The Behavior of Information: A Reconsideration of Social Norms
Abstract
:1. Introduction
“…without a clean empirical identification of the relevant norms almost every behaviour can be rationalized as norm driven, thus rendering norms useless as an explanatory construct. This raises the question of whether social norms are indeed causal drivers of behaviour and can convincingly explain major cooperation-related regularities.”
2. (Re-)Defining the Problem of Norms
2.1. The Strangeness of Normality
“It is my feeling that the pragmatic aspects pertaining to the socio-psychological contexts in which norms emerge, exist, and disappear have been relatively neglected in recent and current philosophical discussions, possibly because of the aforementioned reason – that the great variety of contexts concerned precludes adequate systematization.”
2.2. Normalizing Norms
3. Norms as Information
3.1. Ontology of Social Information
3.2. Individual and Collective Experience
3.3. The Process of Belief
- Believed to be true from prior experience and evaluation (i.e., a “belief that…”);
- Believed should be true based on all other available information (i.e., a “belief in…”).
4. Social Norms, Normativity, and Institutions
4.1. Norm and Collective Expectations
4.2. Collective and Normative Expectations
4.3. Normative Expectations and Curation of Information
5. Institutions and the Curation of Social Information
5.1. Curation and Instrumental Information
5.2. Social Information, Risk, and Efficiency
6. Discussion
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Kroeber, A.L.; Kluckhohn, C. Culture: A Critical Review of Concepts and Definitions; Alfred A. Knopf, Inc.: New York, NY, USA; Random House, Inc.: New York, NY, USA, 1963. [Google Scholar]
- Bicchieri, C. The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C. Norms in the Wild: How to Diagnose, Measure, and Change Social Norms; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gintis, H. A framework for the unification of the behavioral sciences. Behav. Brain Sci. 2007, 30, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Gintis, H. The Bounds of Reason: Game Theory and the Unification of the Behavioral Sciences, Revised ed.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Young, H.P. The Evolution of Social Norms. Annu. Rev. Econ. 2015, 7, 359–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ostrom, E. Collective action and the evolution of social norms. J. Econ. Perspect. 2000, 14, 137–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fehr, E.; Schurtenberger, I. Normative Foundations of Human Cooperation. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2018, 2, 458–468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nyborg, K. No man is an island: Social coordination and the environment. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2020, 76, 177–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Swidler, A. Culture in action: Symbols and strategies. Am. Sociol. Rev. 1986, 51, 273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Searle, J.R. The Construction of Social Reality; Free Press: New York, NY, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tomasello, M.; Rakoczy, H. What makes human cognition unique? From individual to shared to collective intentionality. Mind Lang. 2003, 18, 121–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rakoczy, H.; Schmidt, M.F.H. The Early Ontogeny of Social Norms. Child Dev. Perspect. 2013, 7, 17–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fricker, E. Norms, Constitutive and Social, and Assertion. Am. Philos. Q. 2017, 54, 397–418. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cislaghi, B.; Heise, L. Theory and practice of social norms interventions: Eight common pitfalls. Glob. Health 2018, 14, 83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Berger, J. Social Tipping Interventions Can Promote the Diffusion or Decay of Sustainable Consumption Norms in the Field. Evidence from a Quasi-Experimental Intervention Study. Sustainability 2021, 13, 3529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berger, J.; Efferson, C.; Vogt, S. Tipping pro-environmental norm diffusion at scale: Opportunities and limitations. Behav. Public Policy 2021, 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Postlewaite, A. Social Norms and Preferences. In Handbook of Social Economics; Bisin, A., Benhabib, J., Jackson, M., Eds.; North-Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2011; Volume 1, pp. 31–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Alderson, K. Making Sense of State Socialization. Rev. Int. Stud. 2001, 27, 415–433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bhui, R.; Chudek, M.; Henrich, J. How exploitation launched human cooperation. Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol. 2019, 73, 78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roth, P.A. The silence of the norms: The missing historiography of The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Stud. Hist. Philos. Sci. Part A 2013, 44, 545–552. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Risjord, M. (Ed.) Normativity and Naturalism in the Philosophy of the Social Sciences; Number 77 in Routledge studies in contemporary philosophy; Routledge: New York, NY, USA, 2016; pp. 1–272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huang, P.H.; Wu, H.M. More Order without More Law: A Theory of Social Norms and Organizational Cultures. J. Law Econ. Organ. 1994, 10, 390–406. [Google Scholar]
- Mahoney, P.G.; Sanchirico, C.W. Norms, Repeated Games, and the Role of Law. Calif. Law Rev. 2003, 91, 1281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Malle, B.F. The social and moral cognition of group agents. J. Law Policy 2010, 20, 95–136. [Google Scholar]
- Connors, M.H.; Halligan, P.W. A cognitive account of belief: A tentative road map. Front. Psychol. 2015, 5, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Badcock, P.B.; Friston, K.J.; Ramstead, M.J.D.; Ploeger, A.; Hohwy, J. The hierarchically mechanistic mind: An evolutionary systems theory of the human brain, cognition, and behavior. Cogn. Affect. Behav. Neurosci. 2019, 19, 1319–1351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Veissière, S.P.L.; Constant, A.; Ramstead, M.J.D.; Friston, K.J.; Kirmayer, L.J. Thinking through Other Minds: A Variational Approach to Cognition and Culture. Behav. Brain Sci. 2019, 43, 1–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Boella, G.; van der Torre, L. An Architecture of a Normative System: Counts-as Conditionals, Obligations and Permissions. In Proceedings of the Fifth International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems—AAMAS’06, Hakodate, Japan, 8–12 May 2006; ACM Press: New York, NY, USA, 2006; p. 229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barandiaran, X.E.; Di Paolo, E.; Rohde, M. Defining Agency: Individuality, Normativity, Asymmetry, and Spatio-temporality in Action. Adapt. Behav. 2009, 17, 367–386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Elsenbroich, C.; Xenitidou, M. Three kinds of normative behaviour: Minimal requirements for feedback models. Comput. Math. Organ. Theory 2012, 18, 113–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Barandiaran, X.E.; Egbert, M.D. Norm-Establishing and Norm-Following in Autonomous Agency. Artif. Life 2013, 24, 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Legros, S.; Cislaghi, B. Mapping the Social-Norms Literature: An Overview of Reviews. Perspect. Psychol. Sci. 2020, 15, 62–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Burtsev, M.; Turchin, P. Evolution of Cooperative Strategies from First Principles. Nature 2006, 440, 1041–1044. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mesoudi, A.; Whiten, A.; Laland, K.N. Towards a unified science of cultural evolution. Behav. Brain Sci. 2006, 29, 329–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Burke, M.A.; Young, H.P. Social norms. In Handbook of Social Economics; Bisin, A., Benhabib, J., Jackson, M., Eds.; North-Holland: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2011; Volume 1, pp. 311–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C. Covenants without Swords. Ration. Soc. 2002, 14, 192–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sripada, C.S.; Stich, S. A Framework for the Psychology of Norms. In The Innate Mind: Culture and Cognition; Carruthers, P., Laurence, S., Stich, S., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2007; Volume 2, Chapter 17; pp. 280–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Härpfer, C.; Kaden, T. Weber and Simmel on the formation of norms, rules, and laws. J. Class. Sociol. 2017, 17, 116–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wallen, K.E.; Romulo, C.L. Social norms: More details, please. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2017, 114, E5283–E5284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fehr, E.; Fischbacher, U. Social Norms and Human Cooperation. Trends Cogn. Sci. 2004, 8, 185–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Roth, P.A. What Would It Be to Be a Norm. In Normativity and Naturalism in the Philosophy of the Social Sciences; Risjord, M., Ed.; Routledge: New York, NY, USA; London, UK, 2016; Chapter 4; pp. 43–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hindriks, F. The Freedom of Collective Agents. J. Political Philos. 2008, 16, 165–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gavrilets, S. Collective action problem in heterogeneous groups. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2015, 370, 20150016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Fehr, E.; Fischbacher, U. Third-party punishment and social norms. Evol. Hum. Behav. 2004, 25, 63–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Laitinen, A. Varieties of normativity: Reasons, expectations, wide-scope oughts, and ought-to-be’s. In Social Ontology, Normativity and Law; Garcia-Godinez, M., Mellin, R., Tuomela, R., Eds.; De Gruyter: Berlin, Germany, 2020; pp. 133–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Dimant, E.; Sonderegger, S. It’s not a lie if you believe the norm does not apply: Conditional norm-following and belief distortion. Games Econ. Behav. 2023, 138, 321–354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mesoudi, A. Cultural Evolution: A Review of Theory, Findings and Controversies. Evol. Biol. 2015, 43, 481–497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shulman, H.C.; Rhodes, N.; Davidson, E.; Ralston, R.; Borghetti, L.; Morr, L. The State of the Field of Social Norms Research. Int. J. Commun. 2017, 11, 1192–1213. [Google Scholar]
- Hume, D. A Treatise of Human Nature; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Morris, R.T. A Typology of Norms. Source 1956, 21, 610–613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lewis, D.K. Convention: A Philosophical Study; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Brandom, R.B. Freedom and Constraint by Norms. Am. Philos. Q. 1979, 16, 187–196. [Google Scholar]
- Brandom, R.B. Action, norms, and practical reasoning. Nous 1998, 32, 127–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Guala, F. Understanding Institutions: The Science and Philosophy of Living Together; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Muldoon, R.; Sontuoso, A. Social Norms. In The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy; Zalta, E.N., Ed.; Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University: Stanford, CA, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Searle, J.R. Social Ontology: Some Basic Principles. Anthropol. Theory 2006, 6, 12–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hardy-Vallée, B.; Dubreuil, B. Folk Epistemology as Normative Social Cognition. Rev. Philos. Psychol. 2009, 1, 483–498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jurgens, A.; Kirchhoff, M.D. Enactive Social Cognition: Diachronic Constitution & Coupled Anticipation. Conscious. Cogn. 2019, 70, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Hédoin, C. Institutions, Rule-Following and Game Theory. Econ. Philos. 2016, 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Constant, A.; Ramstead, M.J.D.; Veissière, S.P.L.; Friston, K.J. Regimes of expectations: An active inference model of social conformity and human decision making. Front. Psychol. 2019, 10, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cialdini, R.B.; Kallgren, C.A.; Reno, R.R. A focus theory of normative conduct: A theoretical refinement and reevaluation of the role of norms in human behavior. Adv. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 1991, 24, 201–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rouse, J. Social Practices and Normativity. Philos. Soc. Sci. 2007, 37, 46–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chrisman, M. The Normative Evaluation of Belief and The Aspectual Classification of Belief and Knowledge Attributions. J. Philos. 2012, 109, 588–612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Xiao, E.; Bicchieri, C. Words or deeds? Choosing What to Know about Others. Synthese 2012, 187, 49–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Dimant, E.; Xiao, E. Deviant or Wrong? The Effects of Norm Information on the Efficacy of Punishment. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2021, 188, 209–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hindriks, F.; Guala, F. The functions of institutions: Etiology and teleology. Synthese 2021, 198, 2027–2043. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Granovetter, M.S. The Strength of Weak Ties. Am. J. Sociol. 1973, 78, 1360–1380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Granovetter, M.S. Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness. Am. J. Sociol. 1985, 91, 481–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Funcke, A. Norm change: Trendsetters and social structure. Soc. Res. 2018, 85, 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; McNally, P. Shrieking sirens: Schemata, scripts, and social norms. How change occurs. Soc. Philos. Policy 2018, 35, 23–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ehlert, A.; Kindschi, M.; Algesheimer, R.; Rauhut, H. Human social preferences cluster and spread in the field. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2020, 117, 22787–22792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aumann, R.J. Correlated Equilibrium as an Expression of Bayesian Rationality. Econometrica 1987, 55, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Vanderschraaf, P. Knowledge, equilibrium and convention. Erkenntnis 1998, 49, 337–369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gintis, H. Strong reciprocity and human sociality. J. Theor. Biol. 2000, 206, 169–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Sillari, G. A Logical Framework for Convention. Synthese 2005, 147, 379–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gintis, H.; Doebeli, M.; Flack, J. The Evolution of Human Cooperation. Cliodynamics 2012, 3, 172–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hindriks, F.; Guala, F. Institutions, rules, and equilibria: A unified theory. J. Inst. Econ. 2015, 11, 459–480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bicchieri, C. Norms, preferences, and conditional behavior. Politics Philos. Econ. 2010, 9, 297–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aumann, R.J. What is game theory trying to accomplish? Front. Econ. 1985, 29, 28–76. [Google Scholar]
- Schultz, P.W.; Nolan, J.M.; Cialdini, R.B.; Goldstein, N.J.; Griskevicius, V. The Constructive, Destructive, and Reconstructive Power of Social Norms. Psychol. Sci. 2007, 18, 429–434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nolan, J.M.; Schultz, P.W.; Cialdini, R.B.; Goldstein, N.J.; Griskevicius, V. Normative social influence is underdetected. Personal. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 2008, 34, 913–923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Paternotte, C.; Grose, J. Social Norms and Game Theory: Harmony or Discord? Br. J. Philos. Sci. 2013, 64, 551–587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Andrighetto, G.; Campennì, M.; Cecconi, F.; Conte, R. The Complex Loop of Norm Emergence: A Simulation Model. In Simulating Interacting Agents and Social Phenomena; Takadama, K., Cioffi-Revilla, C., Deffuant, G., Eds.; Springer: Tokyo, Japan, 2010; pp. 19–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Centola, D.; Baronchelli, A. The spontaneous emergence of conventions: An experimental study of cultural evolution. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2015, 112, 1989–1994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Centola, D.; Becker, J.; Brackbill, D.; Baronchelli, A. Experimental evidence for tipping points in social convention. Science 2018, 360, 1116–1119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Axelrod, R. An Evolutionary Approach to Norms. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 1986, 80, 1095–1111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Axelrod, R. The Dissemination of Culture. J. Confl. Resolut. 1997, 41, 203–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gavrilets, S.; Richerson, P.J. Collective action and the evolution of social norm internalization. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2017, 114, 6068–6073. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Gilbert, N. Holism, Individualism and Emergent Properties. In Modelling and Simulation in the Social Sciences from the Philosophy of Science Point of View; Hegselmann, R., Mueller, U., Troitzsch, K.G., Eds.; Springer: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 1996; pp. 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sawyer, R.K. Social explanation and computational simulation. Philos. Explor. 2004, 7, 219–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gilbert, N. When Does Social Simulation Need Cognitive Models? In Cognition and Multi-Agent Interaction: From Cognitive Modeling to Social Simulation; Sun, R., Ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Squazzoni, F. The Micro-Macro Link in Social Simulation. Sociologica 2008, 49, 157–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Anzola, D. Causation in Agent-Based Computational Social Science. In Proceedings of the Advances in Social Simulation; Verhagen, H., Borit, M., Bravo, G., Wijermans, N., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2020; pp. 47–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pastrav, C.; Dignum, F. Norms in Social Simulation: Balancing Between Realism and Scalability. In Proceedings of the Advances in Social Simulation; Verhagen, H., Borit, M., Bravo, G., Wijermans, N., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2020; pp. 329–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mesoudi, A. Pursuing Darwin’s curious parallel: Prospects for a science of cultural evolution. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2017, 114, 7853–7860. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Muldoon, R. Perspectives, norms, and agency. Soc. Philos. Policy 2017, 34, 260–276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Therborn, G. Back to Norms! On the Scope and Dynamics of Norms and Normative Action. Curr. Sociol. 2002, 50, 863–880. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Mercier, H. Norms and Beliefs: How Change Occurs. Jerus. Philos. Q. 2014, 63, 60–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Andrighetto, G.; Vriens, E. A research agenda for the study of social norm change. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. A Math. Phys. Eng. Sci. 2022, 380, 20200411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Prentice, D.A. Intervening to Change Social Norms: When Does It Work? Soc. Res. Int. Q. 2018, 85, 115–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hoeft, L. The Force of Norms? The Internal Point of View in Light of Experimental Economics. Ratio Juris 2019, 32, 339–362. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Prentice, D.A.; Paluck, E.L. Engineering social change using social norms: Lessons from the study of collective action. Curr. Opin. Psychol. 2020, 35, 138–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Muldoon, R. Understanding norms and changing them. Soc. Philos. Policy 2018, 35, 128–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Richter, I.; Thøgersen, J.; Klöckner, C. A Social Norms Intervention Going Wrong: Boomerang Effects from Descriptive Norms Information. Sustainability 2018, 10, 2848. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Masur, P.K.; DiFranzo, D.; Bazarova, N.N. Behavioral contagion on social media: Effects of social norms, design interventions, and critical media literacy on self-disclosure. PLoS ONE 2021, 16, e0254670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Dimant, E.; Gächter, S.; Nosenzo, D. Social proximity and the erosion of norm compliance. Games Econ. Behav. 2022, 132, 59–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fricker, E. Second-hand knowledge. Philos. Phenomenol. Res. 2006, 73, 595–618. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baldassarri, D.; Grossman, G. Centralized sanctioning and legitimate authority promote cooperation in humans. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2011, 108, 11023–11027. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Silk, J.B.; House, B.R. The evolution of altruistic social preferences in human groups. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2016, 371, 20150097. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fehr, E.; Fischbacher, U.; Gächter, S. Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms. Hum. Nat. 2002, 13, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fix, J.; von Scheve, C.; Moldt, D. Emotion-based norm enforcement and maintenance in multi-agent systems: Foundations and petri net modeling. In Proceedings of the Fifth International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems, Hakodate, Japan, 8–12 May 2006; pp. 105–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Reuben, E.; Riedl, A. Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogeneous populations. Games Econ. Behav. 2013, 77, 122–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Abbink, K.; Gangadharan, L.; Handfield, T.; Thrasher, J. Peer punishment promotes enforcement of bad social norms. Nat. Commun. 2017, 8, 609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Stagnaro, M.N.; Arechar, A.A.; Rand, D.G. From good institutions to generous citizens: Top-down incentives to cooperate promote subsequent prosociality but not norm enforcement. Cognition 2017, 167, 212–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Winter, F.; Zhang, N. Social norm enforcement in ethnically diverse communities. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2018, 115, 2722–2727. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fehr, E.; Gächter, S. Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 2002, 415, 137–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Houser, D.; Xiao, E.; McCabe, K.; Smith, V. When punishment fails: Research on sanctions, intentions and non-cooperation. Games Econ. Behav. 2008, 62, 509–532. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rebers, S.; Koopmans, R. Altruistic Punishment and Between-Group Competition: Evidence from n-person Prisoner’s Dilemmas. Hum. Nat. 2012, 23, 173–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Henrich, J.; Ensminger, J. Theoretical Foundations: The Coevolution of Social Norms, Intrinsic Motivation, Markets, and the Institutions of Complex Societies. In Experimenting with Social Norms: Fairness and Punishment in Cross-Cultural Perspective; Ensminger, J., Henrich, J., Eds.; Russell Sage Foundation: New York, NY, USA, 2014; Chapter 2; pp. 19–44. [Google Scholar]
- Crawford, S.E.S.; Ostrom, E. A Grammar of Institutions. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 1995, 89, 582–600. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alesina, A.; Giuliano, P. Culture and Institutions. J. Econ. Lit. 2015, 53, 898–944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Misztal, B.A. Normality and Trust in Goffman’s Theory of Interaction Order. Sociol. Theory 2001, 19, 312–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wehrle, M. Normality and Normativity in Experience. In Normativity in Perception; Doyon, M., Breyer, T., Eds.; Palgrave McMillan: Basingstoke, UK, 2015; pp. 128–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bear, A.; Knobe, J. Normality: Part descriptive, part prescriptive. Cognition 2017, 167, 25–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Cialdini, R.B. Descriptive Social Norms as Underappreciated Sources of Social Control. Psychometrika 2007, 72, 263–268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Muldoon, R.; Lisciandra, C.; Bicchieri, C.; Hartmann, S.; Sprenger, J. On the emergence of descriptive norms. Politics Philos. Econ. 2013, 13, 3–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Melnyk, V.; van Herpen, E.; Fischer, A.R.H.; van Trijp, H.C.M. To think or not to think: The effect of cognitive deliberation on the influence of injunctive versus descriptive social norms. Psychol. Mark. 2011, 28, 709–729. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eriksson, K.; Strimling, P.; Coultas, J.C. Bidirectional associations between descriptive and injunctive norms. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 2015, 129, 59–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gavrilets, S. The dynamics of injunctive social norms. Evol. Hum. Sci. 2020, 2, e60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C. Norms, Conventions and the Power of Expectations. In Philosophy of Social Science: A New Introduction; Cartwright, N., Montuschi, E., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2014; Chapter 11; pp. 208–229. [Google Scholar]
- House, B.R. How do social norms influence prosocial development? Curr. Opin. Psychol. 2018, 20, 87–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hawkins, R.X.D.; Goodman, N.D.; Goldstone, R.L. The Emergence of Social Norms and Conventions. Trends Cogn. Sci. 2019, 23, 158–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hawkins, R.X.D.; Goldstone, R.L. The Formation of Social Conventions in Real-Time Environments. PLoS ONE 2016, 11, e0151670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jones, J.P.G.; Andriamarovololona, M.M.; Hockley, N. The importance of taboos and social norms to conservation in madagascar. Conserv. Biol. 2008, 22, 976–986. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ryabova, M. Politeness Strategy in Everyday Communication. Procedia-Soc. Behav. Sci. 2015, 206, 90–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bourdieu, P. Distinction: A social critique of the judgement of taste. In Social Stratification, Class, Race, and Gender in Sociological Perspective; Grusky, D., Ed.; Taylor & Francis Group: New York, NY, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
- Nassauer, J.I.; Wang, Z.; Dayrell, E. What will the neighbors think? Cultural norms and ecological design. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2009, 92, 282–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- MacNeil, M.K.; Sherif, M. Norm change over subject generations as a function of arbitrariness of prescribed norms. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 1976, 34, 762–773. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- FeldmanHall, O.; Son, J.Y.; Heffner, J. Norms and the Flexibility of Moral Action. Personal. Neurosci. 2018, 1, e15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dutant, J.; Littlejohn, C. Just do it? When to do what you judge you ought to do. Synthese 2018, 195, 3755–3772. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Désilets, É.; Brisson, B.; Hétu, S. Sensitivity to social norm violation is related to political orientation. PLoS ONE 2020, 15, e0242996. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Villatoro, D.; Sen, S.; Sabater-Mir, J. Of Social Norms and Sanctioning. Int. J. Agent Technol. Syst. 2010, 2, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bicchieri, C.; Dimant, E. Nudging with care: The risks and benefits of social information. Public Choice 2019, 401, 1–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zou, X.; Morris, M.W.; Benet-Martínez, V. Identity motives and cultural priming: Cultural (dis)identification in assimilative and contrastive responses. J. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 2008, 44, 1151–1159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goncalo, J.A.; Duguid, M.M. Follow the crowd in a new direction: When conformity pressure facilitates group creativity (and when it does not). Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 2012, 118, 14–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Littlejohn, C. Who Cares What You Accurately Believe? Nous-Suppl. Philos. Perspect. 2015, 29, 217–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Pryor, C.; Perfors, A.; Howe, P.D.L. Even arbitrary norms influence moral decision-making. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2019, 3, 57–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Cialdini, R.B. Crafting Normative Messages to Protect the Environment. Curr. Dir. Psychol. Sci. 2003, 12, 105–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nichols, S. Sentimental Rules: On the Natural Foundations of Moral Judgement; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sherif, M. The Psychology of Social Norms; Harper: New York, NY, USA, 1936. [Google Scholar]
