Big Tech, Competition Policy, and Strategic Management: An Alternative Perspective to Teece
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. The Main Critiques
3. An Alternative Perspective on BT
4. Possible Paths Forward
5. Concluding Thoughts
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
1 | Given the nature of the opinions raised in the essay and this exchange, disclosure over potential conflicts of interest is appropriate. The authorship of this essay has no conflicts; we have no business, financial or otherwise, in BT or over its regulation. The Berkeley Research Group—Teece’s consultancy may, however, have significant conflicts, given it is one of the handful of firms that “control the lion’s share of the market for expert witnesses and economic reports in antitrust cases and merger reviews” [https://www.yahoo.com/now/inside-compass-lexecon-one-top-080000400.html] (accessed on 5 November 2023). It is difficult to fathom why such a conflict of interest was not explicitly provided to readers of that COPE journal, however. |
2 | We question why there is any need to take swipes at unnamed economists, or to make CP an us-as-SM versus them-as-competition-economists narrative. Nothing is gained in terms of such framing [either BT is good for innovation or it is not, separate from any economist’s opinions]. Further, that framing is false; economists have been studying dynamics, even involving digital platforms, for decades (e.g., Davis 2011; Evans 2003; Rochet and Tirole 2003). |
3 | Recent SM empirical work (e.g., Thatchenkery and Katila 2023) indicates regulation is good for innovation. And, a cursory literature review of a half-dozen top SM journals [with BT firms mentioned in the abstract, as well as either antitrust, competition, or innovation as search terms] indicates a mainly even split on positive and negative attributions. |
4 | As of mid-August 2023, the markets indicate that BT is expected to do well: among the top five US platforms (AAPL, AMZN, GOOG, MSFT, and META), the median P/E is 35 (max 328), the market value is USD 1.65T (max 2.8), and the operating margins are 26 percent (max 41). Between 2015 and 2020, about 80 percent of revenues were derived from each firm’s core business (Anonymous 2021). |
5 | We do not formally define such terms here, not to be hypocritical, but rather because our precision lies in describing the targeted ideas and not with the terminology of the SM field itself. |
6 | Note that the very idea that a select few general concepts from SM should dominate CP thinking seems overly hopeful. Taking just the M&A application, there are a myriad of other issues that can be involved, from multi-market competition to social dumping and camouflage, to job market effects countering efficiency arguments, to effects on local cluster strength, and so on. In other words, suggestions for improvements to CP should come from many sources, not just a profit-performance-oriented SM. |
7 | Not only are the specifics lacking, but neither the message nor the arguments are new. In the past few years there has been a marked uptick on this subject by Teece and his consulting firm (Berkeley Research Group [BRG]), especially as it relates to BT (see, for example, Teece’s (2021) paper’s similarities in the Table 1’s; the commonalities here with the Petit and Teece (2021) piece in the journal he co-edits, specifically in Section 2’s comparison of static and dynamic competition, Section 3.3’s focus on digital firms, Section 4’s analysis of BT’s rent types, and Section 5.2’s messages on the dynamic competition paradigm; the supplementary materials on BRG’s website with analogous messages—https://www.thinkbrg.com/insights/news/comp-disputes-big-tech/, and https://www.thinkbrg.com/insights/publications/ts-big-tech-antitrust-legislation-digital/ (accessed on 5 November 2023); or, the recent Academy Proceedings (Jacobides et al. 2021) that featured a distinguished forum—including Teece—where many of the same issues were discussed). |
8 | Note that most of the firms and their digital processes alluded to by Teece are embedded in consumer-driven data and consumer manipulation, often leveraging private information that most consumers, if they had a real choice, would refuse to provide. |
9 | Note that in Internet time, BT firms have ‘lasted forever’—Apple and Microsoft are over 40 years old, and Google and Amazon are over 20; even Meta is over 15 years old. Obviously, the ability for platforms to endure is a newer phenomenon, but one based on established ideas, like network effects and anticompetitive actions (e.g., tying), that have not been well investigated or enforced for decades. |
10 | Setting aside the preceding concerns over the rationale, logic, originality, and specifics of Teece’s call to action for SM scholars, it is worthwhile to just consider for a moment the limits involved in the processes implied. Even if ‘we’ could provide new, evidence-based advice to improve CP, its translation into reality—in law and in enforcement—is likely to be severely restricted by the real legal and political issues involved (e.g., Rainey 2019). Also, consider ‘our’ own limitations before even providing that new, evidence-based advice to potentially improve CP in the first place. SM scholarship faces many challenges in doing so: We have an overflow of questionable, partial, and mostly untested theories that span a very wide and growing set of loosely related phenomena. Such theorizing has too often been critiqued for lacking any practical value, which is unsurprising given current incentives that motivate conceptualizations at a more generalizable and citable level (e.g., Cronin et al. 2021). And, we have no recognized system to critique, assess, and remove ‘bad’ theory (e.g., Arend 2022). We put our faith in a very flawed ‘marketplace of ideas’—one that has too often been revealed as trendy and commercial (e.g., Ghemawat 2002). And, for some unspoken reason, our associations outright refuse to generate a database of the field’s knowledge—one that is searchable and exploitable by AI (e.g., to identify gaps and conflicts in our current knowledge). |
11 | Additional and often more subtle advantages BT has over new rivals include the following: being able to shape consumer expectations (e.g., in website aesthetics, functions, inter-operability) to their strengths and rivals’ weaknesses; being able to push the edges of performance more based on having access to more data and more levers to alter conditions near that data’s local inputs; having more confidence in the AI/ML tools being used because they were developed in-house; being able to hire more specialists and gain from their inputs and automated coordination; and being more able to leverage the legal systems to delay enforcement and drain plaintiff rivals of funds and of time to pursue their limited opportunities. |
12 | While BT can act in ways to enhance innovation (e.g., by providing stability in the market for complementors) (e.g., Gavetti et al. 2017; Gawer and Henderson 2007), they often behave in other ways to depress it (e.g., through tying and otherwise advantaging their own offerings over those of would-be rivals) (e.g., Eisenmann et al. 2011; Kamepalli et al. 2020; Ozcan and Hannah 2020; Wen and Zhu 2019). Regulatory action—in the few cases it occurs—often has had pro-innovation effects not noted until years later (e.g., Google not being crushed by Microsoft because Bing was not tied to Office—see Lohr 2019). |
13 | Note that CSR-related, DEI-related, and other such scores (e.g., for assessing B-Corp eligibility [https://www.bcorporation.net/en-us/certification/] (accessed on 5 November 2023)) are here and expanding, whether we participate or not. We need to be part of, if not lead, those conversations, or we risk being left behind in our own area of expertise, and that is not good for society or science because inevitably, when such measures are not based on objective research, they end up being bent towards private ends rather than public interests. |
References
- Anonymous. 2021. Collusion and collisions. The Economist, February 27. [Google Scholar]
- Arend, Richard J. 2006. Bursting Bubbles: What the Internet Could Have Meant to Management Academia. Journal of Management Inquiry 15: 372–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arend, Richard J. 2022. We Are Crisis: Runtime Errors in Programmatic Theory. Academy of Management Review 47: 331–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Besen, Stanley M., and Robert J. Levinson. 2012. Introduction: The Use and Abuse of Voluntary Standard-Setting Processes in a Post-Rambus World: Law, Economics, and Competition Policy. The Antitrust Bulletin 57: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloom, Nicholas, John Van Reenen, and Heidi Williams. 2019. A toolkit of policies to promote innovation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 33: 163–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crémer, Jacques, Gregory S. Crawford, David Dinielli, Amelia Fletcher, Paul Heidhues, Monika Schnitzer, Fiona M. Scott Morton, and Katja Seim. 2021. Fairness and contestability in the Digital Markets Act. Digital Regulation Project. Yale Journal on Regulation 40: 973–1012. [Google Scholar]
- Cronin, Matthew A., Jeroen Stouten, and Daan Van Knippenberg. 2021. The theory crisis in management research: Solving the right problem. Academy of Management Review 46: 667–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Davis, Peter. 2011. On the role of empirical industrial organization in competition policy. International Journal of Industrial Organization 29: 323–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eisenmann, Thomas, Geoffrey Parker, and Marshall Van Alstyne. 2011. Platform envelopment. Strategic Management Journal 32: 1270–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Evans, David. 2003. The Antitrust Economics of Multi-Sided Platform Markets. Yale Journal on Regulation 20: 325–82. [Google Scholar]
- Furman, Jason. 2019. Unlocking Digital Competition. Report of the Digital Competition Expert Panel. London: The National Archives. [Google Scholar]
- Gavetti, Giovanni, Constance E. Helfat, and Luigi Marengo. 2017. Searching, shaping, and the quest for superior performance. Strategy Science 2: 194–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gawer, Annabelle, and Rebecca Henderson. 2007. Platform owner entry and innovation in complementary markets: Evidence from Intel. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 16: 1–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ghemawat, Pankaj. 2002. Competition and business strategy in historical perspective. Business History Review 76: 37–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Girod, S. J. G., and L. S. Duke. 2019. Digital Transformation at GE: Shifting Minds for Agility. New Delhi: IMD, IMD-7-2011. [Google Scholar]
- Guggenberger, Nikolas. 2020. Essential platforms. Stanford Technology Law Review 24: 237–343. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hajiyev, Nazim U. 2012. Studying of Special Practical Issues of Abuse of Dominance. Journal of Economic Sciences: Theory, and Practice 69: 55–90. [Google Scholar]
- Jacobides, M. G., M. Cusumano, A. Gawer, J. Kwoka, I. Lianos, G. Parker, N. Petit, G. Petropoulos, D. J. Teece, V. Tommasso, and et al. 2021. How should we Regulate Platforms and Ecosystems? Management tools for a key societal challenge. Academy of Management Annual Meeting Proceedings 2021: 1. [Google Scholar]
- Jennejohn, Matthew. 2015. Innovation and the Institutional Design of Merger Control. The Journal of Corporate Law 41: 167–215. [Google Scholar]
- Kamepalli, Sai Krishna, Raghuram Rajan, and Luigi Zingales. 2020. Kill Zone. SSRN Working Paper. no. 27146. Available online: https://www.nber.org/papers/w27146 (accessed on 5 November 2023).
- Kaplan, Philip J. 2002. F’d Companies: Spectacular Dot-com Flameouts. New York: Simon and Schuster. [Google Scholar]
- Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro. 1985. Network externalities, competition, and compatibility. The American Economic Review 75: 424–40. [Google Scholar]
- Katz, Michael L., and Carl Shapiro. 1994. Systems competition and network effects. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 93–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kerber, Wolfgang. 2022. Taming Tech Giants: The Neglected Interplay Between Competition Law and Data Protection (Privacy) Law. The Antitrust Bulletin 67: 280–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Khan, Lina M. 2017. Amazon’s antitrust paradox. Yale Law Journal 126: 710–805. [Google Scholar]
- Kimmelman, G. 2023. Diving into the Digital Markets Act (DMA): Implementation and Implications. [Powerpoint presentation slides of 20 September 2023]. September 20. [Google Scholar]
- Knee, Jonathan A. 2021. The Platform Delusion: Who Wins and Who Loses in the Age of Tech Titans. New York: Portfolio/Penguin. [Google Scholar]
- Krotz, Riley T., Gregory T. Gundlach, and Diana L. Moss. 2022. Modernizing Competition Policy and Law: The Impact of Marketing Developments on the Legal Treatment of Price Maintenance in the United States, the European Union, and China. Journal of Public Policy, and Marketing 41: 221–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lașcov, Victor, and Constanța Tiuhtii. 2020. The Damage Caused by Anticompetitive Practices. Effective Methods and Techniques of Quantification. Ovidius University Annals, Economic Sciences Series 20: 380–86. [Google Scholar]
- Lemley, Mark A., and Andrew McCreary. 2019. Exit Strategy. Stanford Law and Economics, Working Paper No. 542. Clayton: Olin. [Google Scholar]
- Lohr, Steve. 2019. 5 Lessons from Microsoft’s antitrust woes, by people who lived it. The New York Times, June 23. [Google Scholar]
- Marty, Frédéric, and Thierry Warin. 2023. Multi-sided platforms and innovation: A competition law perspective. Competition, and Change 27: 184–204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mitroff, Ian I., and Abraham Silvers. 2010. Dirty Rotten Strategies: How We Trick Ourselves and Others into Solving the Wrong Problems Precisely. Stanford, CA: Stanford Business Books. [Google Scholar]
- Nelson, R. Richard, and Sidney G. Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Newman, John M. 2019. Antitrust in digital markets. Vanderbilt Law Review 72: 1497–561. [Google Scholar]
- Ozcan, Pinar, and Douglas Hannah. 2020. Forced ecosystems and digital stepchildren: Reconfiguring advertising suppliers to realize disruptive social media technology. Strategy Science 5: 193–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Petit, Nicolas, and David J. Teece. 2021. Innovating big tech firms and competition policy: Favoring dynamic over static competition. Industrial and Corporate Change 30: 1168–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Petit, Nicolas, and David Teece. 2020. Taking Ecosystems Competition Seriously in the Digital Economy: A (Preliminary) Dynamic Competition/Capabilities Perspective. Capabilities Perspective, December 9. [Google Scholar]
- Popiel, Pawel. 2023. Emerging platform governance: Antitrust reform and non-competitive harms in digital platform markets. Information, Communication, and Society, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Posner, Richard A. 2001. Antitrust in the New Economy. Antitrust Law Journal 68: 925–39. [Google Scholar]
- Rainey, Toria. 2019. Is breaking up Amazon, Facebook, and Google a good idea? BU Today, October 7. [Google Scholar]
- Rochet, Jean-Charles, and Jean Tirole. 2003. Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association 1: 990–1029. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sautet, Frederic. 2018. Schumpeterian Rents. In The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management. Edited by Mie Augier and David J. Teece. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 1528–30. [Google Scholar]
- Shapiro, Carl, and Hal R. Varian Varian. 1999. Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Press. [Google Scholar]
- Stigler, George J. 1971. The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economicsc and Management Science 2: 3–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Teece, David J. 2020. Innovation, governance, and capabilities: Implications for competition policy: A Tribute to Nobel Laureate Oliver Williamson by his Colleague and Mentee David J. Teece. Industrial and Corporate Change 29: 1075–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Teece, David J. 2021. Towards a dynamic competition approach to big tech merger enforcement: The Facebook-Giphy example. Competition Policy International, December 6. [Google Scholar]
- Teece, David J. 2023. Big Tech and Strategic Management: How Management Scholars Can Inform Competition Policy. Academy of Management Perspectives 37: 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thatchenkery, Sruthi, and Riitta Katila. 2023. Innovation and profitability following antitrust intervention against a dominant platform: The wild, wild west? Strategic Management Journal 44: 943–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tirole, Jean. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Vaheesan, Sandeep. 2015. Reconsidering Brooke Group: Predatory Pricing in Light of Empirical Learning. Berkeley Business Law Journal 12: 81–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wen, Wen, and Feng Zhu. 2019. Threat of platform-owner entry and complementor responses: Evidence from the mobile app market. Strategic Management Journal 40: 1336–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, Tim. 2019. The Utah Statement: Reviving Antimonopoly Traditions for the Era of Big Tech. OneZero. Available online: https://onezero.medium.com/the-utah-statement-reviving-antimonopoly-traditions-for-the-era-of-big-tech-e6be198012d7 (accessed on 5 November 2023).
- Zerbe, Richard O., Jr., and Michael T. Mumford. 1996. Does predatory pricing exist? Economic theory and the courts after Brooke Group. The Antitrust Bulletin 41: 949–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
(Alleged) Direct Abuse of Position/Anti-Competitive Behavior
| Building Barriers to Entry to Remain Dominant through…
|
Advantages of Size and Scope
| |
Ways to Make More Money from a Dominant Position
|
Harms to Customers
| Harms to Rivals
|
Evidence of Dominance or of Expected Dominance
| |
Evidence of Collusion
|
Economists and Economic Theory Involved
| What Competition Policy Should/Could Involve
|
Implementation Issues for Competition Policy
| Big Tech Regulatory Defenses that Do Not Work
|
Current Competition Policy Lack of Impact
| What Competition Policy Does Not Cover But Is Important
|
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Arend, R.J. Big Tech, Competition Policy, and Strategic Management: An Alternative Perspective to Teece. Adm. Sci. 2023, 13, 243. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci13110243
Arend RJ. Big Tech, Competition Policy, and Strategic Management: An Alternative Perspective to Teece. Administrative Sciences. 2023; 13(11):243. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci13110243
Chicago/Turabian StyleArend, Richard J. 2023. "Big Tech, Competition Policy, and Strategic Management: An Alternative Perspective to Teece" Administrative Sciences 13, no. 11: 243. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci13110243
APA StyleArend, R. J. (2023). Big Tech, Competition Policy, and Strategic Management: An Alternative Perspective to Teece. Administrative Sciences, 13(11), 243. https://doi.org/10.3390/admsci13110243