Next Article in Journal
Regional Landslide Hazard and Risk Assessment Considering Landslide Spatial Aggregation and Hydrological Slope Units
Previous Article in Journal
A Combined Approach of Heat Map Confusion and Local Differential Privacy for the Anonymization of Mobility Data
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Transformation of Demand-Response Aggregator Operations in Future US Electricity Markets: A Review of Technologies and Open Research Areas with Game Theory

by
Styliani I. Kampezidou
* and
Dimitri N. Mavris
Aerospace Systems Design Laboratory, School of Aerospace Engineering, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA 30332, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Appl. Sci. 2025, 15(14), 8066; https://doi.org/10.3390/app15148066
Submission received: 30 May 2025 / Revised: 8 July 2025 / Accepted: 17 July 2025 / Published: 20 July 2025

Abstract

The decarbonization of electricity generation by 2030 and the realization of a net-zero economy by 2050 are central to the United States’ climate strategy. However, large-scale renewable integration introduces operational challenges, including extreme ramping, unsafe dispatch, and price volatility. This review investigates how demand–response (DR) aggregators and distributed loads can support these climate goals while addressing critical operational challenges. We hypothesize that current DR aggregator frameworks fall short in the areas of distributed load operational flexibility, scalability with the number of distributed loads (prosumers), prosumer privacy preservation, DR aggregator and prosumer competition, and uncertainty management, limiting their potential to enable large-scale prosumer participation. Using a systematic review methodology, we evaluate existing DR aggregator and prosumer frameworks through the proposed FCUPS criteria—flexibility, competition, uncertainty quantification, privacy, and scalability. The main results highlight significant gaps in current frameworks: limited support for decentralized operations; inadequate privacy protections for prosumers; and insufficient capabilities for managing competition, uncertainty, and flexibility at scale. We conclude by identifying open research directions, including the need for game-theoretic and machine learning approaches that ensure privacy, scalability, and robust market participation. Addressing these gaps is essential to shape future research agendas and to enable DR aggregators to contribute meaningfully to US climate targets.

1. Introduction

According to NASA’s Goddard Institute for Space Studies (GISS) [1], the average global temperature on Earth has increased by about 0.8° Celsius (1.4° Fahrenheit) since 1880. Two-thirds of the warming has occurred since 1975, while the consequences have been catastrophic for food and water security [2], the population living within 100 km of the coast, and international peace and security due to the competition for resources. The aforementioned climate change concerns in combination with concerns about the dependency on decreasing oil resources and political games (i.e., 1973 embargo by Saudi Arabia against the USA, which led to a 300% oil price increase) have directed the USA’s attention away from conventional fuels. Specifically, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) proposed the Clean Power Plan (CPP) policy in 2014, which suggests reducing carbon dioxide (CO2) by 32% in the years 2005–2030 and reducing coal plants’ CO2 emissions, increasing renewable integration, and investing in energy-saving programs [3].
Although multiple measures have been taken to reduce CO2 emissions and achieve the CPP policy goals, the climate change crisis continues to persist due to an increase in energy generation emissions in the 2020s in order to cover the increasing global energy demand. Therefore, the CPP policy goals were revised to the more aggressive 2030 generation decarbonization and 2050 net-zero economy goals. Specifically, the International Energy Agency (IEA) set four pillars for action in the 2020s [4], which, if implemented, will be sufficient to keep the global temperature increase under 1.7 °C by 2100, i.e., aligning with the net-zero emissions scenario. These pillars concern [5] deforestation reduction by 2030 and land use decarbonization; the reduction in non-CO2 emissions; the use of carbon capture, utilization, and storage (CCUS); and the decarbonization of electricity generation by 2030. IEA has summarized the importance of revising existing market instruments, mechanisms, and regulations to achieve the 2030 and 2050 goals [6], knowing that, by 2050, the global electricity demand is expected to more than double compared to 2020. These revisions include the following:
  • Deploying significantly more renewable resources and completing the demand coverage with low-carbon resources, such as nuclear and hydrogen, is important [7]. Battery storage and DR are not considered as additional generation capacity but rather important enablers if sufficiently incentivized due to the introduced flexibility [8].
  • Incentivizing clean technology market players with effective investment frameworks, carbon pricing, and other decarbonization instruments.
  • Improving market price signals to better represent the time and geographical value of the energy.
  • Ensuring that hedging with long-term contracts does not harm the short-term market dispatch.
  • Offering decarbonization financial instruments that help reduce the long recoupment periods of wind and solar to attract new private investment.
  • Incorporating distributed energy resources via aggregators to increase flexibility and resilience in systems with high-penetration renewable resources and defer system upgrade costs. Digitization via metering devices is necessary to increase visibility and ensure fair compensation with adequate customer privacy.
  • Facilitating battery storage investments with taxation and network tariffs that appropriately recognize its role as a flexibility provider, ensuring that it is not charged twice as a consumer and as a generator, and compensating for its fast response and flexibility services.
  • Rewarding capacities that can respond in periods of high system stress to reduce price volatility.
  • Protecting retail customers against market risks, natural gas price peaks, and extreme weather phenomena.
  • Planning system expansion to support low-carbon resources (including DR).
As a result of the CPP, 2030, and 2050 policies, the US energy mix has changed significantly in the last decade, with oil and coal resources progressively being replaced by renewable and natural gas-based generation (less polluting than oil and coal; backs up intermittent renewable sources) [9,10]. However, over-investment in renewable resources has introduced manufacturing pollution (renewable devices), natural-gas-related pollution from backing up renewable sources [9,10,11,12], and operational issues. In California (CAISO), the duck curve [13,14] indicates that the increasing trend in solar panel investment can be threatening to the system’s reliability and efficiency for two reasons. First, renewable over-generation can compromise the system’s safe dispatch due to uncertainty in generated power, lack of control, increased marginal prices (aging network congestion [15]), potential blackouts (2001 California crisis [16]), and negative marginal prices (renewable over-supply [17,18,19]). Second, ramping, i.e., sudden renewable production changes, can cause dispatching difficulties since conventional generators’ ramping is limited and they have voltage support issues [20] due to the lack of sufficient reactive power in solar and most wind farms [20].
Similar problems have been observed or are expected to happen in other systems, such as in Irish systems [20], ERCOT, MISO, and NYISO [21]. With the aforementioned operational and investment issues related to renewable resources and battery storage in the CAISO and other US markets, the incorporation of the distributed load, i.e., commercial and residential buildings with a complex net load consisting of demand, local generation, and storage, in DR has been increasingly gaining interest for CO2 emission reduction and grid operation support (by the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, also known as FERC) [22]. As distributed loads may be a mix of different loads, battery storage, and generation, their contribution to CO2 reduction, as well as grid flexibility, will be vital to the 2030 and 2050 goals. However, their large-scale integration via aggregators is difficult to implement due to the load mix complexity behind the meter, aggregator operations’ scalability, prosumer privacy, and uncertainty quantification. Therefore, the need for aggregator operations with the aforementioned characteristics is immediate.
Related Works: Although previous review papers have provided overviews of demand–response (DR) programs [23,24,25,26,27], DR frameworks [23,26,28], DR benefits for systems penetrated by renewable resources [24,29,30], ancillary services offered by DR [27,28,31], customer response to DR programs [24], DR pilot studies [26], demand-side resources [23] and methods [31], potential savings from energy management systems [32], blockchain technologies [33,34,35,36], or local trading methods [37], a critical view on the role that distributed loads will play in future US electricity markets is missing not only in terms of energy savings, reliability, and flexibility but also in terms of the scalability of aggregator operations and the privacy of the prosumer in a future fully digitized smart grid. This review paper provides a holistic investigation of existing DR aggregator and prosumer technologies and frameworks, and proposes future directions for research that are compatible with five identified criteria. Limited related work exists in terms of critical review papers for game-theoretic frameworks on DR aggregators and distributed loads. For example, Ref. [38] covers a breadth of game-theoretic frameworks without proposing a unified evaluation framework to guide researchers on how to facilitate the large-scale and safe integration of distributed loads for the 2030 and 2050 goals. Our paper introduces and uses five evaluation criteria, including scalability, which evaluates the computational complexity of existing frameworks; this is something that is missing from [38], which primarily focuses on modeling. Other review papers in game theory with a scope broader than that of the DR aggregator exist [39,40] but are not directly relevant.
The contributions of this review are threefold. First, a thorough overview and evaluation of existing energy efficiency solutions and technologies for the distributed load are provided, including energy management systems and market-based DR via aggregators. The overview includes the operational and privacy challenges of the distributed load due to its complex nature and the existing state of its integration in different markets via DR aggregators. Second, a critical analysis of the existing DR aggregator and prosumer framework literature in terms of five important gaps is carried out: flexibility, competition, uncertainty, privacy, and scalability (FCUPS framework). These evaluation criteria support the safe and large-scale integration of distributed loads into future US electricity markets and facilitate the 2030 and 2050 goals. Third, future work directions are provided for researchers to develop FCUPS-compatible frameworks that allow for the safe and large-scale integration of distributed loads via DR aggregators in future US electricity markets.
The rest of this paper is organized according to Figure 1. Section 2 analyzes the potential for energy savings and grid reliability improvement from distributed loads in the US and provides an overview of energy-efficient technologies, with a focus on DR aggregators. In Section 3, available frameworks for the DR aggregator’s operation are investigated in terms of flexibility, reliability, uncertainty, scalability, and the consideration of prosumer’s privacy, and missing framework capabilities are identified. This section summarizes open research questions for researchers and market policymakers that will transform the US electricity markets and help achieve the 2030 and 2050 goals.

2. Transformation of Future US Electricity Markets by Distributed Load and Demand-Response Aggregators

2.1. Overview of Energy Efficient Technologies for Distributed Load

In the USA, the second most polluting country in terms of CO2 after China (Figure 2a), the breakdown of electricity usage by sector shows great potential for energy and CO2 savings in residential and commercial buildings (distributed loads), which are responsible for 32% of the total CO2 emissions in the USA (Figure 2b). Several technologies for energy savings and grid support from the distributed load exist today, such as participation in building energy efficiency programs [41], which have increased rapidly over the past 10 years by performing structural upgrades for indoor heating, ventilation, and air conditioning (HVAC) (up to 55% energy can be saved [42]); and investing in smart energy management systems, efficient lighting, sensors [43], and other controls [41]. By investing in these technologies, the USA can save up to 16% of CO2 emissions by 2050 compared to the 2005 reference. Additionally, another 62% of CO2 savings is possible with renewable technologies applied on buildings [44,45]. Table 1 summarizes energy-efficient solutions in buildings.
The large-scale integration of such energy-efficient technologies can provide energy savings and grid reliability towards the 2030 and 2050 goals. However, such integration introduces several operational challenges due to the distributed load’s complex nature, which is analyzed next.

2.2. Complexity of Distributed Load Mix in Future US Electricity Markets

Prosumers (distributed load) may already have (or will have in the future) diverse load characteristics and, therefore, may require different contracts or pricing schemes (Figure 1 in [67]), some of which have been tested in pilot programs [31]. The prosumer’s load synthesis is better explained by Figure 3. Five load sub-types are identified:
  • Storable load (i.e., electric cars, batteries);
  • Shiftable load (i.e., dishwasher);
  • Curtailable load (i.e., lighting);
  • Self-generation (i.e., solar panels);
  • Baseload, which is not curtailable and therefore not appropriate for DR [68].
The customer may choose if they wish to control their load independently via an energy management system or if they wish to transfer the control of their mixed load to the DR aggregator [69]. However, with the increasing penetration of renewable resources and storage in the load mix, the role of the DR aggregator has become more challenging, not only because of the millions of constraints but also due to the data coupling from a prosumer’s meter. The customer’s load mix shown in Figure 3 is measured as one net demand, and hence, existing forecasting methods for individual load sub-types do not apply [70].
Figure 3. Distributed load mixture [71]. CHP stands for combined heat and power, and IT stands for information technology.
Figure 3. Distributed load mixture [71]. CHP stands for combined heat and power, and IT stands for information technology.
Applsci 15 08066 g003
The challenge of managing thousands/millions of prosumers with different load types, device constraints, demand and generation forecasting, and coupled behind-the-meter data creates the need for decentralized DR aggregator operations and for prosumers to schedule their own operations via an energy management system under the coordination of the DR aggregator while having more control over their own data privacy from local sensors and meters (open research questions on distributed load privacy, DR aggregators, and distributed load scalability are provided in Section 3.7). This necessity will be investigated in Section 3, where gaps in the literature and research questions will be addressed properly for the future work of the interested researcher and policymaker. Meanwhile, the next section will introduce energy management systems for distributed loads and emphasize their role in energy efficiency and grid reliability.

2.3. Energy Management Systems for Distributed Load Complexity Management

Energy management systems can manage demands in distributed loads based on optimization algorithms; energy production forecasting from distributed resources, and appliances; and energy storage control [72]. For a distributed load that participates in the wholesale DR market through a DR aggregator [73,74], such energy management systems can schedule appliance and device operations to match with the new demand bid submitted into the market. In other cases, the energy management system responds directly to price signals from the local utility [75]. The related terminology includes Home Energy Management Systems (HEMSs) for residential buildings and Building Energy Management Systems (BEMSs) for commercial buildings. These systems optimize the total operation cost, and in some cases, they also maximize user satisfaction. For examples of implementations, see Table 2.
Energy management systems utilize sensors that receive environmental, biomedical, or device usage signals and an associated controller that makes decisions to modify a device’s demand so that an optimal result is achieved, such as energy efficiency, occupant’s thermal comfort, occupant’s visual comfort, or indoor air quality [83]. Table 3 summarizes sensing technologies and applications in building device control for energy savings. Energy management systems may also consider sensor input to schedule the day-ahead demand or to make demand modifications in real time. Specifically, when bidding into the day-ahead market (DAM), an initial demand schedule may be derived for the prosumer, but due to multiple uncertainties, this demand may slightly vary in real time when the day-ahead demand is realized. Therefore, real-time sensor inputs, such as the occupancy state of a room or building, may become real-time suggestions made in energy management systems that modify the operation of appliances, such as lights and HVAC [43], in order to avoid large deviations from the day-ahead demand bid and associated market costs and penalties; this is carried out if the real-time pricing (spot market) is higher than the day-ahead demand for some hour of the day and the prosumer demand has increased for that hour.
The current literature in energy management systems for the distributed load does not consider integration with the prosumer–aggregator game via its pricing signals, as will be better explained in Section 3, and therefore, each prosumer’s day-ahead demand bid is not tested for feasibility according to the prosumer’s schedule, i.e., whether the demand bid is feasible and optimal for the prosumer’s load mix (Section 2.2), leading to potential spot-market-imposed fines due to the day-ahead versus real-time demand discrepancies. This observation leads to the open research questions outlined in Section 3.7, which are related to the distributed load’s HEMS/BEMS flexibility; its competition with the DR aggregator and other prosumers; uncertainty around the day-ahead demand considered by HEMS/BEMS; prosumer’s preferences or personally identifiable (PI) information collected from the distributed load’s HEMS/BEMS; and scalability when multiple device constraints, load types, and forecasting signals are present within HEMS/BEMS or when multiple distributed loads are integrated under the same DR aggregator via their HEMS/BEMS. The next section will introduce market-based DR programs via DR aggregators for the distributed load and emphasize the benefits of market participation for CO2 emission reduction and grid reliability support.
The next section will explain the current operating mechanism of the DR aggregator, the plethora of information it requires from the distributed load, which may include personally identifiable (PI) data, and the challenges associated with future DR aggregator operations in US electricity markets.

