Next Article in Journal
Infinitesimal Affine Transformations and Mutual Curvatures on Statistical Manifolds and Their Tangent Bundles
Next Article in Special Issue
Federated Learning Incentive Mechanism with Supervised Fuzzy Shapley Value
Previous Article in Journal
Determinantal Expressions, Identities, Concavity, Maclaurin Power Series Expansions for van der Pol Numbers, Bernoulli Numbers, and Cotangent
Previous Article in Special Issue
Federated Learning Incentive Mechanism Design via Shapley Value and Pareto Optimality
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Discrete Characterization of the Solvability of Equilibrium Problems and Its Application to Game Theory

by
Maria Isabel Berenguer
,
Domingo Gámez
,
Ana Isabel Garralda-Guillem
* and
Manuel Ruiz Galán
E.T.S. Ingeniería de Edificación, Department of Applied Mathematics, Institute of Mathematics (IMAG), University of Granada, 18071 Granada, Spain
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Axioms 2023, 12(7), 666; https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12070666
Submission received: 23 May 2023 / Revised: 25 June 2023 / Accepted: 28 June 2023 / Published: 5 July 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Advances in Logic and Game Theory)

Abstract

:
We state a characterization of the existence of equilibrium in terms of certain finite subsets under compactness and transfer upper semicontinuity conditions. In order to derive some consequences on game theory—Nash equilibrium and minimax inequalities—we introduce a weak convexity concept.
MSC:
91B50; 49J35

1. Introduction

This paper deals with the study of scalar equilibria under certain weak topological and convex assumptions. To be more precise, let α R , X and Y be nonempty sets, f : X × Y R , and let us consider the so-called equilibrium problem:
there   exists   x 0 X :   α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y ) ,
or, in a more general way, this weak equilibrium inequality:
α sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) .
Although easy examples show that (1) is stronger than (2), when X is compact and f is upper semicontinuous on X, they are equivalent problems. Indeed, our main result—Theorem 1—establishes, among other things, the equivalence of (1) and (2) under less restrictive conditions. The study of equilibrium problems can be traced back to the K. Fan minimax inequality [1], although the nomenclature is adopted from L.D. Muu and W. Oettli in [2]. Most results guaranteeing the existence of equilibrium for a scalar function assume topological hypotheses on one variable, and in addition, either convexity or concavity conditions on the other or concavity–convexity assumptions on both variables [3,4,5,6,7,8,9,10].
This kind of problem comprises the study of the celebrated Nash equilibrium [11,12,13,14] and the existence of saddle points or, more generally, the validity of the minimax inequality [15,16,17,18,19,20,21], to name only a few.
In Section 2, we state our main result, the aforementioned Theorem 1, where we provide not only the equivalence between the equilibrium problem (1) and the weak equilibrium inequality (2) under suitable conditions, but also a condition in terms of finite subsets that characterizes the existence of a solution for (1). Although it is a result of a topological nature, in order to derive applicable results we introduce in Definition 1 a convexity concept that is necessary for the existence of equilibrium. In Section 3, we obtain some consequences on game theory (Nash equilibrium and minimax inequalities), extending some known results in [22]. We finish with some conclusions.

2. A Discrete Characterization of Equilibrium

In this section, we assume certain topological hypotheses: X is a nonempty and compact topological space and f satisfies a not very restrictive continuity condition, the so-called α -transfer upper semicontinuity on X, more general than upper semicontinuity. Under them, we prove that the equilibrium problem (1) admits a solution when the weak equilibrium inequality (2) is valid and state a characterization of its solvability in terms of some finite subsets of Y, which leads to a quite general result on the existence of equilibrium.
Let us recall ([23], Definition 8) that if α R , X is a nonempty topological space, x 0 X and Y is a nonempty set, then a function f : X × Y R is α -transfer upper semicontinuous in x 0 provided that
( x 0 , y 0 ) X × Y f ( x 0 , y 0 ) < α     there   exist   y 1 Y   and   a   neighborhood   U   of   x 0 :   x U     f ( x , y 1 ) < α .
In addition, f is said to be α -transfer upper semicontinuous on X when it is at each x 0 X . A function is α -transfer upper semicontinuous on X as soon as it is upper semicontinuous on X, although the converse is not true:
Example 1. 
Let 0 < α < 1 , 0 < x 1 < x 2 < 1 and let f : [ 0 , 1 ] × { 0 , 1 } R be the function given for any 0 x 1 by
f ( x , 0 ) = 0 , if     0 x x 1 1 , otherwise
and
f ( x , 1 ) = 0 , if     0 x < x 2 1 , otherwise .
Then f is α-transfer upper semicontinuous on [ 0 , 1 ] , since for ( x 0 , y 0 ) [ 0 , 1 ] × { 0 , 1 } with f ( x 0 , y 0 ) < α we take y 1 : = 1 and U : = [ 0 , x 2 ) to arrive at
x U     f ( x , y 1 ) < α .
However,
{ x [ 0 , 1 ] :   α f ( x , 0 ) } = ( x 1 , 1 ]
is not closed, hence f is not upper semicontinuous on [ 0 , 1 ] .
It is a well-known fact (see [23], Remark 7) that f is α -transfer upper semicontinuous on X if, and only if,
y Y { x X :   α f ( x , y ) } = y Y cl ( { x X :   α f ( x , y ) } ) ,
where “cl” stands for “closure”.
The next result is a first version of the discrete characterization of the solvability of the equilibrium problem (1).
Lemma 1. 
Suppose that X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y is a nonempty set, α R and f : X × Y R is α-transfer upper semicontinuous on X. Then
there   exists   x 0 X :   α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y )
if, and only if, there exists a finite subset Y 1 of Y such that
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) .
Proof. 
The existence of x 0 X satisfying
α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y )
implies the other condition with Y 1 = , since for each nonempty and finite subset Y 0 of Y we have that
α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y ) min y Y 0 f ( x 0 , y ) ,
so
y Y 0 { x X : α f ( x , y ) }
and then (4) holds.
Conversely, let Y 1 be a finite subset of Y in such a way that
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) .
The compactness of X implies that
y Y cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } )
and the α -transfer upper semicontinuity of f on X and (3) that
y Y { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ,
i.e., for some x 0 X ,
α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y ) .
The next result provides us with a discrete weak equilibrium inequality implying the condition y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) :
Lemma 2. 
If X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y 0 is a nonempty and finite set, f : X × Y 0 R and α R satisfy
α sup x X min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) ,
and
there   exists   δ > 0 : β [ α δ , α ]     f   is   β transfer   upper   semicontinuous   on   X ,
then
y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) .
Proof. 
Let us proceed by contradiction, so, let us assume that
y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) = ,
i.e.,
x 0 X     there   exists   y x 0 Y 0 : x 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y x 0 ) } ) ,
in particular, there exists 0 < δ x 0 < δ , with
f ( x 0 , y 0 ) < α δ x 0 .
Therefore, according to the α δ x 0 transfer upper semicontinuity of f on X, there exists a y x 0 Y 0 and a neighborhood U x 0 of x 0 such that
  x U x 0     f ( x , y x 0 ) < α δ x 0 .
Then
X = x X U x
and, by compactness, there exist x 1 , , x n X with
X = i = 1 n U x i .
Given x X , let i { 1 , , n } such that x U x i , so
f ( x , y x i ) < α δ x i
and thus, if we set δ : = min { δ x 1 , , δ x n } > 0 , then
min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) < α δ
