Next Article in Journal
A Simplified Approach to the Pricing of Vulnerable Options with Two Underlying Assets in an Intensity-Based Model
Previous Article in Journal
Remarks on Conjectures in Block Theory of Finite Groups
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Branch-and-Bound Algorithm in Optimizing Mathematical Programming Models to Achieve Power Grid Observability
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Efficient Formulation for Vendor–Buyer System Considering Optimal Allocation Fraction of Green Production

Department of Business Administration, College of Business Administration, Majmaah University, Majmaah 11952, Saudi Arabia
Axioms 2023, 12(12), 1104; https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12121104
Submission received: 19 October 2023 / Revised: 29 November 2023 / Accepted: 30 November 2023 / Published: 7 December 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Applied Optimization for Solving Real-World Problems)

Abstract

:
The classical joint economic lot-sizing (JELS) policy in a single-vendor single-buyer system generates an equal production quantity in all cycles, where the input parameters remain static indefinitely. In this paper, a new two-echelon supply chain inventory model is developed involving a hybrid production system. The proposed model simultaneously focuses on green and regular production methods with an optimal allocation fraction of green and regular productions. Unlike the classical mathematical formulation, cycles do not depend on each other, and consequently, each model parameter can be adjusted to be responsive to the dynamic nature of demand rate and/or price fluctuation. A rigorous heuristic approach is used to derive a global optimal solution for a joint hybrid production system. This paper accounts for carbon emissions from production and storage activities related to green and regular produced items along with transportation activity under a multi-level emission-taxing scheme. The results emphasize the significant impact of green production on emissions. That is, the higher the allocation fraction of green production, the lower the total amount of emissions generated by the system, i.e., the system becomes more sustainable. Adopting a hybrid production method not only decreases the greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions dramatically, but also reduces the minimum total cost per unit time when compared with regular production. One of the main findings is that the total system cost generated by the base closed-form formula of the proposed model is considerably lower in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) than that of the existing literature, i.e., 33.59% (16.13%) when the regular production method is assumed. Moreover, the optimal production rate generated by the proposed model is the one that minimizes the emissions production function. In addition, the system earns further revenue by utilizing a mixed transportation policy that combines the Truck Load (TL) and Less than Truck Load (LTL) services. Illustrative examples and special cases that reflect different realistic situations are compared to outline managerial insights.

1. Introduction

Nowadays, global warming and environmental change emerge as a challenge facing governments and the United Nations (UN). This can be attributed to the dramatic increase in greenhouse gas (GHG) over the last decade, with a rate of increase almost twice that recorded for the last three decades [1]. The impact of such an increase has forced governments to design regulations to limit GHG emissions into the environment. Such regulations may comprise carbon cap-and-trade, carbon tax, carbon offset, or carbon cap policies. These polices have been established by the UN and the European Union (EU) to reflect and emphasize the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) [2]. Several countries have made a commitment to limit GHG emissions as a response to the regulations. Manufacturing and transportation are among the biggest sectors in the world that contribute to GHG emissions [3]. For, example, 29% of total GHG emissions in the U.S. is emitted by transportation activities, which is recognized as the major sector generating GHG emissions [4]. To comply with the GHG emissions policies established by the governments, the manufacturers need to adopt sustainable development of production methods aiming to minimize overall emissions. In this regard, adopting green technology is one of the most effective strategies to reduce carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions in their supply chain activities [5,6]. Implementing green technology leads to green production that reflects environmentally friendly inventions. The aim is to use renewable energy, reduce energy use, generate lower emissions, and emphasize awareness of health and safety concerns. Although green production reduces GHG emissions dramatically when compared with regular production, it may result in higher operating costs [7,8,9]. Therefore, it is perhaps more cost effective if the manufacturer uses a hybrid production system that combines green and regular productions. This entails a mechanism that balances green and regular production activities considering operating costs.
Supply chain management (SCM) aims to decrease costs and enhances coordination between supply chain members. One of the main objectives of such coordination is to achieve economic balance among supply chain entities. This can be attained by sharing accurate and timely information towards effective use of recourses. It is worth noting here that the classical two-level supply chain consisting of a vendor and a buyer, and assumes that the lot sizing strategy is optimized independently. A joint economic lot sizing (JELS) refines traditional independent inventory control methods for a joint strategy that simultaneously determines optimal production quantity and the number of shipments per time interval [10,11,12,13]. It has been introduced by many researchers to show that a joint production and inventory policy is a key determinant in carbon emission reduction [14,15,16]. The Vendor-Managed Inventory (VMI) represents a two-echelon supply chain system that involves information sharing between the vendor and the buyer. Through a collaborative relationship, the vendor adjusts the production-inventory policy to replenish multiple lot sizes for the buyer, subject to the buyer’s information related to demand and stock-level. Sustainable supply chain cooperation between a vendor and a buyer emerges as an opportunity beyond cost-sharing efficiency. In the VMI systems, a collaborative relationship may lead to a more profitable joint policy, carbon emissions reduction, inventory cost reduction, and logistic flexibility. This partnership also implies that economic, social, and environmental aspects are nested inside each other, i.e., the system becomes more sustainable [17,18,19]. The highlights of this paper are summarized below:
A two-echelon supply chain inventory model is developed for a VMI system. The developed model considers a hybrid production system involving green and regular production methods with an optimal allocation fraction of green and regular production. The proposed model accounts for GHG emissions from both green and regular production and storage activities related to green and regular produced items along with transportation activity. The cost function includes a penalty charge for exceeding the permissible emissions limits. However, the system reflects the cap-and-trade policy and reaps further cost reduction by selling excess quota in the case that the total emissions emitted is less than that of the emission cap. In addition, the system earns further revenue by utilizing a mixed transportation policy that combines the Truck Load (TL) and Less than Truck Load (LTL) services. In the first time interval, the initial on-hand inventory at the buyer’s warehouse is zero, which can be attributed to the fact that no items have been produced yet. Therefore, two models are formulated to reflect this consideration. The first model reflects the mathematical formulation of the first cycle, whereas the second considers subsequent cycles. This implies that cycles do not depend on each other, and consequently, each model parameter can be adjusted to be responsive to the dynamic nature of demand rate and/or related issues associated with price fluctuation. Results show that the base closed-form formula of the proposed model offers substantial cost savings when compared with the existing literature. The optimal production rate generated by the proposed model is the one that minimizes the emission production function; that is, it generates the lowest emissions possible when compared with the existing literature. For subsequent cycles, the production process starts at the time needed for the first lot size to be produced and delivered. Such displacement in time benefits the vendor for not keeping items for an extra amount of time related to the consumption of the last lot size at the buyer’s warehouse that has been delivered from previous cycle.

2. Literature Review

The first model that formulated a joint inventory problem was investigated by Goyal [20]. The model studied the vendor production policy assuming an instantaneous production rate, where a lot-for-lot (LFL) policy is considered for delivering the lot sizes to the buyer. Banerjee [13] considered the model of Goyal [20] under the assumption of a finite production rate. Wahab et al. [21] proposed inventory models considering emissions costs from transportation activity. The models determine the optimal production quantity and shipment frequency for imperfect-quality items. Hua et al. [22] investigated the model for carbon footprints along with carbon emissions trading. They examined the effects of carbon taxes, carbon caps, and carbon trade on total cost, order quantity, and carbon emissions. Wangsa [23] examined the JELS model considering industrial and transport emissions under penalties and incentives. Ben-Daya and Hariga [24] investigated the model where the lead time is a function of the lot size quantity. Hariga et al. [25] evaluated the effect of carbon emissions in a multistage supply chain of a cold item during storage and transportation activities. Gautam et al. [26] studied the model, with the assumption that GHG emission is caused by transportation activity. Halat and Hafezalkotob [27] considered a multi-stage green inventory model under four different types of carbon regulations. They examined the effect of coordinated and non-coordinated structures on inventory cost and carbon emissions. Khouja and Mehrez [28] investigated the case when the unit production cost is a function of the production rate. They assumed that the increase in the production rate deteriorates the quality of the production process. Eiamkanchanalai and Banerjee [29] considered the case when the unit production cost is a quadratic function of the production rate in a single-level inventory model. Ghosh et al. [30] considered a strict carbon cap policy on a multi-echelon supply chain inventory model. They considered emissions related to production, inventory, and transportation activities. Saga et al. [31] investigated the model for imperfect production processes and inspection errors. The carbon emissions are related to energy generated from transportation and production activities, where incentive and penalty policies are assumed for carbon emission reduction. Huang et al. [32] investigated a two-echelon supply chain to study the effect of green technology. They considered carbon emissions related to production, transportation, and storage activities along with carbon taxes, limited total carbon emissions, and cap-and-trade policies.
Chen et al. [33] provided conditions for reducing emissions by modifying order quantities. They discussed factors affecting emission reductions and cost increases. Kumar and Uthayakumar [34] considered five different stock control policies for unequal shipments. The cost function assumed in the model comprises taxes and penalties to reducing emission associated with production. Zanoni et al. [35] presented a JELS model with a consignment stock (CS) agreement considering emissions taxes, penalty costs, and an emission-trading scheme. Jaber et al. [36] examined the effect of carbon emissions on the JELS inventory models. They accounted for carbon taxes and penalties, where the production rate is assumed as a function of the rate of the carbon emission. Turken et al. [37] considered various environmental regulations in a multiple buyers–single vendor inventory model. Bazan et al. [38] proposed two models that investigate emissions costs from transportation activity along with energy used for production. The first model underlies the traditional coordination strategy and the second underlies a CS agreement strategy.
Astanti et al. [39] considered a VMI model for imperfect-quality items and deterioration. The model is associated with carbon emissions related to transportation and production operations. Malik and Kim [40] investigated the model considering defects from production operations, where the production rate is a function of the carbon emission. Jauhari et al. [41] proposed a VMI model for a hybrid production system involving green and regular production. They assumed carbon emissions related to transportation, storage, and production activities.
The above-cited references are directly relevant to the proposed model. However, the effects of carbon emission reduction on the JELS models have been extended in several ways. Many researchers have accounted for cases that include, but are not limited to, deterministic and stochastic demand, imperfect-quality items related to the production process, equal or unequal shipments policies, and deterioration [42,43,44,45,46,47,48,49,50,51,52,53,54,55,56]. For more details on the mathematical modeling of the JELS and the related research, see [6,10]. Recently, Alamri [57] pointed out that the mathematical formulation of the classical joint VMI system is based on the assumption of an infinite planning horizon. Therefore, the formulation ignored the fact that the inventory level at the buyer’s warehouse is zero in the first cycle since the vendor has not yet started the production process. The author rectified the model of Jaber et al. [36] and provided a closed-form formula that generates considerably lower total cost. Two models were developed involving carbon emissions from production, storage, and transportation activities. The first model formulates the total cost function for the first cycle, whereas the second formulates the function of subsequent cycles. The author also showed that the physical transportation cost can be ignored with no effect on the optimal production quantity.

