1. Introduction
The Black–Scholes–Merton option pricing model (referred to as BSM) introduced by Black and Scholes [
1] and Merton [
2] is widely recognized as a cornerstone in the field of option pricing and financial economics [
3]. The value of the BSM model can be seen from two perspectives. First, from a narrow viewpoint of option pricing, the BSM model provides an operational formula. Second, from a broader asset pricing context, the “arbitrage argument” generalized by the concepts of “risk-neutral valuation” offers a powerful framework. This framework allows for determining the price of any contingent asset as the expected present value of promised cash flows [
4].
The analytical framework initiated by the BSM model has been particularly fruitful in modeling the term structure of interest rates, as it has generated a wide range of models that have been applied to the evaluation of yield-curve dynamics and bond valuation, as well as the valuation of derivative assets on interest-rate-sensitive instruments such as bond options, caps, or floors. Following Sundaresan [
5], we can distinguish three types of models: unifactorial, multifactorial, and calibrated, also known as variable parameter models [
6].
Unifactorial models fit the term structure with solely the movement of short-term interest rates. Examples of such models are [
7,
8];
Multifactorial models, developed toward the end of the 1970s, explain the dynamics of interest-rate movements using one or several additional factors, such as fluctuations in long-term interest rates, the spread between short- and long-term interest rates, or volatility. An example of this approach is [
9];
The parsimony of the models discussed above allows them to be useful for a wide range of economic and financial analyses, such as testing the existence of mean reversion in prices and modeling discount rates for financial and actuarial pricing. Likewise, their estimation has a low cost since it requires the adjustment of a few parameters. On the other hand, that parsimony leads them to have a limited ability to capture the profiles of the term structure of interest rates, thus limiting their usefulness in other applications such as valuing derivative assets [
6]. This problem gave rise in the late 1980s to models called calibrated or time-varying parameter models [
10,
11,
12,
13]. These are unifactorial models that model the fluctuation of short-term interest rates in a manner similar to [
7] but allow for variability in the parameters of the stochastic process, which are calibrated with zero-coupon bond prices to perfectly capture the observed yield curve. While such models are widely used in derivative asset valuation, their lack of parsimony reduces their interest in other types of analysis.
Option pricing models have relied on the analytical framework of stochastic calculus and probability theory since their inception [
14]. Nevertheless, financial and economic activity involves varying degrees of knowledge and may combine risk with other sources of uncertainty, such as imprecision or vagueness. Fuzzy-subset theory is a valid tool for modeling uncertainty, and fuzzy numbers can be used for this same purpose regarding a variable. For example, for a reference
and a variable
(such as volatility), we can define the fuzzy number
, which can be interpreted as “volatility is approximately
” with the degree of possibility of σ
in
being the likelihood that this variable precisely takes the value σ [
15].
The usefulness of fuzzy-subset theory has been exploited by various authors to model the uncertainty of the parameters that govern the random movement of the underlying asset in option pricing models. This stochastic process, which can be in discrete or continuous time, is fuzzified by modeling the uncertainty about the parameters that govern the evolution of the underlying asset prices, assuming that they are fuzzy numbers, defined through a possibility distribution [
16]. This is a set of works that make up a current within fuzzy mathematics that can be categorized as fuzzy-random option pricing (FROP) [
17]. A review of the FROP literature leads us to conclude that the type of random schemes in which the vagueness of the parameters is treated through fuzzy uncertainty is relatively broad. There is also a wide range of production in both equity and index options, as well as in real options [
16]. However, the concern for connecting objective information from financial markets with the calibration of the parameters that make up the models has been much scarcer [
16]. Moreover, the application of the FROP approach to fixed-income markets is practically nonexistent [
17].
Thus, this paper aims to make a twofold contribution. The first would be motivated by the fact that the FROP literature is scarce in the context of fixed-income markets and the valuation of derivative instruments sensitive to interest rates. This work extends the term structure models compatible with bond option pricing by Jamshidian [
18] and that option pricing formula to the assumption that the parameters governing the variation of short-term interest rates (equilibrium interest rate, speed of return to equilibrium, and market volatility) are imprecisely given through fuzzy numbers. Therefore, this paper extends the results in [
19] about Vasicek’s model of term structure developed under the hypothesis that the parameters that rule short-term interest rates are given by fuzzy numbers.
The second contribution of this work is to develop a methodology for estimating fuzzy parameters based on market data. On the one hand, we will take advantage of the fact that the α-cut of a fuzzy number can be interpreted as a confidence interval in which the probability that the variable of interest is
[
20]. This allows us to use the approaches of [
21,
22,
23], who propose quantifying estimates from conventional regression models through fuzzy numbers induced by statistical confidence intervals, and [
24], who use an analogous procedure to model uncertainty of variance by using fuzzy numbers. On the other hand, those fuzzy estimates will be grounded in the standard parameter-calibration methodologies based on least-squares regression [
6]. Our developments will be applied to data on the zero-coupon curve published by the European Central Bank for the highest credit-rated bonds in the Eurozone during the period from November 2021 to May 2023.
2. Fuzzy-Random Option Pricing
The fuzzy sets theory (FST) has provided tools that have been used in option pricing valuation to capture uncertainty as fuzzy measures, fuzzy numbers, fuzzy expert systems, or fuzzy regression [
16,
17]. These instruments have been intensively applied since the beginning of the 21st century to option valuation from four different perspectives [
17]. The first perspective is what we have called FROP, with seminal works in this regard by [
25,
26,
27]. This is the setting in which this paper must be understood. The second approach consists of using Sugeno’s integral and fuzzy measures to model the existence of imperfections in the market [
28]. The third focus is the so-called fuzzy payoff for real options valuation [
29]. The fourth approach seeks to take advantage of the ability of fuzzy neural networks as a universal function approximator to generate nonparametric option valuation models [
30].
The mainstream in the literature on applications of fuzzy set theory to option pricing is likely the FROP approach [
17]. These works assume that the fluctuations in underlying asset prices are governed by the hypothesis of a conventional option valuation model which, in continuous time, is often the geometric Brownian motion that underlies BSM and, in discrete time, the binomial framework by Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein [
31]. In this approach, it is considered that the parameters of the stochastic process governing price fluctuations, such as volatility, are not crisp but are observed vaguely. A natural way to represent such uncertainty is through possibility distributions by means of fuzzy numbers [
15]. Thus, the possibility function can be understood as an adequate approximation to the plausible values of the parameter of interest, while the degree of possibility of a value is interpreted as a physical measure of how easily that value will materialize in practice [
15].
As an illustrative example of FROP, let us consider the random instantaneous fluctuations of the price of a financial asset, denoted as , which follows a geometric Brownian motion defined by the equation . Here, represents the current price of the asset, is a Gaussian random variable with a mean of zero and a standard deviation of , denotes the price annual growth rate, and represents the annualized standard deviation of these fluctuations.
In the fuzzy-random approach, the precise values of the parameters m and σ are not known but are represented by fuzzy numbers and , respectively. The possibility distribution functions for and are denoted as and , respectively. Consequently, the price fluctuation becomes a fuzzy-random variable and, for a possible random realization , the possibility measure is .
Regarding the framework utilized by FROP, contributions can be differentiated between discrete and continuous time. Developments in continuous time typically rely on conventional univariate geometric Brownian motion [
25,
26,
27], which can be multivariate in the case of compound options [
32]. However, the fuzzy-random literature has also extended to more complex continuous time modeling, such as Lévy processes [
33,
34] or fractional-type random movements [
35,
36,
37,
38]. In discrete time, the most common approach is provided by the binomial framework [
31], with examples in this context found in [
39,
40,
41,
42,
43]. Although less common, FROP has also employed other discrete time approximations, such as the trinomial methodology developed in [
43] and Monte Carlo simulation [
44].
The literature review of FROP in both continuous and discrete time leads to the conclusion that most works are devoted to the valuation of options on stocks or stock indices, either under the framework provided by the BSM model [
26,
45], other more sophisticated continuous time models [
37,
46], or using the binomial model as a reference [
38,
39,
40].
Another particularly fertile field has been the valuation of real options, which has been carried out in continuous time with the framework provided by BSM [
25] or with the derivative of the geometric diffusion models for multiple assets by Geske [
47] or Margabre [
48], [
32,
49]. In discrete time, we can mention the contributions [
40,
41,
43,
50,
51,
52]. Other applications of FROP to asset valuation include assessing firms’ values [
27], as suggested by the seminal work [
1], credit default swaps [
53,
54], bank deposit insurance [
55], catastrophe bonds [
56], and forward contracts in energy markets [
57]. It is striking that FROP extensions to equilibrium models of the term structure or interest-rate derivative valuation models are scarce. In this sense, we can outline the extension of the [
7] model of the yield curve in [
19].
On the other hand, empirical applications that connect theoretical developments with objective market data are relatively scarce [
16]. While [
38] tests a fuzzy binomial extension on DAX index option data, ref. [
58] proposes estimating the implied volatility of options using a probability–possibility transformation based on the empirical distribution function and [
45,
52] also use a probability–possibility transformation grounded on the confidence intervals of the underlying asset’s volatility that were obtained with inferential statistics mathematics.