1. Introduction
This paper deals with the study of scalar equilibria under certain weak topological and convex assumptions. To be more precise, let
,
X and
Y be nonempty sets,
, and let us consider the so-called
equilibrium problem:
or, in a more general way, this
weak equilibrium inequality:
Although easy examples show that (
1) is stronger than (
2), when
X is compact and
f is upper semicontinuous on
X, they are equivalent problems. Indeed, our main result—Theorem 1—establishes, among other things, the equivalence of (
1) and (
2) under less restrictive conditions. The study of equilibrium problems can be traced back to the K. Fan minimax inequality [
1], although the nomenclature is adopted from L.D. Muu and W. Oettli in [
2]. Most results guaranteeing the existence of equilibrium for a scalar function assume topological hypotheses on one variable, and in addition, either convexity or concavity conditions on the other or concavity–convexity assumptions on both variables [
3,
4,
5,
6,
7,
8,
9,
10].
This kind of problem comprises the study of the celebrated
Nash equilibrium [
11,
12,
13,
14] and the existence of saddle points or, more generally, the validity of the minimax inequality [
15,
16,
17,
18,
19,
20,
21], to name only a few.
In
Section 2, we state our main result, the aforementioned Theorem 1, where we provide not only the equivalence between the equilibrium problem (
1) and the weak equilibrium inequality (
2) under suitable conditions, but also a condition in terms of finite subsets that characterizes the existence of a solution for (
1). Although it is a result of a topological nature, in order to derive applicable results we introduce in Definition 1 a convexity concept that is necessary for the existence of equilibrium. In
Section 3, we obtain some consequences on game theory (Nash equilibrium and minimax inequalities), extending some known results in [
22]. We finish with some conclusions.
2. A Discrete Characterization of Equilibrium
In this section, we assume certain topological hypotheses:
X is a nonempty and compact topological space and
f satisfies a not very restrictive continuity condition, the so-called
-
transfer upper semicontinuity on
X, more general than upper semicontinuity. Under them, we prove that the equilibrium problem (
1) admits a solution when the weak equilibrium inequality (
2) is valid and state a characterization of its solvability in terms of some finite subsets of
Y, which leads to a quite general result on the existence of equilibrium.
Let us recall ([
23], Definition 8) that if
,
X is a nonempty topological space,
and
Y is a nonempty set, then a function
is
-
transfer upper semicontinuous in
provided that
In addition,
f is said to be
-
transfer upper semicontinuous on
X when it is at each
. A function is
-transfer upper semicontinuous on
X as soon as it is upper semicontinuous on
X, although the converse is not true:
Example 1. Let , and let be the function given for any by andThen f is α-transfer upper semicontinuous on , since for with we take and to arrive atHowever,is not closed, hence f is not upper semicontinuous on . It is a well-known fact (see [
23], Remark 7) that
f is
-transfer upper semicontinuous on
X if, and only if,
where “cl” stands for “closure”.
The next result is a first version of the discrete characterization of the solvability of the equilibrium problem (
1).
Lemma 1. Suppose that X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y is a nonempty set, and is α-transfer upper semicontinuous on X. Thenif, and only if, there exists a finite subset of Y such that Proof. The existence of
satisfying
implies the other condition with
, since for each nonempty and finite subset
of
Y we have that
so
and then (
4) holds.
Conversely, let
be a finite subset of
Y in such a way that
The compactness of
X implies that
and the
-transfer upper semicontinuity of
f on
X and (
3) that
i.e., for some
,
□
The next result provides us with a discrete weak equilibrium inequality implying the condition :
Lemma 2. If X is a nonempty and compact topological space, is a nonempty and finite set, and satisfyandthen Proof. Let us proceed by contradiction, so, let us assume that
i.e.,
in particular, there exists
, with
Therefore, according to the
transfer upper semicontinuity of
f on
X, there exists a
and a neighborhood
of
such that
Then
and, by compactness, there exist
with
Given
, let
such that
, so
and thus, if we set
, then
and the arbitrariness of
yields
in particular,
which contradicts the hypothesis. □
A first consequence of the previous lemmas is the equivalence of the solvability of the equilibrium problem (
1) and its weak inequality (
2) with the topological conditions under consideration:
Corollary 1. Assume that X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y is a nonempty set, and that satisfies condition (5). If in additionthen Proof. Given a nonempty and finite subset
of
Y, the weak equilibrium inequality yields
and therefore, it follows from Lemma 2 that
Now Lemma 1 applies with
, and we are done. □
We are in a position to establish our main result:
Theorem 1. Let X be a nonempty and compact topological space, Y be a nonempty set, and be a function satisfying condition (5). Then, the following are equivalent: - (i)
The weak equilibrium inequality (
2)
holds, that is, - (ii)
f admits an equilibrium (
1)
, i.e., - (iii)
There exists a finite subset of Y such that - (iv)
For some finite subset of Y there holds - (v)
There exists a finite subset of Y such that
Proof. The equivalence is Corollary 1, the implications are clear, is Lemma 2 and is Lemma 1. □
It is worth mentioning that the equivalence
with
was stated in ([
13], Theorem 3.1), but the fact that
can be nonempty is a useful extension of such a result, as we will show in Example 3. Let us also point out that the equivalence
is an extension of ([
24], Lemma 2.8).
In view of assertions (iii) and (v) in Theorem 1, one could expect that, under the compactness of
X and the condition (
5), for a nonempty and finite subset
of
Y there holds
However, that is not the case:
Example 2. Let be the function defined asand let . Given , and ,andso, for any In particular, f is β-transfer upper semicontinuous on , becausebut for any nonempty and finite subset of not containing , let us say with , we have thatwhile A useful way to handle Theorem 1 is given below. We first introduce an equilibrium concept of convexity. As usual, given
,
stands for the
unit simplex of
:
Definition 1. Given and X and Y nonempty sets, a function is said to be α-convex
on Y provided thatAnd dually, if , then f is ω-concave
on X when When
(respectively,
), this notion of convexity (respectively, concavity) coincides with that of
infsup-convexity on
Y (respectively,
supinf-concavity on
X), a generalization of convexlikeness (or Fan’s convexity) on
Y ([
15] p. 42) which was considered for the first time in ([
16], Corollary 3.1) and arose naturally when dealing with equilibrium and minimax problems (see, for instance, [
16,
20,
25]). Moreover, when
and
,
-convexity on
Y is nothing more than the so-called
inf-diagonal convexity on the second variable ([
26], Definition 2.1), which extends, for instance, the concept of
diagonal convexity when
X is a nonempty subset of a vector space ([
27] Definition 2.5).
Let us notice that
-convexity is a necessary condition in order that problem (
1) admits a solution, and even that (
2) holds. Indeed, if (
2) is valid, then for any
,
and
,
Although easy examples show that the converse is not true, under some additional hypotheses we can state this equilibrium result:
Corollary 2. Let X be a nonempty and compact topological space, Y be a nonempty set, and . Let us also assume that f satifies condition (5) and is α-convex on Y, and that there exists a finite subset of Y such that Then, the equilibrium problem admits a solution, i.e., there exists such that Proof. Let
be a nonempty and finite subset of
Y and containing
. The supinf-concavity of
on
X guarantees, thanks to [
25] Theorem 2.6, the existence of
such that
which, together with the
-convexity of
f on
Y, implies
Finally, the existence of an equilibrium for f follows from the equivalence of Theorem 1. □
The following example proves that the finite set in the corollary above is not necessarily empty. So, by the way, we show that checking condition (iv) in Theorem 1 for a nonempty set , allows us to apply it for more general equilibria:
Example 3. Let function given bywhich is continuous on the compact set (discrete topology) and admits the equilibriumtherefore, it is 0-convex. Despite the fact that for some nonempty subset of , the restriction of f to is not supinf-concave on (), there exists a finite subset of in such a way that for any nonempty and finite subset of with we have that is supinf-concave on : it suffices to take . The convexity conditions considered in the above corollary are different from the concept of
-transfer quasiconvexity considered in [
13,
28]: if
X is a nonempty and convex subset of a linear space and
Y is a nonempty set,
is
-
transfer quasiconvex on
Y if given
and
in
Y, there exists
in
X such that
The notion of -transfer quasiconvexity requires that the set X be convex, while this strong condition is not necessary for the -convexity. On the other hand, the following example shows a function which is -transfer quasiconvex and not -convex for some .
Example 4. Let , and let be given for any byThe function is 0-transfer quasiconvex: If and , we choose and then .
If and , we choose and then .
If , and , we choose and then for any we have
However, f is not 0-convex on , since for and we have that Let us conclude this section by stressing that Corollary 2 improves the topological assumptions in the two-function equilibrium result ([
22] Theorem 2.7) when the involved functions are the same.
3. Application to Game Theory: Nash Equilibrium and Minimax Inequalities
Now we focus on deriving some consequences to game theory, and more specifically, to the existence of Nash equlibria and to establishing the validity of some minimax inequalities, both from the equilibrium results in
Section 2.
We first deal with the existence of certain Nash equilibria. To this end, let us consider the following noncooperative game in the normal form
where
is the finite set of players,
the strategy space of the player
i which is a nonempty subset of a topological space
, and
is the payoff function of player
i, where
.
When the player i chooses a strategy , the situation of the game is described by the vector . For each player denote by the set of all players other than player i. Also denote by the Cartesian product of the sets of strategies of players and . Note that (after rearranging the components if necessary).
With this notation, a strategy profile
is a
pure strategy Nash equilibrium of a game G if
We introduce the following topological concept:
Definition 2. Given , a noncooperative game G is said to be -diagonally transfer continuous
ifwhere is the aggregator function
defined at each by We point out that when
we recover the notion of
diagonally transfer continuity in ([
29], Definition 1).
In this result, we characterize the existence of Nash equilibrium for certain noncooperative games:
Theorem 2. Let be a noncooperative game such that given , is a nonempty and compact topological space, and defined byIf for some , G is β-diagonally transfer continuous for all , then the following assertions are equivalent: - (i)
The weak equilibrium inequality (2) is valid.
- (ii)
The game G has a Nash equilibrium.
- (iii)
For some finite subset of X there holds - (iv)
There exists a finite subset of X such that - (v)
We can find a finite subset of X satisfying
Proof. Note that G being diagonally transfer continuous is equivalent to the fact that f is -transfer upper semicontinuous on the first variable; and the game G has a Nash equilibrium if, and only if, the function f admits an equilibrium (EP). The proof is a straighforward consequence of Theorem 1. □
In view of Corollary 2, we deduce:
Corollary 3. Given , let us assume that is a β-diagonally transfer continuous noncooperative game for all , and such that the strategy sets are nonempty and compact topological spaces. If f defined by (8)
is 0-convex on the second variable, and there exists a finite subset of X such thatthen, the game G has a Nash equilibrium. To conclude this section we state some minimax results. Let us first recall that by a
minimax inequality one means a result guaranteeing that for a function
there holds
and therefore, since the reverse inequality is always valid,
It is worth quoting not only the pioneer work of J. von Neumann [
30], but also those of K. Fan [
15] and S. Sion [
19], where several concepts of weak convexity were considered, namely, the aforementioned
convexlikeness and the well-known
quasi convexity. For a survey on minimax inequalities, we refer interested readers to [
31,
32].
As a consequence of Corollary 2 we state the following minimax theorem that extends ([
24] Theorem 2.1), and even the two-function minimax theorem ([
25] Corollary 3.11) when the two functions coincide:
Corollary 4. Suppose that X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y is a nonempty set and is a function such that . If in addition, f satisfies condition (5) and for some finite subset of Y we have thatthen, f satisfies the minimax inequality if, and only if, it is infsup-convex on Y. Proof. Apply Corollary 2. □
Let us mention another kind of inequality, the one that originated the study of equilibrium problems. Although it is not strictly of the minimax type, a
Fan minimax inequality for a function
is a result stating, under adequate hypotheses, the validity of the inequality
The celebrated result of K. Fan ([
1] Theorem 1) is different from the following one, which in turn extends ([
26] Theorem 3.1):
Corollary 5. Let X be a nonempty and compact topological space and a function such that . If f satisfies condition (
5)
and there exists a finite subset of X such thatthen,if, and only if, f is inf-diagonally convex on its second variable. Proof. It follows from Corollary 2. □
4. Conclusions
In this paper, we have established a result that makes equivalent the existence of equilibrium for a function
and the validity of the corresponding weak equilibrium inequality: Theorem 1. The topological condition on
f that guarantees the equivalence is the condition (
5). Theorem 1 provides not only the equivalence between the equilibrium problem (
1) and the weak equilibrium inequality (
2) but also a condition, (
4), in terms of finite subsets that characterize the existence of a solution for (
1). In particular, we obtain a discrete characterisation of the solvability of the equilibrium problem. When we also include a not very restrictive convexity condition in Definition 1, we obtain the existence of a solution for more general equilibrium problems than others previously established in [
22]. As an application of all this, we obtain both, two results on the existence of Nash equilibria, one topological, Theorem 2 the other also convex, Corollary 3 and some minimax inequalities, Corollaries 4 and 5.