The Configuration Path of the New Rural Collective Economy to Promote the Common Prosperity of Farmers: Based on Qualitative Comparative Analysis Method and the Rural Cases in Zhejiang, China
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review and Theoretical Framework
2.1. New Rural Collective Economy
2.2. Common Prosperity of Rural Households
2.3. The Theoretical Mechanism of the New Rural Collective Economy in Promoting the Common Prosperity of Rural Households
- Economic function. As a typical form of public ownership economy, the rural collective economy not only adapts to the two systems of planned economy and market economy but also effectively plays the market-oriented function of the new rural collective economy under the market economy system. The new rural collective economy has built a support platform for individual economic participants, lowering the threshold to the market, and significantly enhancing their competitiveness in the market and risk resilience. This model gives farmers more rights of speech and more equal participation in the market, thus effectively safeguarding their rights and interests [24]. In addition, based on its advantages in management, the new rural collective economy can effectively cooperate with external market players to introduce capital, technology, and human resources. This cooperation not only promotes the optimization and adjustment of rural industrial structure but also enhances the market competitiveness of rural industries. Additionally, the new rural collective economy can strengthen the self-development power of the countryside as well as promote the rise of new business forms and the expansion of the industrial chain [25]. This economic model has created many jobs in the local and surrounding areas, attracted the return of migrant workers, and provided farmers with more ways to increase their incomes. In this way, the new rural collective economy not only significantly increases the incomes of farmers but also injects new vitality into the rural economy and promotes the sustainable development of the region [26].
- Social function. The new rural collective economy possesses both social and economic attributes [27]. Given its core values of co-creation and sharing, the new rural collective economy carries significant social functions and becomes an important driving force for the development of rural public interests and public welfare undertakings. It plays a key role in improving the comprehensive well-being of rural areas through participating in the improvement of rural infrastructure, ensuring the reliable supply of public services, enriching rural cultural life, and promoting ecological beautification projects [28]. Traditionally, rural public services are largely dependent on government funding. However, the development of a new rural collective economy is bringing about a remarkable transformation. It is able to achieve a major leap from a single “blood transfusion” by the government to “self-hematopoiesis” by the masses, which not only improves the quality of life of farmers but also enhances their sense of happiness and satisfaction.
3. Model Setting, Data Source, and Variable Selection
3.1. Qualitative Comparative Analysis Method
3.2. Data Source
3.3. Variable Setting
3.3.1. Result Variables
3.3.2. Conditional Variables
- ①
- The function condition variable of the new rural collective economy
- (a)
- Economic function. The rural collective economy is a key way to increase farmers’ income and an important force to promote China’s agricultural modernization [40]. Its economic function is to manage assets and formulate collective economic investment strategies, rather than directly participate in daily business activities [41], with the purpose of promoting rural economic development and improving farmers’ income. This article selects the effect degree of the new rural collective economy on the increase in farmers’ total income, operating income, wage income, and dividend income, and comprehensively measures the economic benefits of the new rural collective economy in promoting farmers’ income growth.
- (b)
- Cultural functions. The cultural function of the new rural collective economy covers the organization’s shape and guides the members’ values, norms of behavior, social identity, and other aspects. It can play a role of cultural guidance in the community, provide members with a broader cultural experience, and at the same time transmit positive cultural values. It is of great significance to form a dynamic and cohesive cultural atmosphere and promote the cultural prosperity of the community. This article selects four function indicators, namely, rural cultural activities, publicity of rural civilization, publicity of rural healthy life, and rural cohesion of spiritual emotions, to measure the influence of the new rural collective cultural functions on the common prosperity of rural households.
- (c)
- Social function. The new rural collective economy plays a fundamental and key role in providing rural public goods and maintaining the spiritual home of the farmers. It does not only realize various social functions, such as providing hardship subsidies, medical assistance, and life services for its members, but also plays the role of social stabilizer through the redistribution of collective net income. This reallocation of resources ensures the basic balance of farmers’ income, especially the rural five-guarantees households, poor families, and disabled people, and provides basic livelihood guarantees for rural low-income people [42]. In this article, five functional indicators are selected to comprehensively measure their contribution to improving farmers’ well-being, including farmers’ hardship subsidies, medical assistance, mutual support for the aged, subsistence relief, and education subsidies.
- (d)
- Management functions. The management function of the new rural collective economy refers to the functions of guiding production, coordinating management, infrastructure construction, and supply of public goods in addition to production and business activities. The capacity for effective organization, coordination, decision-making, and control of matters and resources within the collective economic organization helps to ensure that the collective economic organization can function effectively, adapt to change, improve competitiveness, and achieve sustainable development at the economic and social levels. This article selects three function indicators, including rural infrastructure construction, rural public service, and ecological beautiful countryside construction, to measure the influence of the new rural collective economic management function on farmers’ common prosperity.
- ②
- Livelihood capital condition variable.
- (1)
- Human capital. As a key factor to measure farmers’ production efficiency and income-generating ability, human capital covers farmers’ knowledge, skills, labor ability, and physical conditions [44,45]. The selected indicators in this article include the education level of the householder, whether there are college students in the family, the burden coefficient of the household labor force, and the health status of the householder.
- (2)
- Material capital. Material capital is the means of production and fixed assets owned by families to maintain livelihoods [46], which can raise production efficiency, improve quality of life, and enhance the ability to resist risks. Therefore, three indicators are selected to measure the material capital of households: whether households have production tools such as larger agricultural machinery (tractors, agricultural tricycles, pesticide sprayers, and water pumps), vehicles and other means of transportation (cars, motorcycles), and housing level.
- (3)
- Financial capital. As an important index to measure the level of funds available to households in production and daily life and the ability to obtain external financing, financial capital has a direct impact on the investment decisions of farmers in agricultural production, technological innovation, education investment, and health protection. Therefore, the logarithm of per capita household income, the proportion of agricultural income, the proportion of operating income, and whether the family has financial assets are selected as the measurement indicators of financial capital.
- (4)
- Natural capital. For most rural families, natural capital refers to the land resources owned by the family [47], which is the basic element of agricultural production. Good natural capital can directly improve the efficiency and quality of agricultural production, thus increasing the income of farmers. In addition, a healthy natural environment is also crucial to maintaining ecological balance and ensuring agricultural sustainability. This part selects whether households contract cultivated land and whether households contract other resources (garden land, forest land, aquaculture water area) as indicators to measure natural capital.
- (5)
- Social capital. Social capital reflects the family’s position in the social relationship network and the range of social resources available, including the interaction and communication frequency of family members, as well as the closeness of their connections with all sectors of society [48]. This article chooses whether there are close families (families with various forms of mutual assistance frequently) and whether some family members work for bosses, doctors, teachers, staff of government departments or public institutions as indicators to measure social capital [49].
4. Empirical Results and Analysis
4.1. Analysis of Necessity
4.2. Conditional Configuration Analysis
4.3. Reliance on the New Rural Collective Economic Function Variables to Drive Common Prosperity
- The configuration path of economic function driving common prosperity (CR1). The configuration CR1 indicates that economic function is the core driving condition for the rural collective economy in fostering high-level common prosperity among rural farmers. In configuration CR1, regardless of whether farmers have financial capital or not, even if rural households include non-high-level human capital and non-high-level material capital in the core conditions, as long as the village collective economic organization has high economic function in the core conditions, high social function, high management ability, and high cultural function in the marginal conditions, and rural households have high natural capital and high social capital in the marginal conditions, it can still promote farmers to achieve common prosperity. This configuration reflects that while the economic function of the new rural collective economy is developing at a high level, its strong social functions, management functions, and cultural functions can also drive the improved development of village collectives and the sound development of the natural capital of farmers. Under the condition that the new rural collective economy has a strong economic function, it can improve agricultural efficiency and output, increase agricultural productivity, and optimize the income structure of farmers by integrating farmers’ natural capital and social capital and making effective use of natural resources. At the same time, social capital, including community networks and relationships, promotes knowledge exchange, mutual support, and access to markets, enhancing their competitiveness, while collective organizations provide support through technology, market access, and financial services. They create synergies to achieve sustainable development, raise income levels, strengthen resilience to economic and environmental risks, and promote shared prosperity for the farming communities.
- The configuration path of the collective economy linking high-level livelihood capital for households to achieve common prosperity (CR2). The configuration CR2 shows that the economic function of the rural collective economy matches high-level livelihood capital, which is the core driving condition for farmers to achieve high-level common prosperity. In configuration CR2, regardless of whether farmers have natural capital or not, even if the village collective includes non-high-level cultural functions in the marginal conditions, and rural households include non-high-level social capital in the marginal conditions, as long as the village collective economic organization has high economic functions in the core conditions, high social functions and high management capabilities in the marginal conditions, and rural households have a high level of human capital and material capital in the core conditions and a high level of financial capital in the marginal conditions, it can also promote rural households to achieve common prosperity. This configuration reflects that while the economic function of the new rural collective economy is developing at a high level, farmers with strong human capital, material capital, and financial capital can effectively use existing capital to improve their productivity and innovation ability. This does not only enhance the ability of farmers to participate in the market but also increases farmers’ income and improves their quality of life by improving product quality and production efficiency. In addition, strong human capital and material capital provide farmers with more opportunities to adapt to economic changes and withstand economic risks, playing a key role in promoting rural economic diversification and overall social well-being.
- The configuration path of social function and management function driving common prosperity (CR3, CR4). The configuration of CR3 and CR4 demonstrates that social and management functions are the core driving conditions for the rural collective economy to help farmers to attain high-level common prosperity. In configuration CR3, as long as the new rural collective economy has high social function and high management function in the core conditions, and rural households have a high level of human capital and social capital in the marginal conditions, even if the new rural collective economy includes non-high economic function and non-high cultural function in the marginal conditions, and rural households include a non-high level of physical capital and non-high level of natural capital in the core conditions and non-high levels of financial capital in the marginal conditions, it can also promote farmers to achieve common prosperity. In configuration CR4, as long as the new rural collective economy has high-level social functions and high-level management functions in the core conditions, high-level economic functions and high-level cultural functions in the marginal conditions, and rural households have high-level financial capital in the marginal conditions, even if the core conditions of rural households include non-high-level physical capital and non-high-level natural capital, marginal conditions include non-high-level human capital and non-high-level social capital, it still can help farmers achieve common prosperity.
4.4. Prosperity Reliance on the Household Livelihood Capital Variables to Drive Common Prosperity
- The configuration paths of natural capital driving common prosperity (CR5, CR6 and CR7). The configurations CR5, CR6, and CR7 reveal that high-level natural capital is the core driving condition for farmers in achieving common prosperity. These paths include CR5, CR6, and CR7. In configuration CR5, regardless of whether farmers have social capital, even if the four functions of the new rural collective economy are lacking, as long as farmers have high natural capital in the core conditions, and high human capital, high material capital, and high financial capital in the marginal conditions, it can still promote farmers to achieve common prosperity. In configuration CR6, regardless of whether farmers have financial capital, even if the four functions of the new rural collective economy are lacking, as long as farmers have high natural capital in the core conditions and high human capital, high material capital, and high social capital in the marginal conditions, it can help farmers to achieve common prosperity. In configuration CR7, as long as farmers have high natural capital in the core conditions, it can promote farmers to achieve common prosperity even if the farmers’ other livelihood capital and new rural collective economic functions are deficient. These three configurations reflect that when the economic function of the new rural collective economy is seriously missing, farmers can improve their living standards through traditional livelihoods by relying on high natural capital, so as to achieve common prosperity. In situations where rural collective economic organizations are underdeveloped, but farmers have strong natural capital, the effective use of these forms of natural capital is crucial to promote shared prosperity, and maximizing the economic potential of natural assets can lay the foundation for a more prosperous and resilient rural economy.
- 2.
- The configuration path of human capital and social capital driving common prosperity (CR8). Configuration CR8 indicates that high-level human and social capital are the core conditions for farmers to reach common prosperity. When economic and cultural functions of the new rural collective are seriously missing, farmers have high human capital and high social capital, which can also promote the farmers to achieve common prosperity. Through the introduction of social capital, farmers have a redistribution effect on the allocation of other social resources. Specifically, they make investment decisions through the characteristics of social capital, such as trust, risk sharing, and norms, and indirectly affect the allocation of household resources through its informality [57]. Strong social support networks and professional status can enhance the possibility of resource sharing and information exchange, provide additional support and assistance in the face of economic or other challenges, and help to provide more development opportunities, social support, and access to resources. At the same time, Sun [58] found that the richer the social capital, the stronger the willingness of farmers to participate in the improvement of the rural living environment, and the support and resources provided by social capital can help individuals overcome challenges and obstacles, thus encouraging them to pursue their goals more actively.
5. Conclusions and Policy Implications
5.1. Conclusions
5.2. Policy Implications
Author Contributions
Funding
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Lv, D.; Luo, S. The Policy System and Realization Path to Promote the Common Prosperity of Farmers and Rural Areas. Acad. J. Zhongzhou 2022, 44, 83–91. [Google Scholar]
- China Daily. Central No. 1 document: For the first time, it is clear what the “new rural collective economy” is and how to do it. China Collect. Econ. 2023, 39, 5. [Google Scholar]
- Pan, Q. Several Thoughts on Improving the Stock Rights of Rural Collective Assets: Based on a Survey of Zhejiang Province. Manag. Adm. Rural. Coop. 2023, 5, 28–29. [Google Scholar]
- Ma, K. Research on the Historical Evolution, Key Factors and Internal Mechanism of the Development of New Rural Collective Economy. Master’s Thesis, Yanan University, Yanan, China, 2024. [Google Scholar]
- Zhao, Y. On China’s Rural Collective Economy in the Past Seventy Years: Achievements and Experience. Stud. Mao Zedong Deng Xiaoping Theor. 2019, 40, 53–60+108–109. [Google Scholar]
- Yang, B.; Mu, X. Research on Rural Collective Economic Development and Rural Revitalization in New Era: Theoretical Mechanism, Real Predicament and Achieved Breakthrough. Agric. Econ. Manag. 2020, 11, 5–14. [Google Scholar]
- Yi, S.; Huo, Z.; Zhang, M.; Chen, F. An Empirical Study of New Rural Collective Economic Organization in Alleviating Relative Poverty among Farmers. Sustainability 2023, 15, 14126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Guo, X.; Wang, Q. A Multi-perspective Analysis on Rural Collective Economic Organization Governs Relative Poverty. Soc. Sci. Front. 2020, 43, 67–73. [Google Scholar]
- Wen, T.; Dong, X. Village Community Rationality: A New Perspective to Solve the Dilemma of “Three Rural Issues” and “Governance in Three Aspects”. J. CCPS 2010, 14, 20–23. [Google Scholar]
- Tang, L. Realization of Economic and Social Safeguard of Rural Collective under Background of Rural Revitalization-a Case Study on Tongxiang, Zhejiang. Guizhou Soc. Sci. 2020, 41, 143–150. [Google Scholar]
- Qiao, C.; Wang, J. The Path Innovation of Participation in Public Goods Supply by Rural Collective Economic Organizations: A Case Study of “Purchasing Reform” in Daning County. Chin. Rural Econ. 2020, 36, 22–34. [Google Scholar]
- Heng, X. Organization Isomorphism and Governance Embeddedness: How Rural Collective Economy Promotes the High Efficiency of Rural Governance—A Case Study of 13 Towns in Pengzhou City, Sichuan Province. Soc. Sci. Res. 2021, 43, 137–144. [Google Scholar]
- Yang, J.; Li, Y.; Li, T. Innovation of New Collective Economy and Rural Social Governance in Undeveloped Areas—Through the Comparison between Wang Jiabian and Tangyue. J. Beijing Univ. Technol. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2020, 20, 22–28. [Google Scholar]
- Lan, W. Analysis on Innovation of New Rural Collective Rconomic System. Soc. Sci. Guangxi 2009, 25, 38–40. [Google Scholar]
- Ni, K.; He, A.; Gao, M. Perspective on the “New” of the New Rural Collective Economy. Rural. Manag. 2022, 1, 21–23. [Google Scholar]
- Zhao, Y. Cooperative Economy, Collective Economy, New Collective Economy: Comparison and Optimization. Econ. Rev. J. 2021, 36, 20–28. [Google Scholar]
- CPC Central Committee and State Council. Opinions of the CPC Central Committee and the State Council on Steadily Advancing the Reform of the Rural Collective Property Rights System; People Publishing House: Beijing, China, 2017; p. 1. [Google Scholar]
- Zhu, Y.; Chen, W. Research on the Development of New Rural Collective Economy with Chinese Characteristics of Agricultural Modernization. Seeker 2010, 30, 12–14. [Google Scholar]
- Zhou, J.; Zhang, W. Historical Evolution of the Concept and Connotation of Common Prosperity. Jiangxi Soc. Sci. 2022, 42, 15–21. [Google Scholar]
- Li, J. Common Prosperity: Concept Discrimination, Centennial Exploration and Modernization Goal. Reform 2021, 34, 12–21. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, Y.; Huo, Z.; Li, D.; Zhang, M. Evaluation of Common Prosperity Level and Regional Difference Analysis along the Yangtze River Economic Belt. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 11851. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Du, Z. The Source of Common Prosperity Thought and the Path Choice of Farmers’ Rural Realization of Common Prosperity. Econ. Rev. J. 2022, 38, 21–29. [Google Scholar]
- Tan, C.; Wu, H.; Peng, Y. Research on the Impact of Rural Labor Mobility on the Common Prosperity of Farmers. Chin. J. Agric. Resour. Reg. Plann. 2023, 44, 223–231. [Google Scholar]
- Shu, Z.; Zeng, Y. Developing New Rural Collective Economy: Realistic Dilemma and Possible Path. J. Harbin Inst. Tech. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2022, 24, 144–152. [Google Scholar]
- Zheng, Y. Building the Theory of Collective Action of Rural Communities with Strong Endogenous Development Ability—Based on the Collective Accumulation and Coordination Mechanism of Developed Village and Hollow Village Communities. Stud. Marx. 2017, 35, 63–69. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, Z. Research on the Development of New Rural Collective Economy from the Perspective of Common Prosperity. Master’s Thesis, Shanxi University of Finance & Economics, Taiyuan, China, 2024. [Google Scholar]
- Lu, Q.; Yang, Y. Can the Reform of Rural Collective Property Rights System Promote the Development of Rural Collective Economy? An Empirical Test Based on the Survey Data of China’s Rural Revitalization. Chin. Rural Econ. 2022, 38, 84–103. [Google Scholar]
- Ma, L. The Development of New Rural Collective Economy and Reorgnization of Rural Society—Based on a Case of Tangyue Village in Guizhou. Acad. J. Zhongzhou 2021, 43, 66–72. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, M.; Chen, W.; Lan, H. Why Do Chinese Enterprises Completely Acquire Foreign High-Tech Enterprises—A Fuzzy Set Qualitative Comparative Analysis(fsQCA) Based on 94 Cases. China Ind. Econ. 2019, 37, 117–135. [Google Scholar]
- Rangin, C.C. Redesigning Social Inquiry: Fuzzy Sets and Beyond; The University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2009; p. 15. [Google Scholar]
- Du, Y.; Jia, L. Configurational Perspective and Qualitative Comparative Analysis: The New Way of Management Research. J. Manag. World 2017, 33, 155–167. [Google Scholar]
- Duan, S.; Huang, Y.; Long, W. The Influencing Factors and Realization Path of the Development of New Rural Collective Economy in the Underdeveloped Areas of Western China: An Analysis Based on fsQCA Method. J. Yunnan Agric. Uni. (Soc. Sci.) 2023, 17, 38–45. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, H.; Qu, B. Analysis on the Influencing Factors of Village-level Collective Economy Development Based on Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) Method. Chin. J. Agric. Resour. Reg. Plann. 2018, 39, 205–213. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, Y.; Song, Y.; Wang, F. Read Common Prosperity; Citic Press: Beijing, China, 2022; p. 114. [Google Scholar]
- Xi, J. Holding High the Great Banner of Socialism with Chinese Characteristics and Striving Together to Build a Modern Socialist Country in an All-Round Way—Report at the 20th National Congress of the Communist Party of China; People Publishing House: Beijing, China, 2022; pp. 22–23. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, P.; Qian, T.; Huang, X. The Connotation, Realization Path and Measurement Method of Common Prosperity for All. J. Manag. World 2021, 37, 117–129. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, M.; Wang, X. Measurement of Common Prosperity of Chinese Rural Households Using Graded Response Models: Evidence from Zhejiang Province. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2023, 20, 4602. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, H. Construction and Empirical Research of Evaluation Index System of Common Prosperity. Master’s Thesis, Lanzhou University of Finance and Economics, Lanzhou, China, 2023. [Google Scholar]
- Zhou, Y.; Hu, L. Can the Chinese Farmers’ Specialized Cooperatives Realize the Union of the Weak?—Comparative Analysis Based on Chinese and Japanese Practices. Chin. Rural Econ. 2016, 32, 30–38. [Google Scholar]
- Feng, F.; Liao, X. Functional Study of Rural Collective Economy. Seeker 2010, 30, 46–47. [Google Scholar]
- Chen, X. Functional Analysis of Rural Collective Economic Organization. Rural. Manag. 2022, 7, 22–23. [Google Scholar]
- Lv, X. Analysis of the Economic, Social and Ecological Functions of the Rural Collective Economic Organizations. China Townsh. Enterp. Account. 2008, 16, 4–6. [Google Scholar]
- Kuang, F.; Jin, J.; He, R.; Ning, J.; Wan, X. Farmers’ Livelihood Risks, Livelihood Assets and Adaptation Strategies in Rugao City, China. J. Environ. Manag. 2020, 264, 110463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ding, S.; Zhang, Y.; Ma, Z. Research on Changes of Livelihood Capabilities of Rural Households Encountered by Land Acquisition: Based on Improvement of Sustainable Livelihood Approach. Issues Agric. Econ. 2016, 37, 25–34. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, S.; Yang, X.; Luo, C. The Rural Left-Behind Women’s Livelihoods Strategy under the Pressure of Price Rising: Livelihood Diversification. China Rural Surv. 2014, 35, 38–48. [Google Scholar]
- Wu, Y. Poor Mountain Farmers Livelihood Capital Impact on Livelihoods Strategy Research: Based on the Survey Data Pingwu and Nanjiang County of Sichuan Province. Issues Agric. Econ. 2016, 37, 88–94. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, K.; Liu, H.; Zhao, B. The Practice and Countermeasures of Increasing the Reform of Farmers’ Property Income in Sichuan Province. Rural Econ. 2016, 34, 65–70. [Google Scholar]
- Wu, X.; Jin, H. The Changes of Farmers’ Livelihood Strategies and the Influencing Factors from the Perspective of the Livelihood Capital: Based on the four periods of the CFPS Tracking Data. Res. Agric. Mod. 2021, 42, 941–952. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, J. Research on the Impact of Digital Financial Development on Rural Household Livelihood. Ph.D. Thesis, Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences, Beijing, China, 2021. [Google Scholar]
- Schneider, C.Q.; Wagemann, C. Set-Theoretic Methods for the Social Sciences: A Guide to Qualitative Comparative Analysis; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Fiss, P.C. Building Better Causal Theories: A fuzzy Set Approach to Typologies in Organization Research. Acad. Manag. J. 2011, 54, 393–420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ragin, C.C.; Fiss, P.C. Net Effects Analysis Versus Configurational Analysis: An Empirical Demonstration; The University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, Z.; Zhou, L. Rural Land Right Verification, “Separation of Ownership Rights” and Revenue-Increasing Effect—Based on the Dual Perspectives of Collective and Peasant Households. J. Shanxi Univ. Financ. Econ. 2024, 46, 40–53. [Google Scholar]
- Zhu, Z.; Ma, L.; Zong, Y. Research on Differences in Farmers’ Well-being and Enhancement Paths from Subjective and Objective Perspective. J. Guizhou Norm. Univ. (Nat. Sci.) 2024, 42, 39–52+134. [Google Scholar]
- Wei, H.; Lv, L. Research on the Path of Rural Ecological Civilization Construction under the Concept of Life Community. J. Xi’an Jiaotong Univ. (Soc. Sci.) 2024. accepted. [Google Scholar]
- Gu, J.; Zheng, Y. Study on the Linkage Effect Measurement and Driving Force of Beibu Gulf Urban Agglomeration Based on Green innovation System. Resour. Dev. Market. 2024. accepted. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, Q. Mechanism of Social Capital Affect Income: From the Perspective of Resource Allocation Function of Social Capital. Econ. Probl. 2017, 39, 35–41. [Google Scholar]
- Sun, Q. Study on the Influencing Factors of the Willingness of Tibetan Peasant Households to Participate in the Improvement of Rural Living Environment. J. Ecol. Rural Environ. 2019, 35, 976–985. [Google Scholar]
- Liu, G.; Liu, H.; Qi, X. Research on the Historical Evolution and Development Direction of the Public Service Function Undertaken by Rural Collective Economic Organizations. J. Shihezi Univ. (Philos. Soc. Sci.) 2023, 37, 42–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Level-One Variable | Level-Two Variable | Level-Three Variable | Code |
---|---|---|---|
Wealth level | Economic income level | Household incomes per capita | E1 |
Satisfaction with the increase in family income | E2 | ||
Satisfaction with family income | E3 | ||
Satisfaction with the stability of family income | E4 | ||
Satisfaction with the stability of job opportunity | E5 | ||
Spiritual affluence level | Satisfaction with library service in the village | C1 | |
Satisfaction with rural cultural activities | C2 | ||
Satisfaction with rural spiritual life | C3 | ||
Service satisfaction when traveling | C4 | ||
Cultural confidence of rural residents | C5 | ||
Sharing level | Medical and educational level | Satisfaction with the educational gap between urban and rural areas | M1 |
Satisfaction with the teaching quality of their children’s schools | M2 | ||
Satisfaction with the current treatment of serious diseases | M3 | ||
Satisfaction with the serious disease reimbursement ratio of the resident medical insurance | M4 | ||
Satisfaction with commercial health insurance | M5 | ||
Satisfaction with each physical examination | M6 | ||
Pension security level | Satisfaction with the rural pension insurance money received | O1 | |
Satisfaction with rural home care services | O2 | ||
Service satisfaction of social institutions for the aged | O3 | ||
Service satisfaction of commercial pension insurance | O4 | ||
Sustainability level | Ecological environment level | Satisfaction with garbage disposal in the village | Y1 |
Satisfaction with sanitary toilet construction | Y2 | ||
Satisfaction with water pollution, air pollution, and noise pollution in the village | Y3 | ||
Public construction level | Satisfaction with express service in the village | H1 | |
Satisfaction with banking service in the village | H2 | ||
Satisfaction with road traffic conditions in the village | H3 | ||
Satisfaction with public security in the village | H4 | ||
Satisfaction with construction of sports and fitness facilities | H5 |
Level-Two Variable | Code | a | b1 | b2 | b3 | b4 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Economic income level | E2 | 1.787 | −3.431 | −2.003 | −0.277 | 1.706 |
E3 | 1.948 | −3.55 | −1.936 | −0.296 | 1.63 | |
E4 | 1.948 | −3.334 | −2.011 | −0.33 | 1.667 | |
E5 | 2.043 | −3.456 | −1.973 | −0.33 | 1.563 | |
Spiritual affluence level | C1 | 1.996 | −3.062 | −1.992 | −0.284 | 1.591 |
C2 | 3.342 | −2.811 | −1.849 | −0.38 | 1.08 | |
C3 | 3.569 | −2.647 | −1.873 | −0.373 | 1.069 | |
C4 | 3.002 | −2.954 | −1.843 | −0.319 | 1.122 | |
C5 | 3.632 | −3.06 | −1.915 | −0.408 | 1.021 | |
Medical and educational level | M1 | 1.698 | −2.839 | −1.534 | 0.04 | 1.967 |
M2 | 1.789 | −3.903 | −2.32 | −0.349 | 1.799 | |
M3 | 1.908 | −3.732 | −2.207 | −0.407 | 1.496 | |
M4 | 1.803 | −3.046 | −2.239 | −0.511 | 1.521 | |
M5 | 1.503 | −3.463 | −2.049 | 0.228 | 2.211 | |
Pension security level | O1 | 1.864 | −3.164 | −1.958 | −0.29 | 1.714 |
O2 | 2.118 | −2.872 | −2.073 | −0.259 | 1.688 | |
O3 | 2.063 | −3.036 | −1.992 | −0.206 | 1.735 | |
O4 | 1.713 | −3.397 | −2.146 | 0.215 | 1.916 | |
Ecological environment level | Y1 | 2.594 | −2.749 | −1.826 | −0.456 | 1.279 |
Y2 | 2.775 | −2.396 | −1.642 | −0.313 | 1.218 | |
Y3 | 2.726 | −2.409 | −1.616 | −0.426 | 1.237 | |
Public construction level | H1 | 2.352 | −2.883 | −1.976 | −0.438 | 1.297 |
H2 | 2.406 | −2.934 | −2.075 | −0.482 | 1.33 | |
H3 | 2.63 | −2.964 | −1.956 | −0.523 | 1.165 | |
H4 | 2.7 | −2.864 | −2.022 | −0.605 | 1.087 | |
H5 | 2.692 | −2.721 | −1.901 | −0.343 | 1.291 |
Condition Variable | Measurement Index | Definition of Indicator | Weight of Entropy Method (%) |
---|---|---|---|
Economic function | Increase total income | The effect of rural collective economic organization on increasing the total income of farmers (1–5) | 41.171 |
Increase operating income | The effect of rural collective economic organization on increasing farmers’ operating income (1–5) | 19.676 | |
Increase wage income | The effect of rural collective economic organizations on increasing farmers’ wage income (1–5) | 19.478 | |
Increase dividend income | The effect of rural collective economic organization on increasing farmers’ dividend income (1–5) | 19.675 | |
Cultural function | Rural cultural activities | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in carrying out rural cultural activities (1–5) | 25.274 |
Propagandize the new style of rural civilization | The effect of the rural collective economic organization in propagandizing the new style of rural civilization (1–5) | 24.916 | |
Propagandize rural healthy life | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in propagandizing rural healthy life (1–5) | 25.125 | |
Rural cohesion of spiritual emotion | The effect of rural collective economic organization on rural cohesion of spiritual emotion (1–5) | 24.685 | |
Social function | Rural hardship subsidies | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in increasing farmers’ hardship subsidies (1–5) | 10.945 |
Rural medical assistance | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in carrying out rural medical assistance (1–5) | 25.959 | |
Rural mutual assistance for the aged | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in carrying out rural mutual assistance for the aged (1–5) | 27.338 | |
Rural subsistence relief | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in carrying out rural subsistence relief (1–5) | 10.757 | |
Rural education subsidies | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in carrying out rural education subsidies (1–5) | 25.001 | |
Management function | Rural infrastructure construction | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in carrying out rural infrastructure construction (1–5) | 22.229 |
Rural public services | The effect of rural collective economic organizations in developing rural public services (1–5) | 54.714 | |
Build ecologically beautiful villages | The effect of rural collective economic organization in the construction of ecological beautiful countryside (1–5) | 23.057 |
Condition Variable | Measurement Index | Definition of Indicator | Weight of Entropy Method (%) |
---|---|---|---|
Human capital | The educational level of the householder | Householder with high school education or above = 1; otherwise = 0 | 40.6 |
Whether the family has college students | Home with college students = 1; otherwise = 0 | 42.33 | |
Health status of the householder | “Relatively healthy” or “very healthy” for the householder = 1; otherwise = 0 | 6.46 | |
Labor burden coefficient | (Total household number-workforce number)/workforce number | 10.61 | |
Material capital | Vehicle | Having a car or van at home = 1; otherwise = 0 | 7.57 |
Farm machinery | Home with larger agricultural machinery = 1; otherwise = 0 | 33.37 | |
Housing area | The housing area is higher than the average housing area in Zhejiang Province = 1; otherwise = 0 | 59.06 | |
Finance capital | Ln Total per capita household income | Take the logarithm of total household income per capita | 2.59 |
The proportion of agricultural income | The proportion of the household agricultural income in the total income | 38.87 | |
The proportion of operating income | The proportion of the household operating income in the total income | 53.12 | |
Financial assets | Financial assets such as deposits, stocks, and bonds = 1; otherwise = 0 | 5.42 | |
Natural capital | Cultivated land | Contract land at home =1; otherwise =0 | 21.87 |
Garden land, forest land, aquaculture water area | Home has contracted garden land, forest land or aquaculture water area = 1; Otherwise = 0 | 78.13 | |
Social capital | Close family | Families with frequent forms of mutual assistance = 1; otherwise = 0 | 13.79 |
Working status of the family members | Someone in the family is (boss, doctor, teacher, staff of government departments or institutions) = 1; otherwise = 0 | 86.21 |
Antecedent Variables | Consistency | Coverage | Non-Set Antecedent Variable | Consistency | Coverage |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Economic function | 0.622 | 0.635 | ~Economic function | 0.643 | 0.704 |
Social function | 0.637 | 0.644 | ~Social function | 0.680 | 0.752 |
Management function | 0.638 | 0.644 | ~Management function | 0.661 | 0.732 |
Cultural function | 0.652 | 0.664 | ~Cultural function | 0.678 | 0.742 |
Human capital | 0.664 | 0.688 | ~Human capital | 0.601 | 0.646 |
Material capital | 0.691 | 0.670 | ~Material capital | 0.582 | 0.675 |
Finance capital | 0.576 | 0.611 | ~Finance capital | 0.667 | 0.701 |
Natural capital | 0.660 | 0.729 | ~Natural capital | 0.581 | 0.588 |
Social capital | 0.628 | 0.656 | ~Social capital | 0.641 | 0.684 |
Configuration | CR1 | CR2 | CR3 | CR4 | CR5 | CR6 | CR7 | CR8 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Economic function | ⊗ | ● | ⊗ | |||||
Social function | ⊗ | ⊗ | ⊗ | ⊗ | ||||
Management function | ● | ● | ⊗ | ⊗ | ⊗ | ⊗ | ||
Cultural function | ● | ⊗ | ⊗ | ● | ⊗ | ⊗ | ⊗ | |
Human capital | ● | ⊗ | ● | ● | ⊗ | |||
Material capital | ● | ● | ⊗ | ⊗ | ||||
Finance capital | ● | ⊗ | ● | ● | ⊗ | ⊗ | ||
Natural capital | ● | ⊗ | ||||||
Social capital | ● | ● | ⊗ | ● | ⊗ | |||
Consistency | 0.941 | 0.904 | 0.952 | 0.956 | 0.95 | 0.969 | 0.962 | 0.938 |
Native coverage | 0.226 | 0.27 | 0.165 | 0.201 | 0.242 | 0.232 | 0.178 | 0.187 |
Net coverage | 0.039 | 0.076 | 0.019 | 0.03 | 0.024 | 0.022 | 0.029 | 0.038 |
Total consistency | 0.911 | |||||||
Total coverage | 0.606 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Yi, S.; Zhang, M.; Huo, Z.; Mao, Y. The Configuration Path of the New Rural Collective Economy to Promote the Common Prosperity of Farmers: Based on Qualitative Comparative Analysis Method and the Rural Cases in Zhejiang, China. Systems 2024, 12, 256. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12070256
Yi S, Zhang M, Huo Z, Mao Y. The Configuration Path of the New Rural Collective Economy to Promote the Common Prosperity of Farmers: Based on Qualitative Comparative Analysis Method and the Rural Cases in Zhejiang, China. Systems. 2024; 12(7):256. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12070256
Chicago/Turabian StyleYi, Shu, Mei Zhang, Zenghui Huo, and Yating Mao. 2024. "The Configuration Path of the New Rural Collective Economy to Promote the Common Prosperity of Farmers: Based on Qualitative Comparative Analysis Method and the Rural Cases in Zhejiang, China" Systems 12, no. 7: 256. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12070256
APA StyleYi, S., Zhang, M., Huo, Z., & Mao, Y. (2024). The Configuration Path of the New Rural Collective Economy to Promote the Common Prosperity of Farmers: Based on Qualitative Comparative Analysis Method and the Rural Cases in Zhejiang, China. Systems, 12(7), 256. https://doi.org/10.3390/systems12070256