Next Article in Journal / Special Issue
Judicialization and Its Effects: Experiments as a Way Forward
Previous Article in Journal
Justiciability of the Right to Water in the SADC Region: A Critical Appraisal
Previous Article in Special Issue
Off to the Courts? Or the Agency? Public Attitudes on Bureaucratic and Legal Approaches to Policy Enforcement
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

All Their Eggs in One Basket? Ideological Congruence in Congress and the Bicameral Origins of Concentrated Delegation to the Bureaucracy

by
Jordan Carr Peterson
Department of Political Science, Texas Christian University, Fort Worth, TX 76129, USA
Submission received: 30 April 2018 / Revised: 30 April 2018 / Accepted: 9 May 2018 / Published: 12 May 2018
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Intersection between Law, Politics and Public Policy)

Abstract

:
What drives congressional choices to concentrate implementation authority for legislative enactments among relatively few bureaucratic institutions? And are increased levels of concentration in implementation power associated with intercameral ideological proximity in Congress? I theorize that greater ideological congruity between the House and Senate drives increased levels of concentration in delegated implementation authority to federal agencies. By examining every significant legislative enactment from 1947 to 2012 that delegates implementation responsibility to at least one federal agency, I consider the legislative dynamics of decisions regarding the range of institutions charged with policy implementation in the American administrative state. I find that increased concentration of implementation authority is associated with greater ideological congruence between pivotal members of the House and the Senate. These results suggest that the preferences of key officials in Congress contribute to defining the breadth of bureaucratic implementation authority in the federal policy process.

1. Introduction

The operation of law in a system of separated institutions sharing powers demands a certain degree of cooperation between coordinate branches of government. Thus, Congress expects the federal bureaucracy will implement the laws it enacts, and strives to ensure that administrative implementation choices made subject to congressional delegation reflect legislative preferences (Balla 1998). The complications that can arise when separate sets of officials are responsible for the initial determination and ultimate implementation of public policy are relatively simple to conjure. Moreover, the federal bureaucracy comprises a necessarily multifaceted host of institutions that leaves Congress with no shortage of administrative options when designing the contours of delegation and implementation. What, then, drives congressional choices regarding the implementation of law?
Amongst the most prominent dilemmas in institutional politics is the principal-agent question underlying congressional decisions about delegation. Numerous scholars have asked when, and under what conditions, agents in the federal bureaucracy may be trusted to implement policy consistent with congressional preferences (Balla and Wright 2001; Epstein and O’Halloran 1999), as well as the means by which Congress incentivizes bureaucratic cooperation (Bawn 1995, 1997; Whitford 2005). Consideration of the agency loss problem that inheres when legislators rely on bureaucrats to carry out congressional directives has tended to focus on the extent to which common characteristics between legislative and executive branch officials drive expansions or contractions of delegated authority (Bertelli and Grose 2011; Hammond and Knott 1996; Volden 2002). This emphasis is reasonable, given that questions of delegation and implementation immediately direct attention toward inter-institutional relationships. In this article, however, I approach the congressional implementation dilemma in a manner that underscores instead the intra-legislative dynamics of delegation by offering an analysis of congressional delegation to the bureaucracy that centers on political conditions in the legislature itself. I seek primarily to answer two questions: (1) when does Congress concentrate implementation authority in fewer administrative agencies?; and (2) are legislative choices regarding the concentration of delegated authority driven by the congruence of intercameral ideological preferences?
I argue and find that when Congress enacts laws delegating implementation authority to the bureaucracy, legislators concentrate implementation powers in fewer agencies given greater levels of ideological congruence between pivotal actors in the House and Senate, respectively. I posit that increased concentration under such circumstances is driven by an expectation that legislators prefer to share responsibility for policy choices with as few other officials as possible under conditions of intercameral ideological proximity. By examining every significant legislative enactment that delegates authority to at least one administrative agency from 1947–2012, I am able to consider laws enacted under a wide variety of political, social, and economic circumstances. This analysis borrows elements from the theoretical framework of pivotal politics (Krehbiel 1998), and to my knowledge, this is the first article to consider how the bicameral nature of congressional politics impacts questions of concentrated delegation and implementation responsibilities in the bureaucracy. Likewise, my analysis includes a novel independent variable to examine this question that measures intercameral ideological proximity.
As political and technological circumstances lead to increasingly expansive bureaucratic influence over the implementation of federal policy, there is growing normative concern regarding the origins and scope of administrative authority (Hill 1991). The analysis presented here is intended to supplement existing conceptions of how the bureaucratic responsibility to implement federal law is distributed by examining the legislative origins of concentrated administrative implementation powers. My findings suggest that intercameral ideological proximity results in more concentrated delegation choices, thereby reducing the number of administrative agents responsible for implementing public policy.

