In today’s digital economy and competitive global landscape, capital is no longer a solely material or financial category. Modern research highlights its multidimensional nature, including intellectual, technological, and cluster capitals, which play a key role in the development of innovative ecosystems. This section explores the evolution of capital as a concept, examining its modern forms and their interaction in cluster development.
2.4. Cluster Capital: Integrating Resources to Maximize the Synergetic Effect
Cluster capital refers to the combined resources and assets resulting from the collaboration of various participants. This integration gives actors an advantage over competitors and the potential for development. It also provides an effective strategy for implementing change. Cluster capital emphasizes the importance of both tangible and intangible assets in supporting the growth and success of a cluster.
Understanding models of the cluster lifecycle is important for the processes of cluster adaptation and development. M. Porter [
27] proposed a model that describes the evolution of a cluster through stages such as its origin, growth, maturity, and decline. Due to the dynamic nature of clusters, it is significant to consider constant change and adapt capital management strategies.
Each cluster group has its own types of capitals (industrial clusters, the agro-industrial complex, tourism clusters, medical clusters, etc.). Cross-industry clusters integrate potential and resources from various industries.
The basic structure of cluster capital includes the following components:
Technological capital: the availability of technologies and innovations to increase competitiveness and efficiency;
Intellectual capital: the knowledge, skills, and experience of employees to contribute to innovation and improve productivity within the cluster;
Financial capital: access to funding and investment necessary for growth and development within the companies in the cluster.
The Challoumis study [
28] emphasizes that technological innovations have a multiplier effect on economic growth, reducing transaction costs and increasing cluster productivity. However, the key factor is the optimal configuration of different types of capitals, since uneven resource allocation can lead to imbalances and reduced efficiency.
Cluster capital optimization should consider the following:
- ✓
The principle of the co-evolution of capital elements, where technological, intellectual, financial, and other types of capitals develop simultaneously;
- ✓
The principle of complementarity, which allows for the completion of missing resources and skills through cluster interaction;
- ✓
The use of mathematical models to determine the levels of uncertainty in capital allocation.
Therefore, cluster capital management requires a strategic approach that considers not only the accumulation but also the dynamic redistribution of resources within the system. The optimization of the interactions within integration structures is crucial for their effective functioning. For example, too few interactions can result in the insufficient exchange of complementary resources, while too many interactions can complicate coordination and increase costs. Various methods can be employed to solve this issue, depending on the available data and goals of the integration structure.
To solve this problem, various methods can be used, depending on the source data and the goals of the integration structures. Here is a brief overview of them:
1. Methods of network analysis. A network is a complex system composed of several interconnected subsystems that interact with each other. The performance of the entire system is dependent on the effectiveness of its individual parts. Network analysis can be used to analyze the structure of interactions between economic actors, such as participants in integration structures [
29]. This involves assessing interaction patterns and selecting a system of indicators, collecting data, and analyzing individual subnetworks [
30].
In the scientific literature, network interactions are subject to comprehensive and extensive analysis. N. E. Egorova’s work, for example, focuses on developing efficiency indicators that allow for the quantification of network interaction development [
31]. A. A. Afanasyeva and S. P. Kushch analyze the factors that influence the effectiveness of these interactions [
32]. V.L. Simonov and K.B. Rybalko have developed a system of indicators for evaluating the efficiency of network interactions, which includes four stages: creating a model that reflects how the network characteristics influence the outcomes of participants’ activities; identifying factors that affect the effectiveness of interactions at various stages of the network lifecycle; analyzing the relationship between these factors; determining an integrated indicator for the interaction effectiveness, and creating profiles for network participants [
33].
Thus, it is essential to collect data about the network structure to effectively use network analysis methods. This includes information about the participants (agents) and their interactions, as well as about the nature, frequency, and intensity of these interactions. Additionally, it is crucial to identify the key performance indicators for each participant and for the network as a whole. This allows us to evaluate the contribution of each agent to the overall outcome.
However, a drawback of using these approaches is that choosing the evaluation indicators can be subjective and depend on the preferences of the researcher. This may result in an incomplete understanding of all the significant aspects of the networking and reduce the accuracy of the assessment. Therefore, in addition to using an indicator system, it can be beneficial to utilize graph methods, which offer a more structured approach to examining and optimizing network structures.
The interacting structure can be represented as a graph, G = (V,E), where V is the set of nodes (agents), and E is the set of edges (interactions between agents). The goal is to find a subset of edges (E’ ⊆ E) that maximizes a certain objective utility function (U(E’)) while respecting the constraints on the minimum and maximum numbers of interactions for each node. The utility function measures the total value of all selected interactions. Each interaction has a weight, which reflects its significance or quality. Optimizing the network structure is then formulated as follows:
where
is the weight of the interaction (for example, its usefulness or cost) and the degree of the node (number of interactions), and
dmin(
v) and
dmax(
v) are the minimum and maximum allowable numbers of interactions for the given node (
v).
The task is to identify the most significant interactions between the nodes in the network, which together bring the maximum benefit. To study real-world integrations, it is important to know which nodes (economic agents) are interconnected. It is essential to characterize these connections in terms of their significance or quality and to assign the weight to each interaction. These data need to determine the network structure and evaluate its effectiveness. It is also important to take into account limits on the number of interactions that each agent can participate in to balance their involvement in the network. Additionally, we need to determine the target utility function that will be maximized during the network optimization process. This utility function should take into account the overall importance of all the selected interactions;
2. Modeling and simulation. This approach involves creating models that simulate the interactions between economic systems within an integrated association. This allows for the modeling of a large number of relationships to optimize the functioning of these systems. Agent-based modeling is often used for this purpose, where participants in economic relations are considered as agents interacting with each other in a simulated environment. This enables conducting simulation experiments with different levels and types of interactions to achieve the desired balance. Thus, the use of agent-based modeling in combination with simulation experiments is a method for studying the dynamics of complex systems. It consists of autonomous agents interacting with each other, observing the collective effects of their behavior and interactions [
34].
For example, in Reference [
35], a simulation–optimization model is presented to optimize the interaction between high-tech companies and financial institutions with the goal of maximizing the market value of a company’s capital. The article [
36] shows that agent-based modeling can be effectively used in the analysis of dynamic adaptive systems, helping to study the diffusion of innovations and the flow of knowledge and information.
While simulation and agent-based models are effective tools for examining interactions within economic systems, there are several drawbacks to this approach. For instance, the outcomes can significantly depend on the initial conditions and parameters, making them sensitive to data changes. Additionally, successful modeling requires accurate data, which may not always be readily accessible.
Analyzing real-world systems using this toolkit requires detailed information about the participants’ characteristics, such as their behavioral patterns, available resources, and strategies. It is also helpful to have data on the types and levels of interaction between participants, including the frequency and intensity. Additionally, information about the external environment can also be valuable;
3. Game-theoretical models. Game theory can be applied in various fields of economics, such as labor, macroeconomics, and other applied fields. Similar problems arise in these different fields, and game-theoretic models provide a powerful tool for analyzing interactions between economic agents. These models help to understand strategic behavior and decision making, aiming to find effective coordination and cooperation in relationships. They pay special attention to cooperation [
37].
Game-theoretic modeling has become a popular tool in economics for making decisions. However, there has not been enough research conducted to determine the accuracy and effectiveness of this approach [
38]. One article demonstrates how game theory can optimize investment planning and forecasting, as well as effectively manage these processes [
39]. Other studies have shown the use of game-theoretical models in analyzing transport markets and interactions between decision makers [
40], and in responding to the demand for electricity in growing electricity markets [
41].
One tool for optimizing interactions in integrations is cooperative game theory. This field of game theory focuses on analyzing and optimizing the interactions between players to form coalitions and achieve common goals along with the fair distribution of resources. The goal of cooperative games is to maximize the overall benefits for all players while maintaining a balance between their interests.
In cooperative games, the utility function of the coalition (U(C)) is defined for the coalition (C⊆V, where V is the set of all possible players) and measures the overall benefit from the cooperation of all players in the coalition. Formally, the coalition’s utility function can be written as follows:
where
u(
v,
C) is the utility of a player (
v) in a coalition (
C).
To determine the contribution of each player (
v) to the overall utility of the coalition, the Shapley value is used. This value helps to balance the interactions, taking into account the individual contribution of each player [
42]:
where
C is a subset of players, excluding
v, and
is player
v’s contribution to the
C coalition.
To effectively use game-theoretic models in analyzing real-world integration scenarios, it is crucial to have detailed information about the participants and their characteristics, resources, and strategies. Additionally, data on coalitions, conditions for their formation, and outcomes are essential, as well as knowledge of utility functions. It assesses the benefits of cooperation and how individual contributions influence the overall coalition benefit;
4. Models of random processes. Random process models, such as Markov chains, provide powerful tools for analyzing interactions between economic agents. These interactions can be described as a Markov process, where the probability of moving from one state to another depends on the current state of the system. And this reflects the current number of interactions. The goal of these models is to optimize the transition probabilities so that the desired state with the optimal number of interactions is achieved.
Markov models are especially useful for studying the interactions among many agents with asymmetric fluctuations, such as business cycles. They can also be used to describe systems with multiple locally stable equilibrium points, which depend on uncertainties [
43]. For example, the hidden Markov model was used to study customer relationships and their effect on customer behavior in [
44].
In such models, the transition probabilities, denoted as
pij, play a key role, as they determine the likelihood of the system moving from state
i to state
j at time
t:
Optimizing these transition probabilities allows us to either minimize or maximize the objective function related to the number of interactions in the system.
When analyzing real-world systems with models based on random processes, it is important to have a comprehensive understanding of the system’s current states and the probabilities associated with the transitions between these states. Additionally, knowing the target function that we want to optimize is essential for making informed decisions about how to adjust the system’s parameters.
Thus, modern research supports the need for a comprehensive approach to managing resources within clusters. To optimize interactions within integration structures, it is essential to effectively organize financial, technological, and intellectual capitals, and to effectively distribute these resources among participants. However, the challenge of developing mathematical modeling methods for optimizing capital configurations within cluster structures remains significant.