Next Article in Journal
The Impact of Uncertainty on Trade: The Case for a Small Port
Next Article in Special Issue
Domestic vs. External Economic Sectors and the Political Process: Insights from Greece
Previous Article in Journal
The Effects of Diminished Tourism Arrivals and Expenditures Caused by Terrorism and Political Unrest on the Kenyan Economy
Previous Article in Special Issue
Moderation Effects of Government Institutional Support, Active and Reactive Internationalization Behavior on Innovation Capability and Export Performance
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

A Systematic Literature Review of the Impact of Complexity Theory on Applied Economics

1
School of Humanities and Social Science, University of Brighton, Brighton BN1 9PH, UK
2
School of Area Studies, History, Politics and Literature, University of Portsmouth, Portsmouth PO1 3AS, UK
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2022, 10(8), 192; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080192
Submission received: 30 June 2022 / Revised: 27 July 2022 / Accepted: 29 July 2022 / Published: 8 August 2022

Abstract

:
A systematic literature review is used to explore the relationship between complexity theory and economics. Broad search terms identify an unmanageable large number of hits. A more focused search strategy follows the PRISMA protocol and screens for Economics branded publications, and with key words for different applications of economics occurring in the abstract. This results in a distinct group of 247 publications. One hundred and twenty-two publications are excluded due to inclusion criteria or a lack of relevance. The remaining 113 are analysed for (1) use of complexity theory concepts, (2) types of methodology and methods, and (3) the applications for macro, meso, and micro issues. The publication with the greatest frequency of resulting articles is Complexity, closely followed by Ecological Economics. The highest annual citation ratio for a single article was 33.88. Complexity theory concepts included: non-linearity, system interactions, adaption, and resilience. Many developed a meso application, rather than solely focusing on macro or micro designs. Agent Based Models (ABMs) were popular, as were general systems models following the practice of the late system theorist, Donella Meadows. Applications were interdisciplinary and diverse, including world system models that linked macroeconomics to climate and sustainability, as contrast with micro and meso models trying to explain the complexity of agent-based behaviour on specific organisations or higher-level processes.

1. Introduction

Today’s policy makers are faced with unprecedented challenges in tackling their immediate priorities of economic growth as well as how to approach other long-term issues suhch as climate change, energy security, and public health amongst others. For issues with many interdependent factors (‘wicked problems’), it is difficult to determine drivers as multiple factors may produce similar or unidentical outcomes. For this reason, it is becoming more ubiquitous across the economic scholarship that understanding complexity offers a new science in which economic systems are understood as complex systems which cannot be judged using traditional linear analytical frameworks and methodologies. In light of these emerging complex policy challenges, advancements in economic conceptions have led to the development of ‘non-orthodox’ economic thinking with the labels heterodox and/or post-Keynesian economics (Lee and Lavoie 2012). Here, there is a growing scholarship on new ways of thinking that provide complementary, and alternative, perspectives to the equilibrium assumption of economic modelling. Within this economic paradigm lies the assumption that, amongst other things, economic systems are dynamic and oscillate between periods of stability and chaos, making them hard to predict.
Complexity theory is known to have had a growing influence on the broader social sciences in recent decades with increased citations that demonstrate this (Byrne and Callaghan 2013). Complexity theory was first developed in the physical sciences influencing the development of scientific concepts and methods for better understanding of unstable and difficult to predict systems such as meteorology (Lorenz 1963). Given the indeterminate nature of many social science phenomena, with novel behaviour and events resulting from a diversity of social interactions, many scholars soon saw the potential for complexity theory to assist in the explanation of the collective behaviours of societies and economies. Complex systems demonstrate a high level of uncertainty with low agreement between and across systems with regard to the causes of systemic pressures and the potential solutions to resolve such pressures (Bernardo and Smith 2009). This suggests an amount of irreducible uncertainty exists within the system (Sornette 2006). The uncertainty experienced within complex systems denotes non-linearity between cause and effect. This approach to thinking highlights properties that demonstrate features of complexity including, sensitivity to initial conditions and path dependency, emergence and self-organisation, feedback and feedback loops, and dynamic behaviours, as well as the interactions between these properties. Such an approach to economic modelling goes beyond the traditional orthodox approach where systems are seen to share identical patterns of behaviour, with interactions averaging each other out.
Castellani and Gerrits’ (2021) updated Map of the Complexity Sciences argues that Complexity Theory and Economics became increasingly linked from the 1990s onwards. The Santa Fe Institute (https://www.santafe.edu/ accessed on 20 July 2022) founded in 1984 was the first international scientific research institute dedicated to the study of complex adaptive systems. It succeeded in attracting leading scientists from across the world to consider important interdisciplinary science questions. Seminal academic leaders in this field included: Holland (1992), Kauffman (1993). Such scholars were ambitious in their desire to expand the new interdisciplinary scientific framework to cover the major social and economic challenges of the day. An economics program started in 1987, with much emphasis on the boundaries of the discipline, and the potential contribution of the interdisciplinary complexity science to economics. Fontana (2010), in a seminal historical summary of the impact of Santa Fe on economics, summarises three key impacts: dynamics, computational, and connectives. Complex dynamics is concerned with mathematical changes in economics with the developments to model chaos, sensitivity to initial conditions, and bifurcation. The focus here is on nonlinear approaches. Computational modelling primarily includes the development of agent-based modelling (ABM) allowing for a much more complex consideration of the behaviour of economic agents. Connective explanations are interested in the relational aspects of the economy such as positive and negative feedback and the operation of networks.
With this backdrop in mind, we use the Preferred Reporting Items for Systematic Reviews and Meta-Analyses (PRISMA) to comprehend the impact of complexity theory on applied economics. Before commencing this, we use an initial exploration to identify the most cited and highly influential scholars who have affected the metatheoretical union of complexity theory with general economics. We then proceed to make an original and substantial contribution, through the use of PRISMA to identify where this fusion of complexity theory with economics is having the most applied influence. In particular, we identify impacts in the use of microeconomics, including in business, management and organisations, and in macroeconomics, incorporating also political and policy-based interventions. There are also meso applications that link micro and macro in innovative ways. The paper structure is as follows, the subsequent section explains the method of using both an indicative literature search and a more structured systematic approach. Next, we present our results with a discussion on the most cited relevant scholars and PRISMA findings highlighting methodological trends as well as the thematic application of specific complexity concepts across our reviewed documents. Finally, we provide some concluding remarks.

2. Research Method

To assess developments in the application of complexity theory in applied economics, we undertake a two-step approach to data collection and review. First, we use Google Scholar as an initial search tool to explore the broad relationship between scholars and publications that link complexity theory with economics and to observe some quantitative citation evidence about the most important scholars and source material. Google Scholar is used for this indicative purpose because of its wide breadth of coverage, and relatively limited ability for the researcher to control and manipulate the search focus. Google Scholar only offers limited text search options (i.e., publication title, or text from the whole article) and uses automatic search algorithms to find what should be the most useful and relevant examples (Beel and Gipp 2009). The date of the search is 18 July 2022. The search term is: allintitle: complexity OR “complex systems” OR “complex adaptive systems” AND economics. It yields 523 references. We use this to construct an indicative summary of the major scholars who influence the use of complexity theory in economics.
Second, a focused systematic literature review is conducted to identify applied influences of complexity theory in economics research. As noted by Liberati et al. (2009), systematic reviews and meta-analyses are useful for summarising evidence in an accurate and reliable manner. The explicit use of systematic procedures to identify selected literature reduces bias, thereby providing reliable findings from which a researcher can draw conclusions and provide recommendations (Oxman and Guyatt 1993). This approach helps researchers keep up-to-date with topical developments while allowing readers to judge the quality of reporting, through the evidence-based rationale provided (Moher et al. 2016). In this study, our systematic review of relevant literature was undertaken in accordance with the reporting techniques outlined within the Preferred Reporting Items for Systematic Reviews and Meta-Analyses protocol (PRISMA) (Moher et al. 2009). Initially adopted in the medical sciences, the PRISMA protocol offers a set of procedures for the collection and reporting of systematic reviews and meta-analysis. PRISMA consists of four-phases, that is (a) document identification; (b) screening, (c) eligibility and (d) inclusion (see Figure 1 below for a flow diagram). These steps are aimed at improving the reporting of systematic reviews and meta-analysis. As outlined by Liberati et al. (2009), the PRISMA guidelines require a researcher to: (i) explicitly outline the research objectives with areproducible methodology; (ii) undertake a systematic search to identify studies that meet the eligibility criteria; (iii) validate the included studies; and (iv) present a synthesis of the content, characteristics and findings of studies included.
In this systematic review, we utilised a combination of the Elsevier Scopus (‘Scopus’) and Web of Science (WoS) database to search for publications in selected journals—imposing some further restrictions. Scopus is Elsevier’s largest citation and abstract database with peer-reviewed academic literature that cover the areas of social sciences, life sciences as well as health and physical sciences. Similar to Scopus, WoS is an academic citation and indexing database that provides access to journals covering the arts and humanities disciplines, sciences, and social science. The use of both databases offered a wide interdisciplinary coverage in the identification of specific research outputs. Both Scopus and WoS also provide filtering options for the researcher to control the search focus. To ensure a focus search scope, and to capture only relevant documents that fall within the theoretical parameters of the study, we generated the following search string to identify documents with the mention of “complexity theory” OR “complex systems” OR “complex adaptive systems” in the document keywords. From this search string, a combined total of 135,610 documents were identified across both databases. In order to filter for only relevant papers, we restricted our search to documents that included the initial search string in only the publication title, AND econ* OR complex* in the publication source title. This restriction allowed for the identification of publications in journals with a thematic focus on economics and complexity. Likewise, additional restrictions were placed to include policy OR management OR organization OR finan* in the abstract and further limiting this to include only publications in English1. These additional restrictions provided a sample of publications with ‘real world’ applications, rather than ‘theoretical conceptualisations’. After removing duplicates, a subset of 242 documents were identified. The data from Scopus and WoS was then extracted as a .csv file (comma-separated values) for further screening.
Data screening and eligibility were two-part, first, we examined the abstracts of each document to detect and remove irrelevant literature. From this, an initial 60 documents were excluded from our analysis as the content of these publications are not openly assessible to the public domain. The second screening consisted of an examination of the full text of each document. At this stage, we developed an eligibility criterion based on the relevance of the publications (i.e., a direct focus on the application of complexity theory in the areas of applied economics, management, policy or finance). We also utilised publications impacts as both Scopus and WoS offer numeric values on the number of citations each publication has had. Lastly, the document type (i.e., Article, Review, etc.) were also consider in our criterion. From this, an additional 69 documents were removed from our analysis. Three publications were classified as Editorial, 55 documents were classified as either Conference Papers, Proceedings or Note, and the remaining 11 publications were either not contextually relevant or dated prior to 2019 with little research impact (no citations). Figure 1 (above) provides an overview of the document collection process using the PRISMA framework.
Table 1 below shows the top 15 frequently occurring publication titles for the documents included in our meta-analysis. Overall, Complexity has the most journal publications considered in our sample. This journal publishes studies that contribute to discussion on complex systems across a broad range of disciplines. For journals with a direct focus on economics, Ecological Economics features the most and is promoted as covering the situation of economics within ecology and the importance of ecological values to micro and macroeconomics. The International Journal of Production Economics deals with the interface of management and production, including manufacturing and engineering, and is marketed as an interdisciplinary journal. This has similarities with Engineering Economics and Agricultural Economics.

3. Results and Discussion

3.1. Initial Exploration

One of the most cited is a book by Beinhocker (2006) entitled: The origin of wealth: evolution, complexity, and the radical remaking of economics with 2242 citations. Beinhocker is currently a professor at the University of Oxford. His book links economics with evolutionary biology and the thermodynamic laws of physics, therefore replicating some of the Santa Fe influence of seeing the natural sciences as important to economics. The core ideas of his book are summarised on page 97, Table 4.1. Economic systems are dynamic, nonlinear and far from equilibrium. Economic agents are diverse individuals with incomplete information who are subject to errors and biases. They adapt their behaviour. The economic interactions between agents can be partly understood through their changing networks of connections. Micro and macroeconomics are joined by the emergence of behaviours and interactions. The economic system evolves through differentiation, selection and amplification towards novelty and complexity. In the conclusion of his book, he makes a case for the linking of environmental issues and economics.
Arthur’s (2013) Complexity Economics is relevant with 450 citations. Furthermore, his recent (2021) article in Nature Review Physics. This already has 85 hits. Arthur is documented as being one of the first economists to be substantially involved with the Santa Fe Institute and this involvement has continued for several decades (Fontana 2010). An examination of Arthur’s own Google Scholar credentials reveal that he has 50,315 citations. Arthur challenges the basis of neoclassical economics. He rejects the dominant idea of an equilibrium where markets are clear to balance demand and supply. Instead, he argues that consumer and agent behaviour is diverse and evolving, leading to the emergence of new and novel aggregate outcomes. Therefore, economic interactions are not homogeneous but heterogeneous across a range of social networks. This often requires new and different mathematical approaches in economics. For policy makers, this means that they search for plausible patterns of interest that are limited in time and space rather than determined by universal laws. Policy makers face ‘decision making under fundamental uncertainty’ (Arthur 2021, p. 143).
In addition to an interest in the concept of ‘emergence’, Arthur is particularly influenced by several other concepts from complexity science such as: self-organisation (for explaining diversity within networks), power laws and long tails (for changing how policy makers and economists understand risk), and attractors (for explaining where specific empirical data patterns become important for a given time and space). With regard to methodology, Arthur focuses on consumer and agent behaviour in social networks and notes the importance of agent-based modelling as an excellent computation tool for modelling degrees of diversity in patterns of emergent behaviour in a given market context. Like almost all complexity theorists and practitioners in economics, he is committed to interdisciplinarity across the sciences and social sciences and is concerned if economics operates as a discipline in isolation from others.
Other notable substantial contributions identified in the Google Scholar search include Durlauf with two papers that are highly cited (Durlauf 2005, 2012) with 116 and 264 citations. His paper (2012) in Politics, Philosophy and Economics argues that complexity thinking adds value to contemporary economic modelling and analysis, but that it is not a theoretical paradigm shift, and he doubts the real benefits for public policy evaluation. He argues for a greater clarity about the mathematical tools that complexity theory provides for economic analysis. In the earlier paper (2005) published in The Economic Journal, he defines the empirical methods most used by complexity economists as: historical studies, power laws, and analyses of social interactions. He expresses scepticism about the extent to which the use of these methods validates the properties of complex systems.
Another scholar with substantial relevant citations is Rosser with 6660 citations on his Google Scholar author page. His most cited article (581 citations) of direct relevance is a paper in The Journal of Economic Perspectives (Rosser 1999). He argues that complexity economics have evolved from previous approaches examining cybernetic, catastrophic, and chaotic systems. Economic agents are dispersed and adapt their learning and novelty. Rationality becomes bounded. System simulation becomes an important method to understand complexity.
Rosser has also published with two other well cited authors (Holt et al. 2011). Their review of the state of the art of complexity and economics has 172 citations. Neither have Google Scholar author summary web pages, but both have other books and articles listed. For example, Colander’s (2000) single authored book: Complexity and the history of economic thought, is cited 109 times.
Antonelli (2008, 2009) has two single authored papers both with substantial numbers of citations (363, in 2008, and 159, in 2009). He is professor of Economics at the University of Torino and has 12,842 citations on Google Scholar. His scholarship is specific to the economics of technological innovation. He explores and explains innovation as a path-dependent process rooted in the interdependence and interaction of a diversity of heterogeneous agents. He argues: location is important (relative to other agents), agent knowledge of others is always limited (so, none has complete knowledge), interaction is often localised, agents are creative and can deviate from given rules, but agents are also highly interdependent causing systemic phenomena.
It is important to conclude at this point that using Google Scholar in this way is exploratory and not as rigorous and focused as imposing systematic boundaries as used later in this article by applying the PRIMSA method. Nevertheless, it allows for illustration of some of the most important historical influences. The worst consequence is the exclusion of important publications that are very closely related to the topic of interest, but which use title labels that are different.
A good example, offered by one of the reviewers of this paper is when “complexity” is substituted with “evolutionary”. Evolutionary economics is another subject having high impact on the discipline and with much overlap with complexity theory. A specific example is the work of Jason Potts. His Google Scholar author home page has 11,411 citations with several highly cited publications that include the keyword “evolutionary” in the title. On examination, the content overlaps with the conceptual domain of complexity economics. For example, his book: The New Evolutionary Microeconomics (2000) has 868 citations.
Similarly, peer reviewers of our article have pointed out that the eminent international scholar Doyne Farmer, Professor of Mathematics and Director of Complexity Economics at the University of Oxford, does not feature in our Google Scholar summary results, but he has highly cited articles that include the title keywords “chaos” and “chaotic”. In total he has 41,215 citations and one of his most highly cited articles is relevant to complexity and economics: ‘Predicting chaotic time series’ (Farmer and Sidorowich 1987) published with Sidorowich. It is cited 2782 times. These two examples illustrate the limits of using Google Scholar to acquire an overview.
This first overview search with Google Scholar provides a coherent but imperfect sense of the theoretical and conceptual framework of complexity theory as applied to economics.

3.2. Systematic Literature Review

Given what was identified in the broad Google Scholar search about conceptual priorities of complexity theory for economics, our thematic analysis of the PRISMA selected articles focused first on identifying the key conceptual issues presented by each selected publication, and how these compared with each other. Next, we identify the main methodological frameworks used by each publication, placing them into groups of similarity and difference in this respect. Finally, we examined the application of the research and scholarship in the context of the traditional coverage of economics: Macro, Meso and Micro.

3.2.1. Complexity Themes

A central theme emerging across the studies included is the fact that complex systems demonstrate multiple properties (Cilliers 1998). For this reason, in our thematic analysis, we identify a central focus on specific complexity themes across the publications included. While there are overlaps, the majority of studies considered in our analysis discuss non-linearity (43), adaptation (16), system interactions (49) and resilience (5). Table 2 provides an overview of the dominant complexity properties discussed across the 113 publications.
In complexity thinking, systems exhibit non-linear effects and as such they behave in ways that the effects of inputs may not be proportional to outcomes (Beinhocker 2006). From this perspective, slight changes to conditions (initial or in the external environment) can result in larger unpredictable consequences (Turner and Baker 2019). In this realm, systems operate in an unpredictable manner (Hanseth and Lyytinen 2016), reacting disproportionately to their environment (Turner and Baker 2019). For publications that focus on non-linearity, these studies attempt to develop and conceptualise social reality from a Complex Adaptive Systems (CAS) viewpoint, although placing emphasis on the non-linear nature of these systems or their external environment. For example, Gligor et al. (2022) apply this perspective in their observation of gender differences in logistical innovations. Touching on other concepts such as emergence and multiple causality, these scholars highlight how diversity in innovation teams and workforce provides a deeper understanding to customer needs. Their research also shows how applying complexity appropriate methods such as QCA can provide insights that other mainstream ‘regression-based’ approaches may be unable to. Taking an evolutionary approach, Chae (2012) also applies complexity theory to demonstrate predictability, localization, and emergence in service innovation. Importantly, Chae (2012) notes that the environment of service innovation is multifaceted, and uncertain.
Monasterolo et al. (2019) argue that traditional economic and financial risk models do not offer the capacity needed to develop appropriate climate risks models and climate-alignment opportunities. For these authors, this is due to the constrains of ‘equilibrium conditions and linearity of impacts, as well as by representative agents and intertemporal optimization’ (Monasterolo et al. 2019, p. 177). Instead, they attempt to fill this gap by advocating the use of complexity appropriate methods, such as agent-based and network models, for effective alignment between national and global climate targets. Supporting this, Balint et al. (2017) also argue that decentralised economic models offer alternatives to equilibrium-based models in their assessment of non-linear effects. Batabyal and Beladi (2011) take a similar non-equilibrium view in their assessment of agricultural resilience. These scholars also note a need for a departure from equilibrium-based approaches. From these studies, it is evident that the influence of complexity theory has resulted in a different worldview. This particular set of complexity thinkers demonstrate ways to identify and tackle non-linearity across complex systems. The particular focus on the area of ecological economics highlights the need for more realist assessment of policy impacts within this area. Nevertheless, publications within this cluster are premised on the notion that the social world operates in in an unstable and non-predictable uncertain manner. This highlights the need for new ontological and methodological frameworks that transcends the reductionist paradigm.
Our thematic analysis also identified 49 publications (Table 2) that attempt to capture the interactions between and across systems from a multidimensional perspective. These publications provide demonstrations on how individual components of a system affect each other, and in some cases, influence actions. Xepapadeas (2010) advocates the need for adequate modelling that looks at spatial interactions induced by feedback. He finds that linear dynamics are not adequate illustrations of ecological systems. Gimzauskiene and Kloviene (2010, 2011) provide two publications that focus on the application of complexity theory in performance measurement systems. Here, they show an understanding of how systems interact with, and react to, the external environment. Applying complexity theory to the management of building construction projects, both Naderpajouh and Hastak (2014) and Çıdık and Phillips (2021) emphasise the importance of social interactions on risk management. Zhu et al. (2017) provide a unique demonstration of levers and hubs, that is, when a component of a system has disproportionate influence over the whole due to structure and connections. Here, they attempt to develop a model that can predict degrading components. Mylek and Schirmer (2020) also provide an application of complexity thinking in communication strategies. They develop an approach to the design of communication, with the intent to match the complexity of the information with the population. Zhang et al. (2021b) show how institutional complexity can be applied with paradox theory to aid in efficient industrial change management, especially when faced with paradoxicalities.
In so far as systems operate in a non-static dynamic manner, and interact with each other, their components tend to adapt to, or learn from, changes to their environment. Sixteen publications (Table 2) also focus on adaptation, these studies provide a diversity of theoretical and contextual applications within which a system is seen to generate adaptive capabilities. Corbacioglu and Kapucu (2006), Li et al. (2010), Adamides and Pomonis (2009) and Zhang and Cui (2016) apply complexity theory to management practices and show how their attributes spontaneously adapt to changes in the environment. Here, adaptation may stem from organisational learning and self-adaptation in for instance, dynamic disaster environments (Corbacioglu and Kapucu 2006) or interactions within the external environment (Adamides and Pomonis 2009). Zhang and Cui (2016) attempt to quantitatively describe how a complex adaptive system highlightssystems self-adaptive to changing environments while Li et al. (2010) attempts to develop a multi-agent model that also factors in path dependency. Kim and Mackey (2014) and Garver (2019) also demonstrate how the environmental legal system can be viewed as adapting to its environment and suggest a systems-based assessment methodological viewpoint. Studies within this thematic cluster demonstrate how adaption may emerge when systems are at tipping points (Shobe 2020) or on the edge of chaos and uncertainty (Kim and Mackey 2014).
Finally, five articles (Table 2) major on the concept of resilience within the context of complexity theory. These publications take a more ecological perspective in their application of complexity theory. Darnhofer (2014) sees resilience as how complexity theory views the economic world as fundamentally unpredictable and actors and organisations must adapt to face this unpredictability. Korhonen and Snäkin (2015) examine resilience alongside efficiency and see resilience as achieved through diversity of resources. Plummer and Armitage (2007) and Shachak and Boeken (2010) take a non-equilibrium viewpoint in their development of an evaluation frameworks for ecological co-management. These authors argue that interactions do not always produce linear outcomes but are important for social-ecological resilience. Using a bibliometric analysis, Fraccascia et al. (2018) provide a comparison research study in ecological studies focusing on resilience. They show the multidisciplinary nature of resilience, especially in the fields of environmental science, ecology, and engineering.

3.2.2. Methodology and Method

Table 3 shows the overall comparison of the dominant methodology approach to research design across the 113 publications. The largest frequency is for those 45 publications that use a quantitative design. There is a variety of quantitative designs including: multi-agent and agent based modelling (Kukacka and Kristoufek 2020; Li et al. 2010; Hommes 2006; Tesfatsion 2006); Scenario Analysis (Korhonen and Snäkin 2015); Risk Assessment (Naderpajouh and Hastak 2014); Real Option Analysis (ROA) (Guo et al. 2021); statistical analysis of empirical data (Mylek and Schirmer 2020; Kijazi and Kant 2013; Gimzauskiene and Kloviene 2010, 2011); Intelligent Algorithms (Jemmali 2022); Power Law Distributions (Phillips 2019); modelling of live and empirical data (Zhu et al. 2017); and a NK model of fitness landscapes (Adamides and Pomonis 2009).
These examples show the use of quantitative methods to model complexity are diverse, ranging from theoretical mathematical modelling of what a complex economic system might be like, to empirical based models that use historical or current data collections. The quantitative designs explore research questions both for macroeconomics and microeconomics. Furthermore, it is clear in the systematic review that complexity theorists often try to include aspects of the interaction of macro and microeconomics, and the interface between them. This mid-level interaction is referred to in this article as ‘meso economics’. The quantitative microeconomics research that is identified includes applications for financial markets, manufacturing, production, engineering, construction, and environmental concerns.
There are four mixed methods publications in Table 3 and these include the mathematical approaches of Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) (Gligor et al. 2022) and Cluster Analysis (Garmendia and Gamboa 2012). This is interesting given that these are case based methods widely advocated for exploring and explaining complexity in the political sciences and sociology (Rihoux and Ragin 2009). Case based methods are regarded as appropriate in these disciplines because of their ability to detect different causal configurations that evidence social complexity (Haynes 2018). Corbacioglu and Kapucu (2006) used mixed methods to compare the economic adaptation of communities in disasters in Turkey.
Forty-two publications included in our systematic review are best described methodologically as case studies and/or system models. This combined category is because the case studies about complexity theory are not mutually exclusive from system models, which also often use real world examples to embed their concepts. However, some of these articles did this case example embedding much more than others. Some of the system models were primarily case studies and then analysed as system models, while other articles set out much more to define approaches to system modelling and perhaps only included a limited and generalised real-world example. An example of theoretical system modelling is Plummer and Armitage’s (2007) model of adaptive co-management of resources in a complex environment.
Garver’s (2019) publication in Ecological Economics is recognisable as a form of economic discourse, and it takes an abstract theoretical approach to the ambitious topic of the global economic system. The article examines the economy in relation to the interventions of the law and governance and how these macro entities interact through leverage points and lock-ins. If there is a case study in this article, it is the global system. This system modelling approach has some similarities to Kim and Mackey’s (2014 synthesis of international law as a complex adaptive system).
In contrast, the publications by Darnhofer (2014) and Braz and de Mello (2022) develop system models that are much more explicitly embedded in real world case studies. Darnhofer focuses on farm management as a definable system, but not a specific farm, or farming community in time and space. Braz and de Mello use the case study of a well specified supply chain economy in Brazil, using ‘within’ and ‘across’ case analysis. This case analysis clearly aids the explanation and conceptualisation of their theoretical model.
There were two previous systematic literature reviews discovered in our systematic review. Zhang et al. (2021b) explore complex ‘paradoxes’ in supply chain management, for example, improving inventory levels for operational flexibility and effectiveness, but whilst reducing inventory costs. Their article therefore sought out previous research on a very discrete subtopic on the periphery of mainstream complexity theory and was unlike the theoretical coverage of many (but not all) of the publications in our review. In other words, it is found that many of the articles attempted the opposite approach to Zhang et al. (2021b), preferring to offer ambitious and broad coverages across the metatheoretical landscape of complexity theory, rather than understanding a discrete sub-concept such as paradox. The narrow focus of their systematic review is a methodology strength in our opinion. Fraccascia et al. (2018) examine what they describe as ‘state of the art’ literature on complex systems and resilience and argue the literature is interdisciplinary but lacking in a shared understanding of a definition of resilience as a concept. They use a novel cross citation network analysis of the literature identified.
Nine other articles listed in our review were primarily unsystematic literature reviews. These publications deliberately use the research design of focusing on a controversial or seminal set, or single piece, of literature about the application of complexity to economics. The authors seek to add some original points to these arguments. Sometimes these designs are related to interdisciplinary theoretical areas. For example, Monasterolo et al. (2019) use some existing literature to argue for the need for a more robust approach to integrating macroeconomics models with an ecological perspective. Levanti (2018) looks at specific aspects of leading macroeconomic policy in complex socio-economic networks. While these two papers are in danger of presenting a rather esoteric contribution to the metatheoretical challenges of applying complexity theory, in contrast, Balint et al. (2017) present a well-structured critique of the literature on key areas of methodology. They focus on some literature covering the use of agent-based, network, and system dynamics models in ecological economics. While an obvious critique is that this is not done using a systematic method, the paper nevertheless gives a well-structured and robust account of methods that our own systematic review here also evidences as core territory to the application of complexity theory to economics. As a result, on page 262, Table 1, they provide a convincing summary of a comparison of system dynamics models and agent-based models with traditional equilibrium-based models. In their conclusion, they add weight to the prevailing direction of methodological changes in the sphere of applying complexity theory to economics:
‘… agent-based models are increasingly considered as a prominent alternative to standard general equilibrium models which overlook many of the risks of climate change.’ (Op cit, 262)
In another of the identified articles, Holt et al. (2011) draw primarily on existing writings rather than data and modelling to progress scholarship. They make an explicit and unapologetic contribution to an ongoing debate in the literature about whether complexity economics is really mainstream or heterodox. They argue that heterodox economics, especially when exploring scientific theories such as complexity, is not heterodox, but rather a necessary evolving of the mainstream discipline.
Finally, there are 11 articles in Table 3 using qualitative research methods. The definition of ‘qualitative’ here is broad and includes publications that discuss and argue conceptual issues, without being founded on specific literature or literature searches. For example, Kirman (2010) argues the weaknesses of General Equilibrium Theory and its impact on financial modelling and sees a complex adaptive systems approach as needed to better forecast major economic change. Coyne et al. (2021) look at conceptual issues and challenges in the interdisciplinary domain that overlaps public health with economics.
Çıdık and Phillips (2021) collect empirical qualitative data and analyse it for the journal Construction Management and Economics. They combine complexity theories with organisational approaches to reliable organisations to understand the impact of organisational culture on building safety. This is an alternative to taking a reductionist and quantitative approach to risk that assumes organisational stability over time. Twelve unstructured interviews are used to obtain evidence from experts. Social interaction is viewed as an important aspect in mitigating risk, this in addition to classical approaches to quantitative assessments of materials and costs associated with risks of combustibility.

3.2.3. Applications and Impact

Table 4 shows the frequencies of the type of application in economics contributed by the publications reviewed. This is on the basis of a division into the categories: macro, meso and micro.
Macroeconomics counts applications that are primarily directed at national and global economic issues. Microeconomic applications count applications that are primarily concerned with specific organisations and how individual agent behaviour contributes to collective phenomena. Meso economics is focused on the interaction of micro elements with macro elements and how the two dimensions influence and change each other. For example, from the publications considered in our systematic review, Li et al. (2010) see the disruption and uncertainties that external influences have on local organisational processes and systems.
The frequencies of the trio of macro, meso, micro groupings for the publications considered are relatively evenly distributed (Table 4). The importance of meso considerations (n = 39) shows that complex systems theoretical frameworks can be expected to lead researchers towards the interface between individual agents with their locality and the associated relational connections they have with regions, nations, and globalisation. Examples of this from the meso publications we review, include Shobe’s (2020) critique of the difficulty with applying an optimal policy process to the decentralisation of environmental policy making due to the tightly connected and interlinking of organisations and devolved political geographies who have a stake in outcomes. Shobe sees studies of linked and adaptive complex systems as a key methodology for improving policy applications.
Zhang et al. (2021b) acknowledge the paradoxes and contradictions within patterns of agent interactions and how they make sense of the world. This is an aspect of complex outcomes that needs acknowledgment in applications to management practice. Korhonen and Snäkin’s (2015) approach to modelling the Finnish energy system argues it is important to research the interdependent aspect of systems and their boundaries, thereby examining a specific city in relation to other municipalities with which it is regionally linked. Such a quantitative model evidences the importance of collaboration between cities and regions. Similarly, but applying a case study approach rather than a quantitative model, Braz and de Mello (2022) propose a meso complexity informed systems framework that includes management mechanisms, in addition to attributes of the internal and external environment.
Patrucco (2011) describes how changes in the network of the automobile production system in northern Italy is sustained by the dynamic interactions between firms. This modifies the behaviour of the key economic actors involved and promotes cross sector innovation and change with macro consequences. Furthermore, Gimzauskiene and Kloviene (2011), argue for an integrated meso approach to performance management that includes both internal and external influences for any individual organisation. Complexity, as uncertainty in the operating environment, becomes a key component of adaptive performance management (Gimzauskiene and Kloviene 2010). Likewise Batabyal and Beladi (2011) argue the multiple influences on range management in farming.
Garmendia and Gamboa’s (2012) seek to model the many interests of different social groups towards sustainable natural resource management in northern Spain. They evidence that patterns of actor priorities can be grouped rather than being unrelated, but more importantly can give feedback into the dynamics of higher-level deliberation about social and economic change.
A model of service innovation developed by Chae (2012, p. 820) provides evidence of the meso dimensions that impact change in the service industry.
‘Services arise and are emergent through recombination and/or reconfiguration of diverse resources and contexts from service provider, customer, and other economic actors. This recombinant/reconfiguring process, along with an effective balance of mutation and crossover, is a key for business growth and customer service experience.’
Garmendia and Stagl (2010) examine the interaction of participation about sustainability with the need to change social views and attitudes to ecology and economics. They conclude that there are uncertainties about participatory approaches to changing public attitudes towards the economics of sustainability.
These sorts of ambitious attempts at modelling the meso complexity and uncertainty of interactive agents and systems raises the issue about how useful such models can be for applied operational management applications, and whether the research outcomes offer only broad advice, such as the need for a good external view of economic and social change, and the ability to adapt policy and decisions rapidly in response.
Nevertheless, Adamides and Pomonis (2009) argue the emergence of new forms of organisational order from this complex and unpredictable range of meso influences. Rammel et al. (2007) assert the importance of a conceptual approach that understands non-linearity, non-equilibrium, and the resulting co-evolution of the system, if any progress is to be made in a research agenda that informs resource management. For Tesfatsion (2006) and Hommes (2006) ABM and its advancement through related dynamic methods is the research design of choice for progressing research on these meso-economic approaches. Phillips (2019) is concerned with the real-world example of bankers and financiers at the micro level misunderstanding risk with adverse consequences for macroeconomic policy, as in the Great Financial Crisis of 2008. Power Law distributions are seen as the research solution for getting better decision making that avoids such risks in the future.
Given that complexity focused approaches to solving meso-economic challenges are conceptually and methodologically ambitious, and offer limited insights to ‘wicked’ problems, it is not surprising that some applications identified in the selected publications reviewed still use either a macro or micro approach. Here, the system boundaries are restricted to either the global geopolitical economic system, often in the form of ecological economics, or the detail of production or performance within a single organisational system.
Of the 45 publications identified in Table 4 as having macro applications, five of these are published in the journal Ecological Economics. Monasterolo et al. (2019) argue for the changes in economic modelling necessary if countries are to hit global climate targets. Complexity science and evolutionary economics are seen as providing the fundamental framework for these changes. Garver (2019) argues for law and governance system changes in order to make global ecological improvements and identifies system leverage points to achieve change. Balint et al. (2017) cite both micro and macroeconomic literature, but produce largely macroeconomic conclusions about the importance of complexity economics models to provide knowledge on coalition formation, the macroeconomic impact of climate change, energy market dynamics, and the uptake of sustainable technologies. An earlier article by Plummer and Armitage (2007) provides an evaluative framework for the adoption of macro ecosystem and livelihood conditions, alongside the necessary governance changes. Matutinović (2001) hypothesises that socio-economic diversity is a prerequisite for social and ecological stability. At the core of these articles published in Ecological Economics is a meta world view of economics embedded with other global systems such as the available physical resources, climate dynamics and population demographics.
The other publications classified as being applied to macroeconomics in Table 4 include two in sources covering agricultural economics. Xepapadeas (2010) argues for a complexity approach to modelling that includes: nonlinear feedbacks, and spatial and temporal aspects. Darnhofer (2014) develops the concept of resilience as an alternative to equilibrium. This is a method for substantiating both complex system dynamics and the role of individual farms in managing macro social and ecological change. Farms are resilient to external changes by having a buffer capability, and an adaptive and transformative capability.
Other articles classified in Table 4 as having a macroeconomic approach include one about the importance of legal governance within a global economic system (Kim and Mackey 2014). Another by Holt et al. (2011) in Post Keynesian Economics argues that complexity economics needs a broad view of what is accepted within the economics discipline, rather than recognizing alternatives to classicism as heterodoxy. Furthermore, Brunk and Hunter (2008) offer an ecological approach to economic stagnation. They conclude that traditional macroeconomic policy approaches will exacerbate economic problems. Mueller (2020) concludes on the inevitable risk of policy failure for much macroeconomic intervention into complex global and national systems. Matesanz Gomez et al. (2017) argue the great financial crisis of 2008 resulted in increased macroeconomic system changes in Europe that challenge the commonly accepted notion of identifiable core and peripheral euro zone countries. Gaffeo and Tamborini (2011) examine the challenge of regulating macroeconomic finance in an age of globalisation and open capital markets. They see the usefulness of network theory and approaches but conclude that major questions remain about how to apply such idea to regulatory policy interventions. Milne (2009) examines the aims of macroprudential policy and concludes the most important aspect is to maintain the flow of finance through the economic system.
Twenty-nine publications are classified in Table 4 as being primarily micro in their complexity economics design. Jemmali (2022) creates a smart car parking system that enables a health service to vaccinate the most efficient number of people with a given period of time and resources. Gligor et al. (2022) research gender differences in logistics innovation. They identify different causal configurations for innovation with important gender differences across these configurations.
Several publications focus on novel approaches to understanding risk. Brocal et al. (2019) critique current models of risk management and propose a complex system of governance for better risk management. Çıdık and Phillips (2021) research professional opinions about high-risk buildings and conclude that collective culture as social interaction is an important aspect for reducing risk in addition to structured interventions for assessing physical conditions. Mylek and Schirmer (2020) measure the extent to which public actors have some degree of cognitive complexity as ‘integrated complexity’ in their ability to comprehend the socio-economic trade-offs, if policy interventions are to reduce wildfire risks. Another study that brings advances in complexity theory to agent perspectives and how they interact dynamically, is Naderpajouh and Hastak’s (2014) concept of Interaction Analysis (IA). This forms a new type of risk assessment that estimates newly emerging risks in major construction projects.
Other microeconomic publications informed by complexity economics also examine uncertain outcomes from agent activities. Guo et al.’s (2021) model theorises how to optimise concessions to suppliers. This is during the unstable context of managing an ongoing public-private partnership contract. Kopp and Salecker (2020) look at how traders interact with their neighbours. Sellers’ decisions about a buyer are often influenced by debt obligations and past interactions, including similar experiences of education, and living in close proximity. Kijazi and Kant (2013) theorise an approach to complex agent behaviour as ‘socially rational’ agents. These types of analysis of complex agents takes economic perspectives far beyond the concept of rational economic agents who are assumed to behave in similar ways. Nevertheless, agents are influenced by complex patterns of behaviour, often influenced by similar cross cutting social networks.
Not all the micro focused publications examine human interaction and behaviour. Zhu et al. (2017) analyse physical inputs and processes, rather than human actors, this in an engineering production process. They develop a quantitative model to measure the likely boundaries of component degradation (condition-based maintenance) within a complex multifaceted engineering process.

4. Conclusions

Figure 2 shows the frequency of publications from our systematic review over time. This highlights the growing applications of complexity theory in economic research. The trend for the publications included in our systematic review also provides some interesting suggestions on the influence of the global environment and the importance of the contextualization of such events. For instance, the increase in publications during 2010 reflects the impacts of the financial crisis and a moment when academic scholarship further questioned the use of traditional ‘linear’ economic ontologies. There is also an increasing trend in relevant publications during the last 15 years, with some fluctuations in the most recent period after 2018. This may result because of publications taking their time to get listed on databases.
Table 5 shows which of the reviewed publications have had the greatest impact through citations. The ratio index shows the annual ratio of citations per year, to avoid overly rating the impact of older articles. Hommes (2006) and Tesfatsion’s (2006) contributions to the Handbook of Computational Economics have the highest ratios, an indication of the primacy that economics places on these kinds of contemporary quantitative models. Next, in Table 5 are a cluster of several authors publishing in the journal Ecological Economics, a journal that is clearly making an important impact in the integration of complexity theory with macro and meso system modelling that juxtaposes environmental and sustainability issues with the operations of governments and markets. This typifies the interdisciplinary approach of complexity economics. It is also an important observation given the current international concern about climate change and climate warming.
The interdisciplinary nature of complexity theory goes much wider than just this important single journal of Ecological Economics, and the different juxtapositions of other disciplines with economics is evidenced by the range of publication titles in Table 1. The nature of this interdisciplinarity is that it manifests itself especially in sub-disciplinary areas such as business and management studies, and ecology, rather than impacting the historical core of the foundation social science disciplines such as economics, sociology, and psychology. This leaves complexity economics open to the criticism that it is on the periphery of the single discipline. However, conversely the interdisciplinary approaches are contemporary and dealing with current real-world problems and applications. An example is Darnhofer’s system model of farm management published in 2014 that deals with how farms can be resilient to ecological and economic change, and it has the fourth highest citation ratio in Table 5. Not all interdisciplinary complexity work is applied across the meso ‘connect’ and some highly cited scholars attempt an ambitious system world macro view especially when modelling global issues such as sustainability (Balint et al. 2017; Plummer and Armitage 2007).
In the publications reviewed there was a strong presence of ecology and climate change modelling that locate economics in a greater ‘world/ecological/global system’. Table 1 evidences this with nine publications coming from Ecological Economics and seven from Ecological Complexity. (The later journal includes important global systems approaches but is less directly related to economics and the analysis of markets). Highly cited examples of the more economics focused approaches in Table 5 include Rammel et al. (2007) and Garmendia and Stagl (2010) and Garmendia and Gamboa (2012).
In terms of metatheory, complexity contributes a stinging critique of earlier economic approaches through its focus on unpredictability (Arthur 2013, 2021; Beinhocker 2006). Linked to this is a revision of economic agents who become not only consumers, but active actors politically, and motivated by a range of social aspects. Agents are therefore seen as heterogeneous and diverse, but with some consistent patterns of behaviour, often manifest in networks. They are not homogeneous. This has influenced the type of modelling that results (Hommes 2006; Tesfatsion 2006; Monasterolo et al. 2019; Balint et al. 2017).
This aspect of complexity, and the acknowledgement of multiple influences on dynamic economic systems, results in numerous publications having a strong ambition to develop meso models that have the potential to include both macroeconomics and microeconomics in some aspect. Here, there is a linking of the levels of analysis (Korhonen and Snäkin 2015; Garmendia and Stagl 2010; Chae 2012). However, this also results in a caution about how the theory is applied. Sometimes applications are speculative and based on general principles rather than offering prescriptive techniques. Good examples are the approaches towards the management of risk in sectors such as finance, engineering, and production (Chae 2012; Naderpajouh and Hastak 2014; Zhu et al. 2017).
Some important conclusions can be drawn about the use of methods in complexity economics. Agent based models and similar theoretical simulations of how a complex economy might behave are popular and often widely cited (Hommes 2006; Tesfatsion 2006). It is surprising that mixed methods and causal configurative methods do not feature more. The best example of such practices being a recent publication that includes Qualitative Comparative Analysis (Gligor et al. 2022). It is the experience of the authors of this systematic literature review that these types of contemporary complexity appropriate methods are used much more in political science, public policy and sociology. Furthermore, in the UK, they have made an important impact on the work of the HM Treasury (Bicket et al. 2020).
The use of general systems models in the tradition of the late Donella Meadows (2008) continue to have a wide use and impact in complexity economics, especially when concurrent with ecological issues (for example, Matutinović 2001; Garver 2019). This is again evidenced from the important impact of the journal Ecological Economics. System models that combine economics with environmental issues also span a wide range of publications including: Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, Ecological Complexity, Forest Policy and Economics and The Economic Review of Agricultural Economics.
Overall, there are two key sets of publications that our systematic literature review exposed about complexity economics. On the one hand, there is the scholarship that explicitly addresses recognisable aspects of the contemporary agenda of the economics discipline. We have tended to focus on this literature in the examples used in the thematic analysis. The second area of literature is more implicit in its juxtaposition of complexity and economics, it being primarily concerned with the scientific development of complexity theory. In this second field of publications, the ambitious and wide coverage of complexity science across many disciplines, results in the continuing development of the broad theoretical perspective, but where the application to the working practice of economics is often weak. In our review we have chosen to highlight more the best working examples of the application of complexity science that in our opinion are having the greatest impact on the application and practice of economics. It is our argument that this continues to be an important development and one that will continue to change the nature of economics and its applications. The literature review provided gives evidence for our argument.

Author Contributions

Both authors have contributed equally to the article overall, especially with regard to thematic analysis. D.A. led on the PRISMA literature review, P.H. on the introduction and indicative Google Scholar exploration. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

We are grateful to our employing institutions for their support: University of Brighton and University of Portsmouth. David Alemna’s current post is funded by the Economic and Social Research Council [Project Reference: ES/W005743/1], as a South Coast Doctoral Training Partnership Postdoctoral Fellowship.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not Applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not Applicable.

Data Availability Statement

It is possible to reproduce the systematic literature review used in this article, as the search terms are included in full in the text.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interests.

Note

1
The resulting search string: (KEY (“complexity theory” OR “complex system” OR “complex adaptive system”) AND SRCTITLE (econ* OR complex*) AND ABS (policy OR management OR organization OR finan*)) AND (LIMIT-TO (LANGUAGE, “English”)).

References

  1. Adamides, Emmanuel D., and Nikolaos Pomonis. 2009. The Co-Evolution of Product, Production and Supply Chain Decisions, and the Emer-Gence of Manufacturing Strategy. International Journal of Production Economics 121: 301–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Aeeni, Zeynab, and Mehrzad Saeedikiya. 2019. Complexity Theory in the Advancement of Entrepreneurship Ecosystem Research: Future Research Directions. In Eurasian Business Perspectives. Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 19–37. [Google Scholar]
  3. Ahmad, Syed Amaar. 2019. Urbanization, Energy Consumption and Entropy of Metropolises. Complex Systems 28: 287–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Albin, Peter S., and Duncan K. Foley. 2001. The Co-Evolution of Cooperation and Complexity in a Multi-Player, Local-Interaction Pris-Oners’ Dilemma. Complexity 6: 54–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Aldhyani, Theyazn H. H., Manish R. Joshi, Shahab A. AlMaaytah, Ahmed Abdullah Alqarni, and Nizar Alsharif. 2021. Using Sequence Mining to Predict Com-Plex Systems: A Case Study in Influenza Epidemics. Complexity 2021: 9929013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Aldunate, Roberto G., Feniosky Pena-Mora, and Gene E. Robinson. 2005. Collaborative Distributed Decision Making for Large Scale Disaster Re-Lief Operations: Drawing Analogies from Robust Natural Systems. Complexity 11: 28–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Antonelli, C. 2008. Localised Technological Change: Towards the Economics of Complexity. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  8. Antonelli, Cristiano. 2009. The Economics of Innovation: From the Classical Legacies to the Economics of Complexity. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 18: 611–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Aouad, Jennifer, and Fabio Bento. 2019. A Complexity Perspective on Parent–Teacher Collaboration in Special Education: Narratives from the Field in Lebanon. Journal of Open Innovation Technology Market and Complexity 6: 4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Arthur, W. Brian. 2013. Complexity Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  11. Arthur, W. Brian. 2021. Foundations of Complexity Economics. Nature Reviews. Physics 3: 136–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  12. Aymanns, Christoph, J. Doyne Farmer, Alissa M. Kleinnijenhuis, and Thom Wetzer. 2018. Models of Financial Stability and Their Application in Stress Tests ✶. In Handbook of Computational Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 329–91. [Google Scholar]
  13. Balint, Tomas, Francesco Lamperti, Antoine Mandel, Mauro Napoletano, Andrea Roventini, and Alessandro Sapio. 2017. Complexity and the Economics of Cli-Mate Change: A Survey and a Look Forward. Ecological Economics 138: 252–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Batabyal, Amitrajeet A., and Hamid Beladi. 2011. Ecological, Economic, and New Synthetic Perspectives in Range Management: An Interpretative Essay. International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics 5: 147–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Beel, Jöran, and Bela Gipp. 2009. Google Scholar’s Ranking Algorithm: An Introductory Overview. Paper presented at 12th International Conference on Scientometrics and Informetrics (ISSI’09), Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, July 14–17; vol. 1, pp. 230–41. [Google Scholar]
  16. Beinhocker, Eric D. 2006. The Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of Economics. Boston: Harvard Business Press. [Google Scholar]
  17. Bento, Fabio, and Luciano Garotti. 2019. Resilience beyond Formal Structures: A Network Perspective towards the Challenges of an Aging Workforce in the Oil and Gas Industry. Journal of Open Innovation Technology Market and Complexity 5: 15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Berg, Johannes, Matteo Marsili, Aldo Rustichini, and Riccardo Zecchina. 2002. Are Financial Markets Efficient? Phase Transition in the Aggregation of Information. Complexity 8: 20–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Bernardo, José M., and Adrian F. M. Smith. 2009. Bayesian Theory. Hoboken: John Wiley and Sons, vol. 405. [Google Scholar]
  20. Bianchi, Patrizio, and Sandrine Labory. 2019. Regional Industrial Policy for the Manufacturing Revolution: Enabling Conditions for Complex Transformations. Cambridge Journal of Regions Economy and Society 12: 233–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bicket, Martha, Ian Christie, Nigel Gilbert, Dione Hills, Alexandra Penn, and Helen Wilkinson. 2020. Magenta Book 2020 Supplementary Guide: Handling Complexity in Policy Evaluation. London: HM Treas. [Google Scholar]
  22. Braz, Antonio Carlos, and Adriana Marotti de Mello. 2022. Circular Economy Supply Network Management: A Complex Adaptive System. International Journal of Production Economics 243: 108317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Brocal, Francisco, Cristina González, Dragan Komljenovic, Polinpapilinho F. Katina, and Miguel A. Sebastián. 2019. Emerging Risk Management in Industry 4.0: An Approach to Improve Organizational and Human Performance in the Complex Systems. Complexity 2019: 2089763. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Brunk, Gregory G., and Kennith G. Hunter. 2008. An Ecological Perspective on Interest Groups and Economic Stagnation. The Journal of Socio-Economics 37: 194–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Bruno, Bruna, Marisa Faggini, and Anna Parziale. 2018. Innovation Policies: Strategy of Growth in a Complex Perspective. In Social Dynamics in a Systems Perspective. Cham: Springer International Publishing, pp. 65–84. [Google Scholar]
  26. Budd, Leslie, Alessandro Sancino, Michela Pagani, Ómar Kristmundsson, Borut Roncevic, and Michael Steiner. 2017. Sport as a Complex Adaptive System for Place-Based Leadership: Comparing Five European Cities with Different Administrative and Socio-Cultural Traditions. Local Economy 32: 316–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Byrne, David, and Gill Callaghan. 2013. Complexity Theory and the Social Sciences: The State of the Art. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  28. Castellani, Brian, and Lasse Gerrits. 2021. Map of Complexity Sciences. Available online: https://www.art-sciencefactory.com/complexity-map_feb09.html (accessed on 25 July 2022).
  29. Chae, Bongsug K. 2012. An Evolutionary Framework for Service Innovation: Insights of Complexity Theory for Service Science. International Journal of Production Economics 135: 813–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Chakraborti, Anirban, Hrishidev, Kiran Sharma, and Hirdesh K. Pharasi. 2021. Phase Separation and Scaling in Correlation Structures of Financial Markets. Journal of Physics: Complexity 2: 015002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Chikumbo, Oliver, Roger Bradbury, and Stuart Davey. 2000. Large-Scale Ecosystem Management as a Complex Systems Problem: Mul-Ti-Objective Optimisation with Spatial Constraints. Applied Complexity-From Neural Nets to Managed Landscapes 8: 124–55. [Google Scholar]
  32. Çıdık, Mustafa Selçuk, and Stephen Phillips. 2021. Buildings as Complex Systems: The Impact of Organisational Culture on Building Safety. Construction Management and Economics 39: 972–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Cilliers, Paul. 1998. Complexity and Postmodernism: Understanding Complex Systems. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  34. Cioffi-Revilla, Claudio. 2014. Seeing It Coming: A Complexity Approach to Disasters and Humanitarian Crises. Complexity 19: 95–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Colander, David. 2000. Complexity and the History of Economic Thought. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  36. Colander, David, Richard P. F. Holt, and J. Barkley Rosser. 2010. How to Win Friends and (Possibly) Influence Mainstream Economists. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 32: 397–408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Cooper, Melinda. 2011. Complexity Theory after the Financial Crisis: The Death of Neoliberalism or the Triumph of Hayek? Journal of Cultural Economy 4: 371–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Corbacioglu, Sitki, and Naim Kapucu. 2006. Organisational Learning and Selfadaptation in Dynamic DisasterEnvironments. Disas-Ters 30: 212–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  39. Coyne, Christopher J., Thomas K. Duncan, and Abigail R. Hall. 2021. The Political Economy of State Responses to Infectious Disease. Southern Economic Journal 87: 1119–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Dai, Wensheng. 2021. Development and Supervision of Robo-Advisors under Digital Financial Inclusion in Complex Systems. Complexity 2021: 6666089. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Darnhofer, Ika. 2014. Resilience and Why It Matters for Farm Management. European Review of Agricultural Economics 41: 461–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Dong, Xiaoli, and Stuart G. Fisher. 2019. Ecosystem Spatial Self-Organization: Free Order for Nothing? Ecological Complexity 38: 24–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Dosi, Giovanni, and Andrea Roventini. 2017. Agent-Based Macroeconomics and Classical Political Economy: Some Italian Roots. Italian Economic Journal 3: 261–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Durlauf, Steven N. 2005. Complexity and Empirical Economics. Economic Journal (London, England) 115: F225–F243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Durlauf, Steven N. 2012. Complexity, Economics, and Public Policy. Politics Philosophy & Economics 11: 45–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Elidrissi, Hajar Lamghari, Nait-Sidi-Moh Ahmed, and Tajer Abdelouahed. 2020. Knapsack Problem-Based Control Approach for Traffic Signal Management at Urban Intersections: Increasing Smooth Traffic Flows and Reducing Environmental Impact. Ecological Complexity 44: 100878. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Elsner, Wolfram. 2017. Complexity Economics as Heterodoxy: Theory and Policy. Journal of Economic Issues 51: 939–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Espejo, Raul. 2018. Social Dynamics in a Systems Perspective. Cham: Springer, pp. 121–35. [Google Scholar]
  49. Evans, John, Neil Allan, and Neil Cantle. 2017. A New Insight into the World Economic Forum Global Risks. Economic Papers A Journal of Applied Economics and Policy 36: 185–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Farmer, J. Doyne, and John J. Sidorowich. 1987. Predicting chaotic time series. Physical review letters 59: 845. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  51. Fontana, Magda. 2010. The Santa Fe Perspective on Economics: Emerging Patterns in The Science of Complexity. History of Eco-Nomic Ideas XVIII: 167–94. [Google Scholar]
  52. Forbes, Dolores Jane, and Zhixiao Xie. 2018. Identifying Process Scales in the Indian River Lagoon, Florida Using Wavelet Transform Analysis of Dissolved Oxygen. Ecological Complexity 36: 149–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Fraccascia, Luca, Ilaria Giannoccaro, and Vito Albino. 2018. Resilience of Complex Systems: State of the Art and Directions for Future Research. Complexity 2018: 3421529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Friedrich, Jan, Joachim Peinke, Alain Pumir, and Rainer Grauer. 2021. Explicit Construction of Joint Multipoint Statistics in Complex Systems. Journal of Physics: Complexity 2: 045006. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Gaffeo, Edoardo, and Roberto Tamborini. 2011. If the Financial System Is Complex, How Can We Regulate It? International Journal of Political Economy 40: 79–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Garmendia, Eneko, and Gonzalo Gamboa. 2012. Weighting Social Preferences in Participatory Multi-Criteria Evaluations: A Case Study on Sustainable Natural Resource Management. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 84: 110–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Garmendia, Eneko, and Sigrid Stagl. 2010. Public Participation for Sustainability and Social Learning: Concepts and Lessons from Three Case Studies in Europe. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 69: 1712–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Garver, Geoffrey. 2019. A Systems-Based Tool for Transitioning to Law for a Mutually Enhancing Human-Earth Relationship. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 157: 165–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Georgiev, Georgi Yordanov, Kaitlin Henry, Timothy Bates, Erin Gombos, Alexander Casey, Michael Daly, Amrit Vinod, and Hyunseung Lee. 2015. Mechanism of Organization Increase in Complex Systems. Complexity 21: 18–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Gimzauskiene, Edita, and Lina Kloviene. 2010. Research of the Performance Measurement System: Environmental Perspective. Inžinerinė Ekonomika 21: 180–86. [Google Scholar]
  61. Gimzauskiene, Edita, and Lina Kloviene. 2011. Performance Measurement System: Towards an Institutional Theory. Engineering Economics 22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Gligor, David, Ivan Russo, and Michael J. Maloni. 2022. Understanding Gender Differences in Logistics Innovation: A Complexity Theory Perspective. International Journal of Production Economics 246: 108420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. González-Velasco, Carmen, Marcos González-Fernández, and José-Luis Fanjul-Suárez. 2019. Does Innovative Effort Matter for Corporate Performance in Spanish Companies in a Context of Financial Crisis? A Fuzzy-Set QCA Approach. Empirical Economics 56: 1707–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Green, David G., and David Newth. 2001. Grand Challenges in Complexity and Informatics. Complexity International 8: 36. [Google Scholar]
  65. Guo, Kai, Limao Zhang, and Tao Wang. 2021. Concession Period Optimisation in Complex Projects under Uncertainty: A Public–Private Partnership Perspective. Construction Management and Economics 39: 156–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Hanseth, Ole, and Kalle Lyytinen. 2016. Design Theory for Dynamic Complexity in Information Infrastructures: The Case of Build-Ing Internet. In Enacting Research Methods in Information Systems. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 104–42. [Google Scholar]
  67. Hartwell, Christopher A. 2019. Short Waves in Hungary, 1923 and 1946: Persistence, Chaos, and (Lack of) Control. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 163: 532–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Hausner, Jerzy, Michał Możdżeń, and Marek Oramus. 2021. Fragility of Social and Economic Systems and the Role of ‘Modality’. Journal of Economic Issues 55: 1118–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Haynes, P. 2018. Social Synthesis: Finding Dynamic Patterns in Complex Social Systems. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  70. Holland, John H. 1992. Adaptation in Natural and Artificial Systems: An Introductory Analysis with Applications to Biology, Control, and Artificial Intelligence. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
  71. Holt, Richard P. F., J. Barkley Rosser Jr., and David Colander. 2011. The Complexity Era in Economics. Review of Political Economy 23: 357–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Hommes, Cars H. 2006. Chapter 23 Heterogeneous Agent Models in Economics and Finance. In Handbook of Computational Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1109–86. [Google Scholar]
  73. Jemmali, Mahdi. 2022. Intelligent Algorithms and Complex System for a Smart Parking for Vaccine Delivery Center of COVID-19. Complex & Intelligent Systems 8: 597–609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Kauffman, Stuart. A. 1993. The Origins of Order: Self-Organization and Selection in Evolution. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  75. Kijazi, Martin Herbert, and Shashi Kant. 2013. Complexity Theory and Forest Resource Economics. In Post-Faustmann Forest Resource Economics. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 41–70. [Google Scholar]
  76. Kim, Rakhyun E., and Brendan Mackey. 2014. International Environmental Law as a Complex Adaptive System. International Environmental Agreements Politics Law and Economics 14: 5–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Kirman, Alan. 2010. The Economic Crisis Is a Crisis for Economic Theory. CESifo Economic Studies 56: 498–535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Kopp, Thomas, and Jan Salecker. 2020. How Traders Influence Their Neighbours: Modelling Social Evolutionary Processes and Peer Ef-Fects in Agricultural Trade Networks. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 117: 103944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Korhonen, Jouni, and Juha-Pekka Snäkin. 2015. Quantifying the Relationship of Resilience and Eco-Efficiency in Complex Adaptive Energy Systems. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 120: 83–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Korotkikh, Victor, and Galina Korotkikh. 2009. On Irreducible Description of Complex Systems. Complexity 14: 40–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Kukacka, Jiri, and Ladislav Kristoufek. 2020. Do ‘Complex’Financial Models Really Lead to Complex Dynamics? Agent-Based Models and Multifractality. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 113: 103855. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Kukacka, Jiri, and Ladislav Kristoufek. 2021. Does Parameterization Affect the Complexity of Agent-Based Models? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 192: 324–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Lee, Frederic S., and Marc Lavoie, eds. 2012. Defense of Post-Keynesian and Heterodox Economics: Responses to Their Critics. London: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  84. Levanti, Gabriella. 2018. Governing complex strategic networks: Emergence versus enabling effects. In Governing Business Systems. Cham: Springer, pp. 49–65. [Google Scholar]
  85. Lee, Jaesung, and Dae-Won Kim. 2018. Scalable Multilabel Learning Based on Feature and Label Dimensionality Reduction. Complexity 2018: 6292143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Li, Gang, Hongjiao Yang, Linyan Sun, Ping Ji, and Lei Feng. 2010. The Evolutionary Complexity of Complex Adaptive Supply Networks: A Simulation and Case Study. International Journal of Production Economics 124: 310–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Li, Wenrui, Menggang Li, Yiduo Mei, Ting Li, and Fang Wang. 2020. A Big Data Analytics Approach for Dynamic Feedback Warning for Complex Systems. Complexity 2020: 7652496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Liberati, Alessandro, Douglas G. Altman, Jennifer Tetzlaff, Cynthia Mulrow, Peter C. Gøtzsche, John P. A. Ioannidis, Mike Clarke, P. J. Devereaux, Jos Kleijnen, and David Moher. 2009. The PRISMA Statement for Reporting Systematic Reviews and Meta-Analyses of Studies That Evaluate Health Care Interventions: Explanation and Elaboration. Journal of Clinical Epidemiology 62: e1–e34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  89. Liu, Jieling, Franz W. Gatzweiler, and Manasi Kumar. 2021. An Evolutionary Complex Systems Perspective on Urban Health. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 75: 100815. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Lorenz, Edward N. 1963. Deterministic Nonperiodic Flow. Journal of the Atmospheric Sciences 20: 130–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Majeed, Abdul, and Munam Ali Shah. 2015. Energy Efficiency in Big Data Complex Systems: A Comprehensive Survey of Modern Energy Saving Techniques. Complex Adaptive Systems Modeling 3. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Markose, Sheri M. 2005. Computability and Evolutionary Complexity: Markets as Complex Adaptive Systems (CAS). Economic Journal (London, England) 115: F159–F192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Marle, Franck. 2020. An Assistance to Project Risk Management Based on Complex Systems Theory and Agile Project Management. Complexity 2020: 3739129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Maswana, Jean-Claude. 2009. A Contribution to the Empirics of Finance-Growth Nexus in China: A Complex System Perspective. Global Economic Review 38: 29–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Matesanz Gomez, David, Hernan J. Ferrari, Benno Torgler, and Guillermo J. Ortega. 2017. Synchronization and Diversity in Business Cycles: A Network Analysis of the European Union. Applied Economics 49: 972–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Matutinović, Igor. 2001. The Aspects and the Role of Diversity in Socioeconomic Systems: An Evolutionary Perspective. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 39: 239–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. May, Christopher J., Michelle Burgard, and Imran Abbasi. 2011. Teaching Complexity Theory through Student Construction of a Course Wiki: The Self-Organization of a Scale-Free Network. Complexity 16: 41–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Meadows, D. 2008. Thinking in Systems: A Primer. London: Earthscan. [Google Scholar]
  99. Millhiser, William P., and Daniel Solow. 2007. How Large Should a Complex System Be? An Application in Organizational Teams. Complexity 12: 54–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. Milne, Alistair. 2009. Macroprudential Policy: What Can It Achieve? Oxford Review of Economic Policy 25: 608–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Moher, David, Alessandro Liberati, Jennifer Tetzlaff, Douglas G. Altman, and PRISMA Group. 2009. Preferred Reporting Items for Systematic Reviews and Meta-Analyses: The PRISMA Statement. Annals of Internal Medicine 151: 264–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  102. Moher, David, Lesley Stewart, and Paul Shekelle. 2016. Implementing PRISMA-P: Recommendations for Prospective Authors. Systematic Reviews 5: 15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  103. Monasterolo, Irene, Andrea Roventini, and Tim J. Foxon. 2019. Uncertainty of Climate Policies and Implications for Economics and Finance: An Evolutionary Economics Approach. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 163: 177–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Mueller, Bernardo. 2020. Why Public Policies Fail: Policymaking under Complexity. EconomiA 21: 311–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  105. Mylek, Melinda R., and Jacki Schirmer. 2020. Understanding Acceptability of Fuel Management to Reduce Wildfire Risk: Informing Communication through Understanding Complexity of Thinking. Forest Policy and Economics 113: 102120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  106. Naderpajouh, Nader, and Makarand Hastak. 2014. Quantitative Analysis of Policies for Governance of Emergent Dynamics in Complex Construction Projects. Construction Management and Economics 32: 1222–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Oldham, Matthew. 2020. Quantifying the Concerns of Dimon and Buffett with Data and Computation. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 113: 103864. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Oughton, Edward J., Will Usher, Peter Tyler, and Jim W. Hall. 2018. Infrastructure as a Complex Adaptive System. Complexity 2018: 3427826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Oxman, Andrew D., and Gordon H. Guyatt. 1993. The Science of Reviewing Research. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 703: 125–33; discussion 133–4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  110. Patrucco, Pier Paolo. 2011. Changing Network Structure in the Organization of Knowledge: The Innovation Platform in the Evidence of the Automobile System in Turin. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 20: 477–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Phillips, E. 2019. Nassim Taleb heads international banking’s first Grey/Black Swan Committee. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 72: 117–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Plummer, Ryan, and Derek Armitage. 2007. A Resilience-Based Framework for Evaluating Adaptive Co-Management: Linking Ecology, Economics and Society in a Complex World. Ecological Economics: The Journal of the International Society for Ecological Economics 61: 62–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Qiu-Xiang, Li, Zhang Yu-Hao, and Huang Yi-Min. 2018. The Complexity Analysis in Dual-Channel Supply Chain Based on Fairness Concern and Different Business Objectives. Complexity 2018: 4752765. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Raimbault, Juste. 2019. Second-Order Control of Complex Systems with Correlated Synthetic Data. Complex Adaptive Systems Modeling 7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Rammel, Christian, Sigrid Stagl, and Harald Wilfing. 2007. Managing Complex Adaptive Systems-a Co-Evolutionary Perspective on Natural Resource Management. Ecological Economics 63: 9–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  116. Rihoux, Benoît, and Charles C. Ragin. 2009. Configurational Comparative Methods: Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) and Related Techniques. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publication. [Google Scholar]
  117. Rosser, J. Barkley, Jr. 1999. On the Complexities of Complex Economic Dynamics. The Journal of Economic Perspectives: A Journal of the American Economic Association 13: 169–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  118. Rutkauskas, Aleksandras Vytautas, Viktorija Stasytyte, and Edvard Michnevic. 2014. Universally Sustainable Development Strategy for a Small Country: A Systemic Decision. Engineering Economics 25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  119. Ryan, Justin G., John A. Ludwig, and Clive A. Mcalpine. 2007. Complex Adaptive Landscapes (CAL): A Conceptual Framework of Mul-Ti-Functional, Non-Linear Ecohydrological Feedback Systems. Ecological Complexity 4: 113–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Sfa, Fatima Ezahra, Mohamed Nemiche, and Hamza Rayd. 2020. A Generic Macroscopic Cellular Automata Model for Land Use Change: The Case of the Drâa Valley. Ecological Complexity 43: 100851. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  121. Shachak, Moshe, and Bertrand R. Boeken. 2010. Patterns of Biotic Community Organization and Reorganization: A Conceptual Framework and a Case Study. Ecological Complexity 7: 433–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  122. Shen, Yanan. 2021. Modeling and Research on Human Capital Accumulation Complex System of High-Tech Enterprises Based on Big Data. Complexity 2021: 6635228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  123. Shobe, William. 2020. Emerging Issues in Decentralized Resource Governance: Environmental Federalism, Spillovers, and Linked Socio-Ecological Systems. Annual Review of Resource Economics 12: 259–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. Sitthiyot, Thitithep. 2019. On Rank-Size Distribution of Local Government Debt. SSRN Electronic Journal 37: 45–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Sornette, Didier. 2006. Critical Phenomena in Natural Sciences: Chaos, Fractals, Selforganization and Disorder: Concepts and Tools. Berlin: Springer Science and Business Media. [Google Scholar]
  126. Stahel, Andri W. 2006. Complexity, Oikonomía and Political Economy. Ecological Complexity 3: 369–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  127. Stauffer, Maxime, Isaak Mengesha, Konrad Seifert, Igor Krawczuk, Jens Fischer, and Giovanna Di Marzo Serugendo. 2022. A Computational Turn in Policy Process Studies: Coevolving Network Dynamics of Policy Change. Complexity 2022: 8210732. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  128. Stuart, Morgan, Andrew Placona, Gabe Vece, Kelsi Lindblad, Saikou Diallo, and Bob Carrico. 2022. Perspective on Macroscale Complexity in the National Transplant System. Complexity 2022: 3221885. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  129. Sun, Hui, and Xiong Zhong. 2020. Impact of Financial R&D Resource Allocation Efficiency Based on VR Technology and Machine Learning in Complex Systems on Total Factor Productivity. Complexity 2020: 6679846. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  130. Tang, Bo, and Jianzhong Gao. 2014. System Simulation and Reliability Assessment of Chinese Carbon Sequestration Market. Journal of Systems Science and Complexity 27: 760–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  131. Tesfatsion, Leigh. 2006. Chapter 16 Agent-Based Computational Economics: A Constructive Approach to Economic Theory. In Handbook of Computational Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 831–80. [Google Scholar]
  132. Turner, John R., and Rose M. Baker. 2019. Complexity Theory: An Overview with Potential Applications for the Social Sciences. Systems 7: 4. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  133. Vallance, Paul. 2016. Universities, Public Research, and Evolutionary Economic Geography. Economic Geography 92: 355–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  134. Varga, Liz, Marguerite Robinson, and Peter Allen. 2016. Multiutility Service Companies: A Complex Systems Model of Increasing Resource Efficiency. Complexity 21: 23–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  135. Villani, Marco, Laura Sani, Riccardo Pecori, Michele Amoretti, Andrea Roli, Monica Mordonini, Roberto Serra, and Stefano Cagnoni. 2018. An Iterative Infor-Mation-Theoretic Approach to the Detection of Structures in Complex Systems. Complexity 2018: 3687839. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  136. Watson, Richard A., C. L. Buckley, and Rob Mills. 2011. Optimization in ‘Self-Modeling’ Complex Adaptive Systems. Complexity 16: 17–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  137. Wheeler, Thomas J. 2007. Analysis, Modeling, Emergence & Integration in Complex Systems: A Modeling and Integration Framework & System Biology. Complexity 13: 60–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  138. Wiesner, Karoline, and James Ladyman. 2021. Complex Systems Are Always Correlated but Rarely Information Processing. Journal of Physics: Complexity 2: 045015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  139. Wink, Rüdiger, Laura Kirchner, Florian Koch, and Daniel Speda. 2017. Agency and Forms of Path Development along Transformation Processes in German Cities. Cambridge Journal of Regions Economy and Society 10: 471–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  140. Xepapadeas, Anastasios. 2010. Modeling Complex Systems: Modeling Complex Systems. Agricultural Economics (Amsterdam, Netherlands) 41: 181–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  141. Yaneer, Bar-Yam. 2004. Multiscale variety in complex systems. Complexity 9: 37–45. [Google Scholar]
  142. Zhang, Ge, Weijie Wang, and Yikai Liang. 2021a. Understanding the Complex Adoption Behavior of Cloud Services by SMEs Based on Complexity Theory: A Fuzzy Sets Qualitative Comparative Analysis (FsQCA). Complexity 2021: 5591446. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  143. Zhang, Jiayuan, Mehmet G. Yalcin, and Douglas N. Hales. 2021b. Elements of Paradoxes in Supply Chain Management Literature: A Systematic Literature Review. International Journal of Production Economics 232: 107928. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  144. Zhang, Meng, and Jinchuan Cui. 2016. A Quantitative Description of Complex Adaptive System: The Self-Adaptive Mechanism of the Ma-Terial Purchasing Management System towards the Changing Environment. Journal of Systems Science and Complexity 29: 151–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  145. Zheng, Xiaolian, and Ben M. Chen. 2012. Modeling and Forecasting of Stock Markets under a System Adaptation Framework. Journal of Systems Science and Complexity 25: 641–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  146. Zhu, Qiushi, Peng Hao, Timmermans Bas, and van Houtum Geert-Jan. 2017. A Condition-Based Maintenance Model for a Single Compo-Nent in a System with Scheduled and Unscheduled Downs. International Journal of Production Economics 193: 365–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Literature Collection using the PRISMA Protocol.
Figure 1. Literature Collection using the PRISMA Protocol.
Economies 10 00192 g001
Figure 2. Frequency of Publications Over time.
Figure 2. Frequency of Publications Over time.
Economies 10 00192 g002
Table 1. Top 15 Journal Outputs: Frequency of Occurrence.
Table 1. Top 15 Journal Outputs: Frequency of Occurrence.
JournalsTotal
Complexity28
Ecological Economics9
Ecological Complexity7
International Journal of Production Economics7
Construction Management and Economics3
Engineering Economics3
Handbook of Computational Economics3
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control3
Journal of Physics: Complexity3
Journal of Systems Science and Complexity3
Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society2
Complex Adaptive Systems Modeling2
Complexity International2
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization2
Journal of Economic Issues2
Total Number of Journals included47
Table 2. Emergent Complexity Properties.
Table 2. Emergent Complexity Properties.
Complexity ThemesPublicationsTotal
System InteractionsAeeni and Saeedikiya (2019); Ahmad (2019); Albin and Foley (2001); Aouad and Bento (2019); Bianchi and Labory (2019); Brocal et al. (2019); Bruno et al. (2018); Budd et al. (2017); Chakraborti et al. (2021); Chikumbo et al. (2000); Çıdık and Phillips (2021); Coyne et al. (2021); Dong and Fisher (2019); Evans et al. (2017); Forbes and Xie (2018); Garmendia and Stagl (2010); Georgiev et al. (2015); Gimzauskiene and Kloviene (2010, 2011); Guo et al. (2021); Hartwell (2019); Jemmali (2022); Korotkikh and Korotkikh (2009); Kopp and Salecker (2020); Lamghari Elidrissi et al. (2020); Liu et al. (2021); Markose (2005); Marle (2020); Matesanz Gomez et al. (2017); Millhiser and Solow (2007); Mylek and Schirmer (2020); Naderpajouh and Hastak (2014); Oughton et al. (2018); Patrucco (2011); Phillips (2019); Qiu-Xiang et al. (2018); Ryan et al. (2007); Stuart et al. (2022); Tang and Gao (2014); Vallance (2016); Varga et al. (2016); Watson et al. (2011); Watson et al. (2011); Wheeler (2007); Wink et al. (2017); Xepapadeas (2010); Zhang et al. (2021b); Zheng and Chen (2012); Zhu et al. (2017);49
Non-linearityAldhyani et al. (2021); Aymanns et al. (2018); Balint et al. (2017); Batabyal and Beladi (2011); Berg et al. (2002); Brunk and Hunter (2008); Chae (2012); Cioffi-Revilla (2014); Colander et al. (2010); Cooper (2011); Dai (2021); Dosi and Roventini (2017); Elsner (2017); Espejo (2018); Friedrich et al. (2021); Gaffeo and Tamborini (2011); Garmendia and Gamboa (2012); Gligor et al. (2022); González-Velasco et al. (2019); Green and Newth (2001); Hausner et al. (2021); Hommes (2006); Kirman (2010); Kukacka and Kristoufek (2020); Lee and Kim (2018); Li et al. (2020); Majeed and Shah (2015); May et al. (2011); Monasterolo et al. (2019); Mueller (2020); Oldham (2020); Raimbault (2019); Rammel et al. (2007); Rutkauskas et al. (2014); Shen (2021); Sitthiyot (2019); Stahel (2006); Stauffer et al. (2022); Sun and Zhong (2020); Tesfatsion (2006); Villani et al. (2018); Yaneer (2004); Zhang et al. (2021a);43
AdaptationAdamides and Pomonis (2009); Aldunate et al. (2005); Bento and Garotti (2019); Braz and de Mello (2022); Corbacioglu and Kapucu (2006); Garver (2019); Kim and Mackey (2014); Kukacka and Kristoufek (2021); Li et al. (2010); Maswana (2009); Matutinović (2001); Milne (2009); Sfa et al. (2020); Shobe (2020); Wiesner and Ladyman (2021); Zhang and Cui (2016)16
ResilienceDarnhofer (2014); Fraccascia et al. (2018); Korhonen and Snäkin (2015); Plummer and Armitage (2007); Shachak and Boeken (2010);5
Grand Total 113
Table 3. Frequency of Overall Method in the Research Design.
Table 3. Frequency of Overall Method in the Research Design.
Methodological ApproachPublicationsTotal
QuantitativeAdamides and Pomonis (2009); Aldhyani et al. (2021); Aymanns et al. (2018); Chakraborti et al. (2021); Chikumbo et al. (2000); Evans et al. (2017); Forbes and Xie (2018); Friedrich et al. (2021); Gimzauskiene and Kloviene (2010, 2011); González-Velasco et al. (2019); Guo et al. (2021); Hartwell (2019); Hommes (2006); Jemmali (2022); Kopp and Salecker (2020); Korhonen and Snäkin (2015); Korotkikh and Korotkikh (2009); Kukacka and Kristoufek (2021); Kukacka and Kristoufek (2020); Lamghari Elidrissi et al. (2020); Lee and Kim (2018); Li et al. (2010); Maswana (2009); Matesanz Gomez et al. (2017); Millhiser and Solow (2007); Mylek and Schirmer (2020); Naderpajouh and Hastak (2014); Oldham (2020); Phillips (2019); Qiu-Xiang et al. (2018); Rutkauskas et al. (2014); Shachak and Boeken (2010); Shen (2021); Sitthiyot (2019); Stauffer et al. (2022); Tang and Gao (2014); Tesfatsion (2006); Watson et al. (2011); Xepapadeas (2010); Zhang and Cui (2016); Zheng and Chen (2012); Zhu et al. (2017); Villani et al. (2018); Zhang et al. (2021a)45
Case study and/or systems modelAhmad (2019); Albin and Foley (2001); Aldunate et al. (2005); Aouad and Bento (2019); Batabyal and Beladi (2011); Bento and Garotti (2019); Berg et al. (2002); Bianchi and Labory (2019); Braz and de Mello (2022); Brunk and Hunter (2008); Budd et al. (2017); Chae (2012); Cioffi-Revilla (2014); Darnhofer (2014); Dong and Fisher (2019); Dosi and Roventini (2017); Espejo (2018); Garmendia and Stagl (2010); Garver (2019); Kim and Mackey (2014); Liu et al. (2021); Matutinović (2001); Oughton et al. (2018); Patrucco (2011); Plummer and Armitage (2007); Ryan et al. (2007); Sfa et al. (2020); Shobe (2020); Stuart et al. (2022); Vallance (2016); Varga et al. (2016); Watson et al. (2011); Markose (2005); Yaneer (2004); May et al. (2011); Marle (2020); Brocal et al. (2019); Wheeler (2007); Raimbault (2019); Li et al. (2020); Dai (2021); Sun and Zhong (2020)42
QualitativeBruno et al. (2018); Çıdık and Phillips (2021); Coyne et al. (2021); Elsner (2017); Georgiev et al. (2015); Hausner et al. (2021); Kirman (2010); Milne (2009); Mueller (2020); Stahel (2006); Wiesner and Ladyman (2021)11
Literature ReviewAeeni and Saeedikiya (2019); Balint et al. (2017); Colander et al. (2010); Cooper (2011); Gaffeo and Tamborini (2011); Green and Newth (2001); Majeed and Shah (2015); Monasterolo et al. (2019); Rammel et al. (2007)9
Mixed MethodsCorbacioglu and Kapucu (2006); Garmendia and Gamboa (2012); Gligor et al. (2022); Wink et al. (2017)4
Systematic Literature ReviewFraccascia et al. (2018); Zhang et al. (2021b)2
Grand Total 113
Table 4. Summary of the Publication Applications.
Table 4. Summary of the Publication Applications.
Summary Type of ApplicationPublicationsTotal
MacroAymanns et al. (2018); Balint et al. (2017); Bianchi and Labory (2019); Brunk and Hunter (2008); Bruno et al. (2018); Chikumbo et al. (2000); Colander et al. (2010); Cooper (2011); Darnhofer (2014); Dosi and Roventini (2017); Elsner (2017); Espejo (2018); Evans et al. (2017); Forbes and Xie (2018); Friedrich et al. (2021); Gaffeo and Tamborini (2011); Garver (2019); González-Velasco et al. (2019); Green and Newth (2001); Kim and Mackey (2014); Kirman (2010); Kukacka and Kristoufek (2020); Lee and Kim (2018); Maswana (2009); Matesanz Gomez et al. (2017); Matutinović (2001); Milne (2009); Monasterolo et al. (2019); Mueller (2020); Plummer and Armitage (2007); Ryan et al. (2007); Sitthiyot (2019); Stauffer et al. (2022); Tang and Gao (2014); Wiesner and Ladyman (2021); Xepapadeas (2010); Zheng and Chen (2012); Watson et al. (2011); Markose (2005); Yaneer (2004); Villani et al. (2018); Fraccascia et al. (2018); Raimbault (2019); Li et al. (2020); Sun and Zhong (2020)45
MesoAdamides and Pomonis (2009); Aeeni and Saeedikiya (2019); Ahmad (2019); Batabyal and Beladi (2011); Braz and de Mello (2022); Budd et al. (2017); Chae (2012); Chakraborti et al. (2021); Cioffi-Revilla (2014); Corbacioglu and Kapucu (2006); Coyne et al. (2021); Garmendia and Gamboa (2012); Garmendia and Stagl (2010); Georgiev et al. (2015); Gimzauskiene and Kloviene (2010, 2011); Hartwell (2019); Hausner et al. (2021); Hommes (2006); Korhonen and Snäkin (2015); Korotkikh and Korotkikh (2009); Kukacka and Kristoufek (2021); Li et al. (2010); Millhiser and Solow (2007); Oldham (2020); Patrucco (2011); Phillips (2019); Qiu-Xiang et al. (2018); Rammel et al. (2007); Rutkauskas et al. (2014); Shachak and Boeken (2010); Shobe (2020); Stahel (2006); Stuart et al. (2022); Tesfatsion (2006); Wink et al. (2017); Zhang and Cui (2016); Zhang et al. (2021a); Dai (2021)39
MicroAlbin and Foley (2001); Aldunate et al. (2005); Aouad and Bento (2019); Bento and Garotti (2019); Berg et al. (2002); Çıdık and Phillips (2021); Dong and Fisher (2019); Gligor et al. (2022); Guo et al. (2021); Jemmali (2022); Kopp and Salecker (2020); Lamghari Elidrissi et al. (2020); Liu et al. (2021); Majeed and Shah (2015); Mylek and Schirmer (2020); Naderpajouh and Hastak (2014); Oughton et al. (2018); Sfa et al. (2020); Shen (2021); Vallance (2016); Varga et al. (2016); Watson et al. (2011); Zhu et al. (2017); May et al. (2011); Marle (2020); Zhang et al. (2021b); Brocal et al. (2019); Aldhyani et al. (2021); Wheeler (2007)29
Grand Total 113
Table 5. Yearly ratio of citations—Top 15.
Table 5. Yearly ratio of citations—Top 15.
RankAuthor(s)YearCited byRatio
1Hommes200657633.88
2Tesfatsion200644726.29
3Plummer and Armitage200734621.63
4Darnhofer201416117.89
5Rammel, Stagl, and Wilfing200722814.25
6Garmendia and Stagl 201017513.46
7Balint et al.,20177312.17
8Fraccascia, Giannoccaro and Albino2018459.00
9Kirman (2010)20101168.92
10Coyne et al. (2021)2021168.00
11Jemmali (2022)202277.00
12Garmendia and Gamboa (2012)2012726.55
13Brocal et al. (2019)2019266.50
14Zhang et al. (2021b)2021136.50
15Kukacka and Kristoufek 2020196.33
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Haynes, P.; Alemna, D. A Systematic Literature Review of the Impact of Complexity Theory on Applied Economics. Economies 2022, 10, 192. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080192

AMA Style

Haynes P, Alemna D. A Systematic Literature Review of the Impact of Complexity Theory on Applied Economics. Economies. 2022; 10(8):192. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080192

Chicago/Turabian Style

Haynes, Philip, and David Alemna. 2022. "A Systematic Literature Review of the Impact of Complexity Theory on Applied Economics" Economies 10, no. 8: 192. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080192

APA Style

Haynes, P., & Alemna, D. (2022). A Systematic Literature Review of the Impact of Complexity Theory on Applied Economics. Economies, 10(8), 192. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080192

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop