Next Article in Journal
Insights from the Active Use of Neuroscience Findings in Teaching and Learning
Previous Article in Journal
Exploring the Relationship between Surface Acting, Job Stress, and Emotional Exhaustion in Health Professionals: The Moderating Role of LMX
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Impact of Cognitive Load on Cooperation and Antisocial Punishment: Insights from a Public Goods Game Experiment

by
Yanru Zhao
1,
Zhuoran Li
1,
Shan Jin
2 and
Xiaomeng Zhang
2,*
1
College of Economics and Management, Northwest A&F University, Xianyang 712100, China
2
Economics Experimental Lab, Nanjing Audit University, Nanjing 210017, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Behav. Sci. 2024, 14(8), 638; https://doi.org/10.3390/bs14080638
Submission received: 12 June 2024 / Revised: 23 July 2024 / Accepted: 24 July 2024 / Published: 25 July 2024
(This article belongs to the Section Behavioral Economics)

Abstract

:
This paper investigates the impact of cognitive load on the formation and maintenance of cooperation within a public goods game experiment featuring a punishment option. By integrating the experimental designs of prior studies and manipulating cognitive load through the memorization of numbers with varying digits, we reveal that high cognitive load accelerates the breakdown of cooperation, irrespective of the presence of a punishment system. Furthermore, under high cognitive load, participants are more likely to engage in antisocial punishment, while the punishment of free riders remains unaffected. These findings suggest that increased cognitive load depletes the cognitive resources needed for deliberative decision-making, leading to a higher propensity for antisocial punishment. Our study contributes to the literature by demonstrating the significant influence of cognitive load on cooperative behavior and providing new insights into the causes of antisocial punishment.
JEL Classification:
C91; D91

1. Introduction

Cooperation is the most fundamental basis for the development of human society. (On the occasion of its 125th anniversary, the journal Science listed the issue of cooperation as one of the 125 most significant scientific questions for humanity [1].) Understanding how to achieve and sustain human cooperation effectively is paramount for the development and prosperity of human societies [2,3,4,5]. Previous studies have explored the design of mechanisms to promote and sustain cooperation from various perspectives, including social preferences [6,7,8], reciprocity systems [9,10,11], reward systems [12,13,14,15], repeated games [16,17,18], conditional cooperation [19,20,21,22], and homophily [23,24]. For example, Trivers [6] demonstrated that humans retain altruistic preferences through evolution (altruistic preferences are not eliminated by natural selection), which, in turn, maintains human cooperation. Fehr and Fischbacher [7] showed that altruism and cooperation are inherent to human nature. Fischbacher and Gächter [8] illustrated that, although the willingness to cooperate declines as the experiment progresses, humans still possess the willingness and motivation to cooperate. Nowak and Sigmund [9,10] demonstrated that if reciprocity mechanisms exist in society, they can effectively ensure human cooperation. Sigmund et al. [13] found that providing additional rewards to participants can effectively promote cooperation. Yang et al. [15] used endogenous rewards, such as collecting taxes from everyone and allowing participants to reward their partners, which also promoted cooperation. Fudenberg and Maskin [17] showed that, when cooperation is repeated, participants choose to cooperate to achieve greater future gains. Charness and Yang [24] demonstrated that sometimes participants’ decision to cooperate depends on whether others are cooperating, indicating that cooperation is conditional. Furthermore, Fischbacher et al. [20] showed that, in this behavior pattern, if participants are allowed to choose their partners, those inclined to cooperate tend to gather together.
Among the various mechanisms, the introduction of punishment options to penalize free riders has been shown by numerous studies to effectively enhance the efficiency of cooperation and maintain its stability [25,26,27,28,29,30,31]. However, numerous studies have demonstrated that the introduction of punishment also leads to the emergence of antisocial punishment. Antisocial punishment refers to the act of punishing a cooperative individual rather than a free rider. This form of punishment is clearly detrimental to cooperation and results in unnecessary social welfare losses [32,33,34,35,36]. While antisocial punishment is frequently observed in research, the reasons behind participants’ choice to engage in such behavior remain an area that requires further investigation.
Undoubtedly, both the choice to cooperate and the decision to punish others, along with whether such a punishment contributes to sustaining cooperation, require further consideration. This inevitably involves the concept of bounded rationality [37], questioning whether individuals’ cognitive capacities can bear the cognitive load necessary for these decisions. Previous research has demonstrated that cognitive load significantly impacts individuals’ risk decisions [38,39,40,41,42,43,44], intertemporal choices (time preferences) [43,45], trust [46], and economic rationality [43,47,48]. For example, studies have indicated that individuals under higher cognitive load tend to be less patient and more risk-averse [43] (however, see Ball et al. [49], who did not replicate the results of Deck and Jahedi [43]). Ref. [46] demonstrates that, as cognitive load increases, individuals’ levels of trust decrease. However, research on the impact of cognitive load on the formation and maintenance of cooperation is currently lacking. This paper aims to explore the effects of cognitive load on the establishment and sustainability of cooperation, as well as on the use of punishment mechanisms, in an effort to fill this gap in the academic literature.
We are concerned with this issue for several reasons. Firstly, prominent economists have theoretically demonstrated that altruistic behavior is closely related to self-control [50]. There is also a substantial body of psychological literature showing that self-control requires high cognitive ability and cognitive load [51,52,53]. Additionally, other psychologists and neuroscientists have proven that human prosocial behavior (cooperation) and the efforts to maintain such behavior require self-control and deep thinking [54,55,56]. This leads to the hypotheses of this paper: (1) Since prosocial behavior requires high self-control, cognitive load could reduce self-control, thereby decreasing prosocial behavior. (2) If the effort to maintain prosocial behavior requires self-control and careful consideration, cognitive load could reduce the reliability of this effort (e.g., leading to the misuse of punishment or antisocial punishment).
In this study, we integrated the experimental designs of Deck and Jahedi [43] and Fehr and Fischbacher [7], Fehr and Gächter [25] to investigate the effects of cognitive load on cooperation in a public goods game experiment with a punishment option. By manipulating participants’ cognitive load through the memorization of numbers with varying digits, we found that, under high cognitive load, the rate of cooperation breakdown accelerates regardless of the presence of a punishment mechanism. Another interesting finding is that the proportion of participants using punishment significantly increases under high cognitive load, driven by an increase in antisocial punishment, whereas punishment of free riders is not affected by cognitive load. We argue that increased cognitive load depletes the cognitive resources available for considering whether to punish, thereby making participants more inclined to engage in antisocial punishment.
Our research makes the following contributions to the existing literature. First, we reveal the impact of cognitive load on cooperation, finding that cognitive load leads to the rapid breakdown of cooperation. This expands the literature on the effects of cognitive load on economic decision-making [38,39,40,41,42,43,45,46,49]. In particular, Døssing et al. [57] effectively explored the impact of cognitive load (time pressure) on cooperation and found that high cognitive load increases initial willingness to cooperate, whereas we employed an entirely exogenous cognitive load. Our aim was to simulate real-life cognitive loads that do not arise from the task itself but from the environment in which the decision-maker is situated, such as the increased cognitive load due to poverty or hunger. Second, we partially uncover the reasons behind the use of antisocial punishment. We find that, when individuals face high cognitive costs and cannot sufficiently consider the costs and benefits of punishment, they tend to engage in antisocial punishment. This provides new insights into the causes of antisocial punishment [58,59,60].
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces our experimental design and procedure. Section 3 presents our experimental results. In Section 4, we will provide explanations and discussions on various issues related to our experimental design and parameter choices. Finally, Section 5 offers our conclusions.

2. Experiment

2.1. Design

In the present study, we designed a 2 × 2 experimental setup with two dimensions: cognitive load (high vs. low) and the presence of punishment (with vs. without; see Table 1). In the high cognitive load treatment, participants were required to memorize an eight-digit random number, whereas in the low cognitive load treatment, participants only needed to memorize a three-digit random number. Participants who could correctly recall the full number at the end of the experiment received an additional and 20 as a reward.
In the non-punishment treatment, we utilized a linear social dilemma game without punishment opportunities to measure cooperation [7,25]. Participants were randomly paired into two-person groups, and each participant received 10 tokens (each token was equivalent to RMB 2 Yuan). Participants decided how many tokens to contribute to a public goods pool. Each token contributed to the pool was increased by a factor of 1.6 and then equally distributed between the two participants. The payoff function for participant i in the first stage is described by Equation (1):
π i 1 = 10 g i + 1.6 ( g i + g j ) / 2
where g i represents the tokens contributed to the public goods by participant i, and g j represents the tokens contributed by participant j.
In the punishment treatment, participants had the option to allocate tokens to punish their counterpart after observing their own payoff π i 1 . They could choose to impose a punishment at a cost of 1 to 3 tokens (Participants could only choose whole numbers, i.e., 1, 2, or 3). Each token used for punishment inflicted a threefold loss on the other participant. The final payoff for participant i is represented by Equation (2):
π i f i n a l = π i 1 p i j 3 p j i
where p i j denotes the number of punishment tokens assigned by participant i to participant j, and p j i denotes the number of punishment tokens assigned by participant j to participant i.
To differentiate between punitive actions targeting free riders and those aimed at enhancing cooperation, we defined antisocial punishment as per [58,61], which involves punishing a participant who contributed an equal or greater amount than the punisher themselves. The experimental procedure was repeated for 10 rounds, with participants being randomly re-paired after each round.
The details of our treatments are summarized in Table 1.

2.2. Procedures and Sample

We recruited 256 students (theselection of the number of participants was based on a pilot experiment we conducted prior to the main study, combined with a power analysi; we ultimately decided that 60 participants per treatment group was an appropriate number) from the subject pool at the Experimental Economics Lab at Nanjing Audit University (thesubject pool consists of approximately 2000 students at Nanjing Audit University, including both undergraduate and graduate students) to participate in the experiment. These students were randomly assigned to one of the four treatment conditions.
The experimental process comprised five stages: sign-in, memorization of a random number (thememorization stage lasted for 1 min and could not be skipped), a 10-round experiment, number recall, and a follow-up survey.
During the sign-in procedure, participants were asked to read and sign a consent form that had been approved by the Nanjing Audit University Institutional Review Board. In the memorization stage, participants were given either an 8-digit random number (high cognitive load) or a 3-digit random number (low cognitive load) to memorize. Participants will be informed that they will need to recall and write down these numbers at the end of the experiment. Those who correctly write down all the numbers will receive a reward of RMB 20. After the memorization phase, participants will be randomly paired with another participant to engage in a public goods game. In the no-punishment treatment, participants will be informed of the rules of the public goods game and that their partner will change each round. They will also be told that one of their ten decisions will be randomly selected for payment. In the punishment group, participants were informed that, after each round of decision-making, they would have the option to punish their game partner, and the punishment rules were explained to them. Similarly, one of their rounds would be randomly selected for payment. Each round of the experiment was conducted on computers, and participants were instructed to refrain from speaking to one another throughout the process. This experiment was conducted using oTree [62]. The experiment was divided into 8 sessions, each with 30 to 36 participants. All sessions were completed within 2 days, with 4 sessions conducted each day (for more details, please refer to Appendix A). Upon completing all rounds of the experiment, participants were asked to recall the number they had memorized. Subsequently, a demographic survey was administered to collect essential personal information. Upon completion of all these procedures, participants were compensated privately and then dismissed.
We reported the demographic summary statistics in the left panel of Table 2. We also tested the differences in the demographics of the subjects between four treatments and reported them in the right panel. Among the four treatments, there are no significant differences in the basic demographic information of subjects, so we conclude that there is no significant selection bias in any treatment, which is in line with the principle of random selection. In addition, the age of the subjects in each wave ranges from 19 to 23 years old, nearly 74% of the subjects are women, and approximately 29% are majoring in economics, which is consistent with the student structure of Nanjing Audit University.

3. Results

In this section, we will first present the impact of cognitive load on cooperative behavior, followed by a detailed analysis of its influence on punishment choices in the presence of a punishment mechanism.

3.1. Cooperation Behavior

The results obtained for cooperative behavior are shown in Figure 1. We found that, in the initial stages, there were no significant differences in the contribution levels across the various treatments. However, as the experiment progressed, contribution levels began to decline. The treatment group with high cognitive load and no punishment option experienced the fastest decline, with cooperation significantly collapsing by the 10th round. Both the high cognitive load with punishment and low cognitive load without punishment treatments showed a downward trend in cooperation, but not as rapidly as the high cognitive load without punishment treatment. There were no significant differences between these two treatments. The group with low cognitive load and a punishment option maintained the highest level of cooperation.
These results confirm previous findings that the presence of a punishment option is more effective in maintaining cooperation than treatments without punishment [7,25], regardless of the cognitive load. Additionally, we found that cognitive load leads to a significantly faster rate of cooperation collapse, irrespective of the presence of a punishment option. This outcome remains robust across different conditions.
We next turn to the regression results reported in Table 3, which allow us to examine the effect of cognitive load and a punishment option on cooperation willingness and its rate of decline. Specifically, we adopt the following linear regression specification:
Y i t = β 1 × HCL i + β 2 × Punish i + β 3 × HCL i × Punish i + β 4 × t + X i γ + e i ,
where Y i t is subject i’s contribution to the public pool in round t, and H C L i is a variable that indicates the high cognitive load treatment, which is a dummy variable. H C L i equals 1 when participants are in the high cognitive load treatment; otherwise, H C L i equals 0. P u n i s h i is a variable that indicates the treatment with punishment; when the punishment option is available, its value is 1; otherwise, it is 0. Our regression analysis also includes interaction terms, implying that we use the low cognitive load and no punishment treatment group as the reference group. X i is a vector of control variables that includes age, gender, family income, and major, and e i is an error term clustered at the subject level. β 1 measures the effect of cognitive load only on cooperation, β 2 measures the effect of the punishment option only on cooperation, and β 3 measures the combined effect of cognitive load and the punishment option. We report the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) results in columns (1) and (2). To further assess the impact of cognitive load and the punishment option on the speed of cooperation collapse, we included interaction terms between each of the three variables and the round number t in our regression analysis. The results are presented in columns (3) and (4).
From columns (1) and (2), we can see that an increase in cognitive load significantly reduces the average contributions to the public goods pool, indicating a decrease in the average willingness to cooperate. Conversely, the presence of a punishment option increases the willingness to cooperate. For all treatments, the willingness to cooperate declines as the number of rounds increases. Columns (3) and (4) show that both cognitive load and the punishment option significantly affect the rate of cooperation decline. High cognitive load accelerates the collapse of cooperation, while the presence of a punishment option somewhat mitigates this rate of decline. Our interaction terms indicate that, as the experiment progresses, the impact of cognitive load on the breakdown of cooperation becomes increasingly significant. This means that, the longer the memory task, the less willing participants are to contribute to public goods. Conversely, as the experiment continues, the punishment system becomes increasingly effective in maintaining cooperation.

3.2. Punishment Behavior

We divided punishment behavior into two types. The first type consists of participants who punish a partner who has contributed less than themselves, which is defined as the punishment for free-riding behavior. The second type consists of participants who punish a partner who has contributed the same or more than themselves, which is defined as antisocial punishment.
We calculated the average number of rounds and the average number of tokens used for punishment in each treatment (Figure 2a,d). Additionally, we measured the rounds and tokens used for antisocial punishment (Figure 2b,e), as well as for punishing free riders (Figure 2c,f) (theaverage number of punishment tokens used, as we mentioned, refers to the average over the 10 rounds).
Figure 2a,d illustrate that, with an increase in cognitive load, participants are significantly more inclined to punish others (average punishment rounds: H C L R = 4.516 vs. L C L R = 2.515 ) ( H C L R and L C L R represent the punishment rounds in high cognitive load treatment and low cognitive load treatment, respectively) and are willing to use more tokens for punishment (average punishment tokens per round: H C L T = 0.919 vs. L C L T = 0.495 ) ( H C L T and L C L T represent the punishment tokens in high cognitive load treatment and low cognitive load treatment, respectively). These differences are statistically significant (for average punishment rounds: p-value < 0.001; for average punishment tokens: p-value < 0.001).
When breaking down these punishment results into antisocial punishment (Figure 2b,e) and punishment for free riders (Figure 2c,f), we observe that the punishment for free riders does not significantly increase with cognitive load (for average punishment rounds: H C L R = 1.891 vs. L C L R = 1.545 , p-value = 0.099 ; for average punishment tokens: H C L T = 0.389 vs. L C L T = 0.306 , p-value = 0.089 ). (Based on our anonymous reviewer’s suggestion, we examined the accuracy of punishing free riders, specifically the proportion of free riders who were punished. The results show that the punishment rate for free riders is slightly higher in the low cognitive load group compared to the high cognitive load group, but the difference is not significant (HCL: 73% vs. LCL: 76%, p-value = 0.451).) However, antisocial punishment significantly increases with cognitive load (for average punishment rounds: H C L R = 2.625 vs. L C L R = 0.970 , p-value < 0.001 ; for average punishment tokens: H C L T = 0.530 vs. L C L T = 0.189 , p-value < 0.001 ).
These findings indicate that, as cognitive load increases, the punishment behavior of participants significantly rises, primarily driven by an increase in antisocial punishment.
We next turn to the regression results reported in Table 4, which allow us to examine the effect of cognitive load on punishment behavior, especially antisocial punishment behavior. In the left panel of Table 4, we report the estimates from a probit model in Equation (4):
P i t = β × HCL i + X i γ + e i ,
In the right panel of Table 4, we report the estimates from an ordered logit model in Equation (5):
Token i t = β × HCL i + X i γ + e i ,
where P i t is equal to 1 if subject i chooses to punish their partner in round t, T o k e n i t is the number of tokens that subject i uses to punish their partner in round t, HCL i is a variable that indicates the high cognitive load condition, X i is a vector of control variables that includes round numbers, age, gender, income level and major, and e i is an error term clustered at the subject level.
We reported the results of total punishment in columns (1) and (4), the punishment for free riders in columns (2) and (5), and the antisocial punishment in columns (3) and (6). From Table 4, we can conclude that, as cognitive load increases, the punishment behavior and the tokens used for punishment increase significantly. Among all punishments, those for free riders increase slightly, while the antisocial punishment increases very significantly.
Another noteworthy point is that we analyzed the success rates of number recall in both the high cognitive load group and the low cognitive load group. Firstly, we found that the low cognitive load group almost entirely recalled the numbers accurately, with a perfect recall rate of 98.46%. The high cognitive load group had a relatively lower probability of perfect recall at 87.30%, with a 94.44% probability of recalling more than three numbers. This demonstrates, firstly, that most participants in the high cognitive load group indeed bore a higher cognitive load by remembering more than three numbers. Secondly, it shows that the rate of recalling more than three numbers starts to decrease, indicating an effective manipulation of cognitive load.
Regarding the use of punishment tokens among participants in the high cognitive load group who remembered more and fewer numbers, we found that those in the high cognitive load group who recalled three or fewer numbers indeed used fewer punishment tokens. The difference between this subgroup and the low cognitive load group was not significant ( p = 0.146 ), but there was a significant difference between this subgroup and those who remembered more than three numbers ( p = 0.032 ). This indicates that, when participants reduce their cognitive load by not remembering more numbers, their punitive behavior also decreases accordingly.

4. Discussion

In this study, we opted to use an exogenous cognitive load, such as remembering a few numbers, rather than an endogenous one, such as the difficulty of the experiment itself. The reason for focusing on an exogenous cognitive load is that this paper aims to simulate and describe scenarios in which individuals face cooperation dilemmas and public goods problems under varying cognitive abilities or environments. For instance, as highlighted by Banerjee and Duflo [63], individuals living in poverty experience greater cognitive load when making decisions (due to a lack of sufficient energy), which inevitably affects the quality of their decisions. We aim to address this issue. Of course, as our reviewers have pointed out, the cognitive load associated with increased decision-making difficulty is also worth considering. We hope that future research will explore this issue further.
The reason we chose not to have participants memorize a new number each round, but instead to remember a single number throughout the experiment, is twofold. Firstly, each round is relatively short (approximately 30 s). If participants were only required to remember a number for 30 s, it would be difficult to distinguish between high and low cognitive load (i.e., the cognitive resources consumed in remembering an eight-digit number for 30 s is not significantly different from that for a three-digit number; longer durations would amplify the cognitive resource consumption of longer numbers). Secondly, having participants frequently memorize multiple different numbers would also increase the cognitive load for the low cognitive load group, making it challenging to define it as a truly low cognitive load.
For the multiplier of 1.6 used in the public goods game, we based our choice on Fehr and Gächter [25,27]. They found that 1.6 is an effective number to capture the characteristics of public goods. Specifically, it ensures that the marginal benefit to the individual is slightly lower than that of private goods (0.8 vs. 1). However, this reduction is acceptable and does not create an absolute disadvantage that would completely discourage individuals from contributing to public goods. Through repeated experiments, they determined that 1.6 is an appropriate number. Regarding why we chose a 3× multiplier for the punishment, this is also based on Fehr and Gächter [25]’s experimental research. They found that a multiplier of three is appropriate because it makes the punishment effective, ensuring that the punished party incurs a loss. At the same time, it is not so large as to cause the entire experiment to collapse.
The reason we chose a random re-matching mechanism rather than using the same game partner throughout is to separate the reciprocity mechanism [25] from the reputation mechanism [64]. In games with the same opponent, players might engage in reciprocal punishment. For example, if A punishes B in one round, B might punish A in the next round as retaliation. If this happens, it becomes difficult to determine whether the increased retaliation in a specific treatment is due to cognitive load or if the players have randomly fallen into a cycle of retaliation. Additionally, the reputation mechanism also plays a role in cooperative games. When playing with the same partner repeatedly, participants might choose strategies based on their opponent’s reputation, which adds additional endogenous cognitive costs. To avoid these two issues, we chose the commonly used method of randomly re-matching participants with new game partners each round.
Regarding why we chose to reward only those who remembered all the numbers, rather than rewarding each correct number, as done by Cappelletti et al. [65], there are two reasons: (1) In our pilot data, we found that, if participants were rewarded for each correct number, many participants would give up trying to remember all the numbers or stop making efforts to remember more numbers, instead choosing to remember only three (similar to the low cognitive load group). This contradicts our intention to simulate exogenous cognitive load. (2) If we paid participants based on each correct number, it would create different endowments for different treatments, potentially introducing new endowment effect issues.
This paper could potentially connect future directions with the rich literature on social governance. For instance, Ostrom [66] explored how successful ‘commons’ and self-management of public goods often reduce the ‘costs’ associated with monitoring/supervision through (often creatively) structured collective activities and institutions. In our experiment and related previous experiments, players were informed of their partners’ contributions after each round. However, in the real world, gathering information about peers’ behavior usually incurs additional ‘costs’, which are often decisive factors in whether a community can self-manage, despite the possibility of free-riding. This endogenous ‘cognitive load’ could be a future research direction for this paper.
Additionally, some studies [67] indicate that many outcomes are entirely dependent on agents imitating peers with higher fitness and that agents apply the same behavior (whether ‘cooperation’ or ‘free-riding’) across multiple interactions/games they participate in. ‘Cognitive load’ can be a rationale for this hypothesis: agents behave the same across all interactions because they lack the cognitive capacity to simultaneously track many different games. This can be particularly interesting in certain scenarios, as this mechanism can actually promote/spread cooperative behavior in these networked public goods game models. In some cases, the inability to manage ‘cognitive load’ might lead to ‘positive’ effects.

5. Conclusions

This study delved into the significant impact of cognitive load on cooperative behavior and the propensity for antisocial punishment in a public goods game setting. By manipulating cognitive load through the memorization of numbers of varying lengths, we reveal that high cognitive load not only accelerates the breakdown of cooperation but also significantly increases the incidence of antisocial punishment. These findings underscore the crucial role of cognitive resources in sustaining cooperative behavior and the detrimental effects of cognitive overload on social welfare.
Our experiment demonstrates that, under high cognitive load, participants were more likely to engage in antisocial punishment—punishing cooperative individuals rather than free riders. This behavior can be attributed to the depletion of cognitive resources necessary for deliberative decision-making, leading to more impulsive and less socially beneficial actions. The increased cognitive burden impaired participants’ ability to evaluate the long-term benefits of cooperation and the social costs of antisocial punishment accurately. Consequently, the breakdown of cooperation was accelerated, highlighting the fragility of cooperative systems under cognitive strain.
Our findings align with previous research on the impact of cognitive load on decision-making. Studies such as those by Frederick [38] and Burks et al. [39] have shown that cognitive load affects economic preferences and strategic behavior. Specifically, Deck and Jahedi [43] demonstrated that cognitive load reduces patience and increases risk aversion. Our study extends these insights by showing that cognitive load not only influences individual decision-making but also affects cooperative dynamics in social settings.
Moreover, the increase in antisocial punishment under high cognitive load corroborates the findings of Herrmann et al. [58] and Nikiforakis [60] (in fact, this paper does not explore the issue of cultural differences. The literature we cited merely demonstrates that the willingness to engage in antisocial punishment varies across different cultural backgrounds. This could, of course, lead to an interesting future research topic: whether there are differences in responses to cognitive load on punishment across different cultural backgrounds), who highlighted the prevalence of antisocial punishment in various cultural contexts. By linking these behaviors to cognitive load, our study provides a deeper understanding of the cognitive underpinnings of antisocial punishment and its impact on cooperation.
Future research should explore interventions that can mitigate the negative effects of cognitive load on cooperation and punishment behavior. Investigating the role of cognitive training, environmental design, and policy adjustments can provide actionable insights into promoting sustainable cooperation. Additionally, examining the impact of different types of cognitive load, such as emotional or social load—of course, this also includes directly endogenous cognitive loads, such as the complexity of calculations—on cooperative behavior can further elucidate the complex interplay between cognitive resources and social dynamics.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.Z., S.J. and X.Z.; methodology, X.Z.; software, Y.Z. and X.Z.; validation, Y.Z., S.J. and X.Z.; formal analysis, X.Z.; investigation, X.Z.; resources, Y.Z., Z.L., S.J. and X.Z.; data curation, Y.Z., S.J. and X.Z.; writing—original draft preparation, X.Z.; writing—review and editing, Y.Z., S.J. and X.Z.; visualization, X.Z.; supervision, X.Z.; project administration, X.Z.; funding acquisition, X.Z. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

Zhang acknowledges financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 72203101, 72371165, 72373069, and 72250710170).

Institutional Review Board Statement

The study was conducted in accordance with the Declaration of Helsinki, and approved by the Institutional Review Board of Nanjing Audit University (protocol code 20240004 and 19 February 2024 of approval).

Informed Consent Statement

Informed consent was obtained from all subjects involved in the study.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study are openly available in [Cognitive load and cooperation] at [DOI 10.17605/OSF.IO/XKGMN], reference number [XKGMN].

Acknowledgments

Wethank Chun-Lei Yang for their helpful comments.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Appendix A

Appendix A.1. Experimental Instruments

Appendix A.1.1. Part 1

The following text was shown to all participants before the start of the experiment.
Welcome to this experiment.
You now have one minute to memorize the following number: X X X X X X X X . At the end of the experiment, you will be asked to input this number. Entering it correctly will ensure that you receive RMB 20.

Appendix A.1.2. Part 2 without Punishment

The following text was shown to the without punishment treatment group after the number memorization phase ended.
There will be a total of ten rounds in this experiment. In each round, you will randomly form a group with another student (every round, your partner will be a new match). You have 10 experimental tokens in each round, and you have to decide how much of them to put into a public goods pool. The total amount of tokens invested by you and your partner will be multiplied by 1.6 and then divided equally between by the two of you; your final payoff is determined by the sum of the tokens you keep and the tokens you get from the public goods pool.
For example, if you contributed 5 tokens and your partner contributed 10 tokens, now there are 15 tokens in the public goods pool. This is multiplied by 1.6 to obtain 24 tokens, each of you gets 12 tokens, and your final payoff will be the 5 tokens you kept plus the 12 tokens obtained from the public goods pool for a total of 17 tokens.
We will randomly select one round from your ten rounds of experiments to become your final payoff.
Now, please make a choice about how many tokens you want to contribute to the public goods pool.

Appendix A.1.3. Part 2 with Punishment

The following text was shown to the with punishment treatment group after the number memorization phase ended.
In this round, you contributed X tokens to the public goods pool, and your partner contributed Y tokens to the common goods pool.
Now, you have the opportunity to reduce your partner’s payoff. You can choose to pay 1 to 3 tokens to reduce their payoff.
The amount you pay will be multiplied by three and deducted from your partner’s final token count.
For example, if you choose to pay 1 token to reduce your partner’s payoff, they will lose 3 tokens.
Now, please choose whether you want to reduce your partner’s payoff and how many tokens are you willing to pay to do so.

References

  1. Kennedy, D. 125. Science 2005, 309, 19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Chun, H.; Mun, S.B. Determinants of R&D cooperation in small and medium-sized enterprises. Small Bus. Econ. 2012, 39, 419–436. [Google Scholar]
  3. Cimoli, M.; Porcile, G. Global growth and international cooperation: A structuralist perspective. Camb. J. Econ. 2011, 35, 383–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Faerman, S.R.; McCaffrey, D.P.; Slyke, D.M.V. Understanding interorganizational cooperation: Public-private collaboration in regulating financial market innovation. Organ. Sci. 2001, 12, 372–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Axelrod, R.; Hamilton, W.D. The evolution of cooperation. Science 1981, 211, 1390–1396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  6. Trivers, R.L. The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Q. Rev. Biol. 1971, 46, 35–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Fehr, E.; Fischbacher, U. The nature of human altruism. Nature 2003, 425, 785–791. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Fischbacher, U.; Gächter, S. Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 541–556. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Nowak, M.A.; Sigmund, K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring. Nature 1998, 393, 573–577. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Nowak, M.A.; Sigmund, K. Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature 2005, 437, 1291–1298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Guala, F. Reciprocity: Weak or strong? What punishment experiments do (and do not) demonstrate. Behav. Brain Sci. 2012, 35, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Rand, D.G.; Dreber, A.; Ellingsen, T.; Fudenberg, D.; Nowak, M.A. Positive interactions promote public cooperation. Science 2009, 325, 1272–1275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Sigmund, K.; Hauert, C.; Nowak, M.A. Reward and punishment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2001, 98, 10757–10762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  14. Sefton, M.; Shupp, R.; Walker, J.M. The effect of rewards and sanctions in provision of public goods. Econ. Inq. 2007, 45, 671–690. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Yang, C.L.; Zhang, B.; Charness, G.; Li, C.; Lien, J.W. Endogenous rewards promote cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2018, 115, 9968–9973. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Fudenberg, D.; Levine, D. Subgame-perfect equilibria of finite-and infinite-horizon games. J. Econ. Theory 1983, 31, 251–268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Fudenberg, D.; Maskin, E. The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information. Econometrica 1986, 54, 533. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Vyrastekova, J.; Van Soest, D. On the (in) effectiveness of rewards in sustaining cooperation. Exp. Econ. 2008, 11, 53–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Keser, C.; Van Winden, F. Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scand. J. Econ. 2000, 102, 23–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Fischbacher, U.; Gächter, S.; Fehr, E. Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Econ. Lett. 2001, 71, 397–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Rustagi, D.; Engel, S.; Kosfeld, M. Conditional cooperation and costly monitoring explain success in forest commons management. Science 2010, 330, 961–965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  22. Lergetporer, P.; Angerer, S.; Glätzle-Rützler, D.; Sutter, M. Third-party punishment increases cooperation in children through (misaligned) expectations and conditional cooperation. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2014, 111, 6916–6921. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Eshel, I.; Cavalli-Sforza, L.L. Assortment of encounters and evolution of cooperativeness. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1982, 79, 1331–1335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  24. Charness, G.; Yang, C.L. Starting small toward voluntary formation of efficient large groups in public goods provision. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2014, 102, 119–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Fehr, E.; Gächter, S. Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. Am. Econ. Rev. 2000, 90, 980–994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Boyd, R.; Gintis, H.; Bowles, S.; Richerson, P.J. The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2003, 100, 3531–3535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  27. Fehr, E.; Gächter, S. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 2002, 415, 137–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  28. Ohtsuki, H.; Iwasa, Y.; Nowak, M.A. Indirect reciprocity provides only a narrow margin of efficiency for costly punishment. Nature 2009, 457, 79–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  29. Johnson, T.; Dawes, C.T.; Fowler, J.H.; McElreath, R.; Smirnov, O. The role of egalitarian motives in altruistic punishment. Econ. Lett. 2009, 102, 192–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Hauert, C.; Traulsen, A.; Brandt, H.; Nowak, M.A.; Sigmund, K. Via freedom to coercion: The emergence of costly punishment. Science 2007, 316, 1905–1907. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Traulsen, A.; Hauert, C.; De Silva, H.; Nowak, M.A.; Sigmund, K. Exploration dynamics in evolutionary games. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2009, 106, 709–712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  32. Gurerk, O.; Irlenbusch, B.; Rockenbach, B. The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions. Science 2006, 312, 108–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  33. Dreber, A.; Rand, D.G.; Fudenberg, D.; Nowak, M.A. Winners don’t punish. Nature 2008, 452, 348–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Dreber, A.; Rand, D.G. Retaliation and antisocial punishment are overlooked in many theoretical models as well as behavioral experiments. Behav. Brain Sci. 2012, 35, 24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  35. van den Berg, P.; Molleman, L.; Weissing, F.J. The social costs of punishment. Behav. Brain Sci. 2012, 35, 42–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Rand, D.G.; Nowak, M.A. The evolution of antisocial punishment in optional public goods games. Nat. Commun. 2011, 2, 434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  37. Simon, H.A. A behavioral model of rational choice. Q. J. Econ. 1955, 69, 99–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Frederick, S. Cognitive reflection and decision making. J. Econ. Perspect. 2005, 19, 25–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Burks, S.V.; Carpenter, J.P.; Goette, L.; Rustichini, A. Cognitive skills affect economic preferences, strategic behavior, and job attachment. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2009, 106, 7745–7750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Benjamin, D.J.; Brown, S.A.; Shapiro, J.M. Who is ‘behavioral’? Cognitive ability and anomalous preferences. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2013, 11, 1231–1255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Dohmen, T.; Falk, A.; Huffman, D.; Sunde, U. Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 1238–1260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Zhang, X.; Aimone, J.A.; Alsharawy, A.; Li, F.; Ball, S.; Smith, A. The effects of task difficulty and presentation format on eye movements in risky choice. Front. Behav. Econ. 2024, 3, 1321301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Deck, C.; Jahedi, S. The effect of cognitive load on economic decision making: A survey and new experiments. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2015, 78, 97–119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Zhang, X. Experiential and Neurobiological Influences on Economic Preferences and Risky Decision Making; Virginia Tech: Blacksburg, VA, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  45. Israel, A.; Rosenboim, M.; Shavit, T. Time preference under cognitive load-An experimental study. J. Behav. Exp. Econ. 2021, 90, 101633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Samson, K.; Kostyszyn, P. Effects of cognitive load on trusting behavior—An experiment using the trust game. PLoS ONE 2015, 10, e0127680. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Fudenberg, D.; Levine, D.K. A dual-self model of impulse control. Am. Econ. Rev. 2006, 96, 1449–1476. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  48. Drichoutis, A.C.; Nayga, R.M., Jr. Economic rationality under cognitive load. Econ. J. 2020, 130, 2382–2409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Ball, S.; Katz, B.; Li, F.; Smith, A. The effect of cognitive load on economic decision-making: A replication attempt. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2023, 210, 226–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Dreber, A.; Fudenberg, D.; Levine, D.K.; Rand, D.G. Altruism and Selfcontrol. In Proceedings of the Available at Social Science Research Network (SSRN); 2014; Volume 2477454. Available online: http://dklevine.com/papers/altruism-delay.pdf (accessed on 21 November 2014).
  51. Robinson, M.D.; Schmeichel, B.J.; Inzlicht, M. A cognitive control perspective of self-control strength and its depletion. Soc. Personal. Psychol. Compass 2010, 4, 189–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Meichenbaum, D. Toward a cognitive theory of self-control. In Consciousness and Self-Regulation: Advances in Research Volume 1; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1976; pp. 223–260. [Google Scholar]
  53. Nigg, J.T. Annual Research Review: On the relations among self-regulation, self-control, executive functioning, effortful control, cognitive control, impulsivity, risk-taking, and inhibition for developmental psychopathology. J. Child Psychol. Psychiatry 2017, 58, 361–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Kärtner, J.; Keller, H.; Chaudhary, N. Cognitive and social influences on early prosocial behavior in two sociocultural contexts. Dev. Psychol. 2010, 46, 905–914. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  55. Moore, C.; Barresi, J.; Thompson, C. The cognitive basis of future-oriented prosocial behavior. Soc. Dev. 1998, 7, 198–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Molano, A.; Jones, S.M.; Brown, J.L.; Aber, J.L. Selection and socialization of aggressive and prosocial behavior: The moderating role of social-cognitive processes. J. Res. Adolesc. 2013, 23, 424–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Døssing, F.; Piovesan, M.; Wengström, E. Cognitive load and cooperation. Rev. Behav. Econ. 2017, 4, 69–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Herrmann, B.; Thoni, C.; Gachter, S. Antisocial punishment across societies. Science 2008, 319, 1362–1367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  59. Denant-Boemont, L.; Masclet, D.; Noussair, C.N. Punishment, counterpunishment and sanction enforcement in a social dilemma experiment. Econ. Theory 2007, 33, 145–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Nikiforakis, N. Punishment and counter-punishment in public good games: Can we really govern ourselves? J. Public Econ. 2008, 92, 91–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Bruhin, A.; Janizzi, K.; Thöni, C. Uncovering the heterogeneity behind cross-cultural variation in antisocial punishment. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2020, 180, 291–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Chen, D.L.; Schonger, M.; Wickens, C. oTree—An open-source platform for laboratory, online, and field experiments. J. Behav. Exp. Financ. 2016, 9, 88–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Banerjee, A.V.; Duflo, E. The economic lives of the poor. J. Econ. Perspect. 2007, 21, 141–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Bolton, G.E.; Katok, E.; Ockenfels, A. Cooperation among strangers with limited information about reputation. J. Public Econ. 2005, 89, 1457–1468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Cappelletti, D.; Güth, W.; Ploner, M. Being of two minds: Ultimatum offers under cognitive constraints. J. Econ. Psychol. 2011, 32, 940–950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
  67. Santos, F.C.; Santos, M.D.; Pacheco, J.M. Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games. Nature 2008, 454, 213–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Figure 1. Contribution to the public goods pool in each round. Note: This figure depicts the contributions made to the public goods pool in each round in each treatment of the experiment. The x-axis represents the round number, while the y-axis represents the contribution tokens. The error bar denotes the 95% CI.
Figure 1. Contribution to the public goods pool in each round. Note: This figure depicts the contributions made to the public goods pool in each round in each treatment of the experiment. The x-axis represents the round number, while the y-axis represents the contribution tokens. The error bar denotes the 95% CI.
Behavsci 14 00638 g001
Figure 2. Punishment and antisocial punishment. Note: this figure shows the average number of rounds of punishment used by the subjects and the number of tokens used for punishment in each treatment. (a) The number of rounds in which participants used punishment. (b) The number of rounds in which participants engaged in antisocial punishment. (c) The number of rounds in which participants punished free riders. (d) The number of tokens used by participants for punishment. (e) The number of tokens used for antisocial punishment. (f) The number of tokens used to punish free riders. The error bar denotes the 95% CI. *** and * denote statistical significance at the 1 % and 10 % levels, respectively.
Figure 2. Punishment and antisocial punishment. Note: this figure shows the average number of rounds of punishment used by the subjects and the number of tokens used for punishment in each treatment. (a) The number of rounds in which participants used punishment. (b) The number of rounds in which participants engaged in antisocial punishment. (c) The number of rounds in which participants punished free riders. (d) The number of tokens used by participants for punishment. (e) The number of tokens used for antisocial punishment. (f) The number of tokens used to punish free riders. The error bar denotes the 95% CI. *** and * denote statistical significance at the 1 % and 10 % levels, respectively.
Behavsci 14 00638 g002
Table 1. Treatment conditions.
Table 1. Treatment conditions.
High Cognitive LoadLow Cognitive Load
Without PunishmentMemorize an 8-digit numberMemorize a 3-digit number
(ten rounds)Standard PGGStandard PGG
With punishmentMemorize an 8-digit numberMemorize a 3-digit number
(ten rounds)PGG with punishment optionPGG with punishment option
Table 2. Summary statistics and difference test.
Table 2. Summary statistics and difference test.
Summary StatisticsANOVA
Variables High CL and Non-Punish Low CL and Non-Punish High CL and Punish Low CL and Punish p-Values
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Age20.59720.17220.25020.2730.242
(1.123)(1.001)(1.182)(1.603)
Female66.1%75.0%82.8%74.2%0.202
(47.7%)(43.6%)(38.0%)(44.1%)
Family Income29.32329.50029.28129.4550.566
(1.068)(0.925)(1.091)(0.964)
Econ Major30.8%30.9%32.8%34.5%0.428
(46.2%)(46.3%)(47.0%)(47.6%)
Observations62646466
Note: this table reports the demographic information for all subjects in each treatment. The left panel is the summary statistics; we report the means and the standard deviations in parentheses. The right panel is the ANOVA test of the difference among four treatments; we report the p-value.
Table 3. Effect of cognitive load and punishment on cooperation.
Table 3. Effect of cognitive load and punishment on cooperation.
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Variables Contribution Contribution Contribution Contribution
High cognitive load−0.445 ***−0.439 ***0.1320.135
(0.057)(0.057)(0.124)(0.124)
Punishment option0.422 ***0.426 ***0.0190.021
(0.055)(0.127)(0.031)(0.127)
High cognitive load × Punishment option0.0100.007−0.248−0.248
(0.080)(0.081)(0.176)(0.176)
Round × High cognitive load −0.104 ***−0.104 ***
(0.020)(0.130)
Round × Punishment option 0.073 ***0.074 ***
(0.020)(0.019)
Round × High cognitive load × Punishment option 0.0470.046
(0.029)(0.029)
Round−0.309 ***−0.309 ***−0.306 ***−0.307 ***
(0.008)(0.008)(0.013)(0.013)
Constants6.261 ***6.903 ***6.247 ***6.801 ***
(0.060)(0.643)(0.084)(0.654)
DemographicsNoYesNoYes
Number of subjects256256256256
Number of observations2560256025602560
Adjusted R 2 0.4420.4420.4590.459
Note: this table shows the effects of cognitive load and the presence of a punishment option on contributions to the public goods pool. Columns (1) and (2) present the impact on average contribution levels. Columns (3) and (4) display the impact on the trend of cooperation decline. Columns (1) and (3) do not control for demographic variables, while columns (2) and (4) control for participants’ age, gender, family income, and major. Robust standard errors clustered at subject level are reported in parentheses. ***, denote statistical significance at the 1% levels, respectively.
Table 4. Effect of cognitive load on punishment behavior.
Table 4. Effect of cognitive load on punishment behavior.
Probability of Punishment Being UsedTokens Used to Punish
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Variables Total For Free Rider Antisocial Total For Free Rider Antisocial
High cognitive load0.586 ***0.0190.844 ***0.957 ***0.0391.532 ***
(0.162)(0.192)(0.186)(0.267)(0.341)(0.350)
Round−0.001−0.0140.018−0.001−0.0250.035
(0.019)(0.022)(0.024)(0.032)(0.039)(0.048)
High cognitive load × Round−0.0080.021−0.034−0.0120.038−0.062
(0.026)(0.030)(0.031)(0.043)(0.054)(0.057)
Constants−1.280−1.560−1.587−2.135−2.705−2.837
(1.201)(1.390)(1.327)(1.969)(2.534)(2.338)
Number of observations130013001300130013001300
Note: this table reports the estimation results for the effect of cognitive load on punishment behavior. All entries represent 130 subjects and 1300 observations. We controlled all demographics in Table 3. Columns (1), (2), and (3) report estimates of the probability that punishment is used, while Columns (4), (5), and (6) report estimates of the number of tokens used for punishment. Robust standard errors clustered at subject level are reported in parentheses. ***, denote statistical significance at the 1% levels, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhao, Y.; Li, Z.; Jin, S.; Zhang, X. The Impact of Cognitive Load on Cooperation and Antisocial Punishment: Insights from a Public Goods Game Experiment. Behav. Sci. 2024, 14, 638. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs14080638

AMA Style

Zhao Y, Li Z, Jin S, Zhang X. The Impact of Cognitive Load on Cooperation and Antisocial Punishment: Insights from a Public Goods Game Experiment. Behavioral Sciences. 2024; 14(8):638. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs14080638

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhao, Yanru, Zhuoran Li, Shan Jin, and Xiaomeng Zhang. 2024. "The Impact of Cognitive Load on Cooperation and Antisocial Punishment: Insights from a Public Goods Game Experiment" Behavioral Sciences 14, no. 8: 638. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs14080638

APA Style

Zhao, Y., Li, Z., Jin, S., & Zhang, X. (2024). The Impact of Cognitive Load on Cooperation and Antisocial Punishment: Insights from a Public Goods Game Experiment. Behavioral Sciences, 14(8), 638. https://doi.org/10.3390/bs14080638

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop