5.1. Best Fit to Model
All results have been produced against the same graph template so that comparison is possible and, apart from
Figure 6b for the ‘non-bankers’ which seems an outlier, some overall similarities and differences can be noted. The standard deviation of all answers is quite wide, narrowing somewhere between a 20 and 80 percent chance of being caught. In
Figure 2a and
Figure 3a, the results (for ‘bankers’) also show a markedly narrower standard deviation than others at a 100 percent chance of being caught. No set of results runs counter to the model and each markedly declines with decreased probability of being caught.
To identify their statistical significance the empirical results were further examined by the function
where
is the unknown number we are to determine. A nonlinear model fit procedure was used to obtain values of
for each of the contexts. Intrinsically, the algorithm tries many different values of
and picks the one which makes Equation (4) closest to the data points (by minimising the sum of the squares of differences between the curve and the data).
The goodness of fit was further evaluated by calculating the
statistic for each fitted curve:
Specifically, for every response
(i.e., for every grey dot on the plots), the distance to the corresponding mean response
is considered (the corresponding red dot on the plot), and is compared to the standard deviation
corresponding to the same point (the thickness of the shaded area on the plot). The number obtained in Equation (5) follows a chi-square distribution, with the number of degrees of freedom (D.O.F.) equal to the number of grey data points minus 1. The best-fit parameters
, the corresponding values of
, the degrees of freedom, and the corresponding
-values for the data are presented in
Table 2 and
Table 3. This shows the closeness of fit of the empirical data to the proposed model and its statistical soundness.
When the averages of each context, regardless of risk, are analysed in
Table 2, it can be noted that the highest correlation to the model is ‘non-bankers’ in ‘context 3’ and ‘context 4’. The latter is also where the closest correlation between ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’ was identified. On the contrary, the smallest correlation between ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’ appears in ‘context 3’. There seems generally to be a closer fit to the model for ‘bankers’ in every context apart from ‘context 5’. The small difference between ‘context 4’ and ‘context 5’ might be explained by the fact that ‘non-bankers’ may not have enough experience of being paid a bonus to produce reasoned results; yet, according to
Bell and Van Reenen (
2010), some bonus elements and this method of payment are not exclusive to the banking industry.
The most interesting results, therefore, occur when comparing the two subject groups. Despite the general idea that ‘bankers’ through experience generally have a better idea than others of what risks may lead to, or the general effect on their health or future earning potential of transgressing the given rules, these two groups do not show strikingly different results. The latter has been determined to be statistically significant given that the degrees of freedom (in
Table 3) offered are enough to provide robust data for the purposes of this analysis. Therefore, as in every survey concerning people, the nature of perception of risk proved to be different and non-dependent on the field of occupation.
The chi-square, degrees of freedom, and p-values are shown below.
The plots for all of the scenarios show generally higher deterrent penalties with decreasing risk. The best-fit curve in the plots for the data lies relatively close to the curve produced when results from the model are shown graphically, particularly for the low values of risk. While 100 percent risk shows less correlation with the model, real-life risk levels are typically less than 100 percent; therefore, the fit may be expected to be reasonably close to that shown by the model in this case.
The figure below shows the mean number of responses as a function of the fine specified for the data, accumulated over all contexts of risk and scenario (individual context penalties elevated to millions of dollars). It may be seen that the trends are relatively clear for ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’ in the data, with higher fines corresponding to lower numbers of responses, apart from the very high penalties at the apex of the range appearing to cause a leap in responses.
For presentation purposes,
Figure 7 was used to construct
Figure 8 by representing the empirical data through Gaussian functions with the same mean and standard deviation. In this way, the curves in
Figure 8 are described by
where the mean of the Gaussian
and the standard deviation
were set to be equal, corresponding to the mean and the standard deviation of the data. The scaling parameter
was chosen so that the peak of the Gaussian curve corresponded to the number of respondents in each group.
Notably, in
Figure 8 the curves for ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’ lie close to each other, and thus, illustrate that risk aversion based on penalty is very similar for both subject groups. The red dotted line is the mean average for ‘bankers’ and the blue dotted line that for ‘non-bankers’. The statistical significance of the difference was assessed by running a
t-test of independence on the mean values of the deterrent fines indicated for each of the questions in the survey by both subject groups. This demonstrates that in the data there is no statistical evidence that ‘non-bankers’ chose lower values of fine than bankers. This is similar for the raw data. In both cases, there is no statistically significant evidence that ‘bankers’ are deterred by different fines than ‘non-bankers’. Lastly, for all of the numerically answered questions in the raw data and data, Cronbach’s alpha was calculated. The data resulted in a Cronbach’s alpha of 0.966, indicating excellent internal consistency.
5.2. Regulatory Implications
While on the basis illustrated above, the Von Neumann–Morgenstern utility function was proved to be a solid tool for standardisation of capital adequacy violation penalties on an international level to prevent risk taking within the banking industry, given the average correlation at 0.54, responses for all contexts in the data showed a clear dependence of the deterrent penalty on the risk of being caught. The fit was found to be the best for 12.5 and 25 percent risk, perhaps because this degree of risk exists in reality. Only one of the contexts—‘assisted risk’—produced a marked divergence from the model, which could be attributed to the specification of this particular context and consequent potential profits. When the assisted risk context is removed, the average amount of correlation to the model rises to 0.572 for ‘bankers’ and 0.593 for ‘non-bankers’ as an average of all the other contexts.
While the consistency of the data was evaluated by calculating Cronbach’s alpha, which confirmed systematic excellent consistency, showing seriously considered answers by respondents, another key point of the empirical results was concerned with striking similarities between the responses of ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’. The key focus of any penalty system is concerned with the decisions made in a ‘banking context’, whether they include assisted risk or truly individual action. Here, the average correlation of ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’ combined with the model is 0.61 (0.57 and 0.64, respectively). Such similarity between the two groups sufficiently impacts the modern regulatory dialectics—liberalisation and deregulation alternating with re-regulation—as well as the way possible advantages and disadvantages (benefits and costs) of the two approaches for the economy are discussed.
When overregulation is costly and limiting, lenient regulations are mostly underpinned by the assumption that bankers, through experience, generally have a better idea than others of what risks may lead to, or the general effect on their future earning potential of transgressing the given rules. The markets have shown particular volatility during the last twenty years of under-regulation. Examples are legion, from the 1997 Asian crisis, the dotcom ‘bubble’ of 1997 to 2000, the US subprime mortgage crisis, and the European debt crisis. In each case, deregulation was followed by accelerated growth and increased bank lending. Whether through introducing asset-backed securities (ABSs) or mis-selling payment protection insurance (PPI), it is clear that regulations (or gaps in regulation) are frequently abused in the name of competitive advantage.
The empirical results of this paper concluded that risk aversion based on penalty is very similar for ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’, signifying similarities within the overall risk attitude of both groups. The curves of the distribution of the mean numbers of answers as a function of the deterring fine to identify the differences between the responses of ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’ lie close to each other (
Figure 8), with only small visual differences. Based on a
t-test of independence, it was found that there was no statistically significant evidence for any difference in the combined means for the answers by ‘bankers’ and ‘non-bankers’, amplifying that there is no statistical evidence that ‘bankers’ are deterred by different fines than ‘non-bankers’. Put simply, ‘bankers’ seemed to be no more risk averse than ‘non-bankers’. This may raise significant questions about the wisdom of ‘self-regulation’ in banking. Given the potential for damage as a result of undesirable developments and the incentives to which ‘bankers’ are exposed, self-regulation alone does not prove to be sufficient in financial markets, which was also illustrated by the empirical analysis.
A stable banking system requires properly implemented and well-supervised regulation. Only in this way can excessive risk be limited. Most importantly, and contingent to the industry, regulation ensure that banks are not tempted to make bad investments, acting something like a shock absorber in such cases. In the same way, deposit guarantee schemes ensure that even in the case of failure, all deposits under a certain amount are protected. The same goes for the newly created ring-fence practices. It is, nevertheless, questionable whether too tight a regulatory regime might throw up its own problems. Chief among these is an inflexibility and an inability to keep up to date with changing requirements. Too rigid a rulebook might also prove to be too excessive in its restrictions.
There is a need for well-balanced proportions of legal standards and voluntary, negotiated rules. Such an approach addresses responsibilities without strangling the core ability of the banks to function. Whatever the case, any regulatory system must acknowledge the importance and significance of risk. Not to do so is to make the industry a hostage to fortune.