- Rutkowski, G.K.; Gruder, C.L.; Romer, D. Group cohesiveness, social norms, and bystander intervention. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 1983, 44, 545–552. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schiefer, D.; van der Noll, J. The Essentials of Social Cohesion: A Literature Review. Soc. Indic. Res. 2017, 132, 579–603. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gintis, H. The Hitchhiker’s Guide to Altruism: Gene-culture Coevolution, and the Internalization of Norms. J. Theor. Biol. 2003, 220, 407–418. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Read, D.W. Change in the form of evolution: Transition from primate to hominid forms of social organization. J. Math. Sociol. 2005, 29, 91–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Henrich, J.; Boyd, R.; Richerson, P.J. Five misunderstandings about cultural evolution. Hum. Nat. 2008, 19, 119–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- West, S.A.; Griffin, A.S.; Gardner, A. Social semantics: How useful has group selection been? J. Evol. Biol. 2008, 21, 374–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Akçay, E.; an Cleve, J.; Feldman, M.W.; Roughgarden, J. A theory for the evolution of other-regard integrating proximate and ultimate perspectives. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2009, 106, 19061–19066. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nowak, M.A.; Tarnita, C.E.; Wilson, E.O. The Evolution of Eusociality. Nature 2010, 466, 1057–1062. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- West, S.A.; El Mouden, C.; Gardner, A. Sixteen Common Misconceptions about the Evolution of Cooperation in Humans. Evol. Hum. Behav. 2011, 32, 231–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baumard, N.; André, J.B.; Sperber, D. A mutualistic approach to morality: The evolution of fairness by partner choice. Behav. Brain Sci. 2013, 36, 59–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Smaldino, P.E. The cultural evolution of emergent group-level traits. Behav. Brain Sci. 2014, 37, 243–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smith, D.; Schlaepfer, P.; Major, K.; Dyble, M.; Page, A.E.; Thompson, J.; Chaudhary, N.; Salali, G.D.; MacE, R.; Astete, L.; et al. Cooperation and the evolution of hunter-gatherer storytelling. Nat. Commun. 2017, 8, 1853. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Friston, K.J.; Daunizeau, J.; Kiebel, S.J. Reinforcement learning or active inference? PLoS ONE 2009, 4, e6421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Friston, K.J. The free-energy principle: A unified brain theory? Nat. Rev. Neurosci. 2010, 11, 127–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Raub, W.; Snijders, C. Gains, losses, and cooperation in social dilemmas and collective action: The effects of risk preferences. J. Math. Sociol. 1997, 22, 263–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Novak, M.A. Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation. Science 2006, 314, 1560–1563. [Google Scholar]
- Helbing, D.; Yu, W. The outbreak of cooperation among success-driven individuals under noisy conditions. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2009, 106, 3680–3685. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Helbing, D.; Johansson, A. Cooperation, Norms, and Revolutions: A Unified Game-Theoretical Approach. PLoS ONE 2010, 5, e12530. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Richerson, P.; Baldini, R.; Bell, A.V.; Demps, K.; Frost, K.; Hillis, V.; Mathew, S.; Newton, E.K.; Naar, N.; Newson, L.; et al. Cultural group selection plays an essential role in explaining human cooperation: A sketch of the evidence. Behav. Brain Sci. 2016, 39, e30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Lozano, P.; Gavrilets, S.; Sánchez, A. Cooperation, social norm internalization, and hierarchical societies. Sci. Rep. 2020, 10, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arló-Costa, H.; Pedersen, A.P. Social Norms, Rational Choice and Belief Change. In Belief Revision Meets Philosophy of Science; Olsson, E.J., Enqvist, S., Eds.; Springer: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 2011; pp. 163–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baldassarri, D.; Grossman, G. The Effect of Group Attachment and Social Position on Prosocial Behavior. Evidence from Lab-in-the-field Experiments. PLoS ONE 2013, 8, e58750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ullmann-Margalit, E. Emergence of Norms; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2015; p. 224. [Google Scholar]
- Clément, F.; Bernard, S.; Kaufmann, L. Social cognition is not reducible to theory of mind: When children use deontic rules to predict the behaviour of others. Br. J. Dev. Psychol. 2011, 29, 910–928. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jones, M. Bayesian Fundamentalism or Enlightenment ? On the Explanatory Status and Theoretical Contributions of Bayesian Models of Cognition. Behav. Brain Sci. 2010, 5935, 1–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Jacobs, R.A.; Kruschke, J.K. Bayesian learning theory applied to human cognition. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Cogn. Sci. 2010, 2, 8–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- van Dijk, L.; Withagen, R.; Bongers, R.M. Information without content: A Gibsonian reply to enactivists’ worries. Cognition 2015, 134, 210–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chater, N.; Felin, T.; Funder, D.C.; Gigerenzer, G.; Koenderink, J.J.; Krueger, J.I.; Noble, D.; Nordli, S.A.; Oaksford, M.; Schwartz, B.; et al. Mind, rationality, and cognition: An interdisciplinary debate. Psychon. Bull. Rev. 2018, 25, 793–826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zahavi, D. Brain, Mind, World: Predictive Coding, Neo-Kantianism, and Transcendental Idealism. Husserl Stud. 2018, 34, 47–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Friston, K.J.; Stephan, K.E. Free-energy and the brain. Synthese 2007, 159, 417–458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Friston, K.J. The history of the future of the Bayesian brain. Neuroimage 2012, 62, 1230–1233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Clark, A. Whatever next? Predictive brains, situated agents, and the future of cognitive science. Behav. Brain Sci. 2013, 36, 181–204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sanborn, A.N.; Chater, N. Bayesian Brains without Probabilities. Trends Cogn. Sci. 2016, 20, 883–893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Williams, D. Predictive coding and thought. Synthese 2020, 197, 1749–1775. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sterelny, K. Social intelligence, human intelligence and niche construction. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. London. Ser. B Biol. Sci. 2007, 362, 719–730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- André, J.B.; Baumard, N. Social opportunities and the evolution of fairness. J. Theor. Biol. 2011, 289, 128–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Jensen, K.; Vaish, A.; Schmidt, M.F.H. The emergence of human prosociality: Aligning with others through feelings, concerns, and norms. Front. Psychol. 2014, 5, 822. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Kurzban, R.; Burton-Chellew, M.N.; West, S.A. The Evolution of Altruism in Humans. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 2015, 66, 575–599. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fabry, R.E. Betwixt and between: The enculturated predictive processing approach to cognition. Synthese 2018, 195, 2483–2518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fabry, R.E. Limiting the explanatory scope of extended active inference: The implications of a causal pattern analysis of selective niche construction, developmental niche construction, and organism-niche coordination dynamics. Biol. Philos. 2021, 36, 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alexander, J.C. Cultural Pragmatics: Social Performance between Ritual and Strategy. Sociol. Theory 2004, 22, 527–573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baerveldt, C. Cultural psychology as the study of normative experience. In Citizen City: Between Constructing Agent and Constructed Agency; van Deventer, V., Terre Blanche, M., Fourie, E., Segalo, P., Eds.; Captus: Concord, ON, Canada, 2007; pp. 105–114. [Google Scholar]
- Gettier, E.L. Is Justified True Belief Knowledge? Analysis 1963, 23, 121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bogardus, T. Knowledge Under Threat. Philos. Phenomenol. Res. 2014, 88, 289–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cromby, J. Beyond belief. J. Health Psychol. 2012, 17, 943–957. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Railton, P. Reliance, Trust, and Belief. Inquiry 2014, 57, 122–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McHugh, C.; Whiting, D. The Normativity of Belief. Analysis 2014, 74, 698–713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Davidson, D. Three Varieties of Knowledge. R. Inst. Philos. Suppl. 1991, 30, 153–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Floridi, L. What is the Philosophy of Information? Metaphilosophy 2002, 33, 123–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Adriaans, P.; van Benthem, J. Introduction: Information is What Information Does. Philos. Inf. 2008, 8, 3–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dietrich, F.; List, C. Reasons for (prior) belief in Bayesian epistemology. Synthese 2013, 190, 787–808. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fuchs, C. The role of the individual in the social information process. Entropy 2003, 5, 34–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Davidson, D. On the Very Idea of a Conceptual Scheme. Proc. Addresses Am. Philos. Assoc. 1973, 47, 5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Macarthur, D. Putnam’s natural realism and the question of a perceptual interface. Philos. Explor. 2004, 7, 167–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Malle, B.F. Folk Theory of Mind: Conceptual Foundations of Human Social Cognition. In The New Unconscious; Hassin, R.R., Uleman, J.S., Bargh, J.A., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2006; pp. 224–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Clark, A. Busting Out: Predictive Brains, Embodied Minds, and the Puzzle of the Evidentiary Veil. Noûs 2016, 51, 727–753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Mchugh, C. The Truth Norm of Belief. Pac. Philos. Q. 2012, 93, 8–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Quilty-Dunn, J.; Mandelbaum, E. Against Dispositionalism: Belief in cognitive science. Philos. Stud. 2018, 175, 2353–2372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Weinstein, N.D. Effects of personal experience on self-protective behavior. Psychol. Bull. 1989, 105, 31–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- James, W. The psychology of belief. Mind 1889, 14, 321–352. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Braithwaite, R.B. The Nature of Believing. Proc. Aristot. Soc. 1933, 33, 129–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Davidson, D. Rational Animals. Dialectica 1982, 36, 317–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zimmerman, A. The Nature of Belief. J. Conscious. Stud. 2007, 14, 61–82. [Google Scholar]
- Atran, S. The Nature of Belief. Science 2007, 317, 456. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Santiago-Delefosse, M. Deconstructing the notion of ‘belief’ in Psychology: Commentary on ‘Beyond belief’. J. Health Psychol. 2012, 17, 974–976. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Leitgeb, H. The Stability Theory of Belief. Philos. Rev. 2014, 123, 131–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kincaid, H. The Empirical Nature of the Individualism-Holism Dispute. Synthese 1993, 97, 229–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gigerenzer, G.; Brighton, H. Homo Heuristicus: Why Biased Minds Make Better Inferences. Top. Cogn. Sci. 2009, 1, 107–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gigerenzer, G.; Gaissmaier, W. Heuristic Decision Making. Annu. Rev. Psychol. 2011, 62, 451–482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Friston, K.J. Learning and inference in the brain. Neural Netw. 2003, 16, 1325–1352. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Harkness, D.L.; Keshava, A. Moving from the What to the How and Where—Bayesian Models and Predictive Processing. Philos. Predict. Process. 2017, 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Parr, T.; Friston, K.J. The anatomy of inference: Generative models and brain structure. Front. Comput. Neurosci. 2018, 12, 90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Kuchling, F.; Friston, K.; Georgiev, G.; Levin, M. Morphogenesis as Bayesian inference: A variational approach to pattern formation and control in complex biological systems. Phys. Life Rev. 2020, 33, 88–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Millidge, B. Deep active inference as variational policy gradients. J. Math. Psychol. 2020, 96, 102348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rescorla, M. Bayesian modeling of the mind: From norms to neurons. WIREs Cogn. Sci. 2021, 12, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Turner, S.P. Webs of Belief, Practices, and Concepts. Arch. Eur. De Sociol. 2010, 51, 397–421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chamley, C.; Scaglione, A.; Li, L. Models for the diffusion of beliefs in social networks: An overview. IEEE Signal Process. Mag. 2013, 30, 16–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Christoff, Z.; Hansen, J.U. A logic for diffusion in social networks. J. Appl. Log. 2015, 13, 48–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Germar, M.; Mojzisch, A. Learning of social norms can lead to a persistent perceptual bias: A diffusion model approach. J. Exp. Soc. Psychol. 2019, 84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bar, M. The proactive brain: Using analogies and associations to generate predictions. Trends Cogn. Sci. 2007, 11, 280–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sharot, T.; Garrett, N. Forming Beliefs: Why Valence Matters. Trends Cogn. Sci. 2016, 20, 25–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Marchionini, G. Information Seeking in Electronic Environments; Number 9; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Savolainen, R. Everyday life information seeking: Approaching information seeking in the context of “way of life”. Libr. Inf. Sci. Res. 1995, 17, 259–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hersberger, J.A.; Rioux, K.S.; Cruitt, R.O. Examining Information Sharing and Relationship Building in Online Social Networks: An Emergent Analytic Framework. In Proceedings of the Annual Conference of CAIS, London, ON, Canada, 2–4 June 2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ültanır, E. An epistemological glance at the constructivist approach: Constructivist learning in Dewey, Piaget, and Montessori. Int. J. Instr. 2012, 5, 195–212. [Google Scholar]
- Turner, S. Taking the Collective Out of Tacit Knowledge. Philos. Sci. 2013, 17, 75–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Turner, S.P. Double Heuristics and Collective Knowledge: The Case of Expertise. Stud. Emergent Order 2012, 5, 82–103. [Google Scholar]
- Becker, J.C.; Tausch, N. A dynamic model of engagement in normative and non-normative collective action: Psychological antecedents, consequences, and barriers. Eur. Rev. Soc. Psychol. 2015, 26, 43–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Newman, M.E.J.; Girvan, M. Mixing patterns and community structure in networks. In Statistical Mechanics of Complex Networks; Pastor-Satorras, R., Rubi, M., Diaz-Guilera, A., Eds.; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2003; pp. 66–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Vital, C.; Martins, E.P. Using Graph Theory Metrics to Infer Information Flow through Animal Social Groups: A Computer Simulation Analysis. Ethology 2009, 115, 347–355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Makagon, M.M.; McCowan, B.; Mench, J.A. How can social network analysis contribute to social behavior research in applied ethology? Appl. Anim. Behav. Sci. 2012, 138, 152–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bedau, M.A. Emergent models of supple dynamics in life and mind. Brain Cogn. 1997, 34, 5–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bedau, M.A. Weak Emergence. Noûs 2008, 31, 375–399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crutchfield, J.P. The calculi of emergence: Computation, dynamics and induction. Phys. D Nonlinear Phenom. 1994, 75, 11–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chalmers, D.J. Strong and weak emergence. In The Re-Emergence of Emergence: The Emergentist Hypothesis from Science to Religion; Clayton, P., Davies, P., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2008; pp. 244–254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dunbar, R.I.M.; Spoors, M. Social networks, support cliques, and kinship. Hum. Nat. 1995, 6, 273–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Wu, F.; Huberman, B.A.; Adamic, L.A.; Tyler, J.R. Information flow in social groups. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Its Appl. 2004, 337, 327–335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bilek, E.; Ruf, M.; Schäfer, A.; Akdeniz, C.; Calhoun, V.D.; Schmahl, C.; Demanuele, C.; Tost, H.; Kirsch, P.; Meyer-Lindenberg, A. Information flow between interacting human brains: Identification, validation, and relationship to social expertise. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2015, 112, 5207–5212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Agliari, E.; Burioni, R.; Cassi, D.; Neri, F.M. Efficiency of information spreading in a population of diffusing agents. Phys. Rev. E 2006, 73, 046138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Centola, D. The Spread of Behavior in an Online Social Network Experiment. Science 2010, 329, 1194–1197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Savarimuthu, B.T.R.; Cranefield, S. Norm creation, spreading and emergence: A survey of simulation models of norms in multi-agent systems. Multiagent Grid Syst. 2011, 7, 21–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vosoughi, S.; Roy, D.; Aral, S. The spread of true and false news online. Science 2018, 359, 1146–1151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhou, B.; Pei, S.; Muchnik, L.; Meng, X.; Xu, X.; Sela, A.; Havlin, S.; Stanley, H.E. Realistic modelling of information spread using peer-to-peer diffusion patterns. Nat. Hum. Behav. 2020, 4, 1198–1207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xuan, P.; Lesser, V.; Zilberstein, S. Communication in multi-agent Markov decision processes. In Proceedings of the Fourth International Conference on MultiAgent Systems, Boston, MA, USA, 10–12 July 2000; pp. 467–468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nakamura, M.; Masuda, N. Indirect Reciprocity under Incomplete Observation. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2011, 7, e1002113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Janssen, M.A.; Ostrom, E. Vulnerability of social norms to incomplete information. In The Complexity of Social Norms; Xenitidou, M., Edmonds, B., Eds.; Springer International Publishing: Cham, Switzerland, 2014; pp. 161–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hegde, K.; Magdon-Ismail, M.; Szymanski, B.; Kuzmin, K. Clustering, prominence and social network analysis on incomplete networks. In Complex Networks & Their Applications; Cherifi, H., Gaito, S., Quattrociocchi, W., Sala, A., Eds.; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2017; Volume V, pp. 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- de Geest, L.R.; Kingsley, D.C. Norm enforcement with incomplete information. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2021, 189, 403–430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Allen, P.M.; McGlade, J.M. Evolutionary drive: The effect of microscopic diversity, error making, and noise. Found. Phys. 1987, 17, 723–738. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crutchfield, J.P. Is anything ever new? Considering emergence. In Emergence: Contemporary Readings in Philosophy and Science; Bedau, M.A., Humphreys, P., Eds.; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fulmer, C.A.; Ostroff, C. Convergence and emergence in organizations: An integrative framework and review. J. Organ. Behav. 2016, 37, S122–S145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goldstein, J. Emergence as a Construct: History and Issues. Emergence 1999, 1, 49–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goldstein, J. Emergence: A Construct Amid a Thicket of Conceptual Snares. Emergence 2000, 2, 5–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kozlowski, S.W.J.; Klein, K.J. A multilevel approach to theory and research in organizations: Contextual, temporal, and emergent processes. In Multilevel Theory, Research, and Methods in Organizations: Foundations, Extensions, and New Directions; Klein, K.J., Kozlowski, S.W.J., Eds.; Jossey-Bass: San Francisco, CA, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Goldstein, J. Causality and emergence in chaos and complexity theories. In Nonlinear Dynamics in Human Behavior; Sulis, W., Combs, A., Eds.; Studies of Nonlinear Phenomena in Life Science; World Scientific: London, UK, 1996; pp. 159–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kauffman, S.A. At Home in the Universe: The Search for the Laws of Self-Organization and Complexity; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1996; p. 336. [Google Scholar]
- Holland, J.H. Emergence: From Chaos to Order; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1998; p. 258. [Google Scholar]
- Holland, J.H. Studying complex adaptive systems. J. Syst. Sci. Complex. 2006, 19, 1–8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dooley, K.J.; van de Ven, A.H. Explaining complex organizational dynamics. Organ. Sci. 1999, 10, 358–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miller, S.R. Conventions, Interdependence of Action, and Collective Ends. Noûs 1986, 20, 117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Searle, J.R. How to Derive “Ought” from “Is”. Philos. Rev. 1964, 73, 43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vanderschraaf, P. Convention as correlated equilibrium. Erkenntnis 1995, 42, 65–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Railton, P. A priori rules. In New Essays on the A Priori: Wittgenstein on the Normativity of Logic; Boghossian, P., Peacocke, C., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2000; Chapter 8; p. 170. [Google Scholar]
- Coleman, J.S. Norms as social capital. In Economic Imperialism: The Economic Approach Applied Outside The Field of Economics; Radnitzky, G., Bernholz, P., Eds.; Paragon House: New York, NY, USA, 1986; p. 421. [Google Scholar]
- Shepsle, K.A. Studying institutions: Some lessons from the rational choice approach. J. Theor. Politics 1989, 1, 131–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hayek, F.A. The use of knowledge in society. Am. Econ. Rev. 1945, 35, 519–530. [Google Scholar]
- Harsanyi, J.C. Games with incomplete information played by “Bayesian” players, I–III Part I. The basic model. Manag. Sci. 1967, 14, 159–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schauer, F. Playing by the Rules: A Philosophical Examination of Rule-Based Decision-Making in Law and in Life; Clarendon Law Series; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1993; p. 272. [Google Scholar]
- Hodgson, G.M. What are institutions? J. Econ. Issues 2006, 40, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sawy, O.A.E.; Gomes, G.M.; Gonzalez, M.V. Preserving institutional memory: The management of history as an organizational resource. Acad. Manag. Proc. 1986, 1986, 118–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ray, T.; Liew, K.M. Society and civilization: An optimization algorithm based on the simulation of social behavior. IEEE Trans. Evol. Comput. 2003, 7, 386–396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Linde, C. Working the Past; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Greif, A. Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies. J. Political Econ. 1994, 102, 912–950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roberts Clark, W. Agents and Structures: Two Views of Preferences, Two Views of Institutions. Int. Stud. Q. 1998, 42, 245–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Effingham, N. The metaphysics of groups. Philos. Stud. 2010, 149, 251–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nyborg, K.; Anderies, J.M.; Dannenberg, A.; Lindahl, T.; Schill, C.; Schluter, M.; Adger, W.N.; Arrow, K.J.; Barrett, S.; Carpenter, S.; et al. Social norms as solutions. Science 2016, 354, 42–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Morgan, T.J.H.; Rendell, L.E.; Ehn, M.; Hoppitt, W.; Laland, K.N. The evolutionary basis of human social learning. Proc. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2012, 279, 653–662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Haken, H. Chaos and Order in Nature; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1981; pp. 2–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Engel, C. Generating Predictability: Institutional Analysis and Design; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Scholderer, J.; Veflen, N. Social norms and risk communication. Trends Food Sci. Technol. 2019, 84, 62–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ertac, S.; Gumren, M.; Gurdal, M.Y. Demand for decision autonomy and the desire to avoid responsibility in risky environments: Experimental evidence. J. Econ. Psychol. 2020, 77, 102200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Santuoso, A.; Bicchieri, C.; Funcke, A.; Hart, E. Strategic Problems with Risky Prospects; ESI Working paper 20-23; Economic Science Institute, Chapman University: Irvine, CA, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Luhmann, N. The autopoiesis of social systems. In Sociocybernetic Paradoxes: Observation, Control and Evolution of Self-Steering Systems; Geyer, F., Van Der Zouwen, J., Eds.; SAGE Publications Ltd.: London, UK, 1986. [Google Scholar]
- Parra-Luna, F. Social autopoiesis. In Critical Issues in Systems Theory and Practice; Ellis, K., Gregory, A., Mears-Young, B.R., Ragsdell, G., Eds.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 1995; pp. 269–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schwitzgebel, E. Acting contrary to our professed beliefs or the gulf between occurrent judgment and dispositional belief. Pac. Philos. Q. 2010, 91, 531–553. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mavrofides, T.; Kameas, A.; Papageorgiou, D.; Los, A. On the entropy of social systems: A revision of the concepts of entropy and energy in the social context. Syst. Res. Behav. Sci. 2011, 28, 353–368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shannon, C.E. A Mathematical Theory of Communication. Bell Syst. Tech. J. 1948, 27, 623–656. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Luhmann, N. Social Systems; Stanford University Press: Stanford, CA, USA, 1995; p. 627. [Google Scholar]
- von Foerster, H. Observing Systems; Systems inquiry series; Intersystems Publications: Salinas, CA, USA, 1984; p. 331. [Google Scholar]
- von Foerster, H.; Poerksen, B. (Eds.) Understanding Systems: Conversations on Epistemology and Ethics; IFSR International Series on Systems Science and Engineering; Kluwer Academic: New York, NY, USA, 2002; p. 166. [Google Scholar]
- von Foerster, H. Understanding Understanding: Essays on Cybernetics and Cognition; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tomasello, M.; Carpenter, M.; Call, J.; Behne, T.; Moll, H. Understanding and sharing intentions: The origins of cultural cognition. Behav. Brain Sci. 2005, 28, 675–691. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hindriks, F. Collective Acceptance and the Is-Ought Argument. Ethical Theory Moral Pract. 2012, 16, 465–480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Loughmiller-Cardinal, J.A.; Cardinal, J.S. The Behavior of Information: A Reconsideration of Social Norms. Societies 2023, 13, 111. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc13050111
Loughmiller-Cardinal JA, Cardinal JS. The Behavior of Information: A Reconsideration of Social Norms. Societies. 2023; 13(5):111. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc13050111
Chicago/Turabian StyleLoughmiller-Cardinal, Jennifer A., and James Scott Cardinal. 2023. "The Behavior of Information: A Reconsideration of Social Norms" Societies 13, no. 5: 111. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc13050111
APA StyleLoughmiller-Cardinal, J. A., & Cardinal, J. S. (2023). The Behavior of Information: A Reconsideration of Social Norms. Societies, 13(5), 111. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc13050111