2.4. The Intricate Role of Demand-Response Aggregators in Large-Scale Distributed Load Integration with Safety

DR plays a strategic role in improving the safety and reliability of power systems from a demand-side management perspective [67]. According to [30,69], DR can carry out the following:
  • Reduce CO2 emissions;
  • Postpone or prevent the construction of new power plants;
  • Improve the power system’s reliability and security (ramping and reshaping demand [24,95]).
DR is a type of demand-side management [65,96] and includes market-based DR programs that are available via DR aggregators, which allow the distributed load to access higher profits than utility-based DR programs (see Table 4 for a list of US DR aggregators). These programs are very efficient for energy savings, monetary rewards, grid reliability, and overall market performance [95]. DR loads are increasingly participating in different markets (Table 5), and based on PJM, their main role is that of a capacity resource [97]. The main disadvantage of market-based DR is that although investments in market-based DR are growing (slide 34 in [98]), the total payments are not significantly changing, leading to payment reductions per player over time (diminishing marginal returns). According to a Brattle study [99], “the nationwide benefits of load flexibility could exceed $15 billion per year by 2030 and are driven by avoided investment in generation capacity, reduced energy costs, geographically-targeted transmission and distribution investment deferral, and the provision of ancillary services”. However, it is important to consider that the implementation of DR comes with some overhead cost (administrative, incentive, and enabling technologies like telemetry, hardware, software, communication systems, etc.). Another study performed by FERC for the California grid estimates the total benefits from DR across the 3 years of 2012–2014 to be slightly over USD 50 million, and the costs are estimated to be slightly over USD 40 million [100]. The same study emphasizes that if the period is extended, the cost-effectiveness would improve for DR due to the fact that some of these costs are one-time costs, i.e., equipment cost (Figure 6-1 in [100]). A summary of retailers or DR aggregators offering DR services is provided in Table 4.
DR aggregators can offer demand modifications and grid services, such as shifting or curtailing loads, reducing unbalanced costs, participating in balanced markets, and providing ancillary services [31]: for example, providing voltage support and frequency support as one entity [109]. Existing market entities, such as retailers, balanced responsible parties, and third-party companies, may act as aggregators [69]. For a better understanding of the DR aggregator’s interaction with other market players, please see Figure 1 in [23] and Figure 8 in [69]. A DR aggregator is cleared by the energy market similarly to an energy producer or generator, since reducing demand is equivalent to producing energy for the energy market’s clearing mechanism. A DR aggregator will need to be capable of performing the following operations in order to safely integrate large distributed loads into the power grid and future US electricity markets:
  • Analyze the flexibility and capabilities of the customers’ devices [110].
  • Schedule demands ahead of time [111].
  • Install communication infrastructure, necessary controls, and meters [112,113].
  • Perform necessary predictions [114] (system load forecasting [115,116,117], electricity price forecasting [118,119], and wind and solar production forecasting [120,121,122]).
  • Develop protocols and contracts for customer participation [71].
  • Develop the software for managing all of the above.
The DR aggregator may be a retailer or have a close connection to a retailer [71,123]. Retailers perform load forecasting, assess fluctuations in customer demand, and provide new pricing schemes [124], services that are similar to the DR aggregator [125]. On the other hand, the DR aggregator communicates with system operators, such as the distribution system operator (DSO), if it exists, and the ISO. The DSO can provide access to the DR aggregator with customers’ demand data [126], and the ISO is the buyer of services from transmission and distribution resources [70,127].
Case studies have been performed before to evaluate the effectiveness of DR, including Table 5. In a University of Pennsylvania case study [128], the building’s “DR-Advisor” tool showed that with a data-driven DR tool, 17% better curtailment performance can be achieved compared to rule-based strategies (380 kW load curtailment saving over USD 45,000 in one event). In another study by the US Department of Energy [129], 13 different DR types were characterized across sectors according to the frequency and duration of response metrics, enabling costs, etc., and it was found that the cooling load types in residential and commercial prosumers had the least ability to take advantage of energy arbitrage opportunities across US states in the Western Interconnection, while data centers and water heating showed moderate capability, with municipal pumping experiencing the highest ability. CAISO in another voluntary DR study [130] defined a metric for evaluating the response time and ramping capability of DR across 200 K residential buildings and found the period of responses to vary within −18% and 3% from the event’s time, while the response varied with income and other demographics. Another study by OSTI, Department of Energy [131], showed that aggregate DR and battery optimization can reduce the load peak by 2.9% (or 26 MW) during the summer of 2017 in Austin, TX. Lastly, another Department of Energy study [132] framed DR as a co-equal flexibility resource alongside storage. The same study provided materials for future case studies as they emphasized the need for modeling innovation to accurately represent aggregated DR behavior via DR aggregators, while they called attention to regulatory and data hurdles that also plague DR participation and DR valuation. The same study mentions that inconsistent DR participation rules, aggregation limits, inadequate metering/communication, and unclear compensation mechanisms are key obstacles to DR valuation in general.
The traditional operation of DR aggregators provides them with access to information about each distributed load with a load mix, as explained in Section 2.2, which includes knowledge of the prosumer’s devices and models; the prosumer’s demand patterns, behaviors, and preferences (potentially PI data); the prosumer’s work and house occupancy schedule; individual device demand forecasting for devices without models; generation forecasting; operations of battery storage or electric vehicles; etc. All this information is not only overwhelming to the operations of the DR aggregator, which has to coordinate and optimally operate thousands or millions of prosumers, but also a danger to the customer’s privacy because the data collected from local sensors is often PI, as one can see in Table 3. All the aforementioned observations lead to research questions regarding privacy in future US electricity markets (Section 3.7), where privacy and cybersecurity will be an issue of central importance, in addition to the issues related to prosumer’s flexibility and uncertainties, the scalability of DR aggregator operations, and competition with the prosumers or amongst the prosumers. Section 2.5 will analyze prosumer privacy further.

2.5. Privacy Concerns for Distributed Load Integration in Future US Electricity Markets

The modernization of smart grids is occurring with the collection of data from demand meters, sensors, etc., despite the slow introduction of data privacy regulations in smart grids, and this modernization has raised physical safety, privacy, and cybersecurity concerns for the prosumer and other grid and market entities. The contribution of distributed resources to electricity generation decarbonization will not only be further enabled by smart grid digitization via smart meters (Section 2.3) and data exchange structures that increase the visibility of such resources to system operators but also raise customer privacy concerns [6].
The critical role of cybersecurity in the effective operation of the smart grid is documented in legislation and by the Department of Energy [133]. Section 1301 of the Energy Independence and Security Act in 2007 (P.L. 110–140) [134] states that “it is the policy of the United States to support the modernization of the Nation’s electricity transmission and distribution system to maintain a reliable and secure electricity infrastructure that can meet future demand growth and achieve each of the following, which together characterize a smart grid”:
  • “Achieve increased use of digital information and control technology to improve the reliability, security, and efficiency of the electric grid”;
  • “Achieve dynamic optimization of grid operations and resources, with cybersecurity”.
According to the US National Institute for Standards and Technology (NIST) [135,136], common adversaries to Information Systems, including the smart grid, are nation states; hackers, terrorists, and cyberterrorists; organized crime; industrial competitors; disgruntled employees; and careless or poorly trained employees. Due to the privacy and cybersecurity concerns raised by the Department of Energy and NIST, efforts toward preventing physical and cyberphysical attacks on smart grid entities, including the distributed load, and privacy and cybersecurity preservation are important. The privacy abuse caused by the DR aggregator’s unconstrained access to prosumer models, behaviors, and data calls for attention and a potential revision to the DR aggregator’s accessibility that is permitted by the market operator, and a potential revision of such privileges is also needed if alternative operations can be suggested for DR market participation that hide as much sensitive information and/or PI data of the prosumer as possible. The assumption behind this statement is that limited information and data access can minimize knowledge extraction from the phished data and its fusion with other customer data sources. An open question related to prosumer privacy is identified here and summarized in Section 3.7. The next section refers to the market bidding process of a DR aggregator, which is part of its market operations.

2.6. Market Bidding Process and Challenges for Demand–Response Aggregators

Market bidding takes place on an online platform offered by the ISO, and the bidding strategy is often a complicated mathematical tool designed by the DR aggregator. The DR aggregator can participate in the following:
  • The emergency DR market.
  • The economic DR market, which consists of the following:
    -
    The capacity market (pre-capacity bidding).
    -
    The energy market (DAM and spot market).
    -
    The ancillary service market (day-ahead scheduling reserve, synchronous reserve, flexibility reserve, etc.) [137].
Although DR aggregators can sign bilateral contracts with retailers, generators, and system operators, bidding in the energy market directly in order to maximize profit is the most common activity of DR aggregators [138,139]. Settlements are generally determined differently by each market type and the flexibility that market type may offer. In PJM, the DR aggregator is compensated for the reduced demand in full emergency and full pre-emergency markets [69]. The same applies to the emergency energy market, which, however, is voluntarily joined by the prosumer. The DR aggregator is faced with a number of uncertainties when it comes to market bidding, such as market price uncertainty, prosumer demand uncertainty, prosumer flexibility, and competition with other market players; these are major open research topics that, if answered, will enable more efficient DR aggregator operations in future US electricity markets (Section 3.7).
Section 3 will introduce the existing literature frameworks for DR aggregator operations and their interactions with the distributed load and marker, and this is accompanied by critical thinking on how DR aggregator operations will have to change in future US electricity markets in order to support the 2030 and 2050 goals, a topic that the existing literature falls short of covering.

3. Demand–Response Aggregator Frameworks in Future US Electricity Markets

3.1. Competition in the Prosumer–Aggregator Frameworks

An overview of aggregator or prosumer frameworks categorized by methods, objectives, and devices compatible with that framework are presented in Table 6 for the day-ahead and imbalance markets (IM) and for the intra-day (IDM), reserve, and congestion markets equivalently. These frameworks consider specific devices only and optimize either the aggregator’s or the prosumer’s costs, but not both simultaneously; therefore, the underlying competition between the prosumers and the aggregator is neglected (open research question about competition in Section 3.7). This gap around competition is one of the five evaluation criteria summarized in Section 3.7, and it can be overcome with game-theoretic methods, which are analyzed later in this section, where all players are optimized while device models may or may not be considered. In the second case, some energy management systems from the prosumer’s side are assumed.
The literature often models the demand side (prosumer) separately from the supply side (aggregator). For example, Ref. [187] focuses only on the prosumer side, ignoring the presence of an aggregator and the competition between them. These approaches lead to suboptimal solutions because the players (prosumers or aggregators) have a wrong or no perception of the underlying competition. Game theory can model existing market competition and, therefore, derive optimal strategies that maximize the payoffs of all selfish players of the energy trading game. In the case of the prosumer-aggregator, the aggregator firm has the freedom to set up its own competition model for its prosumers, as long as it is able to market it properly and convince the prosumers to register. The market operator (independent system operator, also known as ISO) requires metering infrastructure to be in place so that it is able to monitor actions that are unfair to the market, such as hiding true capacities, bidding significantly lower quantities than the nominal capacity, etc.
The most common types of competition with respect to homogeneous products in markets are Stackelberg, Cournot, and Bertrand. Stackelberg games have a leader–follower structure, where the leader firm (firm with the most market power) plays first with an advantage and the followers observe the leader’s action and respond appropriately. The optimal strategic response (highest payoff for all players) to the leader’s Stackelberg action is a Stackelberg-type response from the followers. Stackelberg describes competition based on quantity [188]. A key advantage of Stackelberg models is that they often yield closed-form strategies, especially in full-information settings, making them analytically tractable and attractive for mechanism designs. However, their main limitation is the strong assumption of perfect information.
In Cournot competition, players play simultaneously by competing for quantity (players with market power can affect the market price). Players can no longer observe others’ actions, and this leads to different equilibria compared to the Stackelberg. Note that the leader in a Stackelberg competition can achieve at least the same or higher payoff as in the Cournot [189], which means that if the leader firm is in charge of the mechanism’s design, it will choose a Stackelberg type of competition. Cournot equilibria can be more realistic than Stackelberg in electricity markets where aggregators or participants act independently and do not know the actions of others in advance. However, Cournot models often yield less efficient market outcomes and may be harder to solve analytically, especially with constraints.
Bertrand competition describes the competition between multiple firms with respect to price. An ideal example of Bertrand competition could be the competition between multiple aggregators for the same prosumer, who would be offered multiple prices simultaneously for the same commodity (homogeneous product). In this case, Bertrand competition would result in marginal costs for the prosumer, which is a significant advantage. However, many system operators currently prohibit prosumers from registering with multiple DR aggregators, a fact that makes this competition type inappropriate. An aggregator may choose how to design the prosumer-aggregator mechanism; therefore, a Stackelberg game would be preferred because it can provide closed-form strategies for game analysis in the full-information setting (see Table 7 for various aggregator applications formulated as Stackelberg/bi-level optimization programs). No estimation or learning would be required for this analysis. In most designs, no direct competition is assumed between aggregators, but rather through the market.
The existing literature considers either the aggregator’s or the prosumer’s cost optimization, but not both. Simultaneous cost optimization would require an underlying competition assumption and would have to be modeled with game theory (open research question about competition in Section 3.7). Such a problem would be very complex and potentially computationally challenging in a centralized manner, especially if device model constraints and energy/demand forecasts are considered for the distributed load (see distributed load mix in Section 2.2). However, few efforts in the game-theoretical direction appear in the literature and are analyzed next.

3.2. Deterministic Game Theoretical Prosumer–Aggregator Frameworks

To enjoy the benefits of market-based DR, market presence in modeling is substantial for DR aggregator frameworks. However, some frameworks like [206,207] consider a non-profitable utility/aggregator (lack of competition) without market access. Both papers assume the deterministic modeling of aggregators and prosumers, ignoring the effect of several uncertainties. At the same time, Ref. [206] proposes a framework with some level of flexibility since prosumer battery models are considered, while Ref. [207] proposes an auction-like process run by a utility with multiple aggregators splitting the rewards but without any consideration of prosumer flexibility. However, Ref. [207] is a good starting point for the derivation of closed-form game-theoretic strategies in DR aggregator frameworks. Prosumer privacy or framework scalability are out of the scope of these studies.
Modeled competition between the DR aggregator and the prosumer can be found in other works like [208], which considers market access but not uncertainty or any particular prosumer flexibility options (no HEMS/BEMS constraints). Prosumer privacy and framework scalability with the number of prosumers and constraints are out of the scope of this work. However, this work is another excellent example of Stackelberg bottom-up pure strategy extraction, with full mathematical proofs provided. Some other Stackelberg competition frameworks with selfish players but without uncertainty include [73,74,209], where a degree of flexibility is assumed through prosumer time-coupling constraints on the total desired daily traded energy. Moreover, in the same works, the authors have considered prosumer privacy by developing a decentralized solution that does not require sharing any HEMS/BEMS details (objective, constraints, devices, preferences, settings, PI data, etc.) with the DR aggregator. The same decentralized solution allows for scalability with the number of prosumers, while the strategies and computational complexities are rigorously derived.
Other game-theoretic competition frameworks, like [210], show a different degree of flexibility by adding budget constraints for the prosumers and considering multiple utilities (no market). Uncertainty is not part of this study; however, a degree of privacy is obtained based on the prosumers’ sharing of optimal decisions, and a degree of scalability is attained from the distributed nature of the algorithm, but for convex games only. Another degree of flexibility is that of bidirectional energy flow between DR aggregators and prosumers. As many frameworks [207,208,210,211] do not allow this, we identify that some other works, like [73,74,204,209], allow for energy to flow bidirectionally between the prosumer, the DR aggregator, and the market, resulting in either selling energy to the market or buying energy from the market, achieving new levels of monetary rewards, as explained in [74,209]. Please note that in the case of [204], a bidirectional energy formulation is offered, but the proposed solution only solves the unidirectional energy flow problem. Moreover, Ref. [204] does not consider any uncertainty, prosumer privacy, or scalability of the solution as part of the scope of their research. A final example of framework flexibility is the prosumer’s behavioral heterogeneity, which includes different objectives and constraints, including differences in prosumer sector (residential, commercial, or industrial) [212], or allowing for elasticity to be evaluated for each prosumer separately [74,209].
Although this deterministic game-theoretic framework review on Stackelberg games may not be fully exhaustive, the key takeaway is the evaluation criteria used in this framework and all subsequent sections, which are one of the main contributions of this paper. Apart from DR applications, Stackelberg games have also been used for energy storage aggregators [213], cybersecurity [214], and road network checkpoints around the LAX airport (ARMOR program) [215]. Other types of games, such as Vickrey and Dutch auctions, have also been studied for DR applications [216] but less frequently, while Nash games are often used to describe the competition between DR aggregators [217], which, as mentioned in Section 3, is not realistic for most market operators.

3.3. Uncertainty in Prosumer–Aggregator Game-Theoretic Frameworks

A DR aggregator and prosumer framework can face several uncertainties depending on the level of implementation details. Some of the most common ones are clearing market price uncertainty, prosumer total and per-device demand uncertainty, and prosumer generation uncertainty [218].
In order to manage uncertainty in modeling, robust, stochastic, or RL-based approaches are usually proposed. In this paper [219], a robust optimization framework for DR aggregators in the DAM and RT markets was proposed, which takes into consideration prosumer demand uncertainty by forecasting the customer’s baseline load. Their method includes a single optimization problem (no competition) where the DR aggregator makes all the decisions for the prosumers who have battery devices and shiftable and reducible loads, therefore allowing a degree of flexibility in the prosumers’ device scheduling; however, this compromises prosumer privacy since the DR aggregator schedules all prosumer devices centrally, while solution scalability is not addressed. Robust optimization methods for DR aggregators have also been proposed within a game-theoretic context for the DAM [220], modeling the competition between DR aggregators as a Nash game but ignoring the competition with the prosumers. The main uncertainty considered is the market-clearing price, and hence, uncertainty sets are constructed. Since there are no explicit prosumer optimization problems, prosumer flexibility is not applicable, while privacy is not guaranteed if the DR aggregator is aware of some prosumer demand forecast. Scalability is not addressed theoretically or experimentally. Distributionally robust Stackelberg games have been proposed for the competition between DSO and DR aggregators, with some level of prosumer load type detail [221] provided specifically for HVAC and solar panels, which are part of the DR aggregator’s model (no privacy). Uncertainties include renewable supply and outdoor temperatures that are distributions within this framework. Utilizing an MILP reformulation, the authors turn this into a tractable problem for a 33-bus system, but no larger simulations were performed to evaluate the scalability further. Lastly, another distributionally robust approach [222] proposed a robust Stackelberg game to model the competition between a microgrid operator (conceptually close to a DR aggregator) that includes battery systems. The microgrid operator competes with the prosumers (some level of flexibility due to load breakdown and EV battery), while the overall uncertainties are around market prices, uncontrollable load demand, and solar generation from each prosumer. The program generated is a MINLP, which is simplified after some linearizations and solved iteratively to protect prosumer privacy.
Some examples in Bayesian or stochastic games for DR aggregators are found in the literature. These approaches assume that Bayesian or stochastic (distribution) uncertainties are present, with solutions optimized on average instead of the worst-case scenario (robust approaches), and they can be used when expected cost savings or performance is more important than guarding against extremes (risk level can be adjusted with CVaR). The DR aggregator game under demand uncertainty has been approached in [223] using Bayesian Stackelberg game theory, modeling only the game between multiple DR aggregators and ignoring the game between the prosumer and the DR aggregator (no competition). It is assumed that the DR aggregator has full control over the prosumer’s load, with the customer’s probability of opting out modeled (no privacy). An example of a stochastic game for the DR aggregator for the interested reader can be found in the context of microgrids participating in DR with DSO [224], solved by introducing the lower level KKT constraints to the upper level program, an approach that can lead to issues with privacy and scalability.
The most important aspect of decision-making under uncertainty in the aggregator’s problem is adaptivity. In energy trading, the players have to be able to adapt to changes in prosumers’ demand (highly uncertain at the residential level [117]), price elasticity, dis-utility, players’ strategy (i.e., dishonesty), and changes in the market side that affect players’ payoffs, i.e., introduction of a new player, change in a player’s strategy, etc. Reinforcement learning (RL) is a popular adaptive method where past knowledge is used (exploitation of learning), in combination with the exploration of actions to further maximize the players’ payoffs, and this has not yet been implemented for the DR aggregator. However, DR approaches related to consumers and utilities have been proposed as bi-level non-cooperative Stackelberg–Nash games [225]. In another RL approach, Ref. [226] proposes a Markov decision process (MDP) for aggregators to learn better pricing strategies. This approach is based on Q-learning, assuming competition between aggregators, but it lacks a game theoretic approach and does not consider prosumer modeling (no prosumer flexibility). It has been stated that decision-making under uncertainty for DR aggregators, especially under partially observed environments, is still an open question [227]. Game-theoretic approaches under uncertainty for the DR aggregator problem are limited, as mentioned by the two literature review papers [227,228]. Additionally, the problem of incomplete information regarding the prosumer’s energy-selling or energy-purchasing patterns was not addressed properly [229] and remained a roadblock until [230] proposed an RL mechanism, in which an EMS (with a role similar to a DR aggregator) coordinates the energy exchange between the utility and prosumers, modeling them in a competitive way via uncertainty quantification and solving it in a combined manner. The scalability of the solution was proven to be satisfactory with the number of prosumers, while heterogeneous prosumer behavior was also modeled. In another work, an RL-based DR strategy is designed for the DR aggregator to learn the best charging decisions for prosumer batteries based on market reward outcomes (no privacy and minimum prosumer flexibility modeled), utilizing deep Q-networks. Scalability was not addressed, but it is dependent on the state and action’s dimensionality. Lastly, a Q-learning framework in [231] allows customers to engage in a cooperative game with the utility, which performs both DR and economic dispatch (ED), while Stackelberg equilibria are found with the help of a pre-trained neural network. The latter provides evidence that learning Stackelberg game equilibria with RL is possible but does not specifically consider the DR aggregator problem. RL can provide model-free frameworks, i.e., frameworks without a specific utility function, opening paths for adaptivity in the prosumer–DR aggregator games while playing close to the equilibrium.
Before any learning can be applied, adaptivity must be ensured for the algorithm. Online metrics such as regret minimization [232] have been used in playing two-player zero-sum Nash games [233] in an adaptive fashion, where the difference between the total payoff under uncertainty and the total best payoff is minimized in a horizon of N games. In [234], players can play non-zero-sum Stackelberg games with uncertainty in the follower’s action, where the leader is trading off the estimated follower’s action with the true value revealed.
In summary, Bayesian approaches require data to construct distributions for the uncertain variable, online learning does not require any a priori knowledge and learns on the fly, and online adaptivity combined with RL methods can trade-off exploration and exploitation compared to robust methods. Decision-making frameworks under uncertainty for prosumer DR aggregators are still an open question due to various challenges and very limited market data access. They are high-dimensional control problems faced with the challenges of partial observability and randomness (open research question about uncertainty in Section 3.7).

3.4. Prosumer Privacy in the Prosumer–Aggregator Game

When it comes to the prosumer DR aggregator game frameworks available in the literature, not much has been carried out to provide such levels of privacy to prosumers. Specifically, in [235], prosumers only share local optimal solutions and their power flexibility in fulfilling the constraints of the proposed global optimization program for the ancillary service market. In other approaches of the day-ahead energy market, like [73,74,209], only optimal solutions from the prosumers are shared with the DR aggregator, which prevents the sharing of objectives, constraints (device models from HEMS/BEMS), preferences and settings, forecasts of demand or generation (including limits), etc., collected from sensors [117] or forecasted with data science methods [236] in accordance with the DR aggregator, protecting prosumer privacy. Another work such as Ref. [237] provides a two-stage framework for day-ahead and real-time market bidding, where only the prosumers’ schedules are shared with the aggregator, and the problem is solved distributively with the alternating direction method of multipliers (ADMM), while they exchange both their optimal solutions and their power flexibility. ADMM methods can be slow in convergence and require strong assumptions for primal variables to converge to an optimal solution, while the decomposability of the objective is necessary [238]. Since prosumer privacy has not been broadly studied with DR aggregator frameworks, privacy will become one of the open research questions in Section 3.7, and these frameworks are also necessary for future US electricity markets. Last but not least, the authors in [239] proposed a distributed, prosumer privacy-preserving algorithm to solve an MILP for a manual frequency restoration reserve (mFRR) service, allowing the aggregators and prosumers to participate in the balancing market. Please note that although prosumer blockchain privacy frameworks exist, these community coordination schemes follow a different logic [240,241,242].

3.5. Scalability in Demand–Response Aggregators’ Operations

Decentralized solutions for the prosumer–aggregator Stackelberg game are limited in the literature. In [73,74,209], a decentralized algorithm was designed for the DAM DR problem to solve the bi-level program, sharing only optimal solutions between prosumers and the DR aggregator. Other decentralized solutions were mentioned in Section 3.4 from a few papers [237,238,239].
The rest of this section will focus on decentralized solutions for general bi-level optimization programs (Stackelberg games) to facilitate the future decentralization of DR aggregator operations in the case of thousands/millions of prosumers with hundreds/thousands of constraints each. A proper game-theoretic framework setup and the proper utilization of one of the decentralized algorithms listed below may additionally allow for a solution to the prosumer privacy problem (constraints and other problem details remain hidden). The specifics of such research remain open questions, and if addressed, they may facilitate the large-scale deployment of DR aggregators in future US electricity markets, contributing significantly to the decarbonization and net-zero emission goals analyzed in Section 1.
In the decentralized algorithm proposed in [243], the lower-level program is reformulated into an unconstrained one with the penalty method, and then, the transformed bi-level program is solved iteratively by applying the penalty function method to the lower-level problems. It was also proven that a sequence of approximated solutions converges to the optimal solution, but privacy concerns for the lower-level programs are not taken into consideration in the solution method, nor is it mentioned whether the same convergence result applies to bi-level programs with multiple followers. In [244], the authors proposed a decentralized bi-level program algorithm that is solved via the collaboration of the lower-level programs. Specifically, all lower-level variables are updated simultaneously based on a gradient descent algorithm, exchanging information about their current variable updates and their objective derivative values at the current variable value (not a completely private algorithm), while the upper-level variable is updated based on lower-level program’s variable update information. After some iterations of lower-level program variable updates, the upper-level program’s variable value is updated based on the current lower-level variable values. The drawback of this method is that the number of iterations is pre-defined and the same for all lower-level programs, and the method may converge to a local optimum. Last but not least, in paper [245], the authors proposed a similar approach to this dissertation, which is a bi-level evolutionary algorithm, but they restricted the solution’s mapping to quadratic polynomial functions. The authors do not study the effect of the approximation and learning errors on the solution’s quality, but they do provide a very insightful visualization of a generic solution map. Moreover, the authors propose a way to find the best solution map approximation model by choosing the model that minimizes the empirical risk error on a given dataset.
To facilitate the large-scale deployment of DR aggregators in future US electricity markets and, hence, the DR benefits, a scalable and private algorithm that is able to solve deterministic or uncertain game-theoretic frameworks that take into consideration prosumer–aggregator competition is necessary. In this way, DR benefits can be extracted on a large scale in future US markets, the probability of electricity generation decarbonization is increased, and a net-zero-emission US economy can be realized.

3.6. Prosumer–Aggregator Market Bidding Frameworks

The problem of market bidding, often formulated as a separate game, considers the market-clearing mechanism with only the total market capacity cleared and the market-clearing prices as the available information. In electricity markets, firms (power producers, aggregators, etc.) compete for both quantity and price, and they all play simultaneously. However, bidding strategies are usually simplified. Examples include auction-like mechanisms [207], piece-wise, constant-quantity price-bidding mechanisms [213,246], a finite pool of past (quantity and price) successful actions, and sampling bids from a nominal bidding curve and running scheduling algorithms [247], among others [246]. Market bidding strategies have also been developed using RL [248,249,250]. In the other literature, players decide to form tacit collusion by withholding capacity [251] in order to minimize a response from another firm (avoid the opportunity to price cut an opponent) without explicitly stating so. These are modeled as auction games with repeated play where the firm that sets the initial price is the leading firm. In [252], RL is used, and the market mechanism is modeled as a double auction between energy sellers and consumers. In [252], microgrids with private information compete in the energy market using RL. Stochastic optimization approaches, such as MILP [123,139,253] and scenario-based stochastic programming [254,255], have been proposed before, in addition to robust optimization [256,257], theoretical information gap decisions [258,259], and genetic algorithms [260,261] according to [69].