3. Research Motivation and Contribution

The inventory mathematical formulation of the classical JELS system generates an equal production quantity indefinitely due to the assumption of an infinite planning horizon. Such an assumption suggests a static production process that generates a fixed coordination multiplier applies for each cycle. However, the initial on-hand inventory at the buyer’s warehouse is zero in the first time interval since no items have been produced yet. This necessitates a production policy that distinguishes the first cycle from subsequent cycles. Therefore, two mathematical formulations that reflect the behavior of the first and subsequent cycles are needed, where each derives its distinct optimal solution. Therefore, each subsequent cycle can be associated with its distinct input parameters to ensure that it is independent from the previous one. It is worth noting here that such consideration overcomes the implicit assumption associated with the classical formulation that input parameters remain static indefinitely. This is so because the classical formulation assumes that the production process for subsequent cycles begins to generate the same lot sizes equal that of the last produced quantity that has been delivered to the buyer in a previous cycle, which represents the buyer’s initial on-hand inventory. Accordingly, if the situation warrants and the decision-maker is obliged to adjust the input parameters, then the optimal production quantity as the classical formulation would then suggest cannot be considered as the optimal quantity for subsequent cycles.
The abovementioned issues are considered in the proposed model and, therefore, allow for the adjustment of the input parameters for any subsequent cycle. This also guarantees that the model remains viable for subsequent cycles and keeps generating optimal results subject to the desired adjustment of any model parameter. In practice, input parameters encounter adjustment due to many realistic situations. Such adjustment may occur because of external competitiveness and/or internal challenges or as a response to the dynamic nature of demand rate and/or price fluctuation. Moreover, implementing an alternative policy resulting from acquiring new knowledge, periodic review applications, and machine maintenance scheduling activities may trigger situations that force the decision maker to consider a suitable adjustment of the input parameters [58,59].
In this paper, we propose a VMI model that investigates the effect of carbon emissions together with the implementation of green technology for a hybrid production system. The developed model simultaneously focuses on green and regular production methods with an optimal allocation fraction of green and regular productions. In this model, emissions are released from production and storage activities related to green and regular produced items along with transportation activity. The carbon emissions are relatively associated with carbon taxes and penalties for exceeding the allowable emissions limits. The proposed model considers the case that the system reaps further cost reduction by selling excess quota if the total emissions generated by the system are less than that of the emission cap, which reflects the cap-and-trade policy. Unlike traditional modeling, hybrid production implies simultaneous production fractions associated with green and regular productions, where each is associated with its distinct released emission level. In this case, the demand is satisfied from a collection of green and regular produced items. This method enables a decision maker to trade-off between the production cost and emissions. For subsequent cycles, the production process starts at the time needed for the first lot size to be produced and delivered. Such displacement in time benefits the vendor by not keeping items for extra time related to the consumption of the last lot size at the buyer’s warehouse that have been delivered from the previous cycle.
Transportation services related to inventory mathematical modeling are either the Truck Load (TL) or Less than Truck Load (LTL) services. A TL service applies such that the cost is incurred for the whole truck [60,61,62], whereas an LTL service refers to the case when the cost is paid per unit of item that is transported. To entice manufacturers, logistics companies often offer the option for utilizing both TL and LTL services. In this regard, the proposed model considers a mixed transportation service of TL and LTL in its mathematical formulation. Therefore, the decision maker needs to allocate the fraction based on the capacity of the truck that renders TL transportation service or a mixed service (policy) of TL and LTL that minimizes the transportation cost. That said, the allocation fraction involves a positive integer multiplier representing the number of trucks (TL) required for each shipment along with the remaining quantity that needs to be transported by LTL service.
Table 1, below, depicts and compares the proposed model with some related previously published works.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: In Section 4, the cost components related to the joint hybrid production system are presented to formulate the first and subsequent cycles. In Section 5, illustrative examples, comparisons between regular, green, and hybrid scenarios, and special cases are offered to support the practical application of the joint model. Section 6 represents a model overview and managerial insights. In Section 7, the concluding remarks and directions for further research are provided. Finally, the holding cost functions related to the joint hybrid model are provided in Appendix A, whereas the solution procedure for the first and subsequent cycles is provided in Appendix B.

4. Formulation of the Joint Model

In this section, we first present the notations and assumptions necessary to formulate the proposed joint hybrid production system. In Section 4.3, the necessary discussion that elaborates on the proposed joint hybrid production system is introduced, followed by the classification of the direct and indirect CO2 emissions generated by the buyer and the vendor activities. Section 4.3.1 and Section 4.3.2 derive the mathematical formulation of the per unit time total cost functions for the joint hybrid production system for the first and subsequent cycles, respectively.

4.1. Notations

The list of notations used to develop the joint hybrid inventory system are provided in Table 2 below:

4.2. Assumptions

The following assumptions have been considered:
  • A single item is manufactured by a combination of green and regular production methods.
  • The demand rate is satisfied from a collection of green and regular produced items.
  • Any order size of q k placed at time t l arrives at the buyer just prior to the depletion of the on-hand inventory of that same period. At the beginning of the production process, the initial inventory at the buyer’s warehouse is zero because no items have been manufactured yet. Accordingly, the first lot size, q 1 , is delivered once it has been accumulated from green and regular produced items by time t 1 and will reach the buyer after a transportation time t l . Therefore, in the first period of the first cycle, shortages are allowed and fully backordered by time t 1 + t l . Thus, we restrict that p 1 ( T 1 t l ) 2 d T 1 in the first cycle, i.e., the second replenishment will reach the buyer’s warehouse before the depletion of the on-hand inventory of the first period, i.e., no later than time T 1 .

4.3. The Mathematical Formulation of the Joint Model

Figure 1 and Figure 2 depict, respectively, inventory variation of the proposed joint model for a two-echelon supply chain consisting of a vendor and a buyer for the first and subsequent cycles. At the beginning of the first cycle, the production process of green and regular produced items starts at a rate p z k . At time t 1 , the vendor delivers the first lot of size q 1 units that have been accumulated from green and regular produced items. This quantity satisfies demand and shortages that has been accumulated during time t 1 + t l . As can been seen from Figure 1 and Figure 2, holding costs are applied for λ lots for both the vendor and the buyer. This is so because the vendor must deliver two lots by time T 1 to avoid shortages for the second period. Therefore, the first lot that has been replenished at time t 1 reaches the buyer at time t 1 + t l to satisfy demand and shortages, whereas the second reaches the buyer just before the inventory level becomes zero, i.e., by time T 1 . In the subsequent cycles, the production process starts at time t d = T s 1 t s t l . That is, the production time is displaced until the time required to produce and deliver the first lot. Note that the last lot produced in the first (subsequent) cycle that appears as a green line in Figure 1 and Figure 2 has been delivered to the buyer in that same cycle to satisfy the demand for the last period (time T 1 ( T s )). More specifically, it represents the buyer’s first lot (for time T s 1 in Figure 2) for the subsequent cycles for illustrative purposes only, though its corresponding costs have been included in the previous cycle (Alamri [57]). This is key in the mathematical formulation, allowing each subsequent cycle to be independent from the previous one, thus allowing for the adjustment of the input parameters for any subsequent cycle as a response to the dynamic nature of demand and/or related issues associated with price fluctuation. Moreover, it guarantees that the model remains viable for subsequent cycles and keeps generating optimal results subject to the desired adjustment of any model parameter.
Figure 3 represents the direct and indirect CO2 emissions generated by the buyer and the vendor activities. The buyer experiences direct CO2 emissions, which are related to amount of GHG emissions generated for keeping items in storage, whereas the vendor experiences both direct and indirect CO2 emissions. The direct CO2 emissions occur due to production and storge activities for both green and regular produced items. The vendor is responsible for transportation activity, which is associated with direct and indirect CO2 emissions. The direct CO2 emissions related to transportation involves product weight, whereas the indirect CO2 emissions related to transportation include shipment frequency, distance traveled from freight to vendor, distance traveled from vendor to buyer, and fuel consumption.

4.3.1. The Mathematical Formulation of the First Cycle

The per unit time holding cost function (see Equations (A2) and (A4) in Appendix A) for the base model depicted by Figure 1 (first cycle) is provided by the following:
W s 1 = h b d 2 t l 2 2 λ q 1 + h b q 1 d 2 λ d p 2 2 p + λ d + h b 2 λ 2 d 2 t l p 2 d t l + h v q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ h v λ 1 d t l λ .
Below, we introduce the relevant elements related to the inventory model with environmental effects:
In addition to the holding cost that is applied for the buyer’s base model represented by the first three terms of Equation (1), the buyer incurs an ordering cost per lot size. The buyer also encounters a cost related to the emissions generated during inventory storage of items because of warehousing activities, which depends on the buyer’s inventory level [27,39,56,63]. Considering the above and Equation (1), the per unit time total cost function for the buyer in the first cycle is provided by the following:
W E b 1 = S b d q 1 + ( h b + E b E e E w b ) d 2 t l 2 2 λ q 1 + ( h b + E b E e E w b ) q 1 d 2 λ d p 2 2 p + λ d + ( h b + E b E e E w b ) 2 λ 2 d 2 t l p 2 d t l .
The CO2 emissions generated by the buyer is provided by the following:
e b 1 = E e E w b d 2 t l 2 2 λ q 1 + E e E w b q 1 d 2 λ d p 2 2 p + λ d + E e E w b 2 λ 2 d 2 t l p 2 d t l .
Similarly, in addition to the holding cost that is applied for the vendor’s base model (see Equations (A4) and (A5) in Appendix A), the vendor incurs a set-up cost as well as the following transportation and carbon emissions costs:
The same as the buyer, the vendor also incurs a cost related to the emissions generated during inventory storage, which depend on the vendor’s inventory levels of green and regular produced items.
Transportation is associated with direct and indirect carbon emissions. The direct emission level underlies the weight of the product transferred to the buyer. The indirect emission level underlies the shipment frequency, distance traveled from freight to vendor, distance traveled from vendor to buyer, and fuel consumption [56]. Transportation is also associated with a cost for delivering each lot size to the buyer. In this regard, the vendor may deliver each lot size using a combination of LTL and TL services. Hence, let = v t c t < v c represent the quantity with identical transportation cost by either service. In addition, let δ = q 1 v c n denote the portion of truck capacity that needs to be delivered using either TL or LTL. If δ v c , then it is more cost effective for the vendor to consider a mixed policy of LTL and TL services, i.e., v t n + q 1 v c n v c c t . Alternatively, if δ v c , then it is more beneficial for the vendor to use TL service, i.e., v t n + 1 trucks. Accordingly, we set = 1 if the TL service is utilized and = 0 if it is cost effective to use a mixed policy of LTL and TL services. Therefore, the physical and emissions transportation costs per unit time for the vendor are provided by the following:
v t n + 1 d q 1 + 1 v t v c c t n + c t q 1 d q 1 + v v + E v T E T d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f .
The vendor has two production options, i.e., green and regular production, where each generates distinct emission levels. In this case, ζ q 1 is produced by the green production method with a production rate ξ p = p g and the rest, i.e., 1 ζ q 1 , is produced by the regular production method with a production rate 1 ζ p = p r . This implies that the first lot size, q 1 , is delivered to the buyer once both quantities accumulate the sum of q 1 units, i.e., at time q 1 p . Accordingly, the mathematical modeling of the duration of time for holding inventories in storage for both methods is identical with that of the base model, except that each method is associated with its distinct input parameters.
The production costs associated with green production are higher than those of the regular one. This can be attribute to the fact that green production is equipped with machine tools that are based on green technology, and consequently, E m g ( E p g ) > E m r ( E p r ) . Here, we assume that E m z   ( E p z ) decreases (increases) as production rate increases (decreases). For example, the more items that are produced by the worker, the lower the wage per unit time is paid by the company. Similarly, as the production rate increases, tool and rework costs increase due to the increase in defective items resulting from tool wear [28]. Therefore, the production costs for green and regular productions per unit time are, respectively, provided by the following:
E m g p g + E p g p g ζ d
E m r p r + E p r p r 1 ζ d
Carbon emissions released from production are represented by a function that links the production rate with the rate of emission [36,38]. However, the vendor invests in the green production facility aiming to reduce CO2 emissions. Therefore, the vendor reaps the benefit of such investment that renders produced items greener, and consequently, the vendor reduces the cost incurred for emissions. The emissions costs for green and regular productions per unit time are, respectively, provided by the following:
E v g a g p g 2 b g p g + c g ζ d
E v r a r p r 2 b r p r + c r 1 ζ d
According to Fandel [64] and Narita [65], machines constructed for green production generate a lower level of emission due to the use of green technology, and consequently, a g < a r ,   c g < c r , a n d   b g > b r . Thus, from Equations (4), (7) and (8) above, and (A4) and (A5) in Appendix A, the CO2 emissions generated by the green and regular facilities are, respectively, provided by the following:
E g 1 = E e E w g ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ ζ λ 1 E e E w g d t l λ + E T d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f + a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d .
E r 1 = E e E w r 1 ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ 1 ζ λ 1 E e E w r d t l λ + a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d .
Note that the emissions related to transportation apply only once; therefore, they are included either for E g 1 or E r 1 .
In addition, the joint system either earns revenue from selling excess quota or incurs a penalty cost for exceeding the allowable limits [36,38]. The penalty cost is provided by the following:
i = 1 k Y i E p i ,
where
Y i = 1 , if E s 1 > E l i ( i = 1 , 2 , , k ) , and Y i = 0 otherwise, where E p i < E p i + 1 .
The cap-and-trade regulations are provided by the following:
E R = E v α E c E s 1 ,
where
α = 1 , if E s 1 < E c , and α = 0 otherwise.
Now, considering the above and Equations (A4) and (A5) in Appendix A, the per unit time total cost functions for the vendor in the first cycle for green and regular productions are, respectively, provided by the following:
W E g 1 = S g d λ q 1 + h g + E v g E e E w g ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ ζ λ 1 h g + E v g E e E w g d t l λ + 1 v t v c c t n + c t q 1 d q 1 + v t n + 1 d q 1 + v v + E v T E T d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s 1 .
W E r 1 = S r d λ q 1 + h r + E v r E e E w r 1 ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ 1 ζ λ 1 h r + E v r E e E w r d t l λ + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d .
Note that the physical and emissions transportation costs, cap-and-trade revenue, and penalty cost apply only once; therefore, they are included either for W E g 1 or W E r 1 . Therefore, the per unit time total joint cost function in the first cycle considering Equations (2), (13) and (14) is provided by the following:
W E s 1 = S b d q 1 + S g + S r d λ q 1 + h b + E b E e E w b d 2 λ d t l 2 q 1 + q 1 d p 2 2 p + λ d + 2 d t l p 2 t l + h g + E v g E e E w g ζ q 1 + h r + E v r E e E w r 1 ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ ζ h g + E v g E e E w g + 1 ζ h r + E v r E e E w r λ 1 d t l λ + v t n + 1 d q 1 + 1 v t v c c t n + c t q 1 d q 1 + v v + E v T E T d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α ( E s 1 E c ) .
For simplicity, let S g + S r = c 1 , h b + E b E e E w b = c 2 , h g + E v g E e E w g = c 3 , h r + E v r E e E w r = c 4   a n d   v v + E v T E T = c 5 . Thus, Equation (15) can be rewritten as follows:
W E s 1 = S b d q 1 + c 1 d λ q 1 + c 2 d 2 λ d t l 2 q 1 + q 1 d p 2 2 p + λ d + 2 d t l p 2 t l + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 λ 1 d t l λ + v t n + 1 d q 1 + 1 v t v c c t n + c t q 1 d q 1 + c 5 d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s 1 .

4.3.2. The Mathematical Formulation of the Subsequent Cycles

The per unit time holding cost function (see Equation (A7) in Appendix A) for the base model depicted by Figure 2 (subsequent cycles) is provided by the following:
W s s = h b q s 2 + h v q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p .
Therefore, by a similar above-discussed approach for the first cycle, the per unit time total joint cost function for subsequent cycles is provided by the following:
W E s s = S b d q s + c 1 d λ q s + c 2 q s 2 + c 3 ζ q s + c 4 1 ζ q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p + v t n + 1 d q s + 1 v t v c c t n + c t q s d q s + c 5 d T f f e q s + T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s s .
From Equation (18), we note that the CO2 emissions generated by the buyer in subsequent cycles is as follows:
e b s = E e E w b q s 2 .
From Equation (18), the CO2 emissions generated by the green and regular facilities in subsequent cycles are, respectively, provided by the following:
E g s = E e E w g ζ q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p + E T d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f + a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d .
E r s = E e E w r 1 ζ q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p + a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d .
Our goal is to minimize W E s 1 ( W E s s ) provided by Equations (16) and (18) subject to integer values of λ   a n d   n .
Therefore, the goal is to solve the following optimization problem.
W E S 1 ( W E S S ) =   minimize   W E s 1 ( W E s s )   given   by   Equations   ( 16 )   and   ( 18 )   subject   to   < v c , q 1 ( q s ) v c n 0 ,   n 0 ,   λ 1 ,   = 1   i f   q 1 ( q s ) v c n v c   0   else     0 ζ 1   p m i n p p m a x   n   and   λ   integer   values .
Recalling Equations (A51) and (A52) (see Appendix B), then W E s 1 ,   m i n and W E s 1 ,   m i n are, respectively, provided by Equations (23) and (24) below:
W E s 1 ,   m i n = d 2 λ S b + c 5 T f f e + 2 c 1 + c 2 d t l 2 c 2 d 2 p 2 2 d p + λ + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ λ + c 2 2 λ 2 d 2 t l p 2 d t l 1 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 λ 1 d t l λ + c 5 d T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s 1 .
W E s s ,   m i n = 2 d λ S b + c 5 T f f e + c 1 c 2 + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d p + λ 1 1 d p λ + c 5 d T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s s .
As can be seen, Equations (23) and (24) still depend on p and ζ ; therefore, no closed-form formulation have been found for p and ζ . Thus, their optimal values can be obtained using numerical search, from which Equations (23) and (24) are minimized subject to p m i n p p m a x and 0 ζ 1 . Then, from Equations (A49) and (A50) (see Appendix B), we can find q 1 v c q s v c ; if δ v c , then we set = 1 in Equations (16) and (18). Otherwise, i.e., δ v c < , we set = 0 in Equations (16) and (18). Note that q 1 v c q s v c represents the integer value of n plus the fraction δ .

5. Numerical Examples

In this section, we present examples and special cases to illustrate the application of the proposed model in different sittings. The problems W E S 1   a n d   W E S S have been coded using the CAGE Model-Based Calibration (MBC) Toolbox in MATLAB for the set of input parameters that are listed in Table 3 and Table 4 below. Table 3 shows the input parameters illustrating the application of the proposed model, whereas Table 4 represents the emissions penalties schedule for exceeding allowable limits.

5.1. Example 1

In this example, we consider the set of values that are presented in Table 3 and Table 4 to observe the behavior of the system.
Table 5 depicts the effect of the hybrid production system on the first and subsequent cycles and summarizes the optimal values of ξ k , p k , q k , λ k , n k , E s k , a n d   W E s k .
In the first cycle, the optimal production quantity of green and regular items is q 1 = 755.76   u n i t s , which satisfies demand and shortages that have been accumulated in the first period, with λ 1 = 2 . The optimal production rate is p 1 = 2635.15   u n i t s , with ξ 1 = 0.686 (68.6%) coming from the green production facility and the remaining fraction produced in the regular production facility. Note that the demand is satisfied from a collection of green and regular produced items. From Equation (A49), q 1 v c = 755.76 300 = 2.5192 n 1 = 2 , where = v t c t = 500 2 = 250   u n i t s < v c = 300   u n i t s . This is so, since δ = q 1 v c n 1 = 0.5192 < c v = v t c v c t = 500 300 × 2 = 0.833 , from which a mixed transportation policy is implemented. Therefore, 0.5192 indicates the fraction of truck capacity that needs to be transported by LTL service. This implies that δ v c = 0.5192 × 300 = 155.76 < = v t c t = 250 v t n + q 1 v c n v c c t . That is, we set n 1 = 2 and = 0 in Equation (16). The total cost per month is W E s 1 = U S D   10,663.86 , with total GHG emissions being emitted equal to E s 1 = 516.74   t o n   C O 2 . The vast majority (71.82%) of the emissions are related to regular production activities ( E r 1 = 371.11   t o n   C O 2 ) even though less than 32% of the production quantity has been produced in the regular facility. Note that this amount does not include emissions related to transportation activity (recall Equation (10)). The amount of GHG emissions related to green production is E g 1 = 145.46   t o n   C O 2 , with 0.587   t o n   C O 2 being released due to transportation activity, whereas the emissions related to storage activity of green and regular produced items at both warehouses are negligible, i.e., 0.06   t o n   C O 2 and 0.024   t o n   C O 2 , respectively. The emissions related to keeping items at the buyer’s warehouse is e b 1 = 0.172   t o n   C O 2 . Here, we have p 1 T 1 t l 2 d T 1 , i.e., p 1 T 1 t l = 2635.15 × 755.76 1000 0.08 = 1780.7 > 2 q 1 = 1511.5 .
In subsequent cycles, the system behaves differently. For example, the optimal production quantity of green and regular items is q s = 1053.79 u n i t s , which satisfies demand in the first period, with λ s = 1 and ξ s = 0.647 . That is, 64.7% of the demand is satisfied from green production and the remaining quantity is fulfilled from regular production with a production rate equals to p s = 3427.72   u n i t s . From Equation (A50), we have q s v c = 1053.79 300 = 3.5126 . Thus, n s = 3   a n d   δ = q s v c n s = 0.5126 < 0.833 , which represents the fraction of truck capacity that needs to be transported by LTL service. Therefore, δ v c = 0.5126 × 300 = 153.79 < = v t c t = 250 v t n + q s v c n v c c t , from which we set n s = 3 and = 0 in Equation (18) and a mixed transportation policy is applied. The total cost per month is greater than that of the first cycle, i.e., W E s s = U S D   11,697.82 , with total GHG emissions equal to E s s = 586.39   t o n   C O 2 . The amount of GHG emissions associated with regular production activities is E r s = 447.02   t o n   C O 2 , which represents 76.25% of the total emissions released into the environment. As that of the first cycle, this amount does not comprise emissions related to transportation activity (recall Equation (21)). The amount of GHG emissions related to green production is E g s = 138.99   t o n   C O 2 , with 0.562   t o n   C O 2 being generated from transportation activity. The amount of GHG emissions associated with keeping items in storage at both warehouses is 0.10   t o n   C O 2 and 0.066 t o n   C O 2 for green and regular produced items, respectively, whereas the amount of emissions related to keeping items at the buyer’s warehouse is e b s = 0.379   t o n   C O 2 . The system incurs penalty costs for exceeding the emissions allowance limit ( E c = 400   t o n   C O 2 ), which occurs in both the first and subsequent cycles. That is, Y 1 = Y 2 = Y 3 = 1 i = 1 3 Y i E p i = U S D   1500 (recall Table 4).
Note that T s 1 = T 1 T s , i.e., the second cycle behaves differently and, therefore, it is independent from the first cycle. That is, the proposed model ensures that T s 1 T s holds for subsequent cycles, which implies that each model parameter can be adjusted in any cycle. However, T s 1 = T s if the input parameters remain identical for the subsequent cycle (e.g., the third cycle). This can also be observed in both the mathematical formulation and Figure 1 and Figure 2. That is, the associated costs of the last lot that has been delivered to the buyer from the previous cycle (the first lot that appears (in green line) for the subsequent cycle for illustrative purposes only) are ignored in cycle T s s but are included in cycle T s s 1 (the same previous cycle) (Alamri [57]). Note also that the constraint p s ( T 1 t l 1 ) 2 d T 1 does not apply for subsequent cycles. In this case, the constraint p s ( 1 + t l ) d is sufficient.
Note that, if the emission cap increased from its current allowance limit ( E c = 400   t o n   C O 2 ) to E c = 1000   t o n   C O 2 , then the cap-and-trade regulations are applied, and the system earns revenue by selling excess quota. This revenue is set equal to E v E c E s 1 = 2 1000 516.74 = 2 483.26 = U S D   966.52 . Note that, in this case, the system also does not incur a cost applied for penalty charges. Therefore, W E s 1 E c = 1000 = 10,663.86 1500 966.52 = U S D 8197.3 , where the first term refers to the total cost of the first cycle of Example 1, the second term represents the penalty charge, and the third term refers to the revenue gained by selling excess quota. The same applies for subsequent cycles if the allowance limit increases from E c = 400   t o n   C O 2 to E c = 1000   t o n   C O 2 .
It is worth noting here that the beginning of production time for subsequent cycles is displaced, i.e., the re-start-up production time is t d = T s 1 t s t l = 755.76 1000 1053.79 3427.72 0.08 = 0.368   m o n t h 11   d a y s . This is key in the mathematical formulation and has two main roles. The first one stems from the fact that this displacement reduces the holding cost. That is, it benefits the vendor for not keeping items for extra time related to the consumption of the last lot size at the buyer’s warehouse that has been delivered from the previous cycle. The second ensures all cycles are independent from each other. Therefore, it allows the decision maker to adjust the model parameters for any subsequent cycle as a response to the dynamic nature of demand and/or price fluctuation. The latter also guarantees that the model remains viable and keeps generating optimal results for subsequent cycles subject to the desired adjustment of the input parameters. Further discussion related to this point is provided in the next example (Example 2).

Remark

Note that the last two terms of Equations (16) and (18) do not affect the optimal produced quantity, its associated optimal production rate, and the allocation fraction of green production. Therefore, the proposed model enables the decision maker to trade-off between the additional cost associated with increasing the allocation fraction of green production (if it is technologically attainable) and the savings that may be earned for not exceeding certain permissible emissions limit(s) applicable to the optimal production policy. It is clear from Equations (5) and (6) and their related input parameters as shown in Table 3 that the unit production cost for green items is greater than that of the regular one. In this case, the per unit time total cost increases excluding the last two terms of Equations (16) and (18), which can be attributed to the increase in producing and storing more green items. On the other hand, the system reduces emissions associated with regular production aiming to avoid one or more penalty charge and may earn additional revenue as an application of the cap-and-trade regulations. Note that the production rate that minimizes the emission production function is that of p g = b g 2 a g ζ and p r = b r 2 a r 1 ζ . Given the input parameters of Table 3 and as ζ 1 , p g p = b g 2 a g = 2000 units and as ζ 0 , p r p = b r 2 a r = 800 units. From Table 3 and Table 5, we have p g = b g 2 a g ζ and p r = b r 2 a r 1 ζ , with p s = 3427.72   u n i t s and ξ s = 0.647 (for subsequent cycles), then p g = b g 2 a g ξ s = 3091.2   a n d   p r = b r 2 a r 1 ξ s = 2266.3 . Therefore, any deviation from p g   a n d   p r , i.e., increasing (decreasing) p g   a n d   p r , increases the emissions generated by each production function. For example, increasing ξ s will result in a new production rate, which will increase the green produced quantity and decreases (increases) p g   ( p r ) . Let us now observe the consequences of such an adjustment by increasing ξ s = 0.647 to be a fixed (deterministic) input parameter equal to 0.73. In this case, the per unit time total cost is W E s s ξ = 0.73 = U S D   10,286.92 > W E s s = U S D   10,197.82 . Note that both costs do not include penalties costs for exceeding the emissions allowance limit. The amount of GHG emissions being generated from production, storage, and transportation activities for the optimal policy is equal to E s s = 586.39   t o n   C O 2 (Table 5), whereas the amount of GHG emissions being generated from production, storage, and transportation activities when ξ = 0.73 is equal to E s s ξ = 0.73 = 494.92   t o n   C O 2 . Therefore, Y 1 = Y 2 = 1 i = 1 2 Y i E p i = U S D   500 compared with U S D   1500 associated with the optimal production policy (recall Table 4). Hence, the saving is set equal to 11,697.82 10,286.92 + 500 = U S D 910.9 . This implies that the trade-off is very much related to the emissions penalties schedule for exceeding allowable limits and the unit production cost for green items.

5.2. Example 2

In this example, we emphasize the viability of the model in the case that the demand rate increases in the third cycle from 1000 units to 1200 units. The rest of the input parameters remain as that listed in Table 3 and Table 4. Such an adjustment is important since the demand rate or any other input parameters are subject to adjustment due to many realistic situations. Moreover, such an adjustment constitutes evidence that the proposed model remains as a viable solution and continues to generate optimal values that reflect the adjustment that might occur for subsequent cycles. Table 6 shows the behavior of the optimal values of ξ k , p k , q k , λ k , n k , E s k , a n d   W E s k when the demand rate increases in the third cycle from 1000 units to 1200 units. Note that the fourth row of Table 6 represents the optimal values that were already derived for the subsequent cycles in Example 1, which now is referred to as the second cycle.
A comparison between the results in Table 6 reveals that increasing the demand rate decreases both the optimal production quantity and the production rate. However, increasing the demand rate slightly increases the proportion of green production, i.e., it increased from ξ 2 = 0.647 to ξ s = 0.654 . The optimal production quantity is q s = 667.01   u n i t s , which is lower than that of the second cycle. The total cost per month is W E s s = U S D   14,776.23 , which can be attributed to the fact that Y 1 = Y 2 = Y 3 = Y 4 = 1 i = 1 4 Y i E p i = U S D   3000 (Table 4). That is, the system encounters an additional penalty charge of U S D   1500 . The system also experiences an extra cost associated with the increase in the amount of emissions generated by the system compared with that of the second cycle. Note that the production rate decreased from p 2 = 3427.72 to p s = 3102.71 even though the emissions increased from E s 2 = 586.39 to E s s = 663.81 . This result is consistent with the finding in Alamri [57], i.e., the amount of GHG emissions generated by the system increases (decreases) as the demand rate increases (decreases). That is, fixing the production rate and increasing (decreasing) the demand rate increases (decreases) the amount of GHG emissions generated by the system. Note that the production rate that minimizes the emission production function is that of p g = b g 2 a g ζ and p r = b r 2 a r 1 ζ . Given the input parameters of Table 3, then p g = 2989.5   a n d   p r = 2416.9 . Therefore, any deviation from p g   a n d   p r , i.e., increasing (decreasing) p g   a n d   p r increases the emissions generated by each production function. Note that, from Table 6, we have p g s = ξ s p s = 2029   a n d   p r s = 1 ξ s p s = 1073.4 . On the other hand, Equations (16) and (18) indicate that the demand rate is linked with each production function. In this case, increasing (decreasing) the demand rate increases (decreases) the emissions generated by the system, which is reflected in this example (Example 2). Therefore, we can deduce that the lower the demand rate the lower the emissions, which implies fewer penalty charges associated with the boundaries of emissions (Table 4).
As can be seen, the proposed model is a viable solution and generates optimal values that reflect the adjustment of the demand rate, i.e., the validity and robustness of our model are ascertained.

5.3. Example 3

In this example, we repeat Example 1 to investigate the behavior of the model in different settings for sensitivity analysis purposes subject to the set of values as listed in Table 3 and Table 4. Namely, the direct input parameters that affect the behavior of the model are considered and the results are summarized in Table 7 below.
Table 7 shows that the model behaves as expected in all cases. For instance, when the vendor allocates equal holding costs for the green and regular produced items, i.e., h r = h g = 4 , then the model generates a greater quantity in the first cycle than that of Example 1, which is associated with a lower total minimum cost. For subsequent cycles, both the optimal production quantity and the total minimum cost per month are lower than those of Example 1. The system emitted lower GHG emissions in both the first and subsequent cycles than those of Example 1. In the first cycle (subsequent cycles), the production rate is higher (lower) than that of Example 1. The allocation fraction of green production in both the first and subsequent cycles is higher than that of Example 1. For equal set-up costs, i.e., S r = S g = 800 , the total minimum cost per month, total amount of GHG emissions, production rate, and the optimal production quantity are higher (lower) than those of Example 1 in the first cycle (subsequent cycles). The allocation fraction of green production in the first cycle is lower than that of Example 1 and slightly increases in subsequent cycles.
In the first and subsequent cycles, decreasing the demand rate from 1000 units to 900 units decreases the total minimum cost per month and total amount of GHG emissions. The optimal production quantity and the production rate increase (decrease) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) compared with those of Example 1. The allocation fraction of green production decreases in the first cycle and remains identical in subsequent cycles when compared with that of Example 1. Finally, when the per unit time costs to run the machine independent of production rate are equal, i.e., p m g = p m r = 2000 , the model behaves differently. In particular, the per unit time total minimum cost, total amount of GHG emissions, and production rate in the first and subsequent cycles are lower than those of Example 1, whereas the allocation fraction of green production is higher than that of Example 1 in both the first and subsequent cycles. The optimal production quantity is higher (lower) than that of Example 1 in the first cycle (subsequent cycles).
As can be seen from the results obtained in Table 5, Table 6 and Table 7, the GHG emissions increase (decrease) with demand rate. Figure 4, Figure 5, Figure 6, Figure 7 and Figure 8 depict and compare the effect of adjusting the input parameters on the optimal production quantity, GHG emissions, the total minimum cost per month, production rate, and the allocation fraction of green production.

5.4. Example 4

In this example, we investigate the behavior of the model for the regular production option to observe the advantages associated with the hybrid production scenario and how much savings the system may gain if a hybrid production option is considered. In this case, we set p m g = S g = ζ = 0 in Equations (16) and (18) where the rest of the input parameters remain as that listed in Table 3 and Table 4. Table 8 depicts the behavior of the model for the regular production option.
A comparison between Table 5 and Table 8 indicates that adopting a hybrid production mode decreases the GHG emissions dramatically, which in turn reduces the total minimum cost per month by 38.40% (33.23%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles). From Table 8, we can see that the production rate and the optimal production quantity are less than those of hybrid production (Table 5). The total cost per month is W E s 1 = U S D   17,245.98 in the first cycle and W E s s = U S D   17,265.70 in the subsequent cycles, which can be attributed to the fact that Y 1 = Y 2 = Y 3 = Y 4 = Y 5 = Y 6 = 1 i = 1 6 Y i E p i = U S D   7500 (Table 4). That is, the system encounters an additional penalty charge of U S D   6000 in all cycles due to the dramatic increase in GHG emissions generated by the regular production. The GHG emissions related to storage and transportation activities are negligible, i.e., 0.74   t o n   C O 2 and 0.81 t o n   C O 2 in the first and subsequent cycles, respectively.

5.5. Example 5

In this example, we investigate the behavior of the model for the green production option to observe the advantages associated with such a production scenario and how much savings the system may gain compared with the regular and hybrid production options. In this case, we set p m r = S r = 0 and ζ = 1 in Equations (16) and (18) where the rest of the input parameters remain as that listed in Table 3 and Table 4. Table 9 depicts the behavior of the model for the green production option.
A comparison between Table 5, Table 8 and Table 9 indicates that adopting the green production option decreases the GHG emissions dramatically, which in turn reduces the minimum total cost per month by 33.34% (27.41%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) compared with hybrid production and 58.78% (50.82%) compared with regular production. From Table 9, we can see that the production rate and the optimal production quantity are less than those of hybrid production (Table 5). Table 9 also shows that the production rate is identical to (greater than) that associated with the regular production option in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) though the optimal production quantity is greater than that of the regular production option for both the first and subsequent cycles (Table 8). The total cost per month is W E s 1 = U S D   7108.19 in the first cycle and W E s s = U S D   8491.07 in the subsequent cycles, which can be attributed to the fact that the system earns revenue by selling excess quota. This revenue is set equal to E v E c E s 1 = 2 400 200.8 = 2 199.2 = U S D   398.4 for the first cycle and E v E c E s s = 2 400 204.63 = 2 159.37 = U S D   390.74 for subsequent cycles due to the dramatic decrease in GHG emissions generated by the green production. The GHG emissions related to storage and transportation activities are negligible in the first and subsequent cycles. Figure 9, Figure 10, Figure 11 and Figure 12 show and compare the effect on the optimal production quantity, production rate, GHG emissions, and the minimum total cost per month with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production options.

5.6. Example 6

In this example, we compare our model for the regular production scenario with the existing literature; in particular, the models of Jaber et al. [36] and Bazan et al. [38], since they have been extensively adopted by many researchers in the field. Therefore, only the input parameters that were considered by [36,38] have been addressed for comparison purposes and the rest of the values have been omitted from our regular model. The input parameters, as that of Example 3 (page 76) in Jaber et al. [36], are as follows: E v r = 18 , E c = 220 ,   a r = 0.0000003 ,   b r = 0.0012 , c r = 1.4 , S b = 400 , S r = 1200 , d = 1000 , h r = 60 ,   a n d   h b = 30 . Table 10 represents a CO2 emissions penalties scheme similar to that suggested by Jaber et al. [36].
The per unit time total cost functions that are presented for comparison purposes are, respectively, provided by the following:
W s 1 = 2 d λ S b + S r h b d 2 p 2 2 d p + λ + h r 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ λ + E v r a r p 2 b r p + c r d + i = 1 k Y i E p i
W s s = 2 d λ S b + S r h b + h r d p + λ 1 1 d p λ + E v r a r p 2 b r p + c r d + i = 1 k Y i E p i
W J = W B = 2 d λ S b + S r h r 1 d p + 1 λ + h b λ + E v r a r p 2 b r p + c r d + i = 1 k Y i E p i
Equation (25) represents the model of regular production in the first cycle, which is a modified version of Equation (23). In this comparison, the lead time t l = 0 as this time is not considered by Jaber et al. [36] and Bazan et al. [38]. Similarly, Equation (26) represents the model of regular production in the subsequent cycles, which is a modified version of Equation (24). Equation (27) represents the models of Jaber et al. [36] and Bazan et al. [38]. It is clear to deduce that only the first term of Equations (25)–(27) affects the optimal production quantity. In addition, the first term of Equations (25) and (26) is identical with that of Alamri [57], from which we conclude that the work of Alamri [57] constitutes a special case of our proposed model.
Now, by implementing the values determined above in Equations (25)–(27), we obtain the following results:
The per unit time total minimum cost generated by Equation (27) is W J = W B = U S D   20,289.54 with a production rate equal to p J =   p B = 1741.8 when λ J = λ B = 3 . The amount of GHG emissions generated is E J = E B = 220   t o n   C O 2 . Therefore, no penalty charge is imposed, though the emissions tax is U S D   3960 . These results are identical with that of Jaber et al. [36] and Bazan et al. [38]. The per unit time total minimum cost generated by Equation (25) is W s 1 = U S D   13,474.21 . The optimal production rate quals to p 1 = 2000 when λ 1 = 2 . The amount of GHG emissions generated by our regular production model is E r 1 = 200   t o n   C O 2 . Similarly, no penalty charge is imposed, though the emissions tax is U S D   3600 . Note that the production rate that minimizes the emissions production function is that of p r = b r 2 a r = 2000 = p 1 (recall Example 2). The optimal production quantity is q 1 = 202.55 , from which p 1 T 1 0 = 2000 × 202.55 / 1000 = 2 d T 1 = 2 q 1 = 405.1 . For subsequent cycles, the minimum total cost generated by Equation (26) is W s 1 = U S D   17,016.41 with an optimal production rate equal to p s = 2000 when λ s = 2 and q s = 149.07 . The amount of GHG emissions is identical with that of the first cycle, i.e., E r s = 200   t o n   C O 2 with no penalty charge is imposed and the system incurs an emissions tax of U S D   3600 . As that of the first cycle, the production rate that minimizes the emissions production function is that of p r = b r 2 a r = 2000 = p s .
As illustrated above, our model produces optimal values associated with substantial cost savings. That is, in the first cycle the cost generated by our model is less than that of Jaber et al. [36] and Bazan et al. [38] by 33.59 %   20,289.54 13,474.21 20,289.54 × 100 = 33.59 . For subsequent cycles, Equation (26) produces optimal values associated with a cost less than that of Jaber et al. [36] and Bazan et al. [38] by 16.13 %   20,289.54 17,016.41 20,289.54 × 100 = 16.13 . This, indeed, constitutes a considerable saving and may interest both practitioners and researchers. Therefore, our model achieves three main features: (1) It produces optimal results associated with lower minimum total system cost; (2) In the first cycle, the buyer’s initial on-hand inventory is zero, which reflects real-life settings and implies that the subsequent cycle is independent from the first one. Moreover, each subsequent cycle can be associated with its distinct input parameters to ensure that it is independent from the previous one (see also Example 2). This is key in the mathematical formulation, which implies that the input parameters can be adjusted for subsequent cycles; (3) The optimal production rate generated by our model is the one that minimizes the emissions production function. That is, the model generates the lowest emissions possible when compared with the existing literature.

6. Summary of Implications and Managerial Insights

  • Unlike the classical JELS inventory model that generates an equal production quantity in all cycles, the proposed model distinguishes the first cycle from subsequent cycles.
  • Two mathematical models that reflect the behavior of the first and subsequent cycles are developed. The first model derives distinct optimal results associated with the first cycle, while the other generates distinct optimal results for subsequent cycles.
  • In the first time interval, the initial on-hand inventory is zero at the buyer’s warehouse since no items have been produced yet.
  • Each subsequent cycle can be associated with its distinct input parameters to ensure that it is independent from the previous one.
  • The proposed model allows for the adjustment of the input parameters for any subsequent cycle.
  • The model remains viable for subsequent cycles and keeps generating optimal results subject to the desired adjustment of any model parameter as a response to the dynamic nature of demand rate and/or price fluctuation. Such adjustment may also reflect situations such as implementing an alternative policy resulting from acquiring new knowledge, periodic review applications, or machine maintenance scheduling activities that may oblige a decision maker to consider a suitable adjustment of any model parameter.
  • The developed model accounts for a hybrid production system in its mathematical formulation that simultaneously focuses on green and regular production methods with an optimal allocation fraction of green and regular productions.
  • The proposed model considers a mixed transportation policy in its mathematical formulation, which enables a decision maker to combine TL and LTL services to reduce transportation cost.
  • The demand is satisfied from a collection of green and regular produced items.
  • The proposed model enables a decision maker to trade-off between the production cost and emissions. In this regard, the trade-off is very much related to the emissions penalties for exceeding allowable limits and the unit production cost for green items.
  • For subsequent cycles, the production process starts at the time needed for the first lot to be produced and delivered. This, indeed, benefits the vendor by not keeping items for extra time related to the consumption of the last lot at the buyer’s warehouse that has been delivered from previous cycle, which implies further cost reduction.
  • Emissions are released from production and storage activities related to green and regular produced items along with transportation activity.
  • The carbon emissions are relatively associated with carbon taxes and penalties for exceeding the allowable emissions limits. However, the system reaps further cost reduction by selling excess quota in the case that the total emissions are less than that of the emission cap, which reflects the cap-and-trade policy.
  • The base closed-form formula of our model generates optimal values with considerable total system cost reduction, i.e., 33.59% (16.13%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) when compared with the existing literature.
  • The optimal production rate generated by the proposed model is the one that minimizes the emissions production function. That is, it generates the lowest emissions possible when compared with the existing literature.
  • Adopting a hybrid production method decreases the GHG emissions dramatically, which in turn reduces the minimum total cost per unit time by 38.16% (32.25%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) when compared with regular production.
  • Adopting a pure green production method decreases the GHG emissions dramatically, which in turn reduces the minimum total cost per unit time by 33.34% (27.41%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) when compared with hybrid production. Such savings increase by 58.78% (50.82%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) when compared with regular production.
  • The total amount of GHG emissions emitted by the system increases (decreases) with demand rate.

7. Conclusions and Further Research

This study developed a VMI model for a JELS policy under a multi-level emission-taxing scheme. Two mathematical formulations that reflect the behavior of the first and subsequent cycles are developed. This implies that each model generates a distinct optimal solution coupled with a distinct fixed multiplier, which guarantees that cycles do not depend on each other. Therefore, the model remains viable for subsequent cycles and keeps generating optimal results subject to the desired adjustment of the input parameters. Such adjustment appears as responsive to the real-life settings that may reflect situations such as the dynamic nature of demand rate, related issues associated with price fluctuation, implementing of an alternative policy resulting from acquiring new knowledge, periodic review applications, or machine maintenance scheduling activities. Therefore, the proposed model enables a decision maker to consider a suitable adjustment of the input parameters when such situations occurred.
This study investigated the effect of carbon emissions together with the implementation of green technology for a hybrid production system. The developed model simultaneously focuses on green and regular production methods with an optimal allocation fraction of green and regular productions. In this model, emissions are released from production and storage activities related to green and regular produced items along with transportation activity. The carbon emissions are relatively associated with carbon taxes and penalties for exceeding the allowable emissions limits. However, the proposed model assumes that the system reaps further cost reduction by selling excess quota in the case that the total emissions are less than that of the emission cap, which reflects the cap-and-trade policy. Hybrid production implies simultaneous production fractions associated with green and regular productions, where each is associated with its distinct released emissions level. In this case, the demand is satisfied from a collection of green and regular produced items.
This study enables a decision maker to trade-off between the production cost and emissions, where the trade-off is very much related to the emissions penalties for exceeding allowable limits and the unit production cost for green items. For subsequent cycles, the production process starts at the time needed for the first lot to be produced and delivered, i.e., it benefits the vendor by not keeping items for extra time related to the consumption of the last lot at the buyer’s warehouse that has been delivered from previous cycle, which implies further cost reduction. In addition, the proposed model considers a mixed transportation policy in its mathematical formulation, which enables decision-maker to reap further cost reductions by combining TL and LTL services.
Illustrative examples emphasized the significant impact of the first cycle on the optimal results, i.e., the first cycle is associated with distinct optimal values. The viability, validity, and robustness of the proposed model are ascertained where the optimal values are divergent for the case that the input parameters are adjusted. Sensitivity analysis is evaluated in different realistic situations to highlight some important opportunities that may interest decision makers. The results emphasized the significant impact of the demand rate on the GHG emissions emitted by the system, which increases (decreases) with demand rate. The results also emphasized the significant impact of green production on emissions. That is, the higher the allocation fraction of green production, the lower the total amount of emissions generated by the system, i.e., the system becomes more sustainable. It is worth noting here that the total system cost generated by the base closed-form formula of the proposed model is considerably lower in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) than that of the existing literature, i.e., 33.59% (16.13%) when the regular production method is assumed, which represents one of the main findings of this study. Moreover, the optimal production rate generated by the proposed model is the one that minimizes the emissions production function. That is, it generates the lowest emissions possible when compared with the existing literature. Adopting a hybrid production method not only decreases the GHG emissions dramatically, but also reduces the minimum total cost per unit time by 38.16% (32.25%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) when compared with regular production. Moreover, adopting a pure green production method decreases the GHG emissions dramatically, which in turn reduces the minimum total cost per unit time by 33.34% (27.41%) and by 58.78% (50.82%) in the first cycle (subsequent cycles) when compared with hybrid production and regular production, respectively.
Further research may include the formulation of imperfect-quality items in the production process where each lot size is subjected to a 100 per cent inspection. Extending the model accounting for general functions of time of demand and deterioration rates is another interesting line of further research. Further inquiry related to this research may include the formulation of a closed-loop supply chain model involving manufacturing, remanufacturing, and transportation under GHG emissions. Furthermore, it seems plausible to consider the formulation of single-vendor multi-buyers inventory mathematical modeling, taking into account different emissions trading schemes. Finally, the proposed mathematical formulation can be implemented to rectify existing VMI systems as well as the consideration of further inquiry related to VMI mathematical modeling.

Funding

Funding is provided by the Deanship of Scientific Research at Majmaah University under Project Number (R-2023-865).

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank Deanship of Scientific Research at Majmaah University for supporting this work under Project Number (R-2023-865). The author is also would like to thank editor-in-chief, guest-editor, and assistance editor for their support and the anonymous reviewers for their valuable remarks and constructive comments that improved the content of the paper and its presentation.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Below, we formulate the average inventory functions related to a hybrid joint model.

Appendix A.1. First Cycle (Figure 1)

Appendix A.1.1. Buyer’s Average Inventory Function

As can be seen from Figure 1, the vendor delivers the first lot size q 1 = d T 1 once it has been accumulated from green and regular produced items by time t 1 and, will reach the buyer after a transportation time t l .
It is worth noting here that shortages are allowed in the first period of the first cycle and fully backordered by time t 1 + t l . In this case, the maximum inventory level for the buyer is T 1 t 1 t l d units, where T 1 t 1 t l = q 1 d q 1 p t l .
In the first period, the buyer’s average inventory function is provided by the following:
q 1 2 2 1 d p d t l q 1 1 d 1 p t l q 1 = q 1 2 2 1 d 2 p 2 t l q 1 + d p 2 + 2 d t l p q 1 + d t l 2 q 1 2 .
Figure 1 indicates that the buyer’s initial inventory level is zero and the last lot produced by the vendor represents the last lot consumed by the buyer. Therefore, we have
T s 1 = λ T 1 = λ q 1 d .
From Equation (A1) and Figure 1, the average inventory function for the remaining lots is provided by the following:
λ 1 q 1 2 2 d .
Therefore, the buyer average inventory function is provided by the following:
q 1 2 2 d p 2 2 p + λ d + q 1 2 2 d t l p 2 t l + d t l 2 2 .
From which, the holding cost function per unit time is provided by the following:
h b q 1 d 2 λ d p 2 2 p + λ d + h b 2 λ 2 d 2 t l p 2 d t l + h b d 2 t l 2 2 λ q 1 .
Note that Equation (A2) is identical with that of Alamri [57].

Appendix A.1.2. Vendor’s Average Inventory Function

From Figure 1, the average inventory function associated with green production can be found as follows:
λ = 1 ζ q 1 2 q 1 p = ζ q 1 2 2 p .
λ = 2 ζ q 1 2 q 1 p + ζ q 1 2 q 1 p + ζ q 1 q 1 d 2 q 1 p t l .
λ = 3 ζ q 1 2 q 1 p + ζ q 1 2 q 1 p + ζ q 1 q 1 d 2 q 1 p t l + ζ q 1 2 q 1 p + ζ q 1 2 q 1 d 3 q 1 p t l .
λ = λ ζ q 1 2 2 2 p + λ 2 1 d 1 p λ d ζ q 1 λ 1 t l
Therefore, the per unit time holding cost function for green production is provided by the following:
h g ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ h g ζ λ 1 d t l λ .
Similarly, the per unit time holding cost function for regular production is provided by the following:
h r 1 ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ h r 1 ζ λ 1 d t l λ
Note that for ζ = 0 , Equations (A4) and (A5) reduce to that of Alamri [57].

Appendix A.2. Subsequent Cycles (Figure 2)

Appendix A.2.1. Buyer’s Average Inventory Function

As can be seen from Figure 2, the average inventory function for the buyer is that of the EOQ. Therefore, the per unit time holding cost function is provided by the following:
h b q s 2 .

Appendix A.2.2. Vendor’s Average Inventory Function

From Figure 2, the average inventory function associated with green production can be found as follows:
λ = 1 ζ q s 2 q s p = ζ q s 2 2 p .
λ = 2 ζ q s 2 q s p + ζ q 1 2 q s p + ζ q s q s d q s p .
λ = 3 ζ q s 2 q s p + ζ q s 2 q s p + ζ q s q s d q s p + ζ q s 2 q s p + ζ q s 2 q s d 2 q s p .
λ = λ λ ζ q s 2 2 d d p + λ 1 1 d p .
Therefore, the per unit time holding cost function for green production is provided by the following:
h g ζ q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p .
Similarly, the per unit time holding cost function for regular production is provided by the following:
h g 1 ζ q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p .
Note that for ζ = 0 , Equations (A7) and (A8) reduce to that of Alamri [57].

Appendix B

Below we derive the solution procedure that renders W E S 1 W E S S as achieving the unique and global optimal solution.

Solution Procedure

According to Alamri [57], the physical transportation costs can be ignored with no effect on the optimal production quantity; therefore, Equations (16) and (18) can be rewritten as follows:
W E s 1 ,   m i n = S b d q 1 + c 1 d λ q 1 + c 2 d 2 λ d t l 2 q 1 + q 1 d p 2 2 p + λ d + 2 d t l p 2 t l + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 λ 1 d t l λ + c 5 d T f f e q 1 + T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s 1 .
W E s s , m i n = S b d q s + c 1 d λ q s + c 2 q s 2 + c 3 ζ q s + c 4 1 ζ q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p + c 5 d T f f e q s + T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s s .
Any existing solution of W E s 1 ,   m i n ( W E s s , m i n ) is a minimizing solution to W E S 1 W E S S if its Hessian matrix H s 1 ( H s s ) is positive definite calculated at any critical point q k , λ k   , p k , ζ k of H s 1 ( H s s ) provided by Equations (A11) and (A12) below:
H s 1 = 2 W E s 1 2 q 1 2 W E s 1 q 1 λ 2 W E s 1 q 1 p 2 W E s 1 q 1 ζ 2 W E s 1 λ q 1 2 W E s 1 2 λ 2 W E s 1 λ p 2 W E s 1 λ ζ 2 W E s 1 p q 1 2 W E s 1 ζ q 1 2 W E s 1 p λ 2 W E s 1 ζ λ 2 W E s 1 2 p 2 W E s 1 ζ p 2 W E s 1 p ζ 2 W E s 1 2 ζ ,
H s s = 2 W E s s 2 q s 2 W E s s q s λ 2 W E s s q s p 2 W E s s q s ζ 2 W E s s λ q s 2 W E s s 2 λ 2 W E s s λ p 2 W E s s λ ζ 2 W E s s p q s 2 W E s s ζ q s 2 W E s s p λ 2 W E s s ζ λ 2 W E s s 2 p 2 W E s s ζ p 2 W E s s p ζ 2 W E s s 2 ζ ,
where
2 W E s 1 2 q 1 = 2 S b d q 1 3 + 2 c 1 d λ q 1 3 + c 2 d 2 t l 2 λ q 1 3 + 2 c 5 d T f f e q 1 3 .
2 W E s 1 2 p = c 2 d λ 3 q 1 d p 7 + 2 d t l p 3 2 q 1 p 3 + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 d 2 λ 4 p 3 2 λ 2 p 3 + 2 E m g d p 3 + 2 E m r d p 3 + 2 E v g a g ζ 3 d + 2 E v r a r 1 ζ 3 d .
2 W E s 1 2 λ = 2 c 1 d λ 3 q 1 + c 2 d λ 3 d t l 2 q 1 + q 1 d p 2 2 p + 2 d t l p 2 t l + 2 c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 d λ 3 p + 2 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 d t l λ 3 .
2 W E s 1 2 ζ = 2 d p E p g + E p r + 2 E v g d p 3 a g ζ p b g + 2 E v r d p 3 a r 1 ζ p b r .
2 W E s 1 q 1 p = 2 W E s 1 p q 1 = c 2 d λ 1 p 2 d p 3 + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d 2 λ λ 2 p 2 2 p 2 .
2 W E s 1 q 1 λ = 2 W E s 1 λ q 1 = c 1 d λ 2 q 1 2 + c 2 d 2 λ 2 d t l 2 q 1 2 d p 2 2 p c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d λ 2 p + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 1 d p .
2 W E s 1 q 1 ζ = 2 W E s 1 ζ q 1 = c 3 c 4 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ .
2 W E s 1 p λ = 2 W E s 1 λ p = c 2 d λ 2 q 1 p 2 q 1 d p 3 d t l p 2 + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 d 2 p 2 + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 d p 2 λ 2 .
2 W E s 1 p ζ = 2 W E s 1 ζ p = c 3 q 1 c 4 q 1 d 2 λ λ 2 p 2 2 p 2 + 2 d E p g ζ E p r 1 ζ + 2 E v g d 3 a g ζ 2 p b g ζ 2 E v r d 3 1 ζ 2 p b r 1 ζ .
2 W E s 1 λ ζ = 2 W E S 1 ζ λ = c 3 q 1 c 4 q 1 d λ 2 p + c 3 q 1 c 4 q 1 2 1 d p c 3 c 4 d t l λ 2 .
Equation A 13 > 0 ; if only the first two terms of Equation (A14) are considered, then Equation A 14 > 0 if λ = 1 . Recall that p 1 > d and c 1 c 2 , then Equation A 15 > 0 . Note that 3 a g ζ p b g > 0 and 3 a r 1 ζ p b r > 0 , from which Equation A 16 > 0 .
Similarly, for H s s we have
2 W E s s 2 q s = 2 S b d q s 3 + 2 c 1 d λ q s 3 + 2 c 5 d T f f e q s 3 .
2 W E s s 2 p = c 3 ζ q s + c 4 1 ζ q s d 2 2 p 3 2 λ 1 p 3 + 2 E m g d p 3 + 2 E m r d p 3 + 2 E v g a g ζ 3 d + 2 E v r a r 1 ζ 3 d .
2 W E s s 2 λ = 2 c 1 d λ 3 q s .
2 W E s s 2 ζ = 2 d p E p g + E p r + 2 E v g d p 3 a g ζ p b g + 2 E v r d p 3 a r 1 ζ p b r .
2 W E s s q s p = 2 W E s s p q s = c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d 2 λ 1 p 2 1 p 2 .
2 W E s s q s λ = 2 W E s s λ q s = c 1 d λ 2 q s 2 + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 1 d p .
2 W E s s q s ζ = 2 W E s s ζ q s = c 3 c 4 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p .
2 W E s s p λ = 2 W E s s λ p = c 3 ζ q s + c 4 1 ζ q s d 2 p 2 .
2 W E s s p ζ = 2 W E s s ζ p = c 3 q s c 4 q s d 2 λ 1 p 2 1 p 2 + 2 d E p g ζ E p r 1 ζ + 2 E v g d 3 a g ζ 2 p b g ζ 2 E v r d 3 a r 1 ζ 2 p b r 1 ζ .
2 W E S s λ ζ = 2 W E S s ζ λ = c 3 q s c 4 q s 2 1 d p .
Equations A 23   a n d   ( A 25 ) > 0 ; if only the first term of Equation ( A 24 ) is considered, then Equation A 24 > 0 if λ = 1 . Recall that 3 a g ζ p b g > 0 and 3 a r 1 ζ p b r > 0 , from which Equation A 26 > 0 .
Moreover, by Stewart [66], Balkhi and Benkherouf [67], Emet [68], and Alamri [69], the symmetric matrix H s 1 ( H s s ) is positive definite if
2 W E s 1 2 q 1 > 2 W E s 1 q 1 λ + 2 W E s 1 q 1 p + 2 W E s 1 q 1 ζ ,
2 W E s 1 2 λ > 2 W E s 1 λ q 1 + 2 W E s 1 λ p + 2 W E s 1 λ ζ ,
2 W E s 1 2 p > 2 W E s 1 p q 1 + 2 W E s 1 p λ + 2 W E s 1 p ζ ,
2 W E s 1 2 ζ > 2 W E s 1 ζ q 1 + 2 W E s 1 ζ λ + 2 W E s 1 ζ p ,
Similarly,
2 W E s s 2 q s > 2 W E s s q s λ + 2 W E s s q s p + 2 W E s s q s ζ ,
2 W E s s 2 λ > 2 W E s s λ q s + 2 W E s s λ p + 2 W E s s λ ζ ,
2 W E s s 2 p > 2 W E s s p q s + 2 W E s s p λ + 2 W E s s p ζ ,
2 W E s s 2 ζ > 2 W E s s ζ q s + 2 W E s s ζ λ + 2 W E s s ζ p ,
Therefore, if conditions (A33)–(A36) ((A37)–(A40)) hold, then they constitute the sufficient conditions under which the Hessian matrix H s 1 ( H s s ) is positive definite.
Thus, any existing solution of W E s 1 ,   m i n ( W E s s ,   m i n ) for which conditions (A33)–(A36) ((A37)–(A40)) hold is the unique and global optimal solution to W E S 1 W E S S .
The necessary conditions for the minimum cost for W E s 1 ,   m i n are as follows:
W E s 1 q 1 = S b d q 1 2 c 1 d λ q 1 2 c 2 d 2 t l 2 2 λ q 1 2 + c 2 d 2 λ d p 2 2 p + λ d + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ c 5 d T f f e q 1 2 = 0 .
W E s 1 p = c 2 d λ q 1 p 2 q 1 d p 3 d t l p 2 + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 d 2 λ λ 2 p 2 2 p 2 + E p g ζ 2 E m g p 2 d + E p r 1 ζ 2 E m r p 2 d + E v g 2 a g ζ 2 p b g ζ ζ d + E v r 2 a r 1 ζ 2 p b r 1 ζ 1 ζ d = 0 .
W E s 1 λ = c 1 d λ 2 q 1 c 2 d 2 λ 2 d t l 2 q 1 + q 1 d p 2 2 p + 2 d t l p 2 t l c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 d λ 2 p + c 3 ζ q 1 + c 4 1 ζ q 1 2 1 d p ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 d t l λ 2 = 0 .
W E s 1 ζ = c 3 q 1 c 4 q 1 2 λ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ c 3 c 4 λ 1 d t l λ + 2 d E p g ζ p 2 d E p r 1 ζ p + E v g d 2 a g ζ p 2 b g p ζ + a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g E v r d 2 a r 1 ζ p 2 b r p 1 ζ + a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r = 0 .
Similarly, the necessary conditions for the minimum cost for W E s s , m i n are as follows:
W E s s q s = S b d q s 2 c 1 d λ q s 2 + c 2 2 + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p c 5 d T f f e q s 2 = 0 .
W E s s p = c 3 ζ q s + c 4 1 ζ q s d 2 λ 1 p 2 1 p 2 + E p g ζ 2 E m g p 2 d + E p r 1 ζ 2 E m r p 2 d + E v g 2 a g ζ 2 p b g ζ ζ d + E v r 2 a r 1 ζ 2 p b r 1 ζ 1 ζ d = 0 .
W E s s λ = c 1 d λ 2 q s + c 3 ζ q s + c 4 1 ζ q s 2 1 d p = 0
W E s s ζ = c 3 q s c 4 q s 2 d p + λ 1 1 d p + 2 d E p g ζ p 2 d E p r 1 ζ p + E v g d 2 a g ζ p 2 b g p ζ + a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g E v r d 2 a r 1 ζ p 2 b r p 1 ζ + a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r = 0 .
From which we have
W E s 1 q 1 = 0 q 1 = d 2 λ S b + c 5 T f f e + 2 c 1 + c 2 d t l 2 c 2 d 2 p 2 2 d p + λ + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ .
W E s s q s = 0 q s = 2 d λ S b + c 5 T f f e + c 1 λ c 2 + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d p + λ 1 1 d p .
Hence, from Equations (A49) and (A50), W E s 1 ,   m i n and W E s 1 ,   m i n are, respectively, provided by Equations (A51) and (A52) below:
W E s 1 ,   m i n = d 2 λ S b + c 5 T f f e + 2 c 1 + c 2 d t l 2 c 2 d 2 p 2 2 d p + λ + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 2 d p + λ 2 1 d p λ λ + c 2 2 λ 2 d 2 t l p 2 d t l 1 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 λ 1 d t l λ + c 5 d T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s 1 .
W E s s ,   m i n = 2 d λ S b + c 5 T f f e + c 1 c 2 + c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d p + λ 1 1 d p λ + c 5 d T v T w f + E m g p + E p g ζ 2 p d + E m r p + E p r 1 ζ 2 p d + E v g a g ζ 2 p 2 b g ζ p + c g ζ d + E v r a r 1 ζ 2 p 2 b r 1 ζ p + c r 1 ζ d + i = 1 k Y i E p i + E v α E c E s s .
Now, considering the first partial derivative of Equations (A51) and (A52) with respect to λ = 0 provides the lower and upper values of λ . Note that infeasible values of λ are ignored. Thus, we have
λ = b ± b 2 4 a c 2 a , where,
a = 6 d S b + c 5 T f f e c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ 1 d p .
b = 2 2 d S b + c 5 T f f e c 2 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 + ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 2 d 2 t l 2 + d ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 2 c 1 + c 2 d t l 2 1 d p .
c = 2 d S b + c 5 T f f e c 2 d 2 p 2 2 c 2 d p + 2 c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ d p + d 2 c 1 + c 2 d t l 2 c 2 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 2 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 2 d 2 t l 2 2 c 2 d 2 t l p 2 c 2 d t l 1 ζ c 3 + 1 ζ c 4 d t l .
for the first cycle, and
λ = ± c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ S b + c 5 T f f e c 1 d p 2 d c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ + c 2 c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ p c 3 ζ + c 4 1 ζ S b + c 5 T f f e d p .
for the subsequent cycles.

References

  1. Wang, X.J.; Choi, S.H. Impacts of Carbon Emission Reduction Mechanisms on Uncertain Make-To-Order Manufacturing. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016, 54, 3311–3328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Benjaafar, S.; Li, Y.; Daskin, M. Carbon Footprint and the Management of Supply Chains: Insights from Simple Models. IEEE Trans. Autom. Sci. Eng. 2012, 10, 99–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Pachauri, R.K.; Reisinger, A. Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report. Contribution of Working Groups I, II and III to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Climate Change 2007. Working Groups I, II and III to the Fourth Assessment 2007. Available online: https://www.ipcc.ch/site/assets/uploads/2018/02/ar4_syr_full_report.pdf (accessed on 12 August 2023).
  4. EPA. Carbon Pollution from Transportation. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. 2022. Available online: https://www.epa.gov/transportation-air-pollution-and-climate-change/carbon-pollution-transportation#transportation (accessed on 12 August 2023).
  5. Damert, M.; Feng, Y.; Zhu, Q.; Baumgartner, R.J. Motivating Low-Carbon Initiatives among Suppliers: The Role of Risk and Opportunity Perception. Resour Conserv. Recycl. 2018, 136, 276–286. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Das, C.; Jharkharia, S. Low Carbon Supply Chain: A State-of-the-Art Literature Review. J. Manuf. Technol. Manag. 2018, 29, 398–428. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Phouratsamay, S.-L.; Cheng, T.C.E. The Single-Item Lot-Sizing Problem with Two Production Modes, Inventory Bounds, and Periodic Carbon Emissions Capacity. Oper. Res. Lett. 2019, 47, 339–343. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gong, X.; Zhou, S.X. Optimal Production Planning with Emissions Trading. Oper. Res. 2013, 61, 908–924. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hong, Z.; Chu, C.; Yu, Y. Dual-Mode Production Planning for Manufacturing with Emission Constraints. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 251, 96–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Utama, D.M.; Santoso, I.; Hendrawan, Y.; Dania, W.A.P. Integrated Procurement-Production Inventory Model in Supply Chain: A Systematic Review. Oper. Res. Perspect. 2022, 9, 100221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Devy, N.L.; Ai, T.J.; Astanti, R.D. A Joint Replenishment Inventory Model with Lost Sales. In Proceedings of the IOP Conference Series: Materials Science and Engineering; IOP Publishing: Bristol, UK, 2018; Volume 337, p. 12018. [Google Scholar]
  12. Dong, Y.; Xu, K. A Supply Chain Model of Vendor Managed Inventory. Transp. Res. E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2002, 38, 75–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Banerjee, A. A Joint Economic-lot-size Model for Purchaser and Vendor. Decis. Sci. 1986, 17, 292–311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Schaefer, B.; Konur, D. Economic and Environmental Considerations in a Continuous Review Inventory Control System with Integrated Transportation Decisions. Transp. Res. E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2015, 80, 142–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Hovelaque, V.; Bironneau, L. The Carbon-Constrained EOQ Model with Carbon Emission Dependent Demand. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 164, 285–291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Bouchery, Y.; Ghaffari, A.; Jemai, Z.; Dallery, Y. Including Sustainability Criteria into Inventory Models. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2012, 222, 229–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Gunasekaran, A.; Irani, Z.; Papadopoulos, T. Modelling and Analysis of Sustainable Operations Management: Certain Investigations for Research and Applications. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2014, 65, 806–823. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Taleizadeh, A.A.; Soleymanfar, V.R.; Govindan, K. Sustainable Economic Production Quantity Models for Inventory Systems with Shortage. J. Clean Prod. 2018, 174, 1011–1020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Montabon, F.; Pagell, M.; Wu, Z. Making Sustainability Sustainable. J. Supply Chain. Manag. 2016, 52, 11–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Goyal, S.K. An Integrated Inventory Model for a Single Supplier-Single Customer Problem. Int. J. Prod. Res. 1977, 15, 107–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wahab, M.I.M.; Mamun, S.M.H.; Ongkunaruk, P. EOQ Models for a Coordinated Two-Level International Supply Chain Considering Imperfect Items and Environmental Impact. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 134, 151–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Hua, G.; Cheng, T.C.E.; Wang, S. Managing Carbon Footprints in Inventory Management. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 132, 178–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Wangsa, I. Greenhouse Gas Penalty and Incentive Policies for a Joint Economic Lot Size Model with Industrial and Transport Emissions. Int. J. Ind. Eng. Comput. 2017, 8, 453–480. [Google Scholar]
  24. Ben-Daya, M.; Hariga, M. Integrated Single Vendor Single Buyer Model with Stochastic Demand and Variable Lead Time. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2004, 92, 75–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Hariga, M.; As’ad, R.; Shamayleh, A. Integrated Economic and Environmental Models for a Multi Stage Cold Supply Chain under Carbon Tax Regulation. J. Clean Prod. 2017, 166, 1357–1371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Gautam, P.; Kishore, A.; Khanna, A.; Jaggi, C.K. Strategic Defect Management for a Sustainable Green Supply Chain. J. Clean Prod. 2019, 233, 226–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Halat, K.; Hafezalkotob, A. Modeling Carbon Regulation Policies in Inventory Decisions of a Multi-Stage Green Supply Chain: A Game Theory Approach. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2019, 128, 807–830. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Khouja, M.; Mehrez, A. An Economic Production Lot Size Model with Imperfect Quality and Variable Production Rate. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 1994, 45, 1405–1417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Eiamkanchanalai, S.; Banerjee, A. Production Lot Sizing with Variable Production Rate and Explicit Idle Capacity Cost. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 1999, 59, 251–259. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Ghosh, A.; Jha, J.K.; Sarmah, S.P. Optimal Lot-Sizing under Strict Carbon Cap Policy Considering Stochastic Demand. Appl. Math Model. 2017, 44, 688–704. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Saga, R.S.; Jauhari, W.A.; Laksono, P.W.; Dwicahyani, A.R. Investigating Carbon Emissions in a Production-Inventory Model under Imperfect Production, Inspection Errors and Service-Level Constraint. Int. J. Logist. Syst. Manag. 2019, 34, 29–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Huang, Y.-S.; Fang, C.-C.; Lin, Y.-A. Inventory Management in Supply Chains with Consideration of Logistics, Green Investment and Different Carbon Emissions Policies. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2020, 139, 106207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Chen, X.; Benjaafar, S.; Elomri, A. The Carbon-Constrained EOQ. Oper. Res. Lett. 2013, 41, 172–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ganesh Kumar, M.; Uthayakumar, R. Modelling on Vendor-Managed Inventory Policies with Equal and Unequal Shipments under GHG Emission-Trading Scheme. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2019, 57, 3362–3381. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Zanoni, S.; Mazzoldi, L.; Jaber, M.Y. Vendor-Managed Inventory with Consignment Stock Agreement for Single Vendor–Single Buyer under the Emission-Trading Scheme. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2014, 52, 20–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Jaber, M.Y.; Glock, C.H.; El Saadany, A.M.A. Supply Chain Coordination with Emissions Reduction Incentives. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2013, 51, 69–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Turken, N.; Geda, A.; Takasi, V.D.G. The Impact of Co-Location in Emissions Regulation Clusters on Traditional and Vendor Managed Supply Chain Inventory Decisions. Ann. Oper. Res. 2021, 1–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Bazan, E.; Jaber, M.Y.; Zanoni, S. Supply Chain Models with Greenhouse Gases Emissions, Energy Usage and Different Coordination Decisions. Appl. Math Model 2015, 39, 5131–5151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Astanti, R.D.; Daryanto, Y.; Dewa, P.K. Low-Carbon Supply Chain Model under a Vendor-Managed Inventory Partnership and Carbon Cap-and-Trade Policy. J. Open Innov. Technol. Mark. Complex. 2022, 8, 30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Malik, A.I.; Kim, B.S. A Constrained Production System Involving Production Flexibility and Carbon Emissions. Mathematics 2020, 8, 275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Jauhari, W.A.; Pujawan, I.N.; Suef, M.; Govindan, K. Low Carbon Inventory Model for Vendor-buyer System with Hybrid Production and Adjustable Production Rate