1. Introduction
This paper studies the interaction between financial frictions and uncertainty shocks, which are arguably two of the most important drivers of business cycle fluctuations (see, for instance,
Bloom 2009;
Jermann and Quadrini 2012). In particular, we explore the role of the credit channel of uncertainty shocks in driving macroeconomic conditions in the US economy. Through this channel, the rise in uncertainty about future productivity aggravates credit market conditions by increasing the information asymmetry between lenders and borrowers, thereby raising the cost of borrowing. The resultant decrease in the supply of credit leads to a fall in investment (see for example
Aghion et al. 2010;
Gilchrist et al. 2017;
Bordo et al. 2016)
1. In the quantitative literature, uncertainty shocks are shown, in general, to exhibit properties of a negative demand shock (see for example
Leduc and Liu 2016). Intuitively, the rise in uncertainty leads to an increase in precautionary behavior which puts a downward pressure on demand. To this extent, uncertainty shocks propagate in the economy through a countercyclical markup channel if prices are sufficiently sticky (see
Born and Pfeifer 2014;
Basu and Bundick 2017). The existence of the credit channel gives rise to supply side effects which would likely exacerbate the impact of the shock on the economy, or yet still alter the cyclical properties of the relevant variables.
In our set up, we model borrowing constraints as a nested function that features both corporate earnings and capital as alternative instruments for assessing credit worthiness in the corporate sector. This particular design allows us to analyze the macroeconomic effects of uncertainty shocks under alternative credit market settings: in one setting, borrowing is backed by the value of capital; in another setting, borrowing is tied exclusively to corporate earnings. Results under these two scenarios are compared to that of a baseline economy that does not feature any borrowing constraints. We also extend the analysis to look at a hybrid scenario where borrowing is tied to both corporate earnings and the value of capital stock. The inclusion of corporate earnings as an instrument in the constraint (in addition to capital) is motivated by recent trends in corporate finance which suggest a strong relationship between corporate earnings and firms’ access to credit. For example,
Lian and Ma (
2020), using micro-level data, find that about 80 percent of corporate loans are backed by cash flows, whereas the remaining 20 percent are backed by assets (capital).
In another study that examines 50,000 loan deals by 15,000 firms,
Drechsel (
2020) finds that about 35 percent of these deals are backed by cash flows as opposed to only 30 percent that are backed by corporate assets. Notwithstanding these findings, a majority of macroeconomic models that feature credit frictions tie borrowing to the value of corporate assets (see for example
Kiyotaki and Moore 1997;
Bernanke et al. 1999;
Mendoza 2010). This marks a shift from earlier studies that primarily anchored borrowing to corporate cash flows (see
Stiglitz and Weiss 1981;
Holmstrom and Tirole 1997). Macroeconomic variables such as output, investment and employment are known to fluctuate significantly with credit market conditions. It would be interesting to see how differences in the assessment criteria for credit worthiness affects the behavior of the economy. Before we proceed, we note that, the phrases”capital-based” and ”asset-based” carry similar meaning in this paper. They are therefore used interchangeably henceforth.
In a preliminary analysis, we examine the effects of uncertainty shocks on the US economy using a Vector Auto-Regressive (VAR) model. In the model, we identify uncertainty shock using a Cholesky decomposition with the uncertainty proxy ordered first, as in
Basu and Bundick (
2017) and
Leduc and Liu (
2016). Using US data, we find that, while uncertainty shocks may display properties of a demand side shock (by generating lower prices concurrently with lower output), the price markup exhibits procyclical characteristics, as it declines (along side output) in response to the rise in uncertainty. This constitutes a disparity between the data and findings in the quantitative literature. The countercyclical markups obtained in quantitative models are contingent on the degree of price rigidity. In an environment where it is costly to adjust prices, firms respond to the decline in demand by moving downward along their marginal cost curves. This leads to an increase in the price markup concurrently with the lower output. In addition, given that prices are not fully rigid, the price level falls, however sluggishly, in response to the downward pressure on demand. Therefore, one possible explanation for procyclical markup in the data is that, in the US economy, prices are not rigid enough to generate countercyclical markups. Alternatively, it is likely that the presence of supply side effects keep the marginal cost sufficiently high to avoid a decline in the price markup. We explore variations in the formulation of the borrowing constraint in the DSGE model, expecting that the inherent supply side effects (through the credit channel) would help explain the disparity between the theory and the data.
In the VAR model, we also show that the credit spread rises in response to uncertainty shock, which is an indication of tightening in the credit market. Moreover, there is a decline in corporate earnings and the value of the capital stock which further aggravates the credit market by limiting the amount of collateral that is available to firms in the non-financial corporate sector to back-up borrowing. This leads to a fall in the flow of credit to the non-financial corporate sector. Consequently, investment, hours of work and output decline. In addition, the results show a very strong relationship between the collateral instruments (capital and earnings) on the one hand, and the flow of credit on the other hand. These findings imply that (on the account of the decline in both corporate earnings and the value of capital), both the earnings-based borrowing constraint and the asset-based borrowing constraint tighten while there is an elevation in uncertainty. This phenomenon highlights the significance of the credit channel for the propagation of uncertainty in the economy.
In the DSGE framework, we introduce uncertainty shocks as a second-moment perturbation which amplifies volatility in the total factor productivity (TFP). We then conduct a series of quantitative experiments to examine the macroeconomic effects of the shock under alternative formulations of the borrowing constraint. The results show that the formulation of the borrowing constraint is critical in determining how the uncertainty shock is characterized. In particular, we have the following findings: First, an increase in uncertainty about future productivity leads to tightening in both the earnings-based and the asset-based constraints, which is consistent with the results in the VAR model. Moreover, the constraint becomes tighter and remains so for a longer period of time if borrowing is constrained by asset as opposed to if it is constrained by earnings.
Secondly, the response of the price level to uncertainty shocks is also dependent on the formulation of the borrowing constraint. This is particularly important, as it indicates whether the shock can be characterized as a demand side shock or a supply side shock. While the price level falls in the model with capital-based constraint, it rises in the model with earnings-based constraint. To this end, the uncertainty shock displays properties of a demand side shock in the presence of the asset-based constraints. The opposite is true in the case of the model with earnings-based constraint. Third, following the rise in uncertainty, the price markup is countercyclical in the presence of the asset-based borrowing constraints. However, it becomes procyclical in the model with earnings-based borrowing constraint.
The last two findings show that the DSGE model with capital-based constraint matches the VAR model in terms of the behavior of output and the price level following uncertainty shocks: The shock exhibit properties of a demand side shock in both models. However, the DSGE model falls short in matching the cyclical properties of the price markup, as it generates countercyclical markups in contrast to that of the VAR model. On the other hand, the model with earnings-based constraint matches the VAR model in terms of the cyclical properties of the price markup, but falls short in terms of how the uncertainty shock is characterized: the shock is akin to a demand side shock in the VAR model, and a supply side shock in the DSGE model. Thus, including only earnings or capital as the only (collateral) instrument in the DSGE model, thus far, helps us explains part of the business cycle properties of the US economy, which leaves much to be desired.
In a special case with a hybrid formulation of the borrowing constraint where both capital and earnings are concurrently used as instruments for assessing credit worthiness, the results improve upon that of the other models where borrowing is constrained by only one of the instruments (assets or earnings), by matching the results in the VAR model. Specifically, both output and inflation decline in response to uncertainty shocks, which is an indication that the demand side effects dominate that of the supply side. At the same time, the price markup falls (concurrently with output) in response to the shock. To this end, the price markup is procyclical, with the correlation coefficient between the simulated output and the markup estimated to be about 0.50. This is also in line with the results in the VAR analysis (where the correlation is estimated to be about 0.12).
The above findings indicate that alternative formulations of credit constraints matter for the propagation of second-moment shocks in the DSGE model. The paper contributes to the plethora of literature on the effects of uncertainty shocks in a number of ways: First, it provides a unique formulation of credit constraints that is more in line with the current credit market. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper that explores alternative formulations of collateral constraints in a single study on uncertainty shocks. Secondly, the hybrid formulation of credit constraints in the DSGE model reverses the cyclical properties of the price mark-up (from countercyclical to procyclical) which puts it in alignment with the data, and constitutes an improvement on the existing models on uncertainty which largely yield countercyclical price mark-ups. This provides more insights into the understanding of uncertainty shocks and macroeconomic fluctuations.
1.1. A Brief Review of Borrowing Constraints and Access to Credit
There have been several micro-level studies on debt contracts (covenants) including those that look at alternative criteria for assessing credit worthiness (see for example
Smith and Warner 1979;
Malitz 1986;
Begley 1994;
Frank and Goyal 2009;
De Fiore and Uhlig 2011;
Bradley and Roberts 2015)
2. Regardless of the differences in methods and objectives, the literature agrees on a variety of instruments by which credit worthiness is assessed. These include; Maximum Debt-to-Earnings before taxes (EBITDA), Maximum Interest Coverage (EBITDA/Interest), Maximum Fixed Charge Coverage (EBITDA/Coverage), Maximum Leverage Ratio, Maximum Capex, and Maximum Net Worth. Of the six instruments, three are related to earnings, with EBITDA being the primary indicator of this variable. Others such as the Maximum Leverage Ration is related to the firm’s assets. These covenants are legal requirements that a borrower (the firm) is obliged to satisfy throughout the lifetime of the loan. In
Table 1, we present a few of the recently documented loan covenants that highlight the relative weight of each instrument in the loan contract.
Table 1 shows that corporate earnings constitutes the most significant part of the criteria for assessing credit worthiness. Notwithstanding, assets still remain an essential part of the criteria. These findings highlight the importance of incorporating both earnings and assets as instruments when studying the role of borrowing constraints in business cycle fluctuations in the economy. This paper moves in that direction.
1.2. Uncertainty Shocks in the Literature
Interests in the study of credit frictions and uncertainty have been evolving since
Bernanke (
1983) and
Kiyotaki and Moore (
1997). After a revived interest in the study of the macroeconomic effects of uncertainty shocks by
Bloom (
2009), several other works have explored different mechanisms through which uncertainty shock propagate in the economy (see for example
Born and Pfeifer 2014;
Carriero et al. 2015;
Leduc and Liu 2016;
Mumtaz and Surico 2018). Some of the mechanisms for the transmission of uncertainty shocks include the Oi–Hartman–Abel affects, real options effects, precautionary savings, and countercyclical markup channels.
The so-called Oi–Hartman–Abel effect (due to
Oi 1961;
Hartman 1972;
Abel 1983) assumes that if profits are convex in demand or costs, then shocks to uncertainty about demand or cost increases expected benefits. Therefore, through the Oi–Hartman–Abel channel, uncertainty shocks are expansionary in nature. However,
Born and Pfeifer (
2014) and
Basu and Bundick (
2017) find that the presence of sticky prices opens the possibility for ’inverse-Oi–Hartman–Abel-effect’. In the sticky-price model, firms choose higher markups following an increase in uncertainty, thereby decreasing output. To this end, uncertainty shocks are contractionary through the countercyclical markup channel, even when profits are convex in demand or costs.
The real options channel of uncertainty is originally due to
Bernanke (
1983), The idea behind this mechanism is that firms are likely to wait for sometime in making decisions about new investments and hiring until there is a resolution of uncertainty shocks. In the case of the precautionary savings channel, uncertainty shocks increase consumers’ desire to save more, thereby decreasing consumers’ total expenditure (see
Bansal and Yaron 2004). While a rise in precautionary savings might increase output in the long-run, the short-run effects are contractionary. Moreover, in the case of a highly open small economy, some of the savings will flow to foreign economies, which dampens both domestic demand and future growth (
Fernandez-Villaverde et al. 2011).
In the formulation of credit frictions, most of the macroeconomic models in the literature rely on assets-based borrowing constraints. However, micro-level data show that creditors primarily use earnings (in one form or another) in the assessment of credit worthiness of firms (see
Table 1). That is, earnings-based instruments are at least as important (if not more important) as asset-based instruments in the design of loan covenants. The choice of an instrument may play a significant role in determining the interaction between uncertainty shocks and credit constraints. In the DSGE model, we account for both earnings and assets as alternative instruments in the formulation of the borrowing constraint. Our analysis show that different specifications of the borrowing constraint lead to different conclusions regarding the transmission of uncertainty shocks, especially as it relates to the price markup channel.
The rest of the paper proceeds as follows.
Section 2 presents the empirical analysis via a VAR model.
Section 3 Presents the theoretical framework which builds on the standard New Keynesian model.
Section 4 presents the numerical results where we discusses the implications of uncertainty shocks under alternative borrowing constraints. Finally,
Section 5 concludes the paper.
2. Empirical Analysis
In this section, we present empirical analysis of the macroeconomic effects of uncertainty shocks using a Vector Auto Regressive (VAR) model. Specifically, we look at the response of macroeconomic variables such as output, consumption, and hours of work to uncertainty shocks in the US economy. We also evaluate the so-called credit channel of uncertainty by looking at the impact of these shocks on credit flow, the credit spread, corporate earnings and the value of capital stock. Moreover, cyclical properties of the price markup has been shown to be central to the propagation of uncertainty shocks in the economy. We therefore analyze the behavior of this variable in the light of these findings.
2.1. Empirical Specification: The VAR Model
In buiding the empirical framework, we employ a VAR model similar to the one discussed in
Lutkepohl (
2005). First, we present the model in the general form with
n lags as:
where
is the
vector of endogenous variables, A is an
matrix of coefficients,
is an
matrix of coefficients, and
is the
vector of exogenous variables. In addition,
is the
vector of white noise innovations, whereas
is the
matrix given by
Alternatively, the model can be written as:
where
, B = (A,
), Z =
, and U= (
,....
). W is
, B is
, Z is
, and U is L × T.
2.2. Variables in the System and Identification Strategy
There are eleven variables in the VAR model. In setting up the variables in the VAR model, We follow
Drechsel (
2020). The data for the analysis spans from the first quarter of 1986 to the last quarter of 2019. The ordering of the selected variables in the model is as follows:
For a measure of uncertainty in the economy, we use the S&P 100 Volatility Index (VXO) as a proxy.
Figure 1 shows the time-series of the VXO from the first quarter of 1986 to the first quarter of 2020. The cyclical property of the VXO makes it a very good fit for measuring uncertainty in the economy. As shown in the figure, the VXO is highly countercyclical. The data shows that the VXO rises significantly during economic downturns, with noticeable spikes during the crises of the 1990s, 2008/09, and the most recent and ongoing global health crisis precipitated by COVID-19. In addition to these features, data on the VXO are prevalent and is readily available in contrast to other competing indices.
Besides the VXO, we collect data on the relative price of investment, the price level, hours of work in the non-financial corporate sector, capital stock in non-financial corporate sector, corporate earnings, credit flow, GDP, the federal funds rate and the price markup. Except for the federal funds rate, all other variables in the model are in log levels. In addition, we identify uncertainty shock using a Cholesky identification scheme with the VXO ordered first. In the ordering of the variables we assume that an increase in uncertainty has an immediate impact on macroeconomic variables, while shocks unrelated to uncertainty do not affect volatility in the stock market. Our identification strategy is similar to the one followed by
Leduc and Sill (
2007),
Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (
2012),
Leduc and Sill (
2013),
Leduc and Liu (
2016), and
Basu and Bundick (
2017).
Sources of the data include the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and the Bank of International Settlements (BIS). We deflate nominal variables with the consumption deflator. For data on corporate credit, we use credit to private non-financial sectors at market value. This is sourced from the Bank of International Settlements (BIS). In addition, given that the data are quarterly in nature, We select four lags of the model variables for the VAR estimation. Details on data construction and sources can be found in
Appendix A.
2.3. The VAR Model Results
Figure 2 presents results of the VAR model. For each variable in the figure, the solid black line represents an average estimate of the impulse response whereas the shaded regions represent the range of the 68 percent confidence band interval (1% standard deviation shock). A one-standard deviation increase in uncertainty raises the VXO by 17.16% from the sample mean of 2.9346. The impact of the shock on the VXO indicates that the standard deviation of the uncertainty shock is about 5.8%. The figure also shows that the uncertainty shock leads to a decline in the hours of work. The decrease in hours of work remains significant for about six quarters, with the peak effect occurring after three quarters from the time of impact. The heightened uncertainty also leads to a persistent decline in the price level for consumer goods, which remains significant for about fifteen quarters from the time of innovation, with the peak occurring after five quarters.
In addition, the rise in uncertainty about the future increases the risk of default by firms in the non-financial corporate sector, which leads to a significant rise in the credit spread—an indication of tightening in the credit market. In addition, the shock gives rise to an increase in precautionary savings which leads to a fall in demand. The decline in demand puts a downward pressure on earnings and the stock of capital. Notably, earnings declines on impact but makes a quick and short-lived recovery after about three quarters. However, unlike earnings, the fall in the capital stock is gradual and lasts for about eight quarters, with a peak around the fourth quarter. In
Table 1, we showed that both earnings and the capital stock constitute instruments by which firms in the non-financial corporate sector are assessed for credit worthiness. To this end, the decline in both earnings and the value of capital further constrains firms in the non-financial corporate sector by limiting the amount of collateral that is available to back-up borrowing. This leads to a decline in the flow of credit to firms in the non-financial corporate sector. As shown in the figure, the decline in credit flow is persistent and remains significant for about eight quarters, with the peak occurring around six quarters after the time of impact.
To demonstrate the strength of the association between these two instruments and the flow of credit to firms in the non-financial corporate sector, we look at the correlation between these variables in the simulated VAR model. We find the correlation coefficient between credit flow and the stock of capital to be about 0.90, whereas that of the credit flow and corporate earnings is about 0.96. These findings imply that (on the account of the decline in both corporate earnings and the value of capital), both the earnings-based constraints and the asset-based constraints tighten while there is a rise in uncertainty about the future. This phenomenon makes the effects of uncertainty on the credit market self-fulfilling, and highlights the significance of the credit channel for the propagation of uncertainty in the economy.
Furthermore, in the literature, uncertainty shocks are shown to exhibit properties of a negative demand shock (see for example
Leduc and Liu 2016). It is therefore argued that uncertainty shocks propagate in the economy through a countercyclical markup channel if prices are sufficiently sticky (see
Born and Pfeifer 2014; and
Basu and Bundick 2017). To this end, the presence of sticky prices also implies that the price markup is procyclical following a negative supply shock (see
Nekarda and Ramey 2021). The intuition is that, a rise in uncertainty causes an increase in precautionary savings which leads to a decline in demand. In an environment where it is costly to adjust prices, firms respond to the lower demand by moving downward along their marginal cost curves. This leads to an increase in the price markup (concurrently with the fall in output). In addition, given that prices are not fully rigid, the price level declines, however sluggishly, in response to the downward pressure on demand.
However, the results in the VAR model indicates that, while uncertainty shocks may display properties of a demand shock by generating lower output concurrently with lower prices, the proxy for the price markup exhibits procyclical characteristics, as it declines (with output) in response to the rise in uncertainty. Specifically, we find the correlation coefficient between the simulated output and the markup proxy to be about 0.12. One possible explanation for this outcome is that, in the US economy, prices are not rigid enough to cause firms to move downward along the marginal cost curve significantly enough to generate countercyclical price markup. That is, although both prices and the marginal cost may decline in response to the uncertainty shock, the decline in the price level is relatively larger, which leads to a fall in the price markup along with the decrease in output.
2.4. Robustness of the VAR Results
In this subsection, we carryout a similar analysis under an alternative measurements of uncertainty in order to provide a layer of robustness to the results in the VAR model. We do so by replacing VXO with the Economic Policy Uncertainty Index (EPUI) which is another popular proxy for uncertainty, developed by
Baker et al. (
2016). We also use an alternative measure of the price mark-up in the VAR model to see if that would impact the main conclusions in the benchmark model. In a separate analysis, we replace the federal Funds rate with the WU-Xia shadow rate which was developed by
Wu and Xia (
2016) to explain the macroeconomic effects of the unconventional monetary policy.
2.4.1. Using the EPUI Measure of Uncertainty
The negative effects of uncertainty shocks on the US economy, both at the firm level and in the macroeconomy, are not confined to the VXO measure of uncertainty. Similar qualitative results are achieved when the VXO is replaced with the economic policy uncertainty index (EPUI). The results are presented in
Figure A3 (in the
Appendix A). The results are consistent with that of the benchmark model. Following an increase in uncertainty, there is a decrease in hours of work for about ten quarters. Output and the price level also declines significantly for about 15 quarters following the innovation, which is an indication that the demand side effects of uncertainty dominates that of the supply side. However, the price mark-up declines (with output) in the first few quarters, which is contrary to findings in the quantitative literature that feature procyclical mark-ups. Moreover, the increase in uncertainty decreases firms’ earnings and capital stock, thereby hindering their access to external credit. Consequently, credit flow to the non-financial corporate sector declines and remains significantly low for more than 16 quarters of innovation.
2.4.2. Using Alternative Measurement of the Price Mark-Up
We now carryout a similar analysis under an alternative measurements of the price mark-up. Specifically, we use the time-series of markup developed by
Nekarda and Ramey (
2021) in the VAR model.
Figure A4 presents the results. Again, in this setting, the main conclusions are upheld: That is, the demand side effects of uncertainty dominates the supply side effects, as both output and the price level decline in response to the rise in uncertainty. The price mar-up on the other hand exhibits procyclical properties. Furthermore, we show that these conclusions stand even if we change the ordering of the variables (see
Figure A5).
2.4.3. Uncertainty Shocks under the WU-Xia Shadow Rate
Wu and Xia (
2016) developed an alternative measurement of the federal funds rate to explain the macroeconomic effects of unconventional monetary policy which is adopted by the Federal Reserve during periods of economic downturns. Using the Wu-Xia shadow rate as a stand-in for monetary policy would add to our understanding of the effects of uncertainty shocks under alternative monetary policy environments.
Figure A6 presents the results. The results are consistent with that of the benchmark model. That is, uncertainty shocks lead to a decline in earnings and the capital stock. This hinders firms’ access to external credit which leads to lower output. ultimately affecting GDP negatively.
2.4.4. Is It about Uncertain Future or Bad Economic Times for Business?
The most important feature of the VXO is that it is countercyclical. Therefore, it is reasonable to interpret the results in the baseline model as an outcome that is driven by perceptions about the current (bad) economic times rather than adjustment towards an uncertain future. To resolve this, we construct a new VAR model with business sector confidence. The approach is similar to the one used by
Baker et al. (
2016) and
Leduc and Liu (
2016). The results are presented in
Figure A7. The results show that the dynamic properties of the selected variables do not change relative to that of the baseline model even after we account for business confidence in the model. An increase in the VXO by one standard deviation decreases the price level and hours of work. In addition, there is an increase in the relative price of investment goods, which is likely an indication of the difficulties involved in adjusting investment. The value of capital stock owned by firms in the non-financial corporate decreases, as do their earnings, which makes it even more difficult for them to attract external credit. This events ultimately lead to a decline in GDP. The robustness of the results, even after accounting for business sector confidence suggest that perceptions about the current state of the economy is not the primary driver of the results as observed.
5. Summary and Conclusions
This paper explores the role of the credit channel of uncertainty shocks in driving macroeconomic conditions in the US economy. In the quantitative literature, uncertainty shocks are shown, in general, to exhibit properties of a negative demand shock (see for example
Leduc and Liu 2016). To this extent, uncertainty shocks propagate in the economy through a counter cyclical markup channel if prices are sufficiently sticky. In our set up, we model borrowing constraints as a nested function that features both corporate earnings and capital as alternative instruments for assessing credit worthiness in the corporate sector, in line with recent trends in corporate finance. This particular design allows us to analyze the macroeconomic effects of uncertainty shocks under alternative credit market settings: in one setting, borrowing is backed by the value of capital; in another setting, borrowing is tied exclusively to corporate earnings. We also extend the analysis to look at a hybrid scenario where borrowing is tied to both corporate earnings and the value of capital stock. In a preliminary analysis, we motivate the study by examining the effects of uncertainty shocks on the US economy using a Vector Auto-Regressive (VAR) model.
We find that the quantitative framework that incorporates only one instrument (capital or earnings) in the borrowing constraint falls short in matching the business cycle properties of the US economy (in the VAR model) in terms of the behavior of output, inflation, and the price markup which are an essential part of the literature on uncertainty shocks. Rather, a hybrid formulation of the borrowing constraint which accounts for both capital and earnings helps us bring the results in the quantitative model closer to the data. Specifically, the price level falls alongside output in the model with capital-based constraint, but rises in the model with earnings-based constraint. To this end, the uncertainty shock displays properties of a demand side shock in the presence of the asset-based constraints. The opposite is true in the case of the model with earnings-based constraint. In addition, following the rise in uncertainty, the price markup is countercyclical in the presence of the asset-based borrowing constraints. However, it becomes procyclical in the model with earnings-based borrowing constraint. In a special case with a hybrid formulation of the borrowing constraint where both capital and earnings are concurrently used as instruments for assessing credit worthiness, the results improve upon that of the other models in which borrowing is constrained by only one instrument (assets or earnings)—by matching the cyclical properties of output, prices and the mark-up in the VAR model. In this specification, the shock exhibits properties of a demand side shock which matches the data. Additionally, the price mar-up is procyclical, which is also consistent with the data.
The above findings show that alternative formulations of borrowing constraints matter for the propagation of second-moment shocks in the DSGE model. The paper contributes to the plethora of literature on the effects of uncertainty shocks in the economy. However, it departs from the rest of the literature by formulating and incorporating credit frictions in a unique way, which we hope would provide further insight into the understanding of uncertainty shocks and macroeconomic fluctuations.