3.7. Open Research Questions for Future Demand–Response Aggregators’ Operations

This paper introduced the environmental goals for 2030 and 2050 in the US and analyzed the role that DR aggregators will play in future US electricity markets, for which their mechanisms are expected to be revised by policymakers in order to better compensate clean technologies and grid reliability support providers. To facilitate the large-scale deployment of DR aggregators and registered distributed loads (prosumers) in future US electricity markets, DR aggregator operation frameworks will need to have the characteristics shown in Figure 4, the achievement of which remains an open research question, as observed and analyzed in Section 2 and Section 3. In short, we refer to this as the FCUPS evaluation scheme for any DR aggregator and prosumer framework, and we next justify how these operational changes in future US electricity markets will facilitate the 2030 and 2050 goals (Section 1):
  • Flexibility (F) with the type of prosumers (residential, commercial, and industrial), their behavior (strategy, rationality, bidirectional flow of energy and information, etc.), their device constraints, their distributed load types, and their operational capabilities through their HEMS/BEMS: Ideally, a flexible DR aggregator prosumer framework would model, in detail, the prosumer’s distributed load mix (Figure 3), data pipelines, settings, and controls via an HEMS/BEMS to ensure the feasibility and optimality of the DR aggregator prosumer solution, utilizing technologies introduced in Section 2.3. Flexibility is important to the 2030 and 2050 goals in order to operate a grid with significant renewable resources, according to Section 1’s points 1 and 6.
  • Competition (C) between the DR aggregator and prosumers, as well as between prosumers, to incentivize prosumer engagement: Competition of the DR aggregator with other market players to maximize profits. Ideally, the DR aggregator and prosumer framework should model the underlying competition type, considering the types of competition analyzed in Section 3.1. Competition consideration is important in order to ensure that the prosumer’s interests are also taken into consideration, considering prosumers as active market players with preferences and rewards, unlike numerous previous approaches (Table 6). In this way, the distributed load is incentivized to participate in market-based DR, which can facilitate the 2030 and 2050 goals according to Section 1’s points 1 and 2.
  • Uncertainty (U) quantification in multiple areas, such as the demand and generation profiles of the prosumers and the market and market prices for the day-ahead and spot markets to reduce unexpected costs: Ideally, the DR aggregator and prosumer game would be modeled as a Bayesian, stochastic, or RL game to allow mixed strategies and uncertainty quantification to be included in decision-making while still considering competition modeling in the framework. Uncertainty consideration is important for better scheduling in electricity markets and helps prevent supply shortages, large demand and price variations, or unexpected costs inflicted on the DR aggregator and prosumer, resulting in more reliable grids and markets, as well as financial prosperity and risk management for market participants. The aforementioned facilitate the 2030 and 2050 goals according to Section 1’s points 3 and 9.
  • Privacy (P) preservation of the prosumer with respect to any for-profit market entities, such as the DR aggregator, hardware manufacturer, software developers, etc.: Privacy preservation includes PI data, prosumer preferences for comfort, device models and the mode/frequency of operation, load types and operational choices, demand and generation forecasts, etc. Ideally, the prosumer’s strategy, PI data, settings, preferences, controls, objectives, and structural details of the HEMS/BEMS would not be shared with the DR aggregator, a goal that aligns with the Department of Energy’s Energy Independence and Security Act (Section 2.5). Decentralized solutions that do not require the DR aggregator to solve the prosumer’s problem, but rather only receive the optimal solution, are preferred for this purpose. Such approaches facilitate the 2030 and 2050 goals according to Section 1’s points 6 and 9.
  • Scalability (S) with the number of prosumers, as well as with the number and type of prosumer constraints, despite the complex nature of the distributed load mix: Ideally, every prosumer would be represented by a detailed HEMS/BEMS system and be given controls to facilitate flexibility, but at the cost of computational complexity. Methods like the solution decentralization of DR aggregator and prosumer operations (i.e, avoid solving a large, single-level optimization problem of the DR aggregator and the prosumers’ KKT conditions), parallelization, and approximate algorithms can be introduced to manage these computational challenges. Scalability is important to the 2030 and 2050 goals because the large-scale integration of flexible generation and demand to the grid via DR can defer system expansion costs and alleviate the system’s stress according to Section 1’s points 6 and 8.
Figure 4. This diagram shows the key players in DR markets and indicates potential interactions between them with arrows. The different necessary frameworks are displayed on the left, and they are enabled by the discussed technologies in this paper. Finally, the operational challenges are depicted in blue, which pose the open research questions examined in this paper, and they are important for the 2030 electricity generation decarbonization and 2050 net-zero-economy goals.
Figure 4. This diagram shows the key players in DR markets and indicates potential interactions between them with arrows. The different necessary frameworks are displayed on the left, and they are enabled by the discussed technologies in this paper. Finally, the operational challenges are depicted in blue, which pose the open research questions examined in this paper, and they are important for the 2030 electricity generation decarbonization and 2050 net-zero-economy goals.
Applsci 15 08066 g004
To allow for the aforementioned characteristics to co-exist in the same prosumer–aggregator framework, researchers and policymakers are encouraged to consider the literature gaps addressed in Section 3 and to find ways to accelerate the distributed load participation in the DR markets (data sharing policies, information provided by ISO/DSO to DR aggregators, carbon pricing, etc.). In future research, the aforementioned characteristics can be addressed by considering flexible constraints (inequalities instead of equalities, a range of possible demand scenarios, etc.); hierarchical or decentralized algorithms that solve the framework (including blockchains); game-theoretic frameworks that address prosumer–aggregator competition according to the mechanism designed by the DR aggregator; RL and multi-agent RL, MPC, and Bayesian games; robust, distributionally robust optimization, or stochastic optimization frameworks that can address uncertainty; and finally, privacy preservation operations that hide prosumer-specific information and PI data from the DR aggregator while still allowing all the above characteristics to exist (i.e., decentralized and private learning, also known as federated learning, differential privacy, homomorphic encryption, and secure multiparty computation). The challenging task of integrating all of the above characteristics in the same framework and algorithm will allow for the large-scale deployment and flexible operation of DR aggregators and distributed loads in future US electricity markets while preserving customer privacy, a concern of increasing amplitude to the Department of Energy.
Following the gap in prosumer DR aggregator game-theoretic frameworks, it is not only necessary that prosumers are able to implement their total demand schedule bid on their devices, but they should also be able ensure that demand uncertainties can be corrected in real time to avoid market fines. Energy-saving solutions at the distributed load level include sensor-based automation for smart device control, as well as energy management systems that optimize the building’s operation based on price signals by a utility or aggregator. Therefore, the direction of integrating the prosumer–aggregator game with the prosumer’s energy management system in the same algorithmic solution and software can facilitate flexibility, scalability, competition, uncertainty, and privacy. In other words, during the negotiation with the DR aggregator, each prosumer can run their day-ahead HEMS/BEMS and provide not only feasible but also optimal demand profile responses to the DR aggregator, which will minimize costly demand discrepancies. Day-ahead and spot market bidding operations can be combined in the same solution so that the cost from real-time demand discrepancies is minimized in the settlement process (multi-horizon frameworks). Such integration of algorithmic solutions and software could facilitate the large-scale deployment of DR aggregators and prosumers in future US electricity markets and help achieve environmental and grid reliability goals.
To enable the integration of energy management systems (HEMS/BEMS) and aggregator–prosumer market bidding games, aggregator optimization programs with prosumer device constraints would be transformed into bi-level programs with lower-level prosumer objectives and device constraints. Such a large-scale bi-level program would be very hard to solve for thousands of prosumers, and it would traditionally require all prosumer information to be available to the aggregator. However, with decentralized, scalable, flexible, uncertainty-quantifying, and privacy-preserving algorithms, such obstacles can be overcome. Some examples satisfying these criteria are federated multi-agent learning with MPC and game theory, or hierarchical distributionally robust optimization with privacy guarantees (coordination at higher levels using differentially private updates) and blockchain-enabled transactive energy markets. Lastly, explainable AI can be utilized to better interpret the main drivers behind demand, price forecasting, etc., with methods like SHAP, LIME, saliency maps, etc., most of which are appropriate for privacy-sensitive applications as well.

4. Discussion

This study highlights the critical role that existing technologies and emerging frameworks can play in achieving the 2030 and 2050 decarbonization and grid reliability goals of the US energy sector. Energy-efficient technologies, such as high-performance HVAC systems, smart lighting, building insulation, advanced sensors, and smart energy management systems (HEMS/BEMS), have already demonstrated measurable reductions in energy consumption and CO2 emissions. For example, structural upgrades and sensor-driven HVAC systems can reduce building energy use by up to 55%, while smart controls and energy management can achieve an additional 23% in savings. These technologies provide a robust foundation for immediate and scalable deployment. However, while these technologies contribute significantly toward CO2 reduction targets, their integration into large-scale distributed energy systems introduces operational challenges that current methods do not fully address. Existing centralized demand–response (DR) aggregator models often require extensive access to prosumer data, including personally identifiable information (PI), device-level demand profiles, and behavioral patterns. This access creates substantial privacy risks and scalability bottlenecks, particularly as the number of participating prosumers grows into the thousands or millions. Moreover, current DR frameworks frequently fall short in managing uncertainty, ensuring competitive fairness between prosumers and aggregators and enabling flexible market participation that aligns with individual prosumer constraints and preferences when evaluated through the proposed FCUPS criteria—flexibility, competition, uncertainty quantification, privacy preservation, and scalability. Centralized models also struggle to efficiently coordinate the diverse and dynamic load types that characterize modern prosumers: from residential solar and battery systems to smart appliances and electric vehicles. To address these gaps, this paper proposes future research directions centered on decentralized, privacy-preserving, and scalable solutions. Specifically, federated multi-agent learning, hierarchical distributionally robust optimization with privacy guarantees, and blockchain-enabled transactive energy markets are identified as promising avenues. These approaches can enable prosumers to retain local control over their data while contributing optimal demand bids to the market. Furthermore, integrating game-theoretic models that rigorously capture competition and cooperation dynamics, along with reinforcement learning for adaptive bidding under uncertainty, could greatly enhance market resilience and efficiency. By focusing on these advanced methods, future DR aggregator frameworks can overcome the limitations of current approaches, facilitating the large-scale adoption of distributed load participation and strengthening the grid’s ability to meet 2030 and 2050 targets for decarbonization, reliability, and a net-zero economy.

5. Conclusions

This review has provided novel insights into the critical role that demand–response (DR) aggregators and distributed load will play in the transformation of future US electricity markets. Unlike prior reviews, this work introduces the FCUPS evaluation framework—highlighting the necessary characteristics of flexibility, competition, uncertainty quantification, privacy preservation, and scalability—as a comprehensive lens through which DR aggregator operations must evolve. The FCUPS framework offers a unified, structured approach for identifying gaps in current DR aggregator and prosumer frameworks, which had not previously been addressed with such holistic rigor. By systematically analyzing operational challenges across flexibility, privacy, uncertainty, scalability, and competitive mechanisms, this paper opens clear research directions that can shape future agendas. These directions include the development of decentralized, privacy-preserving frameworks, the incorporation of advanced game-theoretic and machine learning models to capture competition and uncertainty, and scalable solutions capable of managing millions of prosumers with complex, heterogeneous load mixes. Furthermore, this review stresses the need for algorithms that balance operational efficiency with privacy and cybersecurity, addressing growing concerns from both consumers and regulatory agencies. The proposed open research questions are positioned to guide interdisciplinary collaborations between energy researchers, data scientists, policymakers, and system operators. By addressing these questions, future work can directly support the 2030 decarbonization and 2050 net-zero goals, helping to redesign electricity markets that not only reduce CO2 emissions but also foster resilient, equitable, and efficient grid operations.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, S.I.K. and D.N.M.; methodology, S.I.K. and D.N.M.; investigation, S.I.K.; writing—original draft preparation, S.I.K.; visualization, S.I.K.; supervision, D.N.M.; project administration, D.N.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

No new data were created or analyzed in this study.

