1. Introduction
With the development of e-commerce enterprises, live streaming and take-out delivery services have entered people’s daily lives. Network platforms as a new form of economy format have attracted wide attention [
1]. The latest data from the National Bureau of Statistics show that, as of 2024, China’s online retail transaction volume was 9.26 trillion CNY, up 9.5 percent year on year. With the continuous emergence of platform technology and model innovation, the consumption of key platform channel network services has increased by 20.2%. Thus, as choosing the right supply chain channel is crucial in the competitive environment of business, many e-commerce enterprises are considering introducing the platform channel. At the same time, a smart economy alongside a green supply chain has become the theme of social development. Promoting a green and low-carbon economy is the key to achieving high-quality development [
2]. The economic priority is to build a green and low-carbon society. Based on this, the Chinese government has introduced relevant green subsidy policies to promote the development of green industries. The green transformation of enterprises requires high costs; due to this, many enterprises are hesitating, despite government subsidies being able to fully alleviate the cost pressure of the green reform of enterprises to promote the development of green industry [
3]. On the other hand, with the improvement of consumers’ awareness of environmental protection, they pay more attention to the environmental pollution of online shopping products; consumers prefer to buy green products as an effective way to save energy and reduce emissions. In this instance, green platform channels have attracted the attention of e-commerce enterprises [
4] and become a powerful tool to improve the revenue of enterprises. What is more, the introduction of platform channels not only opens up the sales market for enterprises but also provides transaction communication channels for consumers and enterprises, and it improves the overall benefits of the product supply chain [
5]. The platform channel has attracted more and more consumers [
6]. The operation of the platform is undertaken using the principal-agent mechanism to improve sales services for e-commerce, and charges commissions from them, which may vary according to different enterprises and commodities [
7]. The pricing of goods sold through platform channels is controlled by the platform, and enterprises have the right of direct pricing of goods. Moreover, the pricing of the platform is reflected in various platform marketing strategy activities. At present, the popular 10 billion active subsidy, the Double Eleven subsidy, and various festival activity vouchers are all different platform pricing strategies [
8]. Compared with traditional multi-level distribution channels, the powerful data analysis and intelligent cloud computing technology of platform channels can allow the faster and more accurate gathering of market sales information [
1]. In addition, the platform’s shared information service can provide data support for manufacturing and e-commerce enterprises [
9]. Thus, for e-commerce enterprises, the introduction of platform channels lies in the mastery of consumer market information [
10]. The introduction of marketplace channels by e-commerce companies provides merchants and consumers with a platform for direct transactions, but at the same time it also intensifies product competition in the market. A series of problems arising from the selection of marketplace channels can be described as follows:
(1) Distribution selection. With the development of the e-commerce economy, consumers are becoming more and more sensitive to logistics [
11]. For example, distribution in the catering industry requires timeliness. In order to preserve the taste of food, constant temperature distribution is required and the delivery time to customers needs to be as short as possible. KFC and Pizza Hut and other large chain enterprises have chosen to build their own logistics distribution system, with ‘express delivery’, while M Cake is outsourced to urban express logistics. How should enterprises choose their mode of logistics distribution? Should they build their own distribution system or outsource it to third-party logistics?
(2) Platform selection and information sharing. Network broadcasting has become a new sales model; businesses have also identified the business opportunities it brings, namely opening up online sales. Do enterprises therefore need to introduce platform channels? Open information channels can improve distribution efficiency, allowing distribution staff to realize the transfer order, and multiple orders can thus be filled. Whether the investment costs for the open sharing of information can be compensated for by increased benefits is still up for debate. For example, Pizza Hut has a self-established application APP for express delivery, and it has also joined the Meituan delivery platform, and consumers can choose to buy its products from both channels. M Cake only has platform channels and has not opened a self-channel, and consumers can only buy products through the platform.
(3) Green governmental subsidy effect. The government provides green subsidies to the platform to improve the economy by reducing the pressure of selling green products, associated, for example with their high cost, so as to guide and encourage retailers to actively sell green products. However, the question remains: how should the relationships within the entire supply chain be coordinated to ensure the policy’s effectiveness?
As described above, logistics distribution and platform operations constitute fundamental factors influencing the e-commerce supply chain channel selection. Current research lacks comprehensive strategies to address this complex issue and fails to take consumers’ preferences into consideration, which represents a significant research gap in the field of e-commerce supply chain management. Therefore, under the government’s green subsidy policy, this paper constructs an e-commerce supply chain composed of an e-commerce self-operated channel and a platform channel. Considering consumers’ green preferences, we analyze the supply chain channel selection strategy from the aspects of logistics distribution, platform selection, and coordination management. The following questions are addressed: (1) Should companies choose self-established distribution logistics or third-party distribution logistics? (2) What are the selection conditions of each channel? What channel strategy should enterprises adopt? (3) Should the supply chain be managed cooperatively under government subsidies and achieve green and low-carbon goals?
The contents of this study are organized as follows: the relevant literature is outlined in
Section 2. In
Section 3, we propose five models of logistics selection, platform channel selection and government coordination, and derive equilibrium solutions for each scenario.
Section 4 analyzes strategies related to logistics and platform channel and green channel information sharing. In
Section 5, a franchise contract is used to coordinate the whole supply chain under the government green subsidy.
Section 6 presents a numerical analysis to visually illustrate the main findings.
Section 7 summarizes the paper and proposes potential directions for future research.
3. Model Description and Analysis
In this research, we built an online sales system composed of e-commerce self-operated channels and platform channels. This study focuses on the strategy of logistics service, channel selection, and the coordinated management of green governmental subsidies. Logistics services can be divided into self-established logistics service modes and third-party logistics service modes; of these, the level of the self-established logistics service is higher than that of third-party logistics, but its operation cost is also higher. The purchase channels are also divided into e-commerce self-operated channels and platform channels, and the revenue for goods purchased through self-operated channels is directly transferred to the e-commerce account, while for purchases made through the platform channel, revenue is first collected by the platform and then transferred to the e-commerce account, after the platform deducts a certain percentage of commission. Notations used in this paper are summarized in
Table 1.
(1) To emphasize the coexistence of competition and cooperation between the self-operated channel and the platform channel, this paper assumes that both channels sell identical goods with the same marginal cost. Without a loss of generality, all marginal costs are set to zero.
(2) Assuming that consumers are equally sensitive to logistics services provided by different entities in the market, if an e-commerce company establishes its own logistics system, consumers’ sensitivity to the self-established logistics services of the e-commerce company is the same as their sensitivity to the logistics services provided by third-party logistics providers.
(3) To obtain the demand, we use the consumer utility function, assuming that consumers have heterogeneous valuations
for the product, where
is uniformly distributed over the interval [0, 1]. This article further assumes that improving logistics service levels can enhance the utility consumers derive from purchasing the product [
51].
By analyzing the consumer utility function, we establish the relationship between logistics service levels, consumer valuations, and demand, thereby deriving the demand function under different logistics service conditions. The sequence of the game is as follows: e-commerce enterprises first decide whether to introduce platform channels. If they choose not to introduce platform channels, they evaluate two types of logistics decisions (self-established logistics or third-party logistics) [
52]; if they introduce platform channels, the impact of platform commission and consumer preference on the overall income is considered to maximize the revenue of enterprises. Subsequently, a franchise system is employed to coordinate the supply chain, leveraging the government’s green subsidies for the platform to enhance overall supply chain efficiency. The decision-making model is shown in
Figure 1. According to the channel structure in different situations, the revenue function of the commodity is obtained, and by using game theory and backward induction, the equilibrium solution of the game in each case is obtained.
3.1. Logistics Distribution Model
3.1.1. Third-Party Distribution Mode in Self-Operated Channel (TP Mode)
In the traditional e-commerce logistics model, goods are sold by e-commerce enterprises, and the products are distributed through third-party logistics after the order is accepted. The utility of the consumer purchasing the product is
. When consumer utility is higher than zero,
, the consumer chooses to buy the product, as shown in
Figure 2a. In this mode, the market demand of the product is
, and the revenue of e-commerce enterprises is:
In order to maximize profit, take the partial derivation for at p and make it equal to 0, ; thus, we obtain and . To ensure , results need to satisfy the condition . Then, by substituting the derived optimal value into (1), we can obtain the maximum profit: .
3.1.2. Self-Established Distribution Mode in Self-Operated Channel (SL Mode)
In this model, sales and distribution are completed by the e-commerce enterprises themselves, and the enterprises build their own logistics for distribution, as shown in
Figure 2b. The utility of consumers purchasing goods is
. When the utility of consumers is higher than zero, they choose to buy products. The market demand of products in this mode is
. The income of e-commerce enterprises is
In the self-established logistics model, product prices and logistics service levels are decided by e-commerce enterprises. The goal of e-commerce is to maximize revenue and find the Hessian matrix of Equation (2); when , the Hessian matrix is negative, so we obtain , , and , and finally substitute it into Equation (2) to obtain the maximum profit .
3.2. Platform Channel Model
3.2.1. Third-Party Logistics Distribution Mode in Green Platform Channel (IT Mode)
After the introduction of green platform channels, consumers choose their own purchase channels, and purchase orders are uniformly delivered by e-commerce enterprises and distributed by third-party logistics. The utility of consumers buying self-operated channel goods is
, and the utility of consumers choosing green platform channel based on their green preference is
. Decisions are made based on utility maximization. When
, consumers buy products through self-operated channels; when
, consumers choose platform channels to buy products, as shown in
Figure 3.
In this model, the commodity demand of each channel is as follows:
and
. The case of positive channel sales is studied and discussed as
and
, so
. The channel income of e-commerce enterprises and platforms are as follows:
The total revenue of the supply chain is as follows:
When the platform channel is introduced and both parties utilize third-party logistics, the consumer preference coefficient is the median number
[
53,
54]. Consumers pay more attention to the green environmental protection of their distribution logistics model. In this scenario, the sales model is structured as the platform provides sales channels, and the e-commerce company makes the sales decisions. The relationship between the e-commerce company and the platform is a leader–follower relationship. The sequence of the game between the two sides is as follows: the e-commerce enterprises, as the leader, decide the commodity prices of their own channels, while the platforms, as the followers, make decisions on the commodity prices of their platform channels after the e-commerce decisions. The Stackelberg game is used to solve this problem through backward induction [
7,
55].
The equilibrium results are as follows:
, ; ; , of which .
The profits of each channel are as follows:
3.2.2. Sharing Distribution Mode in Platform Channel (IS Mode)
In this model, the platform integrates distribution and sales, which uses the platform’s self-established logistics to distribute goods. Consumers can choose e-commerce self-operated channels or platform channels and use the platform’s self-established logistics system for distribution. By sharing information about integrated distribution, consumers can view all aspects of the purchase and distribution process in real time and track each process of the order distribution. The platform also publicly discloses order information and shares the order progress, so that couriers can transfer orders. The service utility is related to the platform input
, and the decision-making model is shown in
Figure 4. The utility of goods obtained by consumers who choose e-commerce self-operated channels is
, and the utility of goods obtained by platform channels is
. When
, consumers choose self-operated channels to buy goods. When
, consumers choose the platform channel to purchase goods.
The demands of self-operated channels and platform channels are
and
to ensure that sales volume is positive. In addition, the condition of
should be satisfied; then, the income of e-commerce self-operated channels is as follows:
In the platform sales and distribution integration model, the self-established logistics investment is
, the revenue is as follows:
In the sharing e-commerce system, the platform utilizes green and low-carbon shared logistics for unified distribution, which generate scale benefits and reduce the level of distribution. Simultaneously, considering the impact of consumers’ green preferences on the selection of purchase channels, the decision-making analysis is conducted by comparing the self-established logistics distribution through the self-operated channels of e-commerce. The equilibrium results are as follows:
3.3. Government Coordination Model
3.3.1. Sharing Distribution Mode Under Green Subsidies (IG Model)
The government gives green subsidies to the platform, and all goods are distributed by the platform’s self-established logistics system, as shown in
Figure 5.
The utility of goods when choosing self-operated channels is , and the utility of goods when choosing government green platform channels is . When , the self-operated channel is selected; when , the green platform channel is selected. The demand for each channel is and , while to ensure a positive sales volume, should be satisfied.
The decision models are as follows:
In this model, platform channels provide sales and distribution services, but sales strategies and product-related services are still decided by e-commerce enterprises. The game sequence is as follows: e-commerce determines the product price of the channel, and platforms determine the commission rate. The optimal solution can be obtained through the backward induction method:
By substituting the value into (8) and (9), the profits of each channel can be obtained as follows:
3.3.2. Channel Coordination Model Under Green Government Subsidies (IGH Model)
On the basis of the government subsidies, the overall collaborative management of supply chain sales channels is implemented. Through centralized decision-making, the overall maximum profit of the supply chain is obtained. The decision-making model is as follows:
The equilibrium result is , ,
The maximum profit is .
4. Channel Selection Strategy Analysis
4.1. Logistics Analysis
The logistics strategy of e-commerce enterprises is discussed based on the cost coefficient of self-established logistics
and the logistics sensitivity of consumers
. The cost coefficient of self-established logistics
is when the cost structures the logistics infrastructure delivery system of logistics, and the logistics sensitivity of consumers
affects the consumers’ choice of purchase channel. A higher level means that the seller should utilize higher-quality logistics to attract the consumer to buy their products [
56].
Proposition 1. When , third-party logistics is used for distribution; when , self-established logistics is used for distribution, where .
Proof. When , .
We obtain .
□
As , the investment of self-established logistics is high. Outsourcing services to third-party companies can effectively reduce the operating costs of enterprises. When , , the coefficient of self-construction increases, the input of self-construction logistics decreases, and e-commerce enterprises receive higher profit margins. Self-construction logistics can improve the effectiveness of consumers to purchase products, so enterprises choose to distribute through self-established logistic systems. Many enterprises such as Pizza Hut choose self-established logistics to increase their income because of their low investment in this system, while M Cake chooses third-party logistics services because of the high cost of its self-established logistics as a result of scale economy.
The influence of consumer logistics sensitivity on the investment coefficient of self-established logistics is further discussed as below.
Corollary 1. When , the investment coefficient of self-established logistics increases as the logistics sensitivity of consumers increases; when , the investment coefficient of self-established logistics decreases as the logistics sensitivity of consumers decreases.
Proof. Partial derivation for
at
; when
, the latter is obtained as
, and it is can be seen from the calculation in
Section 3.1 that
needs to be satisfied using the intersection of the two conditions
.
When , .
The proof is same as above.
□
From the above sections, it can be concluded that when consumers’ logistics awareness increases to , the investment coefficient of self-established logistics decreases as the sensitivity increases, leading to lower investment costs and higher profits. As consumers are sensitive to logistics, the self-established logistics mode better satisfies consumers’ demand for logistics distribution services, and consumers are willing to pay higher fees for logistics services. Therefore, this increases sales volumes for goods and enables enterprises to obtain higher profits and further improve their self-established logistics systems and form a virtuous cycle process.
4.2. Platform Selection Decision Analysis
The key to channel selection is the commission rate of the platform . By comparing the equilibrium results of the platform channel and the self-operated channel, the selection strategy can be obtained.
Proposition 2. When the commission rate of the platform channel , the platform channel is selected; otherwise, the self-operated channel is selected.
Proof. When comparing the income of platform channels and the self-operated channels of e-commerce businesses, the introduction conditions are as follows:
when ,
.
□
When e-commerce enterprises introduce platform channels and both parties use third-party logistics, platform commission is the main factor in channel competition. When platform commission is lower than , platform channels have lower unit costs and higher total revenue than self-operated channels. Introducing platform channels can increase total sales profits, while high profits also result in more bargaining space for channels and improve their competitive advantages. When the platform commission is higher than , more profits from e-commerce enterprises will be shared with the platform, which results in a decline in the total profits of enterprises. Choosing self-operated channels can effectively reduce the enterprises’ expenses and increase their sales volumes, thus increasing the total profits.
The influence of consumers’ logistics sensitivity on channel selection is further analyzed below:
Corollary 2. Platform channels are more attractive to consumers who are more sensitive to logistics services.
Proof. The optimal rate of the platform can be obtained by the derivation of logistics sensitivity.
As seen in
Section 3.2,
,
.
□
A platform obtains the advantages of large-scale logistics services by concentrating on a large number of orders, which improves the logistics distribution services for consumers. However, the more sensitive consumers are to logistics services, the higher the platform commission rate, indicating that under the same conditions, more consumers choose platform channels and, thus, a platform can increase its commission rate, thereby improving its bargaining power and ultimately enhancing channel revenue and efficiency. For example, both Pizza Hut and M Cake have opened platform channels; the main reason for this is that unlike in other industries, consumers are highly sensitive to food quality, and delivery is very important for order fulfillment. Therefore, e-commerce enterprises should combine their own industry and enterprise characteristics, comprehensively consider the third-party logistics costs and platform commission rates, and make their own decisions by comparing their optimal revenue with their actual revenue under the current commission rate. Thus, when the actual commission rate is lower than the optimal commission rate, enterprises should introduce a platform channel; otherwise, they should choose a self-operated channel.
4.3. Decision Analysis of Green Channel with Information Sharing
The decision analysis is carried out by comparing the benefits of self-established logistics distributions and green channel distributions with information sharing distributions.
Proposition 3. When the platform commission rate , sharing the platform information can create more profits for the enterprise.
Proof. When
,
Then, calculate and we obtain .
□
Compared with the income of self-established logistics and platform systems, the determining factor is the platform rate, and when the rate is less than , the platform channel yields the greatest benefit to the enterprise.
The influence of the consumer’s green preference on channel selection is further analyzed and discussed below.
Corollary 3. When , the green preference of consumers is higher, and they are more likely to choose platform channels. When , the higher the consumer’s green preference, the more inclined they are to choose self-operated channels.
Proof. is the critical point of the decision; take the derivative of at and let it equal 0. Thus, we obtain under the condition of . So, , and , .
□
When the investment coefficient is more than twice the logistics sensitivity, the platform channel becomes more attractive, and its income is greatly improved by considering the green preference of consumers. However, when the investment coefficient is less than twice the logistics sensitivity, the benefit of logistics improvement cannot offset the investment cost, and the green preference of consumers cannot meet the sales advantage of the channel. In such cases, adopting the self-operated model yields higher profits.
5. Coordination Model Analysis for Channels with Green Government Subsidies
5.1. Analysis of Channels with Green Subsidies (IG Model)
Proposition 4. Green governmental subsidies can improve the income of the all-channel e-commerce supply chain.
Proof. By comparing the revenue of each channel member operating under a green subsidy, the equilibrium result of Equations (6)–(9) can be obtained:
□
The conclusion shows that government subsidies can increase the income of e-commerce enterprises and platforms and achieve the Pareto improvement of the supply chain. Green subsidies for platforms increase the demand for green commodities in a channel, and thus, more consumers with green preferences choose platform channels. What is more, subsidies reduce commodity prices and improve consumers’ purchasing utility. The self-established logistics service of platform channels improves its logistics service level and consumer benefits and then improves its sales revenue, which is essentially a “free-rider” effect. The income from subsidies can make up for the impact of the platform rate increase on the self-operating income of e-commerce enterprises, so that the total income of e-commerce enterprises will increase. The commodity income of platform channels increases significantly. This is crucial for the development of the green economy. On the one hand, green commodities have long faced challenges in the market due to their higher prices. Although some consumers prefer to purchase green products, the elevated costs often deter them from making a purchase. On the other hand, in order to qualify for government subsidies, self-operated channels generally utilize a platform’s logistics services to enhance their service quality and increase their revenue. Moreover, the increased volume of logistics orders handled by a platform leads to economies of scale in the green economy, which can reduce costs and improve service efficiency.
5.2. Coordinated Strategy with Green Government Subsidies (IGH Model)
On the basis of the coordination of government subsidies, supply chain sale channels are managed as a whole, and the maximum profit of a supply chain is obtained through centralized decision-making. This approach reduces repeat distribution and minimizes multi-level information transfer while enhancing resource utilization which supports the development of a green economy.
It can be concluded that the optimal subsidy value is , the leverage utility of the subsidy can be realized when , and the overall benefit can be maximized with the minimum subsidy input. In addition, the government can improve business channel cooperation through subsidies. However, ultimately, platform information sharing and enterprise marketing strategies can achieve complementary effects to achieve a win–win situation.
Proposition 5. Under the IGH model of governmental collaborative management, the total revenue of the supply chain can be improved.
Proof. By comparing the revenue of decentralized decision-making and governmental coordination benefits, we can obtain the following from Equations (8)–(10):
□
Under this coordination mechanism, the objective is to maximize the overall revenue of the supply chain, without the influence of the double marginal effect. Meanwhile, with the aim of maximizing revenue, the incentive mechanism is adopted for the channel, which improves both service level and revenue.
5.3. Platform Franchise System in the Platform Channel (IB)
The platform franchise system is an important coordination method for profit maximization and supply chain redistribution. A franchise contract is divided into a fixed price and a unit price. The revenue function of e-commerce and platform is as follows:
To maximize channel revenue, the equilibrium solution is obtained as follows:
; add in (11) and (12), and we obtain
By verifying whether the income under a specific decision can maximize the income of the centralized decision, we can compare the channel income with the entire revenue; thus,
is obtained.
Proposition 6. The conditions for the coordination strategy of the franchise system are as follows: Proof. In order for an e-commerce enterprise to join a platform channel, its profit needs to be
, that is,
; when
, we obtain
and when
, we obtain
□
It can be concluded that when the franchise fee is within the optimal range, the income of e-commerce enterprises and platforms can achieve the Pareto improvement, and the rational profit distribution within the franchise contract system can achieve a mutually beneficial win–win situation. Furthermore, under these conditions, green subsidies optimize the whole supply chain and revenue. In addition, the supply chain can be coordinated which ultimately improves the development of the economy.
7. Conclusions and Policy Suggestions
This paper constructs a dual-channel online sales system composed of e-commerce enterprises’ self-operated channels and green platform channels and investigates the impact of green governmental subsidies on e-commerce enterprises’ supply chain channel selection strategies. The results show the following: (1) The logistics selection depends on the relationship between self-established logistics system costs and consumers’ logistics sensitivities. The higher the logistics sensitivity of consumers, the more likely e-commerce enterprises are to choose self-established logistics systems. (2) For channel selection, consumers’ green logistics sensitivities and platform commission rates are two critical factors in decision-making. The equilibrium condition for these factors is obtained by using game theory. When consumers are sensitive to logistics, they are more inclined to adopt platform channels, and platform commission rates will increase with the increase in sensitivity. (3) A platform can improve its efficiency through information sharing, thereby achieving the goal of green and low-carbon distribution. Green preferences of consumers increase the sales volumes of platform channels and improve their channel competitiveness. (4) Green governmental subsidies can achieve the Pareto improvement in a supply chain. Centralized decision-making through the governmental coordination and contract coordination of platform franchise systems can improve the overall efficiency of a supply chain.
When making logistics decisions and channel decisions, e-commerce enterprises should thoroughly consider consumers’ sensitivity to green logistics. For consumers with high logistics sensitivities, they are more inclined to choose self-operated logistics distribution modes. Whether enterprise use self-operated logistics systems or self-operated platform logistics systems, their service quality and green low-carbon levels are higher than those of third-party logistics organizations. However, investment cost is an important factor that affects the selection of systems, and the optimal scheme is obtained through balancing the benefits of the logistics systems. When making decisions regarding channel selection, a platform’s information sharing becomes an important factor. In addition to a platform’s operational costs, the commission rate is also influenced by consumers’ green preferences. The channel selection strategy proposed in this paper can better adjust the supply and demand relationship of commodities and more accurately utilize market demand information. Through the establishment of a green governmental subsidy model, this study expands the research perspective on channel integration. The implementation of franchise contracts reveals three significant outcomes: the maximization of the supply chain’s overall profitability; the effective coordination of inter-channel competitive relationships; and the enhancement of resource utilization efficiency and overall supply chain benefits.
In the era of the rapid development of e-commerce, consumers’ demands for purchasing services have significantly increased. When making channel selection decisions, enterprises must fully consider consumer preferences and comprehensively evaluate factors such as logistics costs and e-commerce platform commissions. For e-commerce enterprises, the improvement of management suggestions lies in establishing self-operated logistics to enhance consumer satisfaction, utilizing shared platforms to improve delivery efficiency, achieving green logistics, and increasing corporate profits. Furthermore, centralized decision-making emerges as the optimal strategy for government administrators to effectively coordinate the entire supply chain and maximize revenue. Additionally, franchise contracts can foster collaboration between businesses and stakeholders by promoting Pareto improvement. Consequently, such strategic implementation ensures the practical realization and operational effectiveness of the proposed policies. This approach not only enhances consumer welfare but also promotes the efficient and green development of the entire supply chain. Platform channel construction under green subsidies can promote information sharing among supply chain members and achieve rapid responses. Adopting a platform franchise system to coordinate a supply chain can facilitate the rapid development of the green economy. There are some limitations to this study, as it focuses solely on a single online platform channel. Multi-platform channel competition and offline channels also affect the channel selection of e-commerce enterprises, and these aspects will be explored in future research.