and the arbitrariness of x X yields
sup x X min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) α δ ,
in particular,
sup x X min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) < α ,
which contradicts the hypothesis. □
A first consequence of the previous lemmas is the equivalence of the solvability of the equilibrium problem (1) and its weak inequality (2) with the topological conditions under consideration:
Corollary 1. 
Assume that X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y is a nonempty set, α R and that f : X × Y R satisfies condition (5). If in addition
α sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) ,
then
there   exists   x 0 X :   α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y ) .
Proof. 
Given a nonempty and finite subset Y 0 of Y, the weak equilibrium inequality yields
α sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) sup x X min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) ,
and therefore, it follows from Lemma 2 that
y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) .
Now Lemma 1 applies with Y 1 = , and we are done. □
We are in a position to establish our main result:
Theorem 1. 
Let X be a nonempty and compact topological space, Y be a nonempty set, α R and f : X × Y R be a function satisfying condition (5). Then, the following are equivalent:
(i)
The weak equilibrium inequality (2) holds, that is,
α sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) .
(ii)
f admits an equilibrium (1), i.e.,
there   exists   x 0 X : α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y ) .
(iii)
There exists a finite subset Y 1 of Y such that
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     y Y 0 { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ,
or, in other words,
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     there   exists   x 0 X :   α min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) .
(iv)
For some finite subset Y 1 of Y there holds
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     α sup x X min y Y 0 f ( x , y ) .
(v)
There exists a finite subset Y 1 of Y such that
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) .
Proof. 
The equivalence ( i ) ( ii ) is Corollary 1, the implications ( ii ) ( iii ) ( iv ) are clear, ( iv ) ( v ) is Lemma 2 and ( v ) ( ii ) is Lemma 1. □
It is worth mentioning that the equivalence ( ii ) ( iii ) with Y 1 = was stated in ([13], Theorem 3.1), but the fact that Y 1 can be nonempty is a useful extension of such a result, as we will show in Example 3. Let us also point out that the equivalence ( i ) ( iv ) is an extension of ([24], Lemma 2.8).
In view of assertions (iii) and (v) in Theorem 1, one could expect that, under the compactness of X and the condition (5), for a nonempty and finite subset Y 0 of Y there holds
y Y 0 { x X : α f ( x , y ) } = y Y 0 cl ( { x X : α f ( x , y ) } ) .
However, that is not the case:
Example 2. 
Let f : [ 0 , 1 ] × [ 0 , 1 ] R be the function defined as
( x , y ) 1 , if     y < x   or   ( x , y ) = ( 1 , 1 ) 0 , otherwise ,
and let 0 < α < 1 . Given 0 < δ < α , β [ α δ , α ] and y [ 0 , 1 ) ,
{ x [ 0 , 1 ] :   β f ( x , y ) } = ( y , 1 ] ,
and
{ x [ 0 , 1 ] :   β f ( x , 1 ) } = { 1 } ,
so, for any y [ 0 , 1 ]
cl ( { x [ 0 , 1 ] :   β f ( x , y ) } ) = [ y , 1 ] .
In particular, f is β-transfer upper semicontinuous on [ 0 , 1 ] , because
y Y { x X : β f ( x , y ) } = { 1 } = y Y cl ( { x X : β f ( x , y ) } ) ,
but for any nonempty and finite subset Y 0 of [ 0 , 1 ] not containing { 1 } , let us say Y 0 = { y 1 , , y m } with 0 y 1 < < y m < 1 , we have that
y Y 0 { x [ 0 , 1 ] :   α f ( x , y ) } = ( y m , 1 ] ,
while
y Y 0 cl ( { x [ 0 , 1 ] :   α f ( x , y ) } ) = [ y m , 1 ] .
A useful way to handle Theorem 1 is given below. We first introduce an equilibrium concept of convexity. As usual, given m 1 , Δ m stands for the unit simplex of R m :
Δ m : = t R m :   0 t 1 , , t m   and   j = 1 m t j = 1 .
Definition 1. 
Given α [ , + ] and X and Y nonempty sets, a function f : X × Y R is said to be α-convexon Y provided that
m 1 ,   t Δ m y 1 , , y m Y     α sup x X j = 1 m t j f ( x , y j ) .
And dually, if ω [ , + ] , then f is ω-concaveon X when
n 1 ,   s Δ n x 1 , , x n X     inf y Y i = 1 n s i f ( x i , y ) ω .
When α = inf y Y sup x X f ( x , y ) (respectively, ω = sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) ), this notion of convexity (respectively, concavity) coincides with that of infsup-convexity on Y (respectively, supinf-concavity on X), a generalization of convexlikeness (or Fan’s convexity) on Y ([15] p. 42) which was considered for the first time in ([16], Corollary 3.1) and arose naturally when dealing with equilibrium and minimax problems (see, for instance, [16,20,25]). Moreover, when X = Y and α = inf x X f ( x , x ) , α -convexity on Y is nothing more than the so-called inf-diagonal convexity on the second variable ([26], Definition 2.1), which extends, for instance, the concept of diagonal convexity when X is a nonempty subset of a vector space ([27] Definition 2.5).
Let us notice that α -convexity is a necessary condition in order that problem (1) admits a solution, and even that (2) holds. Indeed, if (2) is valid, then for any m 1 , t Δ m and y 1 , , y m Y ,
α sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) sup x X j = 1 m t j f ( x , y j ) .
Although easy examples show that the converse is not true, under some additional hypotheses we can state this equilibrium result:
Corollary 2. 
Let X be a nonempty and compact topological space, Y be a nonempty set, f : X × Y R and α R . Let us also assume that f satifies condition (5) and is α-convex on Y, and that there exists a finite subset Y 1 of Y such that
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     f | X × Y 0   is   supinf concave   on   X .
Then, the equilibrium problem admits a solution, i.e., there exists x 0 X such that
α inf y Y f ( x 0 , y ) .
Proof. 
Let Y 0 = { y 1 , , y m } be a nonempty and finite subset of Y and containing Y 1 . The supinf-concavity of f | X × Y 0 on X guarantees, thanks to [25] Theorem 2.6, the existence of t Δ m such that
sup x X min j = 1 , , m f ( x , y j ) = sup x X j = 1 m t j f ( x , y j ) ,
which, together with the α -convexity of f on Y, implies
α sup x X min j = 1 , , m f ( x , y j ) .
Finally, the existence of an equilibrium x 0 for f follows from the equivalence ( ii ) ( iv ) of Theorem 1. □
The following example proves that the finite set Y 1 in the corollary above is not necessarily empty. So, by the way, we show that checking condition (iv) in Theorem 1 for a nonempty set Y 1 , allows us to apply it for more general equilibria:
Example 3. 
Let function f : { 0 , 1 } × [ 0 , 1 ] R given by
f ( 0 , y ) : = 1 , if     0 y < 0.5 0 ,   if     0.5 y 1 ,
f ( 1 , y ) : = 0 , if     0 y 0.5 1 ,   if     0.5 < y 1 ,
which is continuous on the compact set { 0 , 1 } (discrete topology) and admits the equilibrium
0 inf y [ 0 , 1 ] f ( 0 , y ) ,
therefore, it is 0-convex. Despite the fact that for some nonempty subset Y 0 of [ 0 , 1 ] , the restriction of f to { 0 , 1 } × Y 0 is not supinf-concave on { 0 , 1 } ( Y 0 : = { 0 , 1 } ), there exists a finite subset Y 1 of [ 0 , 1 ] in such a way that for any nonempty and finite subset of [ 0 , 1 ] with Y 1 [ 0 , 1 ] we have that f | { 0 , 1 } × Y 0 is supinf-concave on { 0 , 1 } : it suffices to take Y 1 = { 0.5 } .
The convexity conditions considered in the above corollary are different from the concept of α -transfer quasiconvexity considered in [13,28]: if X is a nonempty and convex subset of a linear space and Y is a nonempty set, f : X × Y R is α -transfer quasiconvex on Y if given m 1 and y 1 , , y m in Y, there exists x 1 , , x m in X such that
1 k m ,   t Δ k { i 1 , , i k } { 1 , , m }     α max j = 1 , , k f j = 1 k t i j x i j , y i j .
The notion of α -transfer quasiconvexity requires that the set X be convex, while this strong condition is not necessary for the α -convexity. On the other hand, the following example shows a function which is α -transfer quasiconvex and not α -convex for some α .
Example 4. 
Let X = [ 1 , π / 2 ] , Y = { 0 , 1 } and let f : [ 1 , π / 2 ] × { 0 , 1 } R be given for any 1 x π / 2 by
f ( x , 0 ) : = sin ( x 1 ) ,
f ( x , 1 ) : = sin x .
The function is 0-transfer quasiconvex:
  • If m = 1 and y 1 = 0 , we choose x 1 [ 1 , π / 2 ] and then 0 f ( x 1 , 0 ) .
  • If m = 1 and y 1 = 1 , we choose x 1 [ 1 , 0 ] and then 0 f ( x 1 , 1 ) .
  • If m = 2 , y 1 = 0 and y 2 = 1 , we choose x 1 , x 2 ( 1 , π / 2 ] and then for any t [ 0 , 1 ] we have
    0 max i = 1 , 2 f ( ( 1 t ) x 1 + t x 2 , y i ) .
However, f is not 0-convex on { 0 , 1 } , since for m = 2 and t = ( 1 / 2 , 1 / 2 ) we have that
x [ 1 , π / 2 ]     1 2 f ( x , 0 ) + 1 2 f ( x , 1 ) < sin 1 < 0 .
Let us conclude this section by stressing that Corollary 2 improves the topological assumptions in the two-function equilibrium result ([22] Theorem 2.7) when the involved functions are the same.