Acknowledgments

This section acknowledges the authors of the figures and tables borrowed in this paper and the licensing allowing their publication. The authors would like to thank the EPA for preparing the report [47] and for allowing the reuse of their material for scientific purposes, as declared in [262], from which Table ES-6 was utilized to develop Figure 2b in this paper. Figure 3 was reused from Figure 1 in [71], with electronic permission obtained from Elsevier. Materials for Table 4 were borrowed from Table 2 in [28] and Table 7 in [69], with electronic permission obtained from Elsevier. The material for Table 5 was sourced from Table 1 in [107] and Table 3-3 in [108], which were originally sourced from FERC or an ISO report, both of which allow the reuse of the material, with proper attribution provided here. Lastly, Figure 2a was developed with data provided by the Office of Scientific and Technical Information (OSTI) of the Department of Energy, in accordance with their licensing terms and with appropriate attribution.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. NASA. World of Change. 2023. Available online: https://earthobservatory.nasa.gov/world-of-change/DecadalTemp (accessed on 1 April 2025).
  2. UN. The Climate Change Crisis—A Race We Can Win. 2019. Available online: https://www.un.org/en/un75/climate-crisis-race-we-can-win#:~:text=Rising%20temperatures%20are%20fueling%20environmental,acidifying%2C%20and%20forests%20are%20burning (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  3. EPA. Clean Power Plan Archive. 2019. Available online: https://archive.epa.gov/epa/cleanpowerplan.html (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  4. IEA. Credible Pathways to 1.5 °C. 2023. Available online: https://iea.blob.core.windows.net/assets/ea6587a0-ea87-4a85-8385-6fa668447f02/Crediblepathwaysto1.5C-Fourpillarsforactioninthe2020s.pdf (accessed on 1 April 2023).
  5. UN. Glasgow Leaders’ Declaration on Forests and Land Use. 2021. Available online: https://webarchive.nationalarchives.gov.uk/ukgwa/20230418175226/https://ukcop26.org/glasgow-leaders-declaration-on-forests-and-land-use/ (accessed on 1 November 2021).
  6. IEA. Steering Electricity Markets Towards a Rapid Decarbonisation. 2023. Available online: https://www.whitehouse.gov/briefing-room/statements-releases/2023/04/20/fact-sheet-president-biden-to-catalyze-global-climate-action-through-the-major-economies-forum-on-energy-and-climate/ (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  7. IEA. Net Zero by 2050: A Roadmap for the Global Energy Sector. 2021. Available online: https://iea.blob.core.windows.net/assets/deebef5d-0c34-4539-9d0c-10b13d840027/NetZeroby2050-ARoadmapfortheGlobalEnergySector_CORR.pdf (accessed on 1 October 2021).
  8. Kampezidou, S.I.; Polymeneas, E.; Meliopoulos, S. The economic effect of storage in systems with high penetration of renewable sources. In Proceedings of the 2015 North American Power Symposium (NAPS), Charlotte, NC, USA, 4–6 October 2015; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2015; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  9. EIA. Monthly Energy Review. February 2023. Available online: https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/monthly/previous.php (accessed on 1 June 2025).
  10. EIA. Electricity Explained. 2023. Available online: https://www.eia.gov/energyexplained/electricity/electricity-in-the-us.php (accessed on 1 March 2024).
  11. MIT. Germany Runs Up Against the Limits of Renewables. 2016. Available online: https://www.technologyreview.com/s/601514/germany-runs-up-against-the-limits-of-renewables/ (accessed on 1 May 2016).
  12. World Nuclear Association. Nuclear Power in Germany. 2022. Available online: https://www.world-nuclear.org/information-library/country-profiles/countries-g-n/germany.aspx (accessed on 1 July 2024).
  13. Office of Energy Efficiency & Renewable Energy, US Department of Energy. Confronting the Duck Curve: How to Address Over-Generation of Solar Energy. 2017. Available online: https://www.energy.gov/eere/articles/confronting-duck-curve-how-address-over-generation-solar-energy (accessed on 1 October 2017).
  14. CAISO. What the Duck Curve Tells Us About Managing a Green Grid. 2013. Available online: https://www.caiso.com/documents/flexibleresourceshelprenewables_fastfacts.pdf (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  15. PJM. MISO/PJM Joint Modeling Case Study: Clean Power Plan Analysis. Technical Report, March 2017. Available online: https://www.pjm.com/-/media/library/reports-notices/clean-power-plan/20170310-pjm-miso-cpp-case-study.ashx?la=en (accessed on 1 March 2017).
  16. Joskow, P.L. California’s electricity crisis. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 2001, 17, 365–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Sewalt, M.; De Jong, C. Negative prices in electricity markets. Commod. Now 2003, 7, 74–77. [Google Scholar]
  18. Fanone, E.; Gamba, A.; Prokopczuk, M. The case of negative day-ahead electricity prices. Energy Econ. 2013, 35, 22–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Nicholson, E.; Rogers, J.; Porter, K. Relationship Between Wind Generation and Balancing Energy Market Prices in ERCOT: 2007–2009; Technical Report; National Renewable Energy Lab. (NREL): Golden, CO, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  20. EirGrid and SONI. Ensuring a Secure, Reliable and Efficient Power System in a Changing Environment. 2011. Available online: http://www.eirgridgroup.com/site-files/library/EirGrid/Ensuring-a-Secure-Reliable-and-Efficient-Power-System-Report.pdf (accessed on 1 June 2011).
  21. Adams, J.; O’Malley, M.; Hanson, K. Flexibility Requirements and Potential Metrics for Variable Generation: Implications for System Planning Studies; NERC: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2010; pp. 14–17. [Google Scholar]
  22. FERC. Demand Response. 2023. Available online: https://ferc.gov/power-sales-and-markets/demand-response (accessed on 1 February 2023).
  23. D’Ettorre, F.; Banaei, M.; Ebrahimy, R.; Pourmousavi, S.A.; Blomgren, E.; Kowalski, J.; Bohdanowicz, Z.; Łopaciuk-Gonczaryk, B.; Biele, C.; Madsen, H. Exploiting demand-side flexibility: State-of-the-art, open issues and social perspective. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 165, 112605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Paterakis, N.G.; Erdinç, O.; Catalão, J.P. An overview of Demand Response: Key-elements and international experience. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 69, 871–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Yan, X.; Ozturk, Y.; Hu, Z.; Song, Y. A review on price-driven residential demand response. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 96, 411–419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Shariatzadeh, F.; Mandal, P.; Srivastava, A.K. Demand response for sustainable energy systems: A review, application and implementation strategy. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 45, 343–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Gržanić, M.; Capuder, T.; Zhang, N.; Huang, W. Prosumers as active market participants: A systematic review of evolution of opportunities, models and challenges. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 154, 111859. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Carreiro, A.M.; Jorge, H.M.; Antunes, C.H. Energy management systems aggregators: A literature survey. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 73, 1160–1172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Hu, J.; Harmsen, R.; Crijns-Graus, W.; Worrell, E.; van den Broek, M. Identifying barriers to large-scale integration of variable renewable electricity into the electricity market: A literature review of market design. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 81, 2181–2195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Pourramezan, A.; Samadi, M. A system dynamics investigation on the long-term impacts of demand response in generation investment planning incorporating renewables. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2023, 171, 113003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Behrangrad, M. A review of demand side management business models in the electricity market. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2015, 47, 270–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Lee, D.; Cheng, C.C. Energy savings by energy management systems: A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 56, 760–777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Arnone, D.; Cacioppo, M.; Ippolito, M.G.; Mammina, M.; Mineo, L.; Musca, R.; Zizzo, G. A methodology for exploiting smart prosumers’ flexibility in a bottom-up aggregation process. Appl. Sci. 2022, 12, 430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Kharatovi, L.; Gantassi, R.; Masood, Z.; Choi, Y. A Multi-Objective Optimization Framework for Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading in South Korea’s Tiered Pricing System. Appl. Sci. 2024, 14, 11071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Aoun, A.; Adda, M.; Ilinca, A.; Ghandour, M.; Ibrahim, H. Comparison between Blockchain P2P Energy Trading and Conventional Incentive Mechanisms for Distributed Energy Resources—A Rural Microgrid Use Case Study. Appl. Sci. 2024, 14, 7618. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Merrad, Y.; Habaebi, M.H.; Islam, M.R.; Gunawan, T.S.; Elsheikh, E.A.; Suliman, F.; Mesri, M. Machine learning-blockchain based autonomic peer-to-peer energy trading system. Appl. Sci. 2022, 12, 3507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Khaskheli, S.; Anvari-Moghaddam, A. Energy Trading in Local Energy Markets: A Comprehensive Review of Models, Solution Strategies, and Machine Learning Approaches. Appl. Sci. 2024, 14, 11510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Ji, Z.; Liu, X.; Tang, D. Game-theoretic applications for decision-making behavior on the energy demand side: A systematic review. Prot. Control Mod. Power Syst. 2024, 9, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Biancardi, A.; Di Silvestre, M.L.; Favuzza, S.; Montana, F.; Sanseverino, E.R.; Sciumè, G. Game Theory approaches for Renewable Energy Communities: A critical comparison. In Proceedings of the IECON 2024—50th Annual Conference of the IEEE Industrial Electronics Society, Chicago, IL, USA, 3–6 November 2024; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2024; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  40. Dong, Y.; Dong, Z. Bibliometric analysis of game theory on energy and natural resource. Sustainability 2023, 15, 1278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Asensio, O.I.; Delmas, M.A. The effectiveness of US energy efficiency building labels. Nat. Energy 2017, 2, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Jin, M.; Bekiaris-Liberis, N.; Weekly, K.; Spanos, C.J.; Bayen, A.M. Occupancy detection via environmental sensing. IEEE Trans. Autom. Sci. Eng. 2016, 15, 443–455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Kampezidou, S.I.; Ray, A.T.; Duncan, S.; Balchanos, M.G.; Mavris, D.N. Real-time occupancy detection with physics-informed pattern-recognition machines based on limited CO2 and temperature sensors. Energy Build. 2021, 242, 110863. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Langevin, J.; Harris, C.B.; Reyna, J.L. Assessing the potential to reduce US building CO2 emissions 80% by 2050. Joule 2019, 3, 2403–2424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Kok, N.; McGraw, M.; Quigley, J.M. The diffusion of energy efficiency in building. Am. Econ. Rev. 2011, 101, 77–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Boden, T.; Marland, G.; Andres, R.J. Global, Regional, and National Fossil-Fuel CO2 Emissions (1751–2014) (V. 2017). 1999. Available online: https://www.osti.gov/biblio/1389331 (accessed on 1 July 1999).
  47. EPA. Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Sinks: 1990–2020; Technical Report; US Environmental Protection Agency: Washington, DC, USA, 2020. Available online: https://www.epa.gov/system/files/documents/2022-04/us-ghg-inventory-2022-main-text.pdf (accessed on 1 April 2022).
  48. Pérez-Lombard, L.; Ortiz, J.; Pout, C. A review on buildings energy consumption information. Energy Build. 2008, 40, 394–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Sanchez, M.C.; Brown, R.E.; Webber, C.; Homan, G.K. Savings estimates for the United States Environmental Protection Agency’s ENERGY STAR voluntary product labeling program. Energy Policy 2008, 36, 2098–2108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Webber, C.A.; Brown, R.E.; Koomey, J. Savings estimates for the Energy Star® voluntary labeling program. Energy Policy 2000, 28, 1137–1149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Dubois, M.C.; Blomsterberg, Å. Energy saving potential and strategies for electric lighting in future North European, low energy office buildings: A literature review. Energy Build. 2011, 43, 2572–2582. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Wang, L.; Li, H.; Zou, X.; Shen, X. Lighting system design based on a sensor network for energy savings in large industrial buildings. Energy Build. 2015, 105, 226–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Mohsen, M.S.; Akash, B.A. Some prospects of energy savings in buildings. Energy Convers. Manag. 2001, 42, 1307–1315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Larsen, S.F.; Filippín, C.; Beascochea, A.; Lesino, G. An experience on integrating monitoring and simulation tools in the design of energy-saving buildings. Energy Build. 2008, 40, 987–997. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Pappas, A.; Reilly, S. Energy performance of a double skin. In Proceedings of the International Solar Energy Conference, Denver, CO, USA, 8–13 July 2006. [Google Scholar]
  56. Charron, R.; Athienitis, A.K. Optimization of the performance of double-facades with integrated photovoltaic panels and motorized blinds. Sol. Energy 2006, 80, 482–491. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Pérez, G.; Coma, J.; Martorell, I.; Cabeza, L.F. Vertical Greenery Systems (VGS) for energy saving in buildings: A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 39, 139–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Marks, W. Multicriteria optimisation of shape of energy-saving buildings. Build. Environ. 1997, 32, 331–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Sher, F.; Kawai, A.; Güleç, F.; Sadiq, H. Sustainable energy saving alternatives in small buildings. Sustain. Energy Technol. Assess. 2019, 32, 92–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Westermann, D.; John, A. Demand matching wind power generation with wide-area measurement and demand-side management. IEEE Trans. Energy Convers. 2007, 22, 145–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Schneider, K.P.; Fuller, J.C.; Tuffner, F.K.; Singh, R. Evaluation of Conservation Voltage Reduction (CVR) on a National Level; Technical Report; Pacific Northwest National Lab. (PNNL): Richland, WA, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  62. Kampezidou, S.; Wiegman, H. Energy and power savings assessment in buildings via conservation voltage reduction. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE Power & Energy Society Innovative Smart Grid Technologies Conference (ISGT), Washington, DC, USA, 23–26 April 2017; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2017; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar]
  63. Wiegman, H.; Kampezidou, S.I.; Nikolakopulos, M.; GE Global Research Niskayuna United States. Advanced Micro Grid Energy Management Coupled with Integrated Volt/VAR Control for Improved Energy Efficiency, Energy Security, and Power Quality at DoD Installations. Defense Technical Information Center. 2016. Available online: https://apps.dtic.mil/sti/html/tr/AD1026014/index.html (accessed on 1 October 2016).
  64. Qdr, Q. Benefits of Demand Response in Electricity Markets and Recommendations for Achieving Them; Technical Report; US Department of Energy: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  65. Albadi, M.H.; El-Saadany, E.F. Demand response in electricity markets: An overview. In Proceedings of the 2007 IEEE Power Engineering Society General Meeting, Tampa, FL, USA, 24–28 June 2007; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2007; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar]
  66. Barbose, G.; Goldman, C.; Neenan, B. A Survey of Utility Experience with Real Time Pricing; Technical Report; Lawrence Berkeley National Lab. (LBNL): Berkeley, CA, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  67. Abedrabboh, K.; Al-Fagih, L. Applications of mechanism design in market-based demand-side management: A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2023, 171, 113016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Li, K.; Liu, L.; Wang, F.; Wang, T.; Duić, N.; Shafie-khah, M.; Catalão, J.P. Impact factors analysis on the probability characterized effects of time of use demand response tariffs using association rule mining method. Energy Convers. Manag. 2019, 197, 111891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Lu, X.; Li, K.; Xu, H.; Wang, F.; Zhou, Z.; Zhang, Y. Fundamentals and business model for resource aggregator of demand response in electricity markets. Energy 2020, 204, 117885. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Li, K.; Wang, F.; Mi, Z.; Fotuhi-Firuzabad, M.; Duić, N.; Wang, T. Capacity and output power estimation approach of individual behind-the-meter distributed photovoltaic system for demand response baseline estimation. Appl. Energy 2019, 253, 113595. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. He, X.; Keyaerts, N.; Azevedo, I.; Meeus, L.; Hancher, L.; Glachant, J.M. How to engage consumers in demand response: A contract perspective. Util. Policy 2013, 27, 108–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Eyimaya, S.E.; Altin, N. Review of energy management systems in microgrids. Appl. Sci. 2024, 14, 1249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Kampezidou, S.I.; Romberg, J.; Vamvoudakis, K.G.; Mavris, D.N. Online Adaptive Learning in Energy Trading Stackelberg Games with Time-Coupling Constraints. In Proceedings of the 2021 American Control Conference (ACC), New Orleans, LA, USA, 25–28 May 2021; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2021; pp. 718–723. [Google Scholar]
  74. Kampezidou, S.I.; Romberg, J.; Vamvoudakis, K.G.; Mavris, D.N. Decentralized and Privacy-Preserving Learning of Approximate Stackelberg Solutions in Energy Trading Games with Demand Response Aggregators. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. Syst. 2024, 54, 6304–6319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Ozturk, Y.; Senthilkumar, D.; Kumar, S.; Lee, G. An intelligent home energy management system to improve demand response. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2013, 4, 694–701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Zhou, B.; Li, W.; Chan, K.W.; Cao, Y.; Kuang, Y.; Liu, X.; Wang, X. Smart home energy management systems: Concept, configurations, and scheduling strategies. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 61, 30–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Han, D.M.; Lim, J.H. Smart home energy management system using IEEE 802.15. 4 and zigbee. IEEE Trans. Consum. Electron. 2010, 56, 1403–1410. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Marinakis, V.; Doukas, H. An advanced IoT-based system for intelligent energy management in buildings. Sensors 2018, 18, 610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Varlamis, I.; Sardianos, C.; Chronis, C.; Dimitrakopoulos, G.; Himeur, Y.; Alsalemi, A.; Bensaali, F.; Amira, A. Smart fusion of sensor data and human feedback for personalized energy-saving recommendations. Appl. Energy 2022, 305, 117775. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Martirano, L.; Parise, G.; Greco, G.; Manganelli, M.; Massarella, F.; Cianfrini, M.; Parise, L.; di Laura Frattura, P.; Habib, E. Aggregation of users in a residential/commercial building managed by a building energy management system (BEMS). IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2018, 55, 26–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Macarulla, M.; Casals, M.; Forcada, N.; Gangolells, M. Implementation of predictive control in a commercial building energy management system using neural networks. Energy Build. 2017, 151, 511–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Thanayankizil, L.V.; Ghai, S.K.; Chakraborty, D.; Seetharam, D.P. Softgreen: Towards energy management of green office buildings with soft sensors. In Proceedings of the 2012 Fourth International Conference on Communication Systems and Networks (COMSNETS 2012), Bangalore, India, 3–7 January 2012; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2012; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  83. Dong, B.; Prakash, V.; Feng, F.; O’Neill, Z. A review of smart building sensing system for better indoor environment control. Energy Build. 2019, 199, 29–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Leephakpreeda, T. Adaptive occupancy-based lighting control via grey prediction. Build. Environ. 2005, 40, 881–886. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Linhart, F.; Scartezzini, J.L. Evening office lighting–visual comfort vs. energy efficiency vs. performance? Build. Environ. 2011, 46, 981–989. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Labeodan, T.; Zeiler, W.; Boxem, G.; Zhao, Y. Occupancy measurement in commercial office buildings for demand-driven control applications—A survey and detection system evaluation. Energy Build. 2015, 93, 303–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Ekwevugbe, T.; Brown, N.; Fan, D. A design model for building occupancy detection using sensor fusion. In Proceedings of the 2012 6th IEEE International Conference on Digital Ecosystems and Technologies (DEST), Campione d’Italia, Italy, 18–20 June 2012; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2012; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  88. Dikel, E.E.; Newsham, G.R.; Xue, H.; Valdés, J.J. Potential energy savings from high-resolution sensor controls for LED lighting. Energy Build. 2018, 158, 43–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Ryu, S.H.; Moon, H.J. Development of an occupancy prediction model using indoor environmental data based on machine learning techniques. Build. Environ. 2016, 107, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Akkaya, K.; Guvenc, I.; Aygun, R.; Pala, N.; Kadri, A. IoT-based occupancy monitoring techniques for energy-efficient smart buildings. In Proceedings of the 2015 IEEE Wireless Communications and Networking Conference Workshops (WCNCW), New Orleans, LA, USA, 9–12 March 2015; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2015; pp. 58–63. [Google Scholar]
  91. Cheng, C.C.; Lee, D. Smart sensors enable smart air conditioning control. Sensors 2014, 14, 11179–11203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Sim, S.Y.; Koh, M.J.; Joo, K.M.; Noh, S.; Park, S.; Kim, Y.H.; Park, K.S. Estimation of thermal sensation based on wrist skin temperatures. Sensors 2016, 16, 420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Sheikhi, E.; Cimellaro, G.P.; Mahin, S.A. Adaptive energy consumption optimization using IoT-based wireless sensor networks and structural health monitoring systems. In Proceedings of the European Workshop on Structural Health Monitoring, EWSHM, Bilbao, Spain, 5–8 July 2016; Volume 8, pp. 520–526. [Google Scholar]
  94. Cheng, C.C.; Lee, D. Enabling smart air conditioning by sensor development: A review. Sensors 2016, 16, 2028. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Albadi, M.H.; El-Saadany, E.F. A summary of demand response in electricity markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2008, 78, 1989–1996. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Palensky, P.; Dietrich, D. Demand side management: Demand response, intelligent energy systems, and smart loads. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2011, 7, 381–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. PJM. PJM Demand Side Response Estimated Revenue, Presented to PJM Demand Response Steering Committee; Technical Report; PJM: Audubon, PA, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  98. Warner-Freeman, J. PJM Markets Report. October 2019. Available online: https://www.pjm.com/committees-and-groups/committees/mc (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  99. Brattle. Cost-Effective Load Flexibility Can Reduce Costs by More Than $15 Billion Annually. 2019. Available online: https://www.brattle.com/insights-events/publications/brattle-study-cost-effective-load-flexibility-can-reduce-costs-by-more-than-15-billion-annually/?utm_source=chatgpt.com (accessed on 1 June 2019).
  100. Woolf, T.; Economics, E.M.E.; Schwartz, L.; Shenot, J. A Framework for Evaluating the Cost-Effectiveness of Demand; Technical Report; US Department of Energy: Washington, DC, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  101. Enel X. Enel Group. 2023. Available online: https://www.enelx.com/n-a/en (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  102. C Power. C Power Energy. 2023. Available online: http://www.cpower-energy.com/ (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  103. Comverge. 2023. Available online: https://energycentral.com/ (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  104. Energy Connect. 2023. Available online: https://portal.cpowercorp.com/Authentication (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  105. ECS. Energy Custailment Specialists, Inc. Available online: https://www.ecsgrid.com/ (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  106. North America Power Partners (NAPP). 2023. Available online: https://www.hugedomains.com/domain_profile.cfm?d=nappartners.com (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  107. Hurley, D.; Peterson, P.; Whited, M. Demand Response as a Power System Resource; Synapse Energy Economics Inc.: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  108. FERC. 2022 Assesment of Demand Response and Advanced Metering; Technical Report; Federal Energy Regulatory Commission: Washington, DC, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  109. NERC. Distributed Energy Resources: Connection, Modeling, and Reliability Considerations; Technical Report; NREL: Washington, DC, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  110. Li, W.; Xu, P.; Lu, X.; Wang, H.; Pang, Z. Electricity demand response in China: Status, feasible market schemes and pilots. Energy 2016, 114, 981–994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  111. Ayón, X.; Gruber, J.K.; Hayes, B.P.; Usaola, J.; Prodanović, M. An optimal day-ahead load scheduling approach based on the flexibility of aggregate demands. Appl. Energy 2017, 198, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Li, K.; Mu, Q.; Wang, F.; Gao, Y.; Li, G.; Shafie-Khah, M.; Catalão, J.P.; Yang, Y.; Ren, J. A business model incorporating harmonic control as a value-added service for utility-owned electricity retailers. IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2019, 55, 4441–4450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Ratshitanga, M.; Orumwense, E.F.; Krishnamurthy, S.; Melamu, M. A review of demand-side resources in active distribution systems: Communication protocols, smart metering, control, automation, and optimization. Appl. Sci. 2023, 13, 12573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Khan, A.R.; Mahmood, A.; Safdar, A.; Khan, Z.A.; Khan, N.A. Load forecasting, dynamic pricing and DSM in smart grid: A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 54, 1311–1322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Vallés, M.; Bello, A.; Reneses, J.; Frías, P. Probabilistic characterization of electricity consumer responsiveness to economic incentives. Appl. Energy 2018, 216, 296–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  116. Kampezidou, S.I.; Grijalva, S. Distribution transformers short-term load forecasting models. In Proceedings of the 2016 IEEE Power and Energy Society General Meeting (PESGM), Boston, MA, USA, 17–21 July 2016; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2016; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar]
  117. Fu, H.; Kampezidou, S.; Sung, W.; Duncan, S.; Mavris, D.N. A Data-driven Situational Awareness Approach to Monitoring Campus-wide Power Consumption. In Proceedings of the 2018 International Energy Conversion Engineering Conference, Cincinnati, OH, USA, 9–11 July 2018; p. 4414. [Google Scholar]
  118. Katz, J.; Andersen, F.M.; Morthorst, P.E. Load-shift incentives for household demand response: Evaluation of hourly dynamic pricing and rebate schemes in a wind-based electricity system. Energy 2016, 115, 1602–1616. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  119. Wang, F.; Li, K.; Zhou, L.; Ren, H.; Contreras, J.; Shafie-Khah, M.; Catalão, J.P. Daily pattern prediction based classification modeling approach for day-ahead electricity price forecasting. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2019, 105, 529–540. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Wang, F.; Zhang, Z.; Liu, C.; Yu, Y.; Pang, S.; Duić, N.; Shafie-Khah, M.; Catalao, J.P. Generative adversarial networks and convolutional neural networks based weather classification model for day ahead short-term photovoltaic power forecasting. Energy Convers. Manag. 2019, 181, 443–462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  121. Zhen, Z.; Pang, S.; Wang, F.; Li, K.; Li, Z.; Ren, H.; Shafie-khah, M.; Catalao, J.P. Pattern classification and PSO optimal weights based sky images cloud motion speed calculation method for solar PV power forecasting. IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2019, 55, 3331–3342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  122. Zhen, Z.; Liu, J.; Zhang, Z.; Wang, F.; Chai, H.; Yu, Y.; Lu, X.; Wang, T.; Lin, Y. Deep learning based surface irradiance mapping model for solar PV power forecasting using sky image. IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2020, 56, 3385–3396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  123. Wang, D.; Jia, H.; Hou, K.; Du, W.; Chen, N.; Wang, X.; Fan, M. Integrated demand response in district electricity-heating network considering double auction retail energy market based on demand-side energy stations. Appl. Energy 2019, 248, 656–678. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  124. Chen, T.; Alsafasfeh, Q.; Pourbabak, H.; Su, W. The next-generation US retail electricity market with customers and prosumers—A bibliographical survey. Energies 2017, 11, 8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Yang, J.; Zhao, J.; Luo, F.; Wen, F.; Dong, Z.Y. Decision-making for electricity retailers: A brief survey. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2017, 9, 4140–4153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  126. Apostolopoulou, D.; Bahramirad, S.; Khodaei, A. The interface of power: Moving toward distribution system operators. IEEE Power Energy Mag. 2016, 14, 46–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  127. Koltsaklis, N.E.; Dagoumas, A.S. Incorporating unit commitment aspects to the European electricity markets algorithm: An optimization model for the joint clearing of energy and reserve markets. Appl. Energy 2018, 231, 235–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  128. Behl, M.; Jain, A.; Mangharam, R. Data-Driven Modeling, Control and Tools for Cyber-Physical Energy Systems. In Proceedings of the 2016 ACM/IEEE 7th International Conference on Cyber-Physical Systems (ICCPS), Vienna, Austria, 11–14 April 2016; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2016; pp. 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  129. Ma, O.; Cheung, K. Demand Response and Energy Storage Integration Study; Technical Report; Office of Energy Efficiency and Renewable Energy, Office of Electricity: Washington, DC, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  130. Peplinski, M.; Sanders, K.T. Residential electricity demand on CAISO Flex Alert days: A case study of voluntary emergency demand response programs. Environ. Res. Energy 2023, 1, 015002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  131. Bandyopadhyay, A.; Conger, J.P.; Webber, M.E. Energetic potential for demand response in detached single family homes in Austin, TX. In Proceedings of the 2019 IEEE Texas Power and Energy Conference (TPEC), College Station, TX, USA, 7–8 February 2019; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2019; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  132. US Department of Energy. Analytic Challenges to Valuing Energy Storage. 2011. Available online: https://www.energy.gov/sites/default/files/2015/06/f24/analytic_challenges_to_valuing_energy_storage_workshop_report.pdf (accessed on 1 November 2011).
  133. Department of Energy. Roadmap to Achieve Energy Delivery Systems Cybersecurity. September 2011. Available online: https://www.energy.gov/sites/prod/files/Energy%20Delivery%20Systems%20Cybersecurity%20Roadmap_finalweb.pdf (accessed on 1 September 2011).
  134. EPA. Energy Independence and Security Act. 2007. Available online: https://www.epa.gov/laws-regulations/summary-energyindependence-and-security-act#:~:text=Public%20Law%20110%2D140%20(2007)&text=protect%20consumers%3B,of%20the%20Federal%20Government%3B%20and (accessed on 19 December 2007).
  135. NIST. Framework for Improving Critical Infrastructure Cybersecurity, Version 1.0; NIST: Gaithersburg, MD, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  136. NIST. Guidelines for Smart Grid Cybersecurity: Smart Grid Cybersecurity Strategy, Architecture, and High-Level Requirements; National Institute of Standards and Technology: Gaithersburg, MD, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  137. Iria, J.; Soares, F.; Matos, M. Optimal supply and demand bidding strategy for an aggregator of small prosumers. Appl. Energy 2018, 213, 658–669. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  138. Wang, F.; Ge, X.; Li, K.; Mi, Z. Day-ahead market optimal bidding strategy and quantitative compensation mechanism design for load aggregator engaging demand response. IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2019, 55, 5564–5573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  139. Xu, H.; Zhang, K.; Zhang, J. Optimal joint bidding and pricing of profit-seeking load serving entity. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2018, 33, 5427–5436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  140. Parvania, M.; Fotuhi-Firuzabad, M.; Shahidehpour, M. Optimal demand response aggregation in wholesale electricity markets. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2013, 4, 1957–1965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  141. Okur, Ö.; Voulis, N.; Heijnen, P.; Lukszo, Z. Critical analysis of the profitability of demand response for end-consumers and aggregators with flat-rate retail pricing. In Proceedings of the 2018 IEEE PES Innovative Smart Grid Technologies Conference Europe (ISGT), Sarajevo, Bosnia and Herzegovina, 21–25 October 2018; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2018; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  142. Nan, S.; Zhou, M.; Li, G. Optimal residential community demand response scheduling in smart grid. Appl. Energy 2018, 210, 1280–1289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  143. Agnetis, A.; De Pascale, G.; Detti, P.; Vicino, A. Load scheduling for household energy consumption optimization. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2013, 4, 2364–2373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  144. Vayá, M.G.; Andersson, G. Optimal bidding strategy of a plug-in electric vehicle aggregator in day-ahead electricity markets under uncertainty. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2014, 30, 2375–2385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  145. Baringo, L.; Amaro, R.S. A stochastic robust optimization approach for the bidding strategy of an electric vehicle aggregator. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2017, 146, 362–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  146. Chen, Z.; Wu, L.; Fu, Y. Real-time price-based demand response management for residential appliances via stochastic optimization and robust optimization. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2012, 3, 1822–1831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  147. Barhagh, S.S.; Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B.; Anvari-Moghaddam, A.; Asadi, S. Risk-involved participation of electric vehicle aggregator in energy markets with robust decision-making approach. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 239, 118076. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  148. Correa-Florez, C.A.; Michiorri, A.; Kariniotakis, G. Robust optimization for day-ahead market participation of smart-home aggregators. Appl. Energy 2018, 229, 433–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  149. Alahäivälä, A.; Corbishley, J.; Ekström, J.; Jokisalo, J.; Lehtonen, M. A control framework for the utilization of heating load flexibility in a day-ahead market. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2017, 145, 44–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  150. Adika, C.O.; Wang, L. Smart charging and appliance scheduling approaches to demand side management. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2014, 57, 232–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  151. Wu, D.; Aliprantis, D.C.; Ying, L. Load scheduling and dispatch for aggregators of plug-in electric vehicles. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2011, 3, 368–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  152. Bessa, R.J.; Matos, M. Global against divided optimization for the participation of an EV aggregator in the day-ahead electricity market. Part I: Theory. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2013, 95, 309–318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  153. Ali, M.; Alahäivälä, A.; Malik, F.; Humayun, M.; Safdarian, A.; Lehtonen, M. A market-oriented hierarchical framework for residential demand response. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2015, 69, 257–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  154. Momber, I.; Siddiqui, A.; San Roman, T.G.; Söder, L. Risk averse scheduling by a PEV aggregator under uncertainty. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2014, 30, 882–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  155. Chen, S.; Chen, Q.; Xu, Y. Strategic bidding and compensation mechanism for a load aggregator with direct thermostat control capabilities. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2016, 9, 2327–2336. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  156. Nguyen, D.T.; Le, L.B. Risk-constrained profit maximization for microgrid aggregators with demand response. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2014, 6, 135–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  157. Rashidizadeh-Kermani, H.; Najafi, H.R.; Anvari-Moghaddam, A.; Guerrero, J.M. Optimal decision-making strategy of an electric vehicle aggregator in short-term electricity markets. Energies 2018, 11, 2413. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  158. Mahmoudi, N.; Heydarian-Forushani, E.; Shafie-khah, M.; Saha, T.K.; Golshan, M.H.; Siano, P. A bottom-up approach for demand response aggregators’ participation in electricity markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2017, 143, 121–129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  159. Mathieu, J.L.; Kamgarpour, M.; Lygeros, J.; Andersson, G.; Callaway, D.S. Arbitraging intraday wholesale energy market prices with aggregations of thermostatic loads. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2014, 30, 763–772. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  160. Zhou, Y.; Wang, C.; Wu, J.; Wang, J.; Cheng, M.; Li, G. Optimal scheduling of aggregated thermostatically controlled loads with renewable generation in the intraday electricity market. Appl. Energy 2017, 188, 456–465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  161. Ayón, X.; Moreno, M.Á.; Usaola, J. Aggregators’ optimal bidding strategy in sequential day-ahead and intraday electricity spot markets. Energies 2017, 10, 450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  162. Hedegaard, R.E.; Pedersen, T.H.; Petersen, S. Multi-market demand response using economic model predictive control of space heating in residential buildings. Energy Build. 2017, 150, 253–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  163. Sánchez-Martín, P.; Lumbreras, S.; Alberdi-Alén, A. Stochastic programming applied to EV charging points for energy and reserve service markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2015, 31, 198–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  164. Posma, J.; Lampropoulos, I.; Schram, W.; van Sark, W. Provision of ancillary services from an aggregated portfolio of residential heat pumps on the Dutch Frequency Containment Reserve market. Appl. Sci. 2019, 9, 590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  165. Heleno, M.; Matos, M.A.; Lopes, J.P. A bottom-up approach to leverage the participation of residential aggregators in reserve services markets. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2016, 136, 425–433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  166. Jargstorf, J.; Wickert, M. Offer of secondary reserve with a pool of electric vehicles on the German market. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 185–195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  167. Peng, C.; Zou, J.; Lian, L.; Li, L. An optimal dispatching strategy for V2G aggregator participating in supplementary frequency regulation considering EV driving demand and aggregator’s benefits. Appl. Energy 2017, 190, 591–599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  168. Bessa, R.J.; Matos, M.A.; Soares, F.J.; Lopes, J.A.P. Optimized bidding of a EV aggregation agent in the electricity market. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2011, 3, 443–452. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  169. Bessa, R.J.; Matos, M. Optimization models for an EV aggregator selling secondary reserve in the electricity market. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2014, 106, 36–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  170. Liu, K.; Chen, Q.; Kang, C.; Su, W.; Zhong, G. Optimal operation strategy for distributed battery aggregator providing energy and ancillary services. J. Mod. Power Syst. Clean Energy 2018, 6, 722–732. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  171. Bessa, R.J.; Matos, M.A. Optimization models for EV aggregator participation in a manual reserve market. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 3085–3095. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  172. Sarker, M.R.; Dvorkin, Y.; Ortega-Vazquez, M.A. Optimal participation of an electric vehicle aggregator in day-ahead energy and reserve markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2015, 31, 3506–3515. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  173. Jin, C.; Tang, J.; Ghosh, P. Optimizing electric vehicle charging: A customer’s perspective. IEEE Trans. Veh. Technol. 2013, 62, 2919–2927. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  174. Han, S.; Han, S.; Sezaki, K. Optimal control of the plug-in electric vehicles for V2G frequency regulation using quadratic programming. In Proceedings of the ISGT 2011, Anaheim, CA, USA, 17–19 January 2011; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2011; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  175. Alipour, M.; Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B.; Moradi-Dalvand, M.; Zare, K. Stochastic scheduling of aggregators of plug-in electric vehicles for participation in energy and ancillary service markets. Energy 2017, 118, 1168–1179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  176. Iria, J.; Soares, F.; Matos, M. Optimal bidding strategy for an aggregator of prosumers in energy and secondary reserve markets. Appl. Energy 2019, 238, 1361–1372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  177. Vatandoust, B.; Ahmadian, A.; Golkar, M.A.; Elkamel, A.; Almansoori, A.; Ghaljehei, M. Risk-averse optimal bidding of electric vehicles and energy storage aggregator in day-ahead frequency regulation market. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2018, 34, 2036–2047. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  178. Iria, J.; Soares, F. Real-time provision of multiple electricity market products by an aggregator of prosumers. Appl. Energy 2019, 255, 113792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  179. Pavlak, G.S.; Henze, G.P.; Cushing, V.J. Optimizing commercial building participation in energy and ancillary service markets. Energy Build. 2014, 81, 115–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  180. Vagropoulos, S.I.; Bakirtzis, A.G. Optimal bidding strategy for electric vehicle aggregators in electricity markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 4031–4041. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  181. Iria, J.P.; Soares, F.J.; Matos, M.A. Trading small prosumers flexibility in the energy and tertiary reserve markets. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2018, 10, 2371–2382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  182. Shafie-Khah, M.; Moghaddam, M.; Sheikh-El-Eslami, M.; Catalão, J. Optimised performance of a plug-in electric vehicle aggregator in energy and reserve markets. Energy Convers. Manag. 2015, 97, 393–408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  183. Sarker, M.R.; Ortega-Vazquez, M.A.; Kirschen, D.S. Optimal coordination and scheduling of demand response via monetary incentives. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2014, 6, 1341–1352. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  184. Ghazvini, M.A.F.; Lipari, G.; Pau, M.; Ponci, F.; Monti, A.; Soares, J.; Castro, R.; Vale, Z. Congestion management in active distribution networks through demand response implementation. Sustain. Energy Grids Netw. 2019, 17, 100185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  185. O’Connell, N.; Wu, Q.; Østergaard, J.; Nielsen, A.H.; Cha, S.T.; Ding, Y. Day-ahead tariffs for the alleviation of distribution grid congestion from electric vehicles. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2012, 92, 106–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  186. Liu, W.; Wu, Q.; Wen, F.; Østergaard, J. Day-ahead congestion management in distribution systems through household demand response and distribution congestion prices. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2014, 5, 2739–2747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  187. Conejo, A.J.; Morales, J.M.; Baringo, L. Real-time demand response model. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2010, 1, 236–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  188. Von Stackelberg, H. Market Structure and Equilibrium; Springer Science & Business Media: Berlin, Germany, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  189. Simaan, M.; Cruz, J.B. On the Stackelberg strategy in nonzero-sum games. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 1973, 11, 533–555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  190. Daraeepour, A.; Kazempour, S.J.; Patiño-Echeverri, D.; Conejo, A.J. Strategic demand-side response to wind power integration. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2015, 31, 3495–3505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  191. Ramirez-Orrego, J.; Illindala, M.S.; Wang, J. Robust Flexible Ramping Product Provision by Electric Vehicles Aggregators In Multi-Settlement Electricity Markets. In Proceedings of the 2023 IEEE/IAS 59th Industrial and Commercial Power Systems Technical Conference (I&CPS), Las Vegas, NV, USA, 21–25 May 2023; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2023; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  192. Khoshjahan, M.; Kezunovic, M. Robust bidding strategy for aggregation of distributed prosumers in flexiramp market. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2022, 209, 107994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  193. Makhdoomi, H.; Moshtagh, J. Optimal Scheduling of Electrical Storage System and Flexible Loads to Participate in Energy and Flexible Ramping Product Markets. J. Oper. Autom. Power Eng. 2023, 11, 203–212. [Google Scholar]
  194. Tan, M.; Dai, Z.; Su, Y.; Chen, C.; Wang, L.; Chen, J. Bi-level optimization of charging scheduling of a battery swap station based on deep reinforcement learning. Eng. Appl. Artif. Intell. 2023, 118, 105557. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  195. Feng, D.; Zhao, Y.; Su, H.; Li, H.; Zhou, Y. Bi-level decomposition algorithm of real-time AGC command for large-scale electric vehicles in frequency regulation. J. Energy Storage 2023, 62, 106852. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  196. Haghifam, S.; Dadashi, M.; Laaksonen, H.; Zare, K.; Shafie-khah, M. A two-stage stochastic bilevel programming approach for offering strategy of DER aggregators in local and wholesale electricity markets. IET Renew. Power Gener. 2022, 16, 2732–2747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  197. Yang, H.; Li, C.; Huang, R.; Wang, F.; Hao, L.; Wu, Q.; Zhou, L. Bi-level Energy Trading Model Incorporating Large-scale Biogas Plant and Demand Response Aggregator. J. Mod. Power Syst. Clean Energy 2022, 11, 567–578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  198. Wang, Y.; Gao, S.; Liu, H.; You, D.; Liu, M.; Zhang, Y. A Bi-Level Optimal Control Method of GSHP in Demand Response Considering TOU Price. In Proceedings of the 2022 4th Asia Energy and Electrical Engineering Symposium (AEEES), Chengdu, China, 25–28 March 2022; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2022; pp. 435–440. [Google Scholar]
  199. Diaz-Londono, C.; Correa-Florez, C.A.; Vuelvas, J.; Mazza, A.; Ruiz, F.; Chicco, G. Coordination of specialised energy aggregators for balancing service provision. Sustain. Energy, Grids Netw. 2022, 32, 100817. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  200. Khojasteh, M.; Faria, P.; Lezama, F.; Vale, Z. Optimal strategy of electricity and natural gas aggregators in the energy and balance markets. Energy 2022, 257, 124753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  201. Khojasteh, M.; Faria, P.; Lezama, F.; Vale, Z. A novel adaptive robust model for scheduling distributed energy resources in local electricity and flexibility markets. Appl. Energy 2023, 342, 121144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  202. Rawat, T.; Niazi, K.; Gupta, N.; Sharma, S. A linearized multi-objective Bi-level approach for operation of smart distribution systems encompassing demand response. Energy 2022, 238, 121991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  203. Sridhar, A.; Honkapuro, S.; Ruiz, F.; Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B.; Annala, S.; Wolff, A. Aggregator decision analysis in residential demand response under uncertain consumer behavior. J. Clean. Prod. 2025, 495, 144997. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  204. Shomalzadeh, K.; Scherpen, J.M.; Camlibel, M.K. Bilevel aggregator-prosumers’ optimization problem in real-time: A convex optimization approach. Oper. Res. Lett. 2022, 50, 568–573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  205. Beraldi, P.; Khodaparasti, S. A bi-level model for the design of dynamic electricity tariffs with demand-side flexibility. Soft Comput. 2023, 27, 12925–12942. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  206. Li, N.; Chen, L.; Low, S.H. Optimal demand response based on utility maximization in power networks. In Proceedings of the 2011 IEEE Power and Energy Society General Meeting, Detroit, MI, USA, 24–28 July 2011; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2011; pp. 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  207. Gkatzikis, L.; Koutsopoulos, I.; Salonidis, T. The role of aggregators in smart grid demand response markets. IEEE J. Sel. Areas Commun. 2013, 31, 1247–1257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  208. Alshehri, K.; Ndrio, M.; Bose, S.; Başar, T. The Impact of Aggregating Distributed Energy Resources on Electricity Market Efficiency. In Proceedings of the 2019 53rd Annual Conference on Information Sciences and Systems (CISS), Baltimore, MD, USA, 20–22 March 2019; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2019; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  209. Kampezidou, S.I. A Decentralized Privacy-Preserving Data-Driven Methodology for Energy Trading in the Smart Grid. Ph.D. Thesis, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA, USA, 2023. Available online: https://hdl.handle.net/1853/76734 (accessed on 26 July 2023).
  210. Maharjan, S.; Zhu, Q.; Zhang, Y.; Gjessing, S.; Basar, T. Dependable demand response management in the smart grid: A Stackelberg game approach. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2013, 4, 120–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  211. Lou, W.; Zhu, S.; Ding, J.; Zhu, T.; Wang, M.; Sun, L.; Zhong, F.; Yang, X. Transactive Demand–Response Framework for High Renewable Penetrated Multi-Energy Prosumer Aggregators in the Context of a Smart Grid. Appl. Sci. 2023, 13, 10083. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  212. Wang, C.; Wu, Z.; Wei, L.; Yang, L.; Zhang, Y.; Yuan, B.; Zhou, M. Evaluating the externality value of distributed photovoltaics: Industry-specific investment decisions under diverse pricing schemes. Renew. Energy 2025, 247, 122986. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  213. Motalleb, M.; Ghorbani, R. Non-cooperative game-theoretic model of demand response aggregator competition for selling stored energy in storage devices. Appl. Energy 2017, 202, 581–596. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  214. Paruchuri, P.; Pearce, J.P.; Marecki, J.; Tambe, M.; Ordonez, F.; Kraus, S. Playing games for security: An efficient exact algorithm for solving Bayesian Stackelberg games. In Proceedings of the 7th International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems—Volume 2. International Foundation for Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, Estoril, Portugal, 12–16 May 2008; pp. 895–902. [Google Scholar]
  215. Jain, M.; Tsai, J.; Pita, J.; Kiekintveld, C.; Rathi, S.; Tambe, M.; Ordóñez, F. Software assistants for randomized patrol planning for the LAX Airport Police and the Federal Air Marshal Service. Interfaces 2010, 40, 267–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  216. Gharbi, A.; Ayari, M.; Yahya, A.E. Demand-response control in smart grids. Appl. Sci. 2023, 13, 2355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  217. Chen, X.; Scherpen, J.M.; Monshizadeh, N. Optimal bidding strategies in network-constrained demand response: A distributed aggregative game theoretic approach. In Proceedings of the 2024 European Control Conference (ECC), Stockholm, Sweden, 25–28 June 2024; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2024; pp. 1516–1521. [Google Scholar]
  218. Taylor, J.A.; Mathieu, J.L. Uncertainty in demand response—Identification, estimation, and learning. In The Operations Research Revolution; Informs: Catonsville, MD, USA, 2015; pp. 56–70. [Google Scholar]
  219. Park, M.; Lee, J.; Won, D.J. Demand response strategy of energy prosumer based on robust optimization through aggregator. IEEE Access 2020, 8, 202969–202979. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  220. Abapour, S.; Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B.; Hagh, M.T. Robust bidding strategy for demand response aggregators in electricity market based on game theory. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 243, 118393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  221. Yin, C.; Dong, J.; Zhang, Y. Distributionally Robust Bilevel Optimization Model for Distribution Network with Demand Response Under Uncertain Renewables Using Wasserstein Metrics. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2024, 16, 1165–1176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  222. Zhang, D.; Han, R.; Fu, W.; Ran, L.; Qin, J. Bi-level Robust Optimal Energy Management of a Community Microgrid via Stackelberg Game. IEEE Trans. Consum. Electron. 2024. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  223. Liu, X.; Gao, B.; Li, Y. Bayesian Game-Theoretic Bidding Optimization for Aggregators Considering the Breach of Demand Response Resource. Appl. Sci. 2019, 9, 576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  224. Norouzi, F.; Jadid, S. Bi-level stochastic modeling of multi-microgrid transactive energy system via coalition formation considering battery storage and demand response programs. J. Energy Storage 2025, 111, 115358. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  225. Nie, Y.; Liu, J.; Liu, X.; Zhao, Y.; Ren, K.; Chen, C. Asynchronous Multi-Agent Reinforcement Learning-Based Framework for Bi-Level Noncooperative Game-Theoretic Demand Response. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2024, 15, 5622–5637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  226. Reddy, P.P.; Veloso, M.M. Strategy learning for autonomous agents in smart grid markets. In Proceedings of the Twenty-Second International Joint Conference on Artificial Intelligence, Barcelona, Spain, 16–22 July 2011. [Google Scholar]
  227. Zhang, D.; Han, X.; Deng, C. Review on the research and practice of deep learning and reinforcement learning in smart grids. CSEE J. Power Energy Syst. 2018, 4, 362–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  228. Vázquez-Canteli, J.R.; Nagy, Z. Reinforcement learning for demand response: A review of algorithms and modeling techniques. Appl. Energy 2019, 235, 1072–1089. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  229. Cui, S.; Wang, Y.W.; Xiao, J.W.; Liu, N. A two-stage robust energy sharing management for prosumer microgrid. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2018, 15, 2741–2752. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  230. Sangoleye, F.; Jao, J.; Faris, K.; Tsiropoulou, E.E.; Papavassiliou, S. Reinforcement learning-based demand response management in smart grid systems with prosumers. IEEE Syst. J. 2023, 17, 1797–1807. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  231. Zhang, X.; Bao, T.; Yu, T.; Yang, B.; Han, C. Deep transfer Q-learning with virtual leader-follower for supply-demand Stackelberg game of smart grid. Energy 2017, 133, 348–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  232. Hazan, E. Introduction to online convex optimization. Found. Trends® Optim. 2016, 2, 157–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  233. Cardoso, A.R.; Abernethy, J.; Wang, H.; Xu, H. Competing Against Equilibria in Zero-Sum Games with Evolving Payoffs. arXiv 2019, arXiv:1907.07723. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  234. Yang, G.; Poovendran, R.; Hespanha, J.P. Adaptive learning in two-player Stackelberg games with continuous action sets. In Proceedings of the 2019 IEEE 58th Conference on Decision and Control (CDC), Nice, France, 11–13 December 2019. [Google Scholar]
  235. Dolatabadi, M.; Siano, P. A scalable privacy-preserving distributed parallel optimization for a large-scale aggregation of prosumers with residential PV-battery systems. IEEE Access 2020, 8, 210950–210960. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  236. Kampezidou, S.I.; Tikayat Ray, A.; Bhat, A.P.; Pinon Fischer, O.J.; Mavris, D.N. Fundamental components and principles of supervised machine learning workflows with numerical and categorical data. Eng 2024, 5, 384–416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  237. Hou, P.; Yang, G.; Hu, J.; Douglass, P.J.; Xue, Y. A distributed transactive energy mechanism for integrating PV and storage prosumers in market operation. Engineering 2022, 12, 171–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  238. Poczos, B.; Tibshirani, R. Dual methods and ADMM. In Carnegie Mellon, Convex Optimization Class Notes; Carnegie Mellon University: Pittsburgh, PA, USA; pp. 10–725. Available online: https://www.stat.cmu.edu/~ryantibs/convexopt-S15/lectures/21-dual-meth.pdf (accessed on 16 July 2025).
  239. La Bella, A.; Falsone, A.; Ioli, D.; Prandini, M.; Scattolini, R. A mixed-integer distributed approach to prosumers aggregation for providing balancing services. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2021, 133, 107228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  240. Yahaya, A.S.; Javaid, N.; Almogren, A.; Ahmed, A.; Gulfam, S.M.; Radwan, A. A two-stage privacy preservation and secure peer-to-peer energy trading model using blockchain and cloud-based aggregator. IEEE Access 2021, 9, 143121–143137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  241. Abdelsalam, H.A.; Srivastava, A.K.; Eldosouky, A. Blockchain-based privacy-preserving and energy-saving mechanism for electricity prosumers. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2021, 13, 302–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  242. Pop, C.D.; Antal, M.; Cioara, T.; Anghel, I.; Salomie, I. Blockchain and demand response: Zero-knowledge proofs for energy transactions privacy. Sensors 2020, 20, 5678. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  243. Aiyoshi, E.; Shimizu, K. Hierarchical decentralized systems and its new solution by a barrier method. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. 1981, 11, 444–449. [Google Scholar]
  244. Chen, X.; Huang, M.; Ma, S. Decentralized bilevel optimization. arXiv 2022, arXiv:2206.05670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  245. Sinha, A.; Malo, P.; Deb, K. Evolutionary algorithm for bilevel optimization using approximations of the lower level optimal solution mapping. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 257, 395–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  246. Wen, F.; David, A. Strategic bidding for electricity supply in a day-ahead energy market. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2001, 59, 197–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  247. Guan, X.; Ho, Y.C.; Lai, F. An ordinal optimization-based bidding strategy for electric power suppliers in the daily energy market. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2001, 16, 788–797. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  248. Nanduri, V.; Das, T.K. A reinforcement learning model to assess market power under auction-based energy pricing. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2007, 22, 85–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  249. Wu, Q.; Guo, J. Optimal bidding strategies in electricity markets using reinforcement learning. Electr. Power Compon. Syst. 2004, 32, 175–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  250. Krause, T.; Andersson, G.; Ernst, D.; Vdovina-Beck, E.; Cherkaoui, R.; Germond, A. Nash equilibria and reinforcement learning for active decision maker modelling in power markets. In Proceedings of the 6th IAEE European Conference: Modelling in Energy Economics and Policy, Zurich, Switzerland, 2–4 September 2004. [Google Scholar]
  251. Tellidou, A.C.; Bakirtzis, A.G. Agent-based analysis of capacity withholding and tacit collusion in electricity markets. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2007, 22, 1735–1742. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  252. Wang, H.; Huang, T.; Liao, X.; Abu-Rub, H.; Chen, G. Reinforcement learning for constrained energy trading games with incomplete information. IEEE Trans. Cybern. 2016, 47, 3404–3416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  253. Kandil, S.M.; Farag, H.E.; Shaaban, M.F.; El-Sharafy, M.Z. A combined resource allocation framework for PEVs charging stations, renewable energy resources and distributed energy storage systems. Energy 2018, 143, 961–972. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  254. Talari, S.; Shafie-Khah, M.; Chen, Y.; Wei, W.; Gaspar, P.D.; Catalao, J.P. Real-time scheduling of demand response options considering the volatility of wind power generation. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2018, 10, 1633–1643. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  255. Safdarian, A.; Fotuhi-Firuzabad, M.; Lehtonen, M. A medium-term decision model for DisCos: Forward contracting and TOU pricing. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2014, 30, 1143–1154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  256. Misaghian, M.S.; Saffari, M.; Kia, M.; Nazar, M.S.; Heidari, A.; Shafie-khah, M.; Catalão, J.P. Hierarchical framework for optimal operation of multiple microgrids considering demand response programs. Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2018, 165, 199–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  257. Li, B.; Wang, X.; Shahidehpour, M.; Jiang, C.; Li, Z. Robust bidding strategy and profit allocation for cooperative DSR aggregators with correlated wind power generation. IEEE Trans. Sustain. Energy 2018, 10, 1904–1915. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  258. Vahid-Ghavidel, M.; Mahmoudi, N.; Mohammadi-Ivatloo, B. Self-scheduling of demand response aggregators in short-term markets based on information gap decision theory. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2018, 10, 2115–2126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  259. Rezaei, N.; Ahmadi, A.; Khazali, A.; Aghaei, J. Multiobjective risk-constrained optimal bidding strategy of smart microgrids: An IGDT-based normal boundary intersection approach. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2018, 15, 1532–1543. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  260. Lujano-Rojas, J.M.; Zubi, G.; Dufo-López, R.; Bernal-Agustín, J.L.; Garcia-Paricio, E.; Catalão, J.P. Contract design of direct-load control programs and their optimal management by genetic algorithm. Energy 2019, 186, 115807. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  261. Hu, M.; Xiao, F. Price-responsive model-based optimal demand response control of inverter air conditioners using genetic algorithm. Appl. Energy 2018, 219, 151–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  262. EPA. Web Policies and Procedures. Available online: https://www.epa.gov/web-policies-and-procedures/epa-disclaimers (accessed on 30 January 2025).
Figure 1. The diagram demonstrates this paper’s motivation (2030 and 2050 goals) and the unique role of distributed loads in achieving the goals in future US electricity markets. To facilitate the integration of distributed loads in future US electricity markets, this paper proposes the FCUPS evaluation criteria for DR aggregator and prosumer operational frameworks (Section 3.7).
Figure 1. The diagram demonstrates this paper’s motivation (2030 and 2050 goals) and the unique role of distributed loads in achieving the goals in future US electricity markets. To facilitate the integration of distributed loads in future US electricity markets, this paper proposes the FCUPS evaluation criteria for DR aggregator and prosumer operational frameworks (Section 3.7).
Applsci 15 08066 g001
Figure 2. Worldwide and US CO2 emissions breakdown: (a) 2014 global CO2 emissions from fossil fuel combustion and industrial processes according to US Department of Energy [46]; (b) total US CO2 gas emissions emitted by economic sector, according to EPA (Table ES-6 in [47]) in 2020, with electricity-related emissions distributed by sector. The transportation sector is growing due to electric vehicles.
Figure 2. Worldwide and US CO2 emissions breakdown: (a) 2014 global CO2 emissions from fossil fuel combustion and industrial processes according to US Department of Energy [46]; (b) total US CO2 gas emissions emitted by economic sector, according to EPA (Table ES-6 in [47]) in 2020, with electricity-related emissions distributed by sector. The transportation sector is growing due to electric vehicles.
Applsci 15 08066 g002
Table 1. Summary of energy-efficient technologies for the distributed load. Energy/CO2 savings are shown as a percentage of the building’s total demand, calculated by multiplying the savings at the device level by the device’s participation in the total building’s demand. HVAC is estimated to consume about 50% of the total building’s demand [48].
Table 1. Summary of energy-efficient technologies for the distributed load. Energy/CO2 savings are shown as a percentage of the building’s total demand, calculated by multiplying the savings at the device level by the device’s participation in the total building’s demand. HVAC is estimated to consume about 50% of the total building’s demand [48].
TechnologyEnergy/CO2 SavingsEquipment/ServicePaper
Efficient equipmentVariesAppliances and devices [49,50]
Efficient lightingVariesMultiple technologies [51]
Efficient HVAC4.5%Energy Star HVAC [48]
Sensors55%Occupancy detection for HVAC [43]
20%Sensing for light control [52]
Energy managementUp to 23%Smart control per device [32]
Efficient structures76.8%Polystyrene insulation [53]
50–70%Passive solar design [54]
3%Double skin facade (DSF) [55]
60%DSF with solar and motor-blinds [56]
VariesGreen walls, shape, atrium architecture [57,58,59]
Renewable integration62%Renewable energy supply [44]
Utility-saving programs30–40% of controllable loadDirect load control (DLC) [60]
3.09%Conservation voltage reduction (CVR) [61,62,63]
64%Irreducible/curtailable programs [64]
Energy market3% in 2004Peak load DR [64]
42%99% time of usage/1% critical peak pricing (CPP) [65]
12–33%Real-time pricing [66]
Table 2. Examples of sensor-based energy management systems for the distributed load.
Table 2. Examples of sensor-based energy management systems for the distributed load.
System TypeSensor InputsDevices ControlledPaper
HEMSAppliance status, renewable energy and energy storage status, electric car battery statusSchedulable appliances, renewable energy storage devices, electric car [76]
HEMSOccupancy sensor, PIR, cameraLights, HVAC, security [77]
HEMSEnergy prices, user behavior, renewable status, weather, indoor temperature, occupancy, CO2 sensor, fuel costHVAC [78]
HEMSUser behavior, user feedback, indoor temperature, luminosity, humidity, appliance demand, motion sensor, cameraSavings recommendations, lights, HVAC, appliances, devices [79]
HEMS/BEMSEnergy pricesHeat pump [80]
BEMSIndoor temperatureBoiler [81]
BEMSCalendars, computer activity, employee badge scanning, Wi-FiLights, HVAC [82]
Table 3. Overview of sensor-based device control for energy savings at the distributed load.
Table 3. Overview of sensor-based device control for energy savings at the distributed load.
Sensor TypeInferenceDevice ControlledPaper
Motion sensorOccupancy levelsLights [84]
Photo sensorLight levelsLights [85]
Chair sensorOccupancy levelsBuilding systems [86]
CO2 sensorOccupancy levelsLights, HVAC [87]
Pressure matsOccupancy levelsLED lights [88]
Sound sensorOccupancy levelsLights, HVAC [87]
Camera sensorOccupancy levelsLights, HVAC, appliances, controls [89]
Wi-Fi sensorOccupancy levelsHVAC [90]
Smart phonesOccupants’ informationHVAC [91]
Indoor temperature sensorOccupants’ informationHVAC [91]
Indoor humidity sensorOccupancy levelsLights, HVAC, appliances, controls [89]
Skin temperature sensorThermal sensationHVAC [92]
Heart rate sensorThermal sensationHVAC [92]
Wearable sensorOccupancy levelsDemand control [93]
Thermo-fluidic sensorOccupancy levelsHVAC [94]
Table 4. Some DR aggregators in the USA [28,69]. Selected content from two references is merged.
Table 4. Some DR aggregators in the USA [28,69]. Selected content from two references is merged.
Company (Capacity)Customer PortfolioStrategyBusiness ModelPaper
EnerNOC (MA) (∼1000 MW)Large customer (<1 GW): industrial, commercialDR design, sell DR to ISOsAutomation, metering, and communication with direct control [101]
Cpower (MD) (∼2000 MW)Large customer (<1 GW)Energy management meteringStrategic energy asset management [102]
Comverge (GA) (∼500 MW)ResidentialSmart thermostat and web portalInstallation and control, sell DR to utilities and ISOs [103]
Energy Connect (CA)Large customer (<1 GW): industrial, commercial, governmentAutomation, metering and communicationEnergy automation service provider [104]
Energy CurtailmentLarge customer (<1 GW): industrial, commercialSell DR to utilitiesMetering [105]
Specialist ECS (NY) (∼1000 MW)Industrial, commercial, servicesSell DR to utilities and ISOsSoftware and analytics
North America Power Partners NAPP (NJ) (∼500 MW)Industrial, commercialSell DR to utilities and ISOsWeb-based platform for monitoring, self-scheduling [106]
Table 5. DR participation across different ISOs in the US in 2010 [107] and in 2022 [108]. The available DR is used as a capacity resource and for DR emergencies, ancillary services, and bidding energy.
Table 5. DR participation across different ISOs in the US in 2010 [107] and in 2022 [108]. The available DR is used as a capacity resource and for DR emergencies, ancillary services, and bidding energy.
ISOTotal DR LoadDR as % of Peak Demand
2010202220102022
CAISO2135 MW3900 MW4.5%36%
ERCOT1484 MW4354.5 MW2.3%5.9%
ISO-NE2116 MW533.7 MW7.8%2.3%
MISO8663 MW12,197 MW8%10.2%
NYISO2498 MW1345.5 MW7.5%4.4%
PJM13,306 MW9914 MW10.5%6.8%
SPP1500 MW176.2 MW3.3%0.3%
Table 6. Overview of DR aggregator frameworks for the DAM, IDM, and reserve markets (aFRR, FCR, and mFRR). The star ✓ denotes an imbalance type of cost for the aggregator. The optimization of either the aggregator’s or the prosumer’s objective indicates a significant lack of competition consideration when modeling aggregator-prosumer frameworks.
Table 6. Overview of DR aggregator frameworks for the DAM, IDM, and reserve markets (aFRR, FCR, and mFRR). The star ✓ denotes an imbalance type of cost for the aggregator. The optimization of either the aggregator’s or the prosumer’s objective indicates a significant lack of competition consideration when modeling aggregator-prosumer frameworks.
Market TypeMethodObjective: Min Agg./Pros. CostDevicesProsumer RewardPaper
DAMLinear Optimization✓/-Appliances- [111]
MILP✓/-BESS, appliancesTime-varying [140]
MILP✓/-AppliancesOptimal flat rate [141]
MILP-/✓BESS, appliancesTOU, CPP, RTP [142]
MILP-/✓AppliancesTOU, time-varying [143]
Bi-level Optimization✓/-EV- [144]
Bi-level Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV- [144]
Stochastic Robust Opt.✓/-EV- [145]
Stochastic Robust Opt.-/✓AppliancesRTP [146]
Robust Optimization✓/-EV- [147]
Robust Optimization✓/-BESS, thermal loads- [148]
Optimization✓/-Electric heatersFlat rate, extra [149]
Algorithm-/✓BESS, appliancesRTP [150]
Algorithm✓/-EV- [151]
DAM, IMLinear Optimization✓/-EV- [152]
Linear Optimization-/✓Storage heatersRTP, fixed pay [153]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV, TCL, appliances- [137]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EVFlat Rate [154]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EVYes [155]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-BESSFlat rate, extra [156]
Bi-level Stochastic Opt.✓/-EVOptimal flat rate [157]
Stochastic Optimization✓/-UnspecifiedOptimal time-varying [158]
IDMLinear Optimization✓/-TCL- [159]
MPC/-TCL- [160]
DAM, IDMProbabilistic Opt.✓/-BESS, appliances- [161]
MPC, Simulation/-Space heaters- [162]
DAM, IDM, aFRR2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV- [163]
FCRSimulation✓/-Heat pumps- [164]
mFRRHeuristic-/✓TCL- [165]
aFRRAgent-based-/✓EVYes [166]
Multi-Objective Opt.✓/-EV- [167]
DAM, aFRROptimization✓/-EV- [168,169]
Optimization✓/-BESS- [170]
Optimization✓/-EV- [171]
Optimization✓/-EVDegradation [172]
Optimization✓/-EVFlat rate [173]
Quadratic Optimization✓/-EV- [174]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV- [175]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV, TCL- [176]
Stochastic Optimization✓/-EV, BESS- [177]
MPC✓/-EV, TCL- [178]
MPC✓/-Office HVAC- [179]
DAM, aFRR, IM2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV- [180]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EV, TCL, appliances- [181]
2-Stage Stochastic Opt.✓/-EVOptimal fixed [182]
Congestion DAMMILP✓/-AppliancesRTP, time-varying [183]
Cong. DAM/DSO tariffsLinear Optimization✓/-EV, heat pumpsFlat rate [184]
Linear Optimization✓/-EV or appliances- [185,186]
Table 7. Aggregator applications formulated as Stackelberg games (also known as bi-level programs). Application areas include different aggregator or prosumer types, as well as different market types where such games are observed between aggregators and prosumers.
Table 7. Aggregator applications formulated as Stackelberg games (also known as bi-level programs). Application areas include different aggregator or prosumer types, as well as different market types where such games are observed between aggregators and prosumers.
Description of Bi-Level ProgramService/MarketApproachPaper
Large consumers, significant windEnergy, reservesStochastic, MPEC [190]
Electric vehicle aggregatorFlexible rampingRobust optimization [191]
DAM and RTM prosumer aggregatorEnergy, reserve, flexible rampingRobust, risk-averse [192]
Batteries and flexible loadEnergy, flexible ramping gen.Co-optimization, MILP [193]
Battery swap aggregatorEconomic, peak shavingRL, MILP [194]
Large-scale electric vehiclesFrequency regulationPiece-wise linear [195]
Strategy evaluation of DER aggregatorEconomic, wholesale and localStochastic, MPEC [196]
Large-scale biogas and DREnergy, DRNon-linear, MPEC [197]
Ground source heat pump aggregatorPeak shaving, valley filling, DROptimal control [198]
Specialized load aggregatorBalancing, frequency, reservesCustom algorithm [199]
Combined heat and powerEnergy, balanceStochastic, big-M, MPEC [200]
Mix load aggregatorEnergy, flexibility, localRobust, cutting planes [201]
DSO and battery-generator aggregatorDR ϵ -constraint, KKT [202]
Residential consumer aggregatorDRStochastic, MPEC [203]
Bidirectional solved uni-directionallyDRConvex optimization [204]
Battery-generator aggregatorDRMINLP [205]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kampezidou, S.I.; Mavris, D.N. Transformation of Demand-Response Aggregator Operations in Future US Electricity Markets: A Review of Technologies and Open Research Areas with Game Theory. Appl. Sci. 2025, 15, 8066. https://doi.org/10.3390/app15148066

AMA Style

Kampezidou SI, Mavris DN. Transformation of Demand-Response Aggregator Operations in Future US Electricity Markets: A Review of Technologies and Open Research Areas with Game Theory. Applied Sciences. 2025; 15(14):8066. https://doi.org/10.3390/app15148066

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kampezidou, Styliani I., and Dimitri N. Mavris. 2025. "Transformation of Demand-Response Aggregator Operations in Future US Electricity Markets: A Review of Technologies and Open Research Areas with Game Theory" Applied Sciences 15, no. 14: 8066. https://doi.org/10.3390/app15148066

APA Style

Kampezidou, S. I., & Mavris, D. N. (2025). Transformation of Demand-Response Aggregator Operations in Future US Electricity Markets: A Review of Technologies and Open Research Areas with Game Theory. Applied Sciences, 15(14), 8066. https://doi.org/10.3390/app15148066

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop