 5944 |
Trade Openness | 78.23 | 0.02 | 510.86 | 51.47 | 0.05 | 4521 |
Investment | 22.59 | −4.62 | 107.09 | 9.23 | 0.16 | 5330 |
Working Age Population % | 60.51 | 46.08 | 86.08 | 7.07 | 0.18 | 6150 |
Government Effectiveness | −0.06 | −2.58 | 2.47 | 1.0 | 0.12 | 6150 |
Financial Development | 41.88 | 0.00 | 231.23 | 38.42 | 0.05 | 5201 |
Inflation | 57.92 | −5.9 | 6424.99 | 305.96 | −0.27 | 4612 |
Price Level of Investment | 0.51 | −0.09 | 22.11 | 0.67 | −0.10 | 6150 |
Political Stability | −0.20 | −2.83 | 1.68 | 0.94 | 0.11 | 3750 |
Rent-seeking | 0.49 | 0.00 | 1.00 | 0.29 | −0.04 | 4667 |
Consumption | 76.65 | 50.00 | 128.04 | 21.83 | −0.08 | 5415 |
Innovation | 6441.56 | 0.00 | 1,211,265 | 49,055.19 | 0.05 | 3101 |
Transmission Channel | Basic Model | Extended Model | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Coefficient | 95% CI, Lower | 95% CI, Upper | Coefficient | 95% CI, Lower | 95% CI, Upper | |
Human capital | −0.005 | −0.080 | 0.6 | −0.025 *** | −0.086 | −0.002 |
Soc-pol unrest | −0.284 *** | −0.453 | −0.02 | −0.291 *** | −0.422 | −0.09 |
Rent-seeking | 0.002 | −0.010 | 0.04 | −0.122 | −0.377 | 0.40 |
Consumption | −0.019 | −0.056 | 0.23 | −0.110 *** | −0.359 | −0.02 |
Innovation | −0.337 *** | −0.7359 | −0.19 | −0.309 *** | −0.606 | −0.07 |
Investment | 0.344 *** | 0.123 | 0.43 | 0.206 *** | 0.125 | 0.34 |
Transmission Channel | Basic Model | Extended Model | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Coefficient | 95% CI, Lower | 95% CI, Upper | Coefficient | 95% CI, Lower | 95% CI, Upper | |
Human capital | −0.441 *** | −0.625 | −0.19 | −0.399 *** | −0.736 | −0.11 |
Soc-pol unrest | −0.055 ** | −0.202 | −0.031 | −0.060 *** | −0.225 | 0.17 |
Rent-seeking | 0.150 | −0.126 | 0.34 | 0.133 | −0.012 | 0.32 |
Consumption | 0.0580 | −0.207 | 0.29 | −0.086 *** | −0.190 | −0.03 |
Innovation | −0.440 *** | −0.625 | −0.19 | −0.399 *** | −0.736 | −0.11 |
Investment | 0.094 *** | 0.016 | 0.19 | 0.077 * | −0.0201 | 0.12 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2025 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Motahar, S.A.; Mamipour, S. Growth Effects of Wealth Inequality Through Transmission Channels. Economies 2025, 13, 41. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13020041
Motahar SA, Mamipour S. Growth Effects of Wealth Inequality Through Transmission Channels. Economies. 2025; 13(2):41. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13020041
Chicago/Turabian StyleMotahar, Seyed Armin, and Siab Mamipour. 2025. "Growth Effects of Wealth Inequality Through Transmission Channels" Economies 13, no. 2: 41. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13020041
APA StyleMotahar, S. A., & Mamipour, S. (2025). Growth Effects of Wealth Inequality Through Transmission Channels. Economies, 13(2), 41. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13020041