3. Application to Game Theory: Nash Equilibrium and Minimax Inequalities

Now we focus on deriving some consequences to game theory, and more specifically, to the existence of Nash equlibria and to establishing the validity of some minimax inequalities, both from the equilibrium results in Section 2.
We first deal with the existence of certain Nash equilibria. To this end, let us consider the following noncooperative game in the normal form
G = ( X i , u i ) i I ,
where I = { 1 , , n } is the finite set of players, X i the strategy space of the player i which is a nonempty subset of a topological space E i , and u i : X R is the payoff function of player i, where X : = i I X i .
When the player i chooses a strategy x i X i , the situation of the game is described by the vector x = ( x 1 , , x n ) X . For each player i I denote by i : = { j I such that j i } the set of all players other than player i. Also denote by X i = j i X j the Cartesian product of the sets of strategies of players i and x i : = ( x 1 , , x i 1 , x i + 1 , , x n ) . Note that x = ( x 1 , x 1 ) = ( x 2 , x 2 ) = = ( x n , x n ) (after rearranging the components if necessary).
With this notation, a strategy profile x * X is a pure strategy Nash equilibrium of a game G if
u i ( y i , x i * ) u i ( x * )       i I ,   y i X i .
We introduce the following topological concept:
Definition 2. 
Given β 0 , a noncooperative game G is said to be β -diagonally transfer continuous if
x , y X Φ ( x , x ) < Φ ( x , y )     there   exist   y 1 X   and   a   neighborhood   U   of   x :   z U     Φ ( z , z ) + β < Φ ( z , y 1 ) ,
where Φ : X × X R is the aggregator function defined at each ( x , y ) X × X by
Φ ( x , y ) : = i = 1 n u i ( x 1 , , y i , , x n ) = i = 1 n u i ( y i , x i ) .
We point out that when β = 0 we recover the notion of diagonally transfer continuity in ([29], Definition 1).
In this result, we characterize the existence of Nash equilibrium for certain noncooperative games:
Theorem 2. 
Let G = ( X i , u i ) i I be a noncooperative game such that given i I , X i is a nonempty and compact topological space, and f : X × X R defined by
f ( x , y ) : = Φ ( x , x ) Φ ( x , y ) = i = 1 n ( u i ( x ) u i ( y i , x i ) ) , ( x , y X ) .
If for some δ > 0 , G is β-diagonally transfer continuous for all β [ 0 , δ ] , then the following assertions are equivalent:
(i)
The weak equilibrium inequality (2)
0 sup x X inf y X f ( x , y )
is valid.
(ii)
The game G has a Nash equilibrium.
(iii)
For some finite subset X 1 of X there holds
X 1 X 0 X X 0   finite     there   exists   x * X :   0 min y X 0 f ( x * , y ) .
(iv)
There exists a finite subset X 1 of X such that
X 1 X 0 X X 0   finite     0 sup x X min y X 0 f ( x , y ) .
(v)
We can find a finite subset X 1 of X satisfying
X 1 X 0 X X 0   finite     y X 0 cl ( { x X : 0 f ( x , y ) } ) .
Proof. 
Note that G being β diagonally transfer continuous is equivalent to the fact that f is β -transfer upper semicontinuous on the first variable; and the game G has a Nash equilibrium if, and only if, the function f admits an equilibrium (EP). The proof is a straighforward consequence of Theorem 1. □
In view of Corollary 2, we deduce:
Corollary 3. 
Given δ > 0 , let us assume that G = ( X i , u i ) i I is a β-diagonally transfer continuous noncooperative game for all β [ 0 , δ ] , and such that the strategy sets X i are nonempty and compact topological spaces. If f defined by (8) is 0-convex on the second variable, and there exists a finite subset X 1 of X such that
X 1 X 0 Y X 0   finite     f | X × X 0   is   supinf concave   on   X ,
then, the game G has a Nash equilibrium.
To conclude this section we state some minimax results. Let us first recall that by a minimax inequality one means a result guaranteeing that for a function f : X × Y R there holds
inf y Y sup x X f ( x , y ) sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) ,
and therefore, since the reverse inequality is always valid,
inf y Y sup x X f ( x , y ) = sup x X inf y Y f ( x , y ) .
It is worth quoting not only the pioneer work of J. von Neumann [30], but also those of K. Fan [15] and S. Sion [19], where several concepts of weak convexity were considered, namely, the aforementioned convexlikeness and the well-known quasi convexity. For a survey on minimax inequalities, we refer interested readers to [31,32].
As a consequence of Corollary 2 we state the following minimax theorem that extends ([24] Theorem 2.1), and even the two-function minimax theorem ([25] Corollary 3.11) when the two functions coincide:
Corollary 4. 
Suppose that X is a nonempty and compact topological space, Y is a nonempty set and f : X × Y R is a function such that α : = inf y Y sup x X f ( x , y ) R . If in addition, f satisfies condition (5) and for some finite subset Y 1 of Y we have that
Y 1 Y 0 Y Y 0   finite     f | X × Y 0   is   supinf concave   on   X ,
then, f satisfies the minimax inequality if, and only if, it is infsup-convex on Y.
Proof. 
Apply Corollary 2. □
Let us mention another kind of inequality, the one that originated the study of equilibrium problems. Although it is not strictly of the minimax type, a Fan minimax inequality for a function f : X × X R is a result stating, under adequate hypotheses, the validity of the inequality
inf x X f ( x , x ) sup x X inf y X f ( x , y ) .
The celebrated result of K. Fan ([1] Theorem 1) is different from the following one, which in turn extends ([26] Theorem 3.1):
Corollary 5. 
Let X be a nonempty and compact topological space and f : X × X R a function such that α : = inf x X f ( x , x ) R . If f satisfies condition (5) and there exists a finite subset X 1 of X such that
X 1 X 0 X X 0   finite     f | X × X 0   is   supinf concave   on   X ,
then,
inf x X f ( x , x ) sup x X inf y X f ( x , y ) ,
if, and only if, f is inf-diagonally convex on its second variable.
Proof. 
It follows from Corollary 2. □

4. Conclusions

In this paper, we have established a result that makes equivalent the existence of equilibrium for a function f : X × Y R and the validity of the corresponding weak equilibrium inequality: Theorem 1. The topological condition on f that guarantees the equivalence is the condition (5). Theorem 1 provides not only the equivalence between the equilibrium problem (1) and the weak equilibrium inequality (2) but also a condition, (4), in terms of finite subsets that characterize the existence of a solution for (1). In particular, we obtain a discrete characterisation of the solvability of the equilibrium problem. When we also include a not very restrictive convexity condition in Definition 1, we obtain the existence of a solution for more general equilibrium problems than others previously established in [22]. As an application of all this, we obtain both, two results on the existence of Nash equilibria, one topological, Theorem 2 the other also convex, Corollary 3 and some minimax inequalities, Corollaries 4 and 5.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; methodology, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; validation, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; formal analysis, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; investigation, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; writing—original draft preparation, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; writing—review and editing, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G.; supervision, M.I.B., D.G., A.I.G.-G. and M.R.G. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research has been partially supported by Junta de Andalucia, Project FQM359, and by the “Maria de Maeztu” Excellence Unit IMAG, reference CEX2020-001105-M, funded by MCIN/AEI/10.13039/501100011033/.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the reviewers for their valuable suggestions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Fan, K. A Minimax Inequality and Applications, Inequalities, III (Proc. Third Sympos. Univ. California, Los Angeles, CA, 1969; Dedicated to the Memory of Theodore S. Motzkin); Academic Press: New York, NY, USA, 1972; pp. 103–113. [Google Scholar]
  2. Muu, L.D.; Oettli, W. Convergence of an adaptive penalty scheme for finding constrained equilibria. Nonlinear Anal. 1992, 18, 1159–1166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Capătă, A.; Kassay, G.; Al-Homidan, S. Existence results for strong vector equilibrium problems with applications. J. Nonlinear Convex Anal. 2018, 19, 1163–1179. [Google Scholar]
  4. Castellani, M.; Giuli, M. Ekeland’s principle for cyclically antimonotone equilibrium problems. Nonlinear Anal. Real World Appl. 2016, 32, 213–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Dinh, N.; Strodiot, J.J.; Nguyen, V.H. Duality and optimality conditions for generalized equilibrium problems involving DC functions. J. Glob. Optim. 2010, 48, 183–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Forgo, F.; Joó, I. Fixed point and equilibrium theorems in pseudoconvex and related spaces. J. Glob. Optim. 1999, 14, 27–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Frenk, J.B.G.; Kassay, G. On Noncooperative Games, Minimax Theorems, and Equilibrium Problems. In Pareto Optimality, Game Theory and Equilibria; Springer Optimization and Applications 17; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2008; pp. 53–94. [Google Scholar]
  8. Horvath, C. Around an inequality, or two, of Ky Fan. Ann. Acad. Rom. Sci. Ser. Math. Its Appl. 2011, 3, 356–374. [Google Scholar]
  9. Iusem, A.N.; Kassay, G.; Sosa, W. On certain conditions for the existence of solutions of equilibrium problems. Math. Program. 2009, 116, 259–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Kassay, G.; Rădulescu, V.R. Equilibrium problems and applications. In Mathematics in Science and Engineering; Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA; Elsevier: London, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  11. Chang, S.Y. Inequalities and Nash equilibria. Nonlinear Anal. 2010, 73, 2933–2940. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Khanh, P.Q.; Long, V.S.T. Weak Finite Intersection Characterizations of Existence in Optimization. Bull. Malays. Math. Sci. Soc. 2018, 41, 855–877. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Nessah, R.; Tian, G. Existence of solution of minimax inequalities, equilibria in games and fixed points without convexity and compactness assumptions. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 2013, 157, 75–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Tian, G. On the existence of equilibria in games with arbitrary strategy spaces and preferences. J. Math. Econ. 2015, 60, 9–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Fan, K. Minimax theorems. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1953, 39, 42–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  16. Kassay, G.; Kolumbán, J. On a Generalized Sup-Inf Problem. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 1996, 91, 651–670. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. König, H. Über das von Neumannsche minimax-theorem. Arch. Der Math. 1968, 19, 482–487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Ricceri, B. On the applications of a minimax theorem. Optimization 2022, 71, 1253–1273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Sion, M. On general minimax theorems. Pac. J. Math. 1958, 8, 171–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Stefanescu, A. A theorem of the alternative and a two-function minimax theorem. J. Appl. Math. 2004, 2004, 169–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Syga, M. Minimax theorems for extended real-valued abstract convex-concave functions. J. Optim. Theory Appl. 2018, 176, 306–318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Ruiz Galán, M. Elementary convex techniques for equilibrium, minimax and variational problems. Optim. Lett. 2018, 12, 137–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Tian, G. Generalizations of the FKKM theorem and the Ky Fan minimax inequality, with applications to maximal elements, price equilibrium, and complementarity. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1992, 170, 457–471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Ruiz Galán, M. An intrinsic notion of convexity for minimax. J. Convex Anal. 2014, 21, 1105–1139. [Google Scholar]
  25. Ruiz Galán, M. The Gordan theorem and its implications for minimax theory. J. Nonlinear Convex Anal. 2016, 17, 2385–2405. [Google Scholar]
  26. Ruiz Galán, M. A concave-convex Ky Fan minimax inequality. Minimax Theory Its Appl. 2016, 1, 111–124. [Google Scholar]
  27. Zhou, J.X.; Chen, G. Diagonal convexity conditions for problems in convex analysis and quasi-variational inequalities. J. Math. Anal. Appl. 1988, 132, 213–225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Tian, G. Full characterizations of minimax inequality, fixed point theorem, saddle point theorem, and KKM principle in arbitrary topological spaces. J. Fixed Point Theory Appl. 2017, 19, 1679–1693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Baye, M.; Tian, G.; Zhou, J. Characterizations of the existence of equilibria in games with discontinuous and nonquasiconcave payoffs. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1993, 60, 935–948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. von Neumann, J. Zur theorie der gesellschaftsspiele. Math. Ann. 1928, 100, 295–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Chinchuluun, A.; Pardalos, P.M.; Migdalas, A.; Pitsoulis, L. Pareto Optimality, Game Theory and Equilibria; Springer Optimization and its Applications 17; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  32. Simons, S. Minimax theorems. In Encyclopedia of Optimization, 2nd ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2009; pp. 2087–2093. [Google Scholar]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Berenguer, M.I.; Gámez, D.; Garralda-Guillem, A.I.; Ruiz Galán, M. A Discrete Characterization of the Solvability of Equilibrium Problems and Its Application to Game Theory. Axioms 2023, 12, 666. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12070666

AMA Style

Berenguer MI, Gámez D, Garralda-Guillem AI, Ruiz Galán M. A Discrete Characterization of the Solvability of Equilibrium Problems and Its Application to Game Theory. Axioms. 2023; 12(7):666. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12070666

Chicago/Turabian Style

Berenguer, Maria Isabel, Domingo Gámez, Ana Isabel Garralda-Guillem, and Manuel Ruiz Galán. 2023. "A Discrete Characterization of the Solvability of Equilibrium Problems and Its Application to Game Theory" Axioms 12, no. 7: 666. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12070666

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop