Pass-Through and C Corp Outputs under TCJA
Abstract
:1. Introduction
ODVs for PTs are smaller than CCs and typically come with a slightly higher quality rating.
CC firm valuation increases by much more than PTs under TCJA with one reason being that the relative lower tax rates under TCJA for CCs makes growth more affordable for CCs compared to PTs. This increase makes switching from a PT to a CC profitable under TCJA. If growth increases as projected under TCJA, PTs and CCs will both profit substantially.
While the superiority of PT compared to CCs depends on the leverage gain output being analyzed, CCs generally perform much better in the category of leverage gain outputs indicating greater gains from leverage compared to PTs.
2. Literature Review
2.1. Ownership Forms
2.2. Financing Forms
2.3. Effective Tax Rates
2.3.1. Effective Tax Rate Described
2.3.2. Effective Tax Rates for Main Tests
2.3.3. Effective Tax Rates for Robust Tests
3. Methodology
3.1. Capital Structure Models
3.2. Identifying an Adequate Capital Structure Model
4. Pass-Through Variables, Procedures, Computations, and Applications
4.1. Procedure to Match Credit Spreads, Ratings, and Costs of Borrowing to Debt-to-Firm Value Ratios
4.2. Procedures to Determine Optimal Outputs
4.2.1. Procedure with No Growth
4.2.2. Procedure with Unrestricted Growth
4.2.3. Procedure with Restricted Growth
4.3. Introductory Variables and Computations Used by Capital Structure Model (CSM)
4.4. Pass-Through Applications: Nongrowth and Growth under TCJA
5. Pass-Through Results in Graphical Form
5.1. Gain to Leverage versus Debt-to-Firm Value Ratio
5.2. Pass-Through Firm Value versus Credit Ratings
6. Results for Pass-Throughs and C Corps
6.1. Optimal Outputs for the Three Categories of Debt Choice, Valuation, and Leverage Gain
6.1.1. Debt Choice Outputs
6.1.2. Valuation Outputs
6.1.3. Leverage Gain Outputs
6.2. Outputs With Lower Tax Rates
6.3. Policy Implications
6.4. Future Research
7. Summary
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Computations for Introductory Variables Used by CSM
Alpha Computations for PTs: |
For the below PT computation, the unlevered tax rate on equity is TE1 and the levered tax rate on equity is TE2 where TE1 > TE2. While TD increases with leverage, it is only a levered tax rate as there is no debt when a firm is unlevered. Given the tax rates of TE1 = 0.33, TE2 = 0.283382, and TD = 0.208669 at OCR, we have: α1 = (1 − TE2)/(1 − TD) = (1 − 0.283382)/(1 − 0.208669) = 0.905586 α2 = (1 − TE2)/(1 − TE1) = (1 − 0.283382)/(1 − 0.33) = 1.069579 |
Unlevered Firm Value Computations for PTs: |
Nongrowth (when gL = 0% at OCR of Moody’s A3) where C is the before-tax payout to equity owners and the CSM uses a before-tax plowback ratio (PBR): PBR = 0 for nongrowth; C = (1 − PBR)(CFBT) = (1 − 0)($1,000,000) = $1,000,000 rU = rF + βU(rM − rF) = 3% + 0.79(7.75% − 3%) = 6.7525% EU (or VU) = (1 − TE1)C/rU = (1 − 0.33)$1,000,000/0.067525 = $9,922,251 |
Growth (when gL = 3.12% at OCR of Moody’s A3): PBR = 0.3435; retained earnings (RE) = PBR(CFBT) = 0.3435($1,000,000) = $343,500; C = (1 − PBR)(CFBT) = (1 − 0.3435)($1,000,000) = $656,500 gU = rU(1 − TE1)RE/C = 0.067525(1 − 0.33)$343,500/$656,500 = 2.3671807%; rUg = rU–gU = 6.7525% − 2.3671807% = 4.3853193% EU (or VU) = (1 − PBR)(1 − TE1)CFBT/rUg = (1 − 0.3435)(1 − 0.33)$1,000,000/0.043853193 = $10,030,170 |
Appendix B. Pass-Through Application with under TCJA with Nongrowth
Table to Accompany Appendix B: Pass-through Outputs with Nongrowth. | |||||||||||
P Choice = Proportion of Unlevered Firm Value (EU) Retired by Debt (D) | |||||||||||
Variables | 0.0000 | 0.0641 | 0.1352 | 0.1674 | 0.2067 | 0.2582 | 0.2960 | 0.3069 | 0.3287 | 0.3227 | 0.3563 |
Credit rating | n.a. | Aaa | Aa2 | A1 | A2 | A3 | Baa2 | Ba1 | Ba2 | B1 | B2 |
D = P(EU) | 0.000 | 0.636 | 1.342 | 1.661 | 2.051 | 2.562 | 2.937 | 3.045 | 3.261 | 3.202 | 3.535 |
Cost of debt: rD | 3.00% | 3.63% | 3.78% | 3.98% | 4.08% | 4.22% | 4.56% | 5.00% | 5.40% | 6.51% | 7.21% |
Cost of equity: rL | 6.75% | 7.08% | 7.23% | 7.43% | 7.53% | 7.67% | 8.01% | 8.45% | 8.85% | 9.96% | 10.7% |
Gain to leverage: GL | 0.000 | 0.045 | 0.358 | 0.377 | 0.548 | 0.710 | 0.523 | 0.105 | −1.195 | −1.248 | −1.677 |
Firm value: VL | 9.922 | 9.967 | 10.281 | 10.299 | 10.470 | 10.633 | 10.446 | 10.027 | 9.727 | 8.674 | 8.245 |
Equity value: EL | 9.922 | 9.331 | 8.939 | 8.638 | 8.419 | 8.071 | 7.508 | 6.982 | 6.466 | 5.472 | 4.710 |
%∆EU | 0.00% | 0.45% | 3.61% | 3.80% | 5.52% | 7.16% | 5.27% | 1.06% | −1.97% | −12.6% | −16.9% |
NB | 0.00% | 7.01% | 26.70% | 22.70% | 26.70% | 27.74% | 17.81% | 3.44% | −6.0% | −39.0% | −47.4% |
DV | 0.0000 | 0.0638 | 0.1305 | 0.1613 | 0.1959 | 0.2409 | 0.2812 | 0.3037 | 0.3353 | 0.3691 | 0.4287 |
Below we compute seven optimal outputs that are given in the bold print column where P is 0.2582 and the nongrowth OCR is A3. They are: D, max GL, max VL, EL, max %∆EU, NB, and ODV. For these computations, we use values up to ten decimal places to avoid rounding off errors. For example, 0.2582 is 0.25816244 as seen below for the optimal P choice. | |||||||||||
For the optimal P choice of 0.25816244, D retires 0.25816244 of EU and we use the values of I = $136,498.62, rD = 0.042168, and rL = 0.076668 from Section 4 and the values of TD = 0.20866933, α1 = 0.905585745, α2 = 1.0695787635, rU = 0.067525, and EU (or VU) = $9,922,251.02 from Appendix A to get: D = P(EU) = 0.25816244($9,922,251) = $2,561,553 or D = (1 − TD)I/rD = (1 − 0.2086693)$136,498.62/0.042168 = $2,561,553 Max GL = [1 − α1rD/rL]D – [1 − α2rU/rL]EU = [1 − 0.905585745(0.042168)/0.076668]$2,561,553 – [1 − 1.0695787635(0.067525)/0.076668]$9,922,251 = $1,285,696 – $575,225 = $710,471 Max VL = EU + Max GL = $9,922,251 + $710,471 = $10,632,722; EL = VL – D = $10,632,722.1 – $2,561,552.5 = $8,071,170 Max %∆EU = Max GL/EU = $710,471/$9,922,251 = 0.07160 or 7.16% NB = Max GL/D = $710,471/$2,561,553 = 0.2774 or 27.74%; ODV = D/Max VL = $2,561,553/$10,632,722 = 0.2409 |
Appendix C. Pass-Through Application with under TCJA with Growth of 3.12%
Table to Accompany Appendix C: Pass-through Outputs when Growth is 3.12%. | |||||||||||
heading | P Choice = Proportion of Unlevered Firm Value (EU) Retired by Debt (D) | ||||||||||
Variables | 0.0000 | 0.0634 | 0.1338 | 0.1656 | 0.2045 | 0.2554 | 0.2929 | 0.3061 | 0.3279 | 0.3221 | 0.3557 |
Credit rating | n.a. | Aaa | Aa2 | A1 | A2 | A3 | Baa2 | Ba1 | Ba2 | B1 | B2 |
D = P(EU) | 0.000 | 0.636 | 1.342 | 1.661 | 2.051 | 2.562 | 2.937 | 3.071 | 3.289 | 3.230 | 3.568 |
Levered growth rate: gL | 2.37% | 2.57% | 2.69% | 2.85% | 2.96% | 3.12% | 3.47% | 3.92% | 4.41% | −4.95% | −4.70% |
Growth adjusted rL: rLg | 4.39% | 4.51% | 4.54% | 4.58% | 4.57% | 4.55% | 4.54% | 4.53% | 4.44% | 14.91% | 15.36% |
Gain to leverage: GL | 0.000 | 0.082 | 0.339 | 0.403 | 0.567 | 0.728 | 0.670 | 0.495 | 0.404 | −4.871 | −4.885 |
Firm value: VL | 10.030 | 10.112 | 10.369 | 10.433 | 10.597 | 10.758 | 10.700 | 10.525 | 10.434 | 5.160 | 5.145 |
Equity value: EL | 10.030 | 9.476 | 9.027 | 8.772 | 8.546 | 8.196 | 7.763 | 7.454 | 7.145 | 1.929 | 1.577 |
%∆EU | 0.00% | 0.81% | 3.38% | 4.02% | 5.65% | 7.25% | 6.68% | 4.93% | 4.03% | −48.6% | −48.7% |
NB | 0.00% | 12.84% | 25.23% | 24.25% | 27.63% | 28.40% | 22.81% | 16.11% | 12.29% | −151% | −137% |
DV: D/VL | 0.0000 | 0.0629 | 0.1294 | 0.1592 | 0.1936 | 0.2381 | 0.2745 | 0.2917 | 0.3152 | 0.6261 | 0.6934 |
Below we compute seven optimal outputs that are given in the bold print column where P is 0.2554 and the growth OCR is A3. They are: D, max GL, max VL, EL, max %∆EU, NB, and ODV. For these computations, we use values up to ten decimal places to avoid rounding off errors. For example, 0.2554 is 0.255384746 as seen below for the optimal P choice. | |||||||||||
For the optimal P choice of 0.255384746, D retires 0.255384746 of EU and we use the values of I = $136,498.62, rD = 0.042168, and rL = 0.076668 from Section 4; gL = 0.0312024037 (determined by iterative process using the gL equation for PTs given by Hull 2019); and, the values of TD = 0.20866933, α1 = 0.9055857453, α2 = 1.0695787635, rU = 0.067525, gU = 0.0236718067, and EU (or VU) = $10,030,170 from Appendix A to get: D = P(EU) = 0.255384746($10,030,170.38) = $2,561,553 or D = (1 − TD)I/rD = (1 − 0.20866933)$136,498.623/0.042168 = $2,561,553. Using (2) with rUg = rU – gU = 0.067525 – 0.02367180674 = 0.04385319326; rLg = rL – gL = 0.076668 – 0.0312024037 = 0.0454655963, and above values for rD, D, EU, and rUg, we have: Max GL = [1 − α1rD/rLg]D – [1 − α2rUg/rLg]EU = [1 − 0.9055857453(0.042168)/0.0454655963]$2,561,553 – [1 − 1.0695787635(0.04385319326)/0.0454655963]$10,030,170 = $410,094.2 – -$317,424.4 = $727,519 Max VL = EU + Max GL = $10,030,170 + $727,519 = $10,757,689; EL = VL – D = $10,757,689 – $2,561,553 = $8,196,136 Max %∆EU = Max GL/EU = $727,519/$10,030,170 = 0.07253 or about 7.25% NB = GL/D = $727,519/$2,561,553 = 0.28401 or about 28.40%; ODV = D/Max VL = $2,561,553/$10,757,689 = 0.2381 |
References
- Asquith, Paul, and David Mullins Jr. 1986. Equity issues and offering dilution. Journal of Financial Economics 15: 61–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baxter, Nevins. 1967. Leverage risk of ruin and the cost of capital. Journal of Finance 22: 395–403. [Google Scholar]
- Berk, Jonathan, Richard Stanton, and Josef Zechner. 2010. Human capital, bankruptcy and capital structure. Journal of Finance 65: 891–926. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bowman, Woods. 2015. The Price of NPO Debt. NPO Quarterly. Available online: https://NPOquarterly.org/2015/08/06/the-price-of-NPO-debt/ (accessed on 31 December 2019).
- D’Melloa, Ranjan, and Mercedes Miranda. 2010. Long-term debt and overinvestment agency problem. Journal of Banking and Finance 34: 324–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Damodaran, Aswath. 2014. External and Internal Financing at US Firms, Page 30. Available online: http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/pdfiles/cfovhds/cfpacket2.pdf (accessed on 29 November 2019).
- Damodaran, Aswath. 2019. Damodaran Online: Home Page for Aswath Damodaran. Available online: http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/New_Home_Page/dataarchived.html (accessed on 25 November 2019).
- Damodaran, Aswath. 2020. Damodaran Online: Home Page for Aswath Damodaran. Available online: http://pages.stern.nyu.edu/~adamodar/New_Home_Page/datacurrent.html (accessed on 15 January 2020).
- Dantzler, William. 2017. The Distinction between Partnership Debt and Partnership Equity. Tax Notes. Available online: https://www.whitecase.com/publications/article/distinction-between-partnership-debt-and-partnership-equity (accessed on 9 September 2019).
- DeAngelo, Harry, and Ronald Masulis. 1980. Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxes. Journal of Financial Economics 8: 3–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Donaldson, Gordon. 1961. Corporate Debt Capacity: A Study of Corporate Debt Policy and the Determination of Corporate Debt Capacity. Boston: Harvard Business School, pp. 1–294. [Google Scholar]
- Farrar, Donald, and Lee Selwyn. 1967. Taxes, corporate financial policy, and returns to investors. National Tax Journal 20: 444–54. [Google Scholar]
- Federal Reserve Economic Data. 2019. Moody’s Seasoned Baa Corporate Bond Yield. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Available online: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/BAA (accessed on 15 January 2019).
- Florida, Richard, and Donald Smith. 1993. Keep the government out of venture capital. Issues in Science and Technology 9: 61–68. [Google Scholar]
- Gay, Gerald, and Jouahn Nam. 1998. The underinvestment problem and corporate derivatives use. Financial Management 27: 53–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Graham, John. 2000. How big are the tax benefits of debt? Journal of Finance 55: 1901–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John, and Campbell Harvey. 2001. The theory and practice of corporate finance: Evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics 60: 187–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John, and Mark Leary. 2011. A review of empirical capital structure research and directions for the future. Annual Review of Financial Economics 3: 309–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grant Thorton International Ltd. 2019. Should Pass-through Owners Switch to C Corp Status? Available online: https://www.grantthornton.com/library/articles/tax/2018/switch-C-corp-status.aspx (accessed on 11 March 2020).
- Henrekson, Magnus, and Tino Sanandaji. 2011. Entrepreneurship and the theory of taxation. Small Business Economics 37: 167–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hodge, Scott. 2014. The US Has More Individually Owned Businesses than Corporations. Available online: https://taxfoundation.org/us-has-more-individually-owned-businesses-corporations (accessed on 21 January 2020).
- Houston, Dana. 2019. You’ve Decided to Switch to a C Corporation: Here’s What’s Next. Available online: https://www.claconnect.com/resources/articles/2019/youve-decided-to-switch-to-a-c-corporation-heres-whats-next (accessed on 12 May 2010).
- Hull, Robert. 2010. A capital structure model with growth. Investment Management and Financial Innovation 7: 26–40. [Google Scholar]
- Hull, Robert. 2012. A capital structure model with wealth transfers. Investment Management and Financial Innovation 9: 19–32. [Google Scholar]
- Hull, Robert. 2014. A Capital Structure Model (CSM) with tax rate changes. Investment Management and Financial Innovations 11: 8–21. [Google Scholar]
- Hull, Robert. 2018. Capital Structure Model (CSM): Correction, constraints, and applications. Investment Management and Financial Innovation 15: 245–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hull, Robert. 2019. Business wealth and tax policy. Theoretical Economics Letters 19: 1020–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hull, Robert. 2020. Credit ratings and firm value. Investment Management and Financial Innovation 17: 157–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hull, Robert, and David Price. 2015. Pass-through valuation. The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance 17: 82–116. [Google Scholar]
- Hull, Robert, Sungkyu Kwak, and Walker Rosemary. 2018. Hedge fund variables and short-run SEO returns. International Journal of Managerial Finance 14: 322–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jensen, Michael. 1986. Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. American Economic Review 76: 323–29. [Google Scholar]
- Jensen, Michael, and William Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kisgen, Darren. 2006. Credit ratings and capital structure. Journal of Finance 61: 1035–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kisgen, Darren. 2009. Do firms target credit ratings or leverage levels? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 44: 1323–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Korteweg, Arthur. 2010. The net benefits of leverage. Journal of Finance 65: 2137–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kraus, Alan, and Robert Litzenberger. 1973. A State-preference model of optimal financial leverage. Journal of Finance 28: 911–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Leland, Hayne. 1998. Agency costs, risk management, and capital structure. Journal of Finance 53: 1213–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Masulis, Ronald. 1983. The impact of capital structure change on firm value: Some estimates. Journal of Finance 38: 107–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miller, Merton. 1977. Debt and taxes. Journal of Finance 32: 261–75. [Google Scholar]
- Modigliani, Franco, and Merton Miller. 1963. Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction. American Economic Review 53: 433–43. [Google Scholar]
- Mohaghegh, Mohsen. 2019. Evolution of Wealth Inequality In the US: Entrepreneurship and Financial Intermediation, Working Paper, Columbus, Ohio, Department of Economics, Ohio State University. Available online: https://drive.google.com/file/d/1lnkax3Vz6Ln4awmQsJNTMotmFxgiP_kk/view (accessed on 26 February 2020).
- Morningstar. 2019. Credit Ratings. Available online: https://ratingagency.morningstar.com/mcr/ratings-surveillance/corporate-financial%20institutions (accessed on 21 July 2019).
- Myers, Stewart. 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5: 147–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Myers, Stewart, and Nicholas Majluf. 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13: 187–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- National Federation of Independent Business. 2013. Entity Choice and Effective Tax Rates. Available online: http://www.s-corp.org/wp-content/uploads/2013/08/Quantria_Study_ETR_8-6-13_Final_pm.pdf (accessed on 7 October 2019).
- Penn Wharton Budget Model. 2017. The Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, as Reported by Conference Committee, December 15. Available online: https://budgetmodel.wharton.upenn.edu/issues/2017/12/15/effective-tax-rates-by-industry (accessed on 26 October 2019).
- Robert, Celene. 2019. Should You Convert Your Company to a C Corp? Available online: https://www.indinero.com/blog/converting-your-company-to-a-c-corp (accessed on 28 April 2020).
- SBA. Office of Advocacy. 2009. Effective Federal Income Tax Rates Faced By Small Businesses in the United States. Small Business Administration. April. Available online: https://www.sba.gov/sites/default/files/advocacy/rs343tot.pdf (accessed on 28 October 2019).
- Tax Foundation. 2014. The U.S. Corporate Effective Tax Rate: Myth and the Fact. Available online: https://files.taxfoundation.org/legacy/docs/SR214.pdf (accessed on 28 October 2018).
- Tax Foundation. 2019. Pass-Through Businesses Q&A. Available online: https://taxfoundation.org/pass-through-businesses/ (accessed on 9 January 2020).
- Tax Policy Center. 2016. Table T16-0181: Distribution of Tax Units with Business Income by Expanded Cash Income Percentile, 2016. August 23. Available online: https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/model-estimates/distribution-business-income-august-2016/t16-0182-distribution-business-income (accessed on 18 January 2020).
- Tax Policy Center. 2018. How Might the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act Affect Economic Output? Available online: https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/briefing-book/how-might-tax-cuts-and-jobs-act-affect-economic-output (accessed on 18 October 2018).
- US Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2020. US Real GDP Growth Rate by Year. Available online: http://www.multpl.com/us-real-gdp-growth-rate/table/by-year (accessed on 11 January 2020).
- Van Binsbergen, Jules, John Graham, and Jie Yang. 2010. Cost of debt. Journal of Finance 65: 2089–136. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | By before-tax, we mean after all expenses (including replacement costs) have been paid except for federal tax expenses. Thus, expenses include all applicable non-federal taxes (such as state taxes, payroll taxes, property taxes, sales taxes, and so forth). Since we begin with an unlevered firm, interest on debt is not yet an expense. |
2 | According to our records, Damodaran’s ICRs were the same for 2018 and 2019. Thus, whereas spreads changed for these two years, the ratings and ICRs that are matched to the spreads did not change. We do not know to what extent, if any, ICRs were provided prior to 2018 because Damodaran’s archive files do not always contain the same details that were provided during the year when the data was first reported. Regardless, our best guest is that ICRs for 2017 existed and are similar to 2018 and 2019. Prior to 2017, we have no record that Damodaran reported ICRs. |
P Choice | ICR | Interest (I) | DV | Spread | Ratings | rD | rL |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0.0641 | 24.000 | $28,329 | 0.0638 | 0.630% | Aaa | 3.63% | 7.08% |
0.1352 | 11.000 | $62,682 | 0.1305 | 0.780% | Aa2 | 3.78% | 7.23% |
0.1674 | 8.500 | $82,214 | 0.1613 | 0.975% | A1 | 3.98% | 7.43% |
0.2067 | 6.750 | $104,867 | 0.1959 | 1.076% | A2 | 4.08% | 7.53% |
0.2582 | 5.250 | $136,499 | 0.2409 | 1.217% | A3 | 4.22% | 7.67% |
0.2960 | 4.250 | $170,616 | 0.2812 | 1.560% | Baa2 | 4.56% | 8.01% |
0.3069 | 3.750 | $195,564 | 0.3037 | 2.000% | Ba1 | 5.00% | 8.45% |
0.3287 | 3.250 | $228,112 | 0.3353 | 2.400% | Ba2 | 5.40% | 8.85% |
0.3227 | 2.750 | $272,409 | 0.3691 | 3.510% | B1 | 6.51% | 9.96% |
0.3563 | 2.250 | $336,289 | 0.4287 | 4.212% | B2 | 7.21% | 10.66% |
0.4054 | 1.750 | $436,543 | 0.5201 | 5.148% | B3 | 8.15% | 11.60% |
0.3751 | 1.375 | $560,751 | 0.6168 | 8.200% | Caa | 11.20% | 14.65% |
0.4833 | 1.025 | $758,928 | 0.7942 | 8.642% | Ca2 | 11.64% | 15.09% |
0.6173 | 0.650 | $1,207,022 | 1.1752 | 11.341% | C2 | 14.34% | 17.79% |
0.8333 | 0.380 | $2,081,650 | 1.9225 | 15.116% | D2 | 18.12% | 21.57% |
P Choice | ODV | EU | Max VL | Max GL | Max %ΔEU | NB | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A. Pass-Throughs (PTs) | |||||||
Nongrowth: Pre-TCJA | 0.2559 | 0.2375 | $9.626 | $10.371 | $0.745 | 7.74% | 30.24% |
Growth (gL = 3.12%): Pre-TCJA | 0.2556 | 0.2371 | $9.638 | $10.390 | $0.752 | 7.80% | 30.51% |
Nongrowth: TCJA | 0.2582 | 0.2409 | $9.922 | $10.633 | $0.710 | 7.16% | 27.74% |
Growth (gL = 3.12%): TCJA | 0.2554 | 0.2381 | $10.030 | $10.758 | $0.728 | 7.25% | 28.40% |
Growth (gL = 3.90%): TCJA | 0.2407 | 0.2226 | $10.644 | $11.506 | $0.863 | 8.11% | 33.68% |
Growth (gL = 4.50%): TCJA | 0.2718 | 0.2499 | $10.807 | $11.756 | $0.948 | 8.77% | 32.28% |
Overall Average for PTs | 0.2563 | 0.2377 | $10.111 | $10.902 | $0.791 | 7.81% | 30.48% |
Panel B: C Corps (CCs) | |||||||
Nongrowth: Pre-TCJA | 0.5434 | 0.4354 | $8.038 | $10.032 | $1.994 | 24.81% | 45.65% |
Growth (gL = 3.12%): Pre-TCJA | 0.5501 | 0.4609 | $7.940 | $9.476 | $1.536 | 19.35% | 35.17% |
Nongrowth: TCJA | 0.5288 | 0.4537 | $9.769 | $11.385 | $1.616 | 16.54% | 31.28% |
Growth (gL = 3.12%): TCJA | 0.5124 | 0.4526 | $10.080 | $11.413 | $1.333 | 13.22% | 25.81% |
Growth (gL = 3.90%): TCJA | 0.4941 | 0.4337 | $10.454 | $11.910 | $1.455 | 13.92% | 28.18% |
Growth (gL = 4.50%): TCJA | 0.4766 | 0.4132 | $10.839 | $12.502 | $1.663 | 15.35% | 32.20% |
Overall Average for CCs | 0.5176 | 0.4416 | $9.520 | $11.120 | $1.600 | 17.20% | 33.05% |
© 2020 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Hull, R. Pass-Through and C Corp Outputs under TCJA. Int. J. Financial Stud. 2020, 8, 46. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8030046
Hull R. Pass-Through and C Corp Outputs under TCJA. International Journal of Financial Studies. 2020; 8(3):46. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8030046
Chicago/Turabian StyleHull, Robert. 2020. "Pass-Through and C Corp Outputs under TCJA" International Journal of Financial Studies 8, no. 3: 46. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8030046
APA StyleHull, R. (2020). Pass-Through and C Corp Outputs under TCJA. International Journal of Financial Studies, 8(3), 46. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8030046