2. An Exception to the Rule: Concentrated Authority in American Government

Scholars of American institutional design typically emphasizes the degree to which public authority in American government is distributed among many actors and institutions. Such emphasis reflects a system characterized by both vertical (e.g., McCann 2016) and horizontal (e.g., Epstein and O’Halloran 1999) fragmentation of policy-making power, which is shared between national and state governments, and between legislative, executive, and judicial institutions (Barnes 2007). In this article, instead of positing a theory regarding the fragmentation of public authority, my intention is to reformulate the usual analysis by offering a theory about the limits of widely-dispersed policy-making power. By contrast, I consider the extent to which constraints on fragmented authority are themselves determined by aspects of institutional design, and in particular how those limits relate to the bicameral dynamics of American legislative politics.
There is a long tradition of scholarship in legislative politics that examines the methods and effectiveness of congressional attempts to exert control over the bureaucracy. Such research tends to examine the institutional tools at the legislature’s disposal to mitigate the problem of agency loss after implementation authority is delegated to administrative agencies. Congress can influence agencies’ composition, function, and capacity by an assortment of means, such as the employment of congressional oversight committees (Weingast and Moran 1983), the legislative role in the nomination and confirmation process for political appointees (Moe 1985), allocational decisions in the federal budget (Fenno 1966; Wildavsky 1964), and the enactment of statutory delegations of authority to bureaucracy, including the enabling statutes that create agencies in the first place (Frug 1984; Noah 2000). The nature of these delegation choices may also be impacted by the employment of so-called “dual” delegation attending delegatory decisions in Congress, first to substantive congressional committees and then to administrative agencies (DeShazo and Freeman 2003), as well as (if conditionally so) by the electoral cross-pressures on legislators (Fox and Jordan 2011). Other research has considered how agency-level factors and the risk preferences of delegating officials may undergird an informational rationale for legislative delegation to the bureaucracy (Bendor and Meirowitz 2004), as well as how delegation may function as a corrective mechanism for governmental accommodation of policy drift (Callander and Krehbiel 2014). As a general matter, the existing scholarship reflects the wide range of oversight mechanisms available in the principal-agent relationship between legislatures and bureaucracies, as well as the different sorts of incentives bearing on legislators charged with making delegation choices (Holmstrom and Milgrom 1991). Much existing research stands for the proposition that legislative efforts at incentivizing or inducing bureaucratic compliance are reasonably effective (McCubbins and Schwartz 1984; Weingast 1984; contra Carpenter 1996; Wilson 1980), and there is little disagreement regarding whether Congress at least occasionally attempts such efforts at management and direction vis-à-vis agencies with delegated authority.
Despite extensive attention paid to the mechanisms of inter-institutional influence discussed above, comparatively less consideration has been given to the possibility that Congress elects to concentrate or fragment delegated authority among federal agencies and bureaus as an instrument of political control. In this article, I consider a specific, important subset of delegation choices, and subsequently present an empirical analysis that reflects a test of my theory regarding the scope of delegated authority among significant congressional enactments. There are, moreover, several notable exceptions to the general lack of work on concentration of delegated authority. While they consider bureaucratic insulation, rather than concentration or fragmentation as such, Epstein and O’Halloran (1999) examine delegation choices and find that Congress is more likely to delegate implementation authority to the bureaucracy “in exactly those areas where the political advantages of doing so outweigh the costs” (p. 232), and announce a variety of political conditions under which broadly delegated authority becomes more likely. Likewise, Lewis (2003) examines the politics of agency design and insulation from a presidential perspective and contrasts the motivations of the chief executive with those of legislators making delegation choices, arguing that Congress and the President are in an ongoing tug of war for political control of the bureaucracy. In other, more recent work, Farhang and Yaver (2016) consider questions of concentration and fragmentation directly by examining congressional delegations to the bureaucracy from 1947–2008 and find that fragmentation of delegated power is more likely given conditions of divided party government across both chambers of Congress and the Presidency. Here, alternatively, I present a theory that builds on prior theories of bureaucratic insulation and fragmented delegation regarding the conditions under which Congress concentrates implementation authority in fewer agencies, explicitly informed by the intra-legislative dynamics of intercameral ideological proximity. As opposed to the existing research that has tended to approach questions of delegation by considering intercameral dynamics only to the extent that they bear on binary definitions of unified or divided government, I employ a deliberately intercameral approach that considers whether ideological congruence between the chambers of a bicameral legislature in a separation of powers system results in laws that concentrate authority in fewer bureaucratic institutions. These theoretical developments motivate my explanation of how closer proximity of intercameral ideological preferences is positively associated with concentration of implementation authority among bureaucratic institutions. This mode of analysis permits me to make a series of inferences about the degree to which concentration of authority in American law, however rare, is driven by the ideological composition of Congress.

3. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation

Two legislative enactments with significant allocational consequences serve broadly to illustrate the question motivating this article. Although there exist differences in the temporal and political circumstances surrounding the enactment of both laws, they nevertheless serve to animate how Congress structures the implementation of federal policy in manners that go unexplained by existing theories regarding the conditions under which legislators concentrate or fragment implementation authority. On 24 March 1948, the House concurred in the Senate’s final amendments to H.R. 4790, a bill otherwise known as the Revenue Act of 1948, which had passed the Senate two days prior. Ultimately enacted via an override of President Truman’s veto, the legislation ordered decreases to individual rates in the Internal Revenue Code, and provided for several additional tax exemptions (Tempalski 2006). In crafting this legislation, designed to relieve the collective tax burden as demand for military spending waned after the end of the Second World War, Congress formulated an implementation scheme that relied only on cooperation by the Department of the Treasury (Yang 2007). Nearly six decades later, on 1 February 2006, the House agreed to the final version of S. 1932, styled the Deficit Reduction Act of 2005. This sweeping legislation also resulted in adjustments to federal spending levels, primarily by modifying coverage structures in the Medicaid and Medicare programs (Wilson 2007). In delegating authority to implement this bill, by contrast, Congress spread responsibility for its execution across some thirteen federal agencies. Why did the congressional approach to delegating implementation powers differ so dramatically between these two enactments?
Attempting to account for such variation in the distribution of delegated authority by examining whether there was unified or divided government across the chambers of Congress and the Presidency proves insufficient. Here, I offer a theory that considers how intra-legislative factors bear on delegated implementation authority across the bureaucracy broadly. Whereas prior research suggests that divided government drives the fragmentation of delegated implementation power, in this instance, implementation authority was concentrated in only one federal agency by the Revenue Act of 1948—under conditions of divided government—while such responsibilities were fragmented across thirteen agencies despite unified government when the Deficit Reduction Act of 2005 was enacted. This binary conception of divided versus unified government, however, neglects to take into account the possibility of ideological heterogeneity within party caucuses in Congress. For example, despite party control of government being divided between Republicans in the Eightieth Congress and Democratic President Truman in 1948, the pivotal legislators in the House and Senate were reasonably similar in ideology—in fact, based on a comparison of scores that use legislators’ roll call votes to estimate their ideological preferences (Poole and Rosenthal 1985), the ideological “distance” between pivotal legislators in the House and Senate during the Eightieth Congress was the fifth smallest of the thirty-three sessions of Congress from 1947–2012. Contrarily, when the Deficit Reduction Act of 2005 was enacted, the ideological space between the House and Senate was relatively substantial—the fourth largest of any Congress during the time period examined here—despite the Republicans controlling both chambers of Congress and the Presidency. This anecdote suggests that intercameral ideological congruity may be an important factor in predicting the distribution of delegated implementation authority in federal statutory design.
I theorize that greater proximity in ideology between the House and the Senate will be associated with increased concentration in policy implementation authority. This builds on existing work by considering how intra-legislative institutional forms affect the extra-legislative construction of federal policy. Congressional choices regarding delegation to the bureaucracy usually implicate assumptions about legislative attempts at political control, animated by principal-agent concerns and the potential for agency loss, or other considerations bearing on legislators such as the electoral incentive. Additionally, there have been a number of social and economic developments that manifest politically in changes in the incentive structure for legislators to delegate policy authority to administrative agents. For example, the expansion of bureaucratic authority during the twentieth century altered the political opportunity structure for legislative delegation in a manner that requires any empirical consideration of delegatory choices to account for the possibility that such choices are timebound. Further, the growth of federal authority more generally may impact how Congress chooses to design the implementation of policy regimes. Here, while I am unable to consider how characteristics of individual agencies may impact delegation choices as I analyze delegatory decision-making at the level of the congressional enactment, I examine broadly how implementation powers are concentrated or fragmented across bureaucratic institutions. I argue that concentrating implementation authority in fewer administrative agencies and bureaus provides Congress with an institutional means for minimizing agency loss. The fewer bureaucrats there are responsible for implementing enacted congressional directives, the fewer opportunities there can be for ideologically or politically recalcitrant administrators to frustrate the purposes of legislative programs. In essence, each bureaucratic institution to which Congress delegates some measure of implementation power when designing legislation functions as a sort of veto player with profound (if non-absolute) influence over the likelihood that policy regimes operate as Congress originally intended. As a result, and because reliance on the bureaucracy to execute at least some features of legislation is virtually unavoidable when governing in the modern administrative state, legislators seeking to ensure that enacted policies are implemented consistent with their own preferences must find ways to write laws that maximize favorable compliance outcomes among bureaucratic recipients of delegated authority. Reducing the number of potentially nonacquiescent administrators by concentrating implementation powers in fewer agencies represents one such legislative tactic. Although situated alongside existing determinants of concentrated implementation authority, my theory contends that intercameral ideological congruence explains some portion of delegated authority to the bureaucracy
My theory posits, however, that there exist political constraints—internal to the legislature itself—on the conditions under which legislators in a bicameral institution will express a willingness to concentrate implementation authority for enacted programs. This argument of mine relies heavily on the theoretical framework of pivotal politics (Krehbiel 1998), which suggests that it is the distribution of ideological preferences within (and, by extension, across) institutions—along with those institutions’ decision rules—that determines their policy outputs. According to the theory, pivotal actors are those at the ideological “tipping points” within the institution, whose preferences determine the collective policy preference for the body. For the purposes of this article, I consider only the preferences of pivotal actors in Congress in keeping with the approach taken in other inter-institutional contexts that do not employ the preferences of the President in their analysis of legislative decision-making (see, e.g., Menounou et al. forthcoming). According to my argument, and all else equal, enacted legislation will probably be closer to the ideological preference of the pivotal member of one chamber given increased proximity between that member’s ideal point and the ideological preference of the pivotal member in the other chamber. To express this more concretely, it is more likely that legislation will contain conservative (or moderate, or liberal) policy enactments if the pivotal members in both chambers of Congress are conservative (or moderate, liberal) than otherwise. Because, then, pivotal legislators in a bicameral system are ultimately more likely to prefer policy outcomes given minimal ideological distance between themselves and pivotal legislators in the corresponding chamber, it follows that legislators operating under such conditions of ideological proximity would view agency loss resulting from unsatisfactory policy implementation by bureaucrats more negatively than were the policies more remote from the legislators’ preferences. Indeed, facing the enactment of laws that specify policy programs they regard as suboptimal, legislators may even positively anticipate the chance of agency loss at the hands of the bureaucracy and seek to avoid concentration of implementation powers. These considerations should motivate members of bicameral legislatures to concentrate authority delegated to the bureaucracy among fewer agencies—i.e., to “put all their eggs in one basket”—given ideological congruence between the two chambers.
The notion that legislators will concentrate implementation authority more frequently under conditions of minimal intercameral ideological distance is not intended to diminish the importance of the ongoing inter-institutional dynamics inherent in congressional efforts to design legislation that the executive branch is willing and able to implement and that withstands judicial scrutiny. Instead, however, I seek to offer an additional explanation for the legislative construction of bureaucratic authority that is internal to the legislature itself. By focusing on the bicameral origins of concentrated delegation by Congress, I establish a theoretical connection between the ideological proximity of the legislature’s two chambers and the designated scope of delegated implementation authority that suggests close congressional management of administrative power. Likewise, the theory and analysis presented here are not intended to negate or refute the possibility that there exists a panoply of concerns that influence legislative decisions whether and how to delegate authority to the bureaucracy. For instance, legislators might consider the availability of oversight mechanisms, specificities and strictures of the administrative process, the ideology of bureaucrats responsible for implementation, the type of policy at issue, and the institutional design of the administrative body. These factors doubtless impact the legislative design of administrative implementation authority, and a theory of how intercameral ideological congruence leads to concentrated bureaucratic implementation power does nothing to theoretically diminish their importance. Further, I do not contend that the partisanship or preferences of officials in the executive or judicial branches are irrelevant for determining the conditions under which the bureaucracy’s responsibility to execute laws will be either concentrated or diffuse. Rather, the theory implies that certain contours of the bureaucracy’s implementation authority are circumscribed prior to coming out of the proverbial starting gate by legislators concerned with ex ante bureaucratic delegation, to the extent they are determined by the relative distribution of ideological preferences among legislators choosing which and how many agencies will carry enacted laws into effect.
To empirically assess this conceptualization of the association between intercameral ideological proximity and concentration of implementation authority in bureaucratic institutions, I develop the following testable expectation based on the observable implications of the theory. The expectations are summarized in the intercameral ideological congruence hypothesis:
Intercameral Ideological Congruence Hypothesis:
As the ideological distance between the House median and the Senate filibuster pivot more remote from the House median increases, the more agencies will be responsible for implementation authority in each instance of enacted legislation.
This hypothesis sets out the measurable consequences of my theory, and seeks to establish clearly the connection between intercameral ideological proximity in Congress and the concentration of implementation power in federal agencies. In the following section, I describe the empirical tests I employ before presenting the results of the analysis.

4. Data and Methods

To test my expectations regarding intercameral ideological congruence and concentration of policy implementation authority, I estimate several iterations of a Poisson regression model that examines the association between ideological proximity and the distribution of implementation authority across federal agencies. Poisson regression is methodologically appropriate for a countable dependent variable with a low arithmetic mean (Coxe et al. 2009). The unit of analysis is at the level of the individual enacted law, and my sample includes all legislation from Mayhew’s (2005) dataset of important congressional enactments from 1947–2012.1
The dependent variable, Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority (μ = 5.89) measures the number of federal agencies to which Congress has delegated implementation authority for each law in my sample. For the purposes of assessing the expectations suggested by my theory, legislation in which Congress has delegated implementation authority to more agencies is considered less concentrated, while legislation in which implementation power is delegated to fewer agencies is considered more concentrated. Descriptive statistics related to the dependent variable appear in Table 1 below. In this table, I also include the percentage of laws from my sample delegating to each of the fifteen agencies to which Congress most frequently delegated implementation authority across my sample.
The dependent variable has been calculated as follows: I searched for and located each reference delegating authority to federal agencies in the text of each law in the sample, then added together the number of cabinet departments responsible for implementation and the number of independent agencies and other non-cabinet bureaus granted implementation authority. This involved performing a full text search of each law and searching for the words administration, agency, bureau, board, commission, department, and secretary (as well as sublexical constituent parts and variants of such words like “administr-” in order that the search captures references to administrators as well as administrations). I then counted the number of mentions of all these institutions (cabinet departments, independent agencies, and non-cabinet bureaus) receiving delegated authority to create the dependent variable. As such, this variable reflects the number of administrative agencies (at the cabinet level and otherwise) responsible for implementing policy. Because I coded delegation across the laws in this set by hand, I ensured that none of the references to agencies with delegated authority in the sample were “negative” mentions in which Congress was forbidding an agency from implementing policy or transferring implementation authority away from an agency or bureau. This approach differs from that in earlier work that counts both institutions and actors in measuring policy implementation authority (Farhang and Yaver 2016), while data from other recent prominent studies of delegation account for the level of executive discretion in each federal law that delegates policy authority (Epstein and O’Halloran 1999). These data are not publicly available but generally consider, as I do here, the distribution of implementation power across institutions as a baseline measure of concentrated delegation, but with a particular focus on constraints imposed by administrative procedures.
The independent variable of interest, Senate-House Distance, is intended to measure the intercameral congruence of ideological preferences. This variable measures the absolute value of the difference between (1) the median first dimension DW-NOMINATE score in the House and (2) the first dimension DW-NOMINATE score of the pivotal Senator ideologically least proximate from the House median.2 As discussed in the previous section, I expect that greater values of Senate-House Distance will be associated with delegation to more agencies, i.e., with less concentrated implementation.
I include several other independent variables to account for the political, administrative, and economic circumstances that might lead Congress to design legislation that concentrates implementation authority in fewer bureaucratic institutions. First, I include two aggregate measures of the partisanship in each chamber of Congress in each year to control for the possibility that members of one party or the other tend to favor concentrating implementation power in fewer agencies. These two variables are the Democratic Percentage in the Senate and the Democratic Percentage in the House, which are continuous measures of the percentage of seats held by Democrats in each chamber. Further, to account for the existing explanation that congressional choices whether to concentrate authority are driven by control of the elected branches of government by one party, I include a binary variable indicating whether there was Unified Government in each year, coded 1 if one party controlled the House, the Senate, and the Presidency, and 0 otherwise. This acknowledges the possibility that Congress will take into account the partisanship of the President when making choices regarding delegation to the bureaucracy.
I also include two variables related to the administrative circumstances surrounding each significant enactment in my sample. Because legislative choices about concentrated delegation may depend on the capacity of the executive branch to implement congressional directives, I include a variable representing the size of the Executive Branch Workforce during each year, which is the number of federal executive branch employees, measured in tens of thousands.3 Likewise, to account for the clerical explanation that Congress delegates implementation powers to more agencies when laws are longer, I include a variable measuring the Length of Legislation in pages for each significant legislative enactment.4 Finally, to control for the possibility that Congress makes implementation decisions subject to economic constraints—and thus, delegates implementation authority to fewer agencies when macroeconomic circumstances are generally worse—I include a variable, Debt per GDP, which measures the United States’ annual public debt as a percentage of the national gross domestic product for each year in my sample.
In addition to the primary version of the model described in the foregoing paragraphs, designated Model 1a in the results that follow, I estimate two additional iterations of the model that appear in the following section. In the first additional model, designated Model 1b, I include an interaction term to examine whether the effect of Senate-House Distance on concentrated versus fragmented implementation authority depends on partisan control of each chamber. This additional variable is designated Senate House-Distance with Unified Congress and is calculated by interacting Senate-House Distance with an indicator variable coded 1 if both chambers of Congress are controlled by the same party, and 0 otherwise. This will permit me to assess whether any effect of intercameral ideological congruence on concentration of implementation power is conditional on unified partisan control of the House and Senate. Last, in a second additional model, designated Model 1c in the table below, I include fixed effects for each decade in my sample, in order to account for any variation or patterns in concentration of implementation authority based on unobservable temporal characteristics. All three models also include fixed effects for the policy area governed by the legislation.

5. Results: Intercameral Ideological Congruence Drives Concentrated Delegation

The results of my analysis appear in Table 2 below. Broadly speaking, these results offer strong support for the intercameral ideological congruence hypothesis. Across all three iterations of the model described in the preceding section, the primary independent variable Senate-House Distance is statistically significant, and greater levels of intercameral ideological congruence are associated with increased concentration of implementation authority. In other words, the more proximate the ideological preferences of pivotal legislators in the Senate and the House, the fewer agencies receiving delegated implementation authority from legislation enacted by such Congress.
In the primary model (designated 1a in Table 2), greater values of Senate-House Distance are associated with increases in the estimated number of agencies to which Congress has delegated implementation authority when drafting legislation. This central result is robust to a number of alternative specifications of this primary model, including Model 1b—in which I estimate the effects of Senate-House Distance on concentrated delegation for conditions of divided and unified control of Congress separately—and Model 1c—in which I include fixed effects at the decade level to account for unobservable temporal circumstances that might impact delegation choices in Congress.5 Not only is there a statistically discernible association between Senate-House Distance and Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority across all three specifications presented here, the results in Model 1b suggest that the tendency for Congress to concentrate implementation authority in fewer agencies given conditions of ideological congruence between pivotal members of the Senate and House holds no matter whether there is unified or divided control of Congress. Although the delegatory consequences of ideological congruity may be diminished under conditions of a unified legislature since the magnitude of the effect for Senate-House Distance with Unified Congress is smaller than for Senate-House Distance (which in Model 1b serves to estimate the effect of intercameral ideological proximity given divided party control of Congress because of the interaction term), this nevertheless suggests that the distribution of ideologies among members of Congress has an impact on the manner in which implementation authority is delegated across agencies independent of whether there is unified control of the executive and legislative branches. In Table A1 in the Appendix A, I estimate the same models that appear in the text without policy area fixed effects, and the results are substantively comparable in direction and magnitude.
The association between Senate-House Distance and the concentration of delegated authority is further illustrated in Figure 1. The figure is based on the results from Model 1a and displays the estimated Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority given a range of values in ideological distance between pivotal members of the Senate and House. The results suggest that intercameral ideological proximity is an important factor in predicting the concentration or fragmentation of implementation authority delegated to the bureaucracy in federal statutes. For example, based on these results, moving from a value one and a half standard deviations below the mean (0.12) to a value one and a half standard deviations above the mean (0.42) for Senate-House Distance, the estimated number of agencies receiving delegated authority moves from 3.96 to 6.31. The results suggest that all else equal, congressional management of structuring implementation powers among bureaucratic institutions is strongly associated with the distribution of ideological preferences within Congress.
A number of the other independent variables accounting for the tendency of Congress to concentrate or fragment implementation authority are statistically significant. For example, in Models 1a and 1b, increases in the size of the executive branch workforce and the length of enacted legislation are associated with delegation to a greater number of agencies. This association between the number of executive branch employees and concentrated delegation, however, vanishes entirely upon the inclusion of decade fixed effects, suggesting that the size of the executive workforce is correlated with some unobserved temporal characteristics operating in the background of this analysis. There is also a strong relationship between the percentage of Democrats in each chamber of Congress and delegation outcomes, although the effects move in different directions in the Senate versus the House. This is likely related to ideological heterogeneity among party caucuses over the time period covered in my sample. Perhaps more importantly, the categorical variable Unified Government is only significantly associated with concentration or fragmentation in Model 1b, but otherwise fails to attain statistical significance. In Model 1b, the results do suggest there is a weak association between the existence of unified government and concentration of implementation authority in the bureaucracy. My findings imply, however, that the effects of unified government on concentrated delegation among the 386 statutes in my sample are attenuated to near imperceptibility once I control for other political and administrative factors including but not limited to intercameral ideological proximity. In general, the results suggest that intra-congressional ideological dynamics are brought to bear on the distribution of delegated authority across bureaucratic institutions independent of other political and administrative determinants of concentration and fragmentation.

6. Conclusions

This article continues a strand of scholarship examining the causes of concentrated implementation authority in federal policy-making, and represents the first work to consider how ideological proximity between the chambers of Congress impacts the concentration of enforcement power in fewer national administrative agencies.
My theory and findings suggest a number of fruitful avenues for future research regarding the causes and consequences of concentrated implementation power. For example, if the congressional intent in concentrating authority in fewer agencies under conditions of intercameral ideological proximity is indeed motivated by a desire to see policy enacted with minimal agency loss, is this approach effective? Despite some challenging issues regarding metrics of bureaucratic outputs and their relationship to congressional aims, investigation into the subject might consider whether policies enforced by fewer administrative agencies are indeed implemented in a way more consistent with the preferences of pivotal members of the House and Senate. Likewise, further consideration of the subject should do its best to take into account the variegation of policy types for which Congress and the federal bureaucracy are responsible. Future research might, for instance, employ measures of agency ideology to see if there exists administrative resistance to the directives expressed in legislative delegations of authority, and to establish whether members of Congress take actual or perceived agency preferences into account when making choices about the distribution of delegated implementation power. It would also behoove future scholars to take into account certain textual and rhetorical characteristics of legislation that delegates implementation authority to the bureaucracy. Perhaps even employing innovative techniques such as automated content analysis and other tools generally borrowed from computational linguistics, subsequent consideration of congressional delegation choices would do well to examine the textual mechanics by which Congress delegates implementation powers in policy design to the bureaucracy—namely, by providing answers to questions regarding whether the length of text delegating authority is associated with expansions in the scope of administrative powers, and how legislators structuring delegation to the bureaucracy employ certain linguistic features to place constraints on administrative implementation capacity. Last, future scholars would do well to employ a research design to examine questions of delegation to the bureaucracy that is equipped to take into account agency-level factors that may impact delegatory choices among legislators. Namely, future work could consider how delegation choices are associated with the range and types of bureaucratic institutions available to receive delegated implementation authority from Congress.
The prevailing normative criticism of bureaucratic governance is that an accountability deficit results in the divorce of policy outcomes from popular preferences. If, so the argument goes, the people elect legislators to design policies that reflect their own preferences, then unilateral alterations made to congressional enactments by unelected bureaucrats represent a subversion of the democratic will. Hollowed out or not, however, the administrative state is here to stay in one form or another, and as a result, the implementation of federal statutes will continue to rely on satisfactory performance from a cooperative (or coerced) bureaucracy. One manner in which legislators can circumvent the problem of agency loss is to distribute implementation powers among fewer bureaucratic institutions, and my findings indicate such concentrations of authority are more common given ideological congruity between the two chambers of a bicameral legislature. This suggests legislative attention to ex ante choices regarding delegation to the bureaucracy, and implies the need to continue examining the relationship between bureaucratic authority and legislative design.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. All Their Eggs in One Basket?

On page 8 of the text, I report that I re-estimate the three models (1a, 1b, and 1c) appearing in the manuscript but exclude the policy area fixed effects included in Table 2. The results of these ancillary analyses appear in Table A1 below, and are substantively comparable to those presented in the main text.
Table A1. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation, 1947–2012. Dependent variable: Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority.
Table A1. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation, 1947–2012. Dependent variable: Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority.
Independent VariablesModel A1 (Primary Model)
Coef. (r.s.e.)
Model A2 (Includes Conditional Indep. Variable)
Coef. (r.s.e.)
Model A3 (with Time Fixed Effects) ^
Coef. (r.s.e.)
Senate-House Distance1.411 (0.535) ***1.160 (0.623) **1.894 (1.228) *
Senate-House Distance with Unified Congress 0.773 (0.495) *
Democratic Percentage in Senate−3.174 (1.357) **−3.260 (1.412) **−1.644 (2.137)
Democratic Percentage in House3.496 (1.312) ***3.714 (1.301)***1.355 (1.535)
Unified Government−0.098 (0.089)−0.158 (0.103) *−0.024 (0.103)
Executive Branch Workforce0.009 (0.003) ***0.009 (0.003) **0.000 (0.004)
Length of Legislation0.002 (0.000) ***0.002 (0.000) ***0.002 (0.000) ***
Debt per GDP−0.025 (0.026)−0.010 (0.028)0.043 (0.051)
Constant−0.365 (0.671)−0.823 (0.611)−0.459 (1.717)
χ2189.61213.88192.66
N386386386
*** p ≤ 0.01; ** p ≤ 0.05; * p ≤ 0.10; all one-tailed tests except Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House. ^ Time fixed effects excluded from the table in the interest of space.
Model A4. Replication of Model 1a with Ideological Control Variables
In endnote 5, referring to material on page 9 of the text, I report that I estimated an additional version of Model 1a from the text in which I account for the possibility that it might be the ideological environment in Congress, broadly, that determines whether delegation authority is more or less concentrated, rather than the partisan composition of each chamber. In this additional model, in place of the variables Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House, I include instead two other variables: the first indicates the ideology of the Senate Pivot—that is, the DW-NOMINATE score of the Senate filibuster pivot less ideologically proximate from the House median than the other—while the second indicates the DW-NOMINATE score for the House Median. For these measures, lower values are more liberal while higher values are more conservative Just as when calculating the main independent variable, Senate-House Distance, and as noted in endnote 2 from the text, the relevant senator changes over time as the filibuster rules changed.
The following Table A2 contains the results from Model A4, which is the exact same as Model 1a in the text other than that Senate Pivot and House Median replace Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House, respectively, and Model A4 does not include policy area fixed effects. As in the text, I report a statistically discernible (if more weakly so) association between intercameral ideological congruence and concentrated delegation.
Table A2. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation (with ideological control variables).
Table A2. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation (with ideological control variables).
Independent VariablesCoef. (r.s.e.)
Senate-House Distance0.829 (0.617) *
Senate Pivot0.996 (0.322) ***
House Median−0.881 (0.340) ***
Unified Government0.097 (0.083)
Executive Branch Workforce0.012 (0.003) ***
Length of Legislation0.002 (0.000) ***
Debt per GDP−0.066 (0.031) **
Constant0.400 (0.500)
χ2207.25
N386
*** p ≤ 0.01; ** p ≤ 0.05; * p ≤ 0.10; all one-tailed tests except Senate Pivot and House Median.
Model A5: Replication of Model 1a with Binary Control Variables
In endnote 5, referring to material on page 9 of the text, I report that I estimated an additional version of Model 1a from the text in which I control for the possibility that the relevant measure of partisan control in Congress is binary rather than continuous—i.e., that it matters for estimating concentrated delegation authority which party controls each chamber, but not necessarily by what margin. In Model A5, whose results appear in Table A3 below, I include binary variables for whether there was a Democratic Senate (coded 1 if there was a Democratic majority in the Senate, and 0 otherwise) and whether there was a Democratic House (coded 1 if there was a Democratic majority in the House, and 0 otherwise) in place of Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House. The results are comparable to those presented in the text.
Table A3. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation (with binary control variables).
Table A3. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation (with binary control variables).
Independent VariablesCoef. (r.s.e.)
Senate-House Distance0.825 (0.567) *
Democratic Senate−0.479 (0.166) ***
Democratic House0.292 (0.190)
Unified Government−0.158 (0.085) **
Executive Branch Workforce0.008 (0.003) ***
Length of Legislation0.002 (0.000) ***
Debt per GDP−0.006 (0.025)
Constant−0.113 (0.469)
χ2169.98
N386
*** p ≤ 0.01; ** p ≤ 0.05; * p ≤ 0.10; all one-tailed tests except Democratic Senate and Democratic House.
Model A6: Replication of Model 1b with Time Fixed Effects
In endnote 5, referring to material on page 9 of the text, I report that I estimated an additional version of Model 1b from the text—which includes an additional interaction term to measure intercameral ideological distance during times of unified and divided government separately—in which I also include time fixed effects at the decade level. Otherwise, Model A6, whose results appear in Table A4 below, is specified identically to Model 1b other than excluding policy area fixed effects. The results are substantively comparable to those in the text, and continue to reflect an association between intercameral ideological proximity and concentrated delegation.
Table A4. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation (with interaction term and time fixed effects) ^.
Table A4. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation (with interaction term and time fixed effects) ^.
Independent VariablesCoef. (r.s.e.)
Senate-House Distance0.829 (0.617) *
Senate-House Distance with Unified Congress0.951 (0.493) **
Democratic Percentage in Senate−2.138 (1.986)
Democratic Percentage in House1.714 (1.430)
Unified Government−0.091 (0.109)
Executive Branch Workforce−0.000 (0.004)
Length of Legislation0.002 (0.000) ***
Debt per GDP0.062 (0.051)
Constant−0.576 (1.666)
χ2221.56
N386
*** p ≤ 0.01; ** p ≤ 0.05; * p ≤ 0.10; all one-tailed tests except Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House. ^ Time fixed effects excluded from the table in the interest of space.

References

  1. Balla, Steven J. 1998. Administrative Procedures and Political Control of the Bureaucracy. American Political Science Review 92: 663–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Balla, Steven J., and John R. Wright. 2001. Interest Groups, Advisory Committees, and Congressional Control of the Bureaucracy. American Journal of Political Science 45: 799–812. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Barnes, Jeb. 2007. Bringing the Courts Back In Interbranch Perspectives on the Role of Courts in American Politics and Policy Making. Annual Review of Political Science 10: 25–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bawn, Kathleen. 1995. Political Control versus Expertise: Congressional Choices about Administrative Procedures. American Political Science Review 89: 62–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Bawn, Kathleen. 1997. Choosing Strategies to Control the Bureaucracy: Statutory Constraints, Oversight, and the Committee System. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 13: 101–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bendor, Jonathan, and Adam Meirowitz. 2004. Spatial Models of Delegation. American Political Science Review 98: 293–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Bertelli, Anthony, and Christian R. Grose. 2011. The Lengthened Shadow of another Institution? Ideal Point Estimates for the Executive Branch and Congress. American Journal of Political Science 55: 767–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Callander, Steven, and Keith Krehbiel. 2014. Gridlock and Delegation in a Changing World. American Journal of Political Science 58: 819–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Carpenter, Daniel P. 1996. Adaptive Signal Processing, Hierarchy, and Budgetary Control in Federal Regulation. American Political Science Review 90: 283–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Coxe, Stefany, Stephen G. West, and Leona S. Aiken. 2009. The Analysis of Count Data: A Gentle Introduction to Poisson Regression and its Alternatives. Journal of Personality Assessment 91: 121–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. DeShazo, J. R., and Jody Freeman. 2003. Competition to Control Delegated Power. Texas Law Review 81: 1443–519. [Google Scholar]
  12. Epstein, David, and Sharyn O’Halloran. 1999. Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy Making under Separate Powers. New York: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  13. Farhang, Sean, and Miranda Yaver. 2016. Divided Government and the Fragmentation of American Law. American Journal of Political Science 60: 401–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Fenno, Richard. 1966. Power of the Purse. Boston: Little, Brown. [Google Scholar]
  15. Fox, Justin, and Stuart V. Jordan. 2011. Delegation and Accountability. Journal of Politics 73: 831–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Frug, Gerald. 1984. The Ideology of Bureaucracy in American Law. Harvard Law Review 97: 1276–388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Hammond, Thomas, and Jack Knott. 1996. Who Controls the Bureaucracy?: Presidential Power, Congressional Dominance, Legal Constraints, and Bureaucratic Autonomy in a Model of Multi-Institutional Policy-Making. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 12: 119–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Hill, Larry B. 1991. Who Governs the American Administrative State? A Bureaucratic-Centered Image of Governance. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 1: 261–94. [Google Scholar]
  19. Holmstrom, Bengt, and Paul Milgrom. 1991. Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization 7: 24–52. [Google Scholar]
  20. Krehbiel, Keith. 1998. Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. [Google Scholar]
  21. Lewis, David. 2003. Presidents and the Politics of Agency Design: Political Insulation in the United States Government Bureaucracy, 1946–1997. Stanford: Stanford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  22. Mayhew, David. 2005. Divided We Govern: Party Control, Lawmaking, and Investigations, 1946–2002. New Haven: Yale University Press. [Google Scholar]
  23. McCann, Pamela J. Clouser. 2016. The Federal Design Dilemma: Congress and Intergovernmental Delegation. New York: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  24. McCubbins, Mathew D., and Thomas Schwartz. 1984. Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms. American Journal of Political Science 28: 165–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Menounou, Elli, Adam Feldman, Thora Giallouri, and Jordan Carr Peterson. Forthcoming. Packing the Courts: Ideological Proximity and Expansions to the Federal Judiciary from 1937–2012. Journal of Law & Courts.
  26. Moe, Terry. 1985. Control and Feedback in Economic Regulation: The Case of the NLRB. American Political Science Review 79: 1094–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Noah, Lars. 2000. Interpreting Agency Enabling Acts: Misplaced Metaphors in Administrative Law. William & Mary Law Review 41: 1463–530. [Google Scholar]
  28. Poole, Keith, and Howard Rosenthal. 1985. A Spatial Model for Legislative Roll Call Analysis. American Journal of Political Science 29: 357–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Tempalski, Jerry. 2006. Revenue Effects of Major Tax Bills. United States Department of the Treasury Office of Tax Analysis Working Paper 81. Washington, DC, USA: United States Department of the Treasury Office of Tax Analysis. [Google Scholar]
  30. Volden, Craig. 2002. A Formal Model of the Politics of Delegation in a Separation of Powers System. American Journal of Political Science 46: 111–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Weingast, Barry. 1984. The Congressional-Bureaucratic System: A Principal-Agent Perspective (with applications to the SEC). Public Choice 44: 147–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Weingast, Barry, and Mark Moran. 1983. Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy 91: 765–800. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Whitford, Andrew B. 2005. The Pursuit of Political Control by Multiple Principals. Journal of Politics 67: 29–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Wildavsky, Aaron. 1964. The Politics of the Budgetary Process. Boston: Little, Brown. [Google Scholar]
  35. Wilson, James Q., ed. 1980. The Politics of Regulation. New York: Basic Books. [Google Scholar]
  36. Wilson, Joy Johnson. 2007. Deficit Reduction Act of 2005: Summary of Medicaid/Medicare/Health Provisions. Paper Presented at National Conference of State Legislatures, Washington, DC, USA, April 18. [Google Scholar]
  37. Yang, Shu-Chun Susan. 2007. A Chronology of Postwar U.S. Federal Income Tax Policy. Center for Applied Economics and Policy Research Working Paper #2007-021. Bloomington: Center for Applied Economics and Policy Research. [Google Scholar]
1
Mayhew’s data regarding significant legislation continue to be updated post-publication and publicly available at http://campuspress.yale.edu/davidmayhew/datasets-divided-we-govern/.
2
From 1947–1975, the relevant Senator for this calculation would be the 67th in a given direction in a 100-member Senate, as the cloture rule required a two-thirds majority to end debate, whereas thereafter—once the cloture rule was modified to require a three-fifths majority—the relevant Senator is the 60th in a given direction. Prior to the admission of Alaska and Hawaii into the union in 1959, there were 96 Senators, during which time the pivotal Senator was the 64th.
3
Data regarding executive branch civilian employment since 1940 are available from the Office of Personnel Management at https://www.opm.gov/policy-data-oversight/data-analysis-documentation/federal-employment-reports/historical-tables/executive-branch-civilian-employment-since-1940/.
4
For this variable, I employ the number of pages in the PDF version of each enacted public law, obtained through ProQuest’s Legislative Insight database, accessible at https://congressional.proquest.com/legislativeinsight/legislativeinsight. The inclusion of this measure is consistent with the approach taken in other recent work regarding delegation of implementation authority to the bureaucracy (Farhang and Yaver 2016).
5
In the Appendix A, I estimate two additional iterations of Model 1a from Table 2, designated Models A4 and A5 and without policy area fixed effects, and one additional version of Model 1b, designated Model A6. In Model A4, I re-estimate Model 1a but with continuous, ideology-based control variables in place of Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House. In Model A5, I re-estimate Model 1b but with binary measures of party control for both chambers in place of those variables. In Model A6, I re-estimate Model 1b but also including the time fixed effects used in Model 1c in Table 2. The results of these supplementary analyses are comparable with those presented in the text.
Figure 1. Intercameral ideological proximity and concentrated delegation.
Figure 1. Intercameral ideological proximity and concentrated delegation.
Laws 07 00019 g001
Table 1. Summary statistics.
Table 1. Summary statistics.
Total Laws in Sample386
Mean agencies delegated to per law5.89
Mean pages of text per law109
Percentage of laws delegating to:
Department of the Treasury48.9%
Executive Office of the President47.9%
Department of Labor36.5%
Department of Agriculture35.8%
Department of Defense32.6%
Department of Justice32.1%
Department of Health and Human Services28.0%
Department of the Interior26.2%
Department of Health, Education and Welfare23.3%
Department of Transportation18.7%
Department of Commerce18.1%
Department of Housing and Urban Development16.8%
Department of State14.8%
Environmental Protection Agency14.5%
Department of Homeland Security12.2%
Table 2. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation, 1947–2012. Dependent variable: Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority.
Table 2. Intercameral Ideological Congruence and Concentrated Delegation, 1947–2012. Dependent variable: Number of Agencies with Implementation Authority.
Independent VariablesModel 1a (Primary Model)
Coef. (r.s.e.)
Model 1b (Includes Conditional Indep. Variable)
Coef. (r.s.e.)
Model 1c (with Time Fixed Effects) ^
Coef. (r.s.e.)
Senate-House Distance1.556 (0.552) ***1.369 (0.632) **1.956 (1.185) **
Senate-House Distance with Unified Congress 0.448 (0.464)
Democratic Percentage in Senate−2.916 (1.320) **−2.985 (1.344) **−1.736 (1.961)
Democratic Percentage in House3.246 (1.223) ***3.369 (1.213) ***1.146 (1.387)
Unified Government−0.133 (0.091) *−0.163 (0.103) *−0.052 (0.101)
Executive Branch Workforce0.008 (0.003) **0.008 (0.003) ***−0.002 (0.004)
Length of Legislation0.002 (0.000) ***0.002 (0.000) ***0.002 (0.000) ***
Debt per GDP−0.015 (0.024)−0.007 (0.026)0.056 (0.047)
Constant−0.406 (0.626)−0.658 (0.611)−0.189 (1.641)
χ2293.21296.92298.75
N386386386
*** p ≤ 0.01; ** p ≤ 0.05; * p ≤ 0.10; all one-tailed tests except Democratic Percentage in Senate and Democratic Percentage in House. ^ Policy area and time fixed effects excluded from the table in the interest of space.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Peterson, J.C. All Their Eggs in One Basket? Ideological Congruence in Congress and the Bicameral Origins of Concentrated Delegation to the Bureaucracy. Laws 2018, 7, 19. https://doi.org/10.3390/laws7020019

AMA Style

Peterson JC. All Their Eggs in One Basket? Ideological Congruence in Congress and the Bicameral Origins of Concentrated Delegation to the Bureaucracy. Laws. 2018; 7(2):19. https://doi.org/10.3390/laws7020019

Chicago/Turabian Style

Peterson, Jordan Carr. 2018. "All Their Eggs in One Basket? Ideological Congruence in Congress and the Bicameral Origins of Concentrated Delegation to the Bureaucracy" Laws 7, no. 2: 19. https://doi.org/10.3390/laws7020019

APA Style

Peterson, J. C. (2018). All Their Eggs in One Basket? Ideological Congruence in Congress and the Bicameral Origins of Concentrated Delegation to the Bureaucracy. Laws, 7(2), 19. https://doi.org/10.3390/laws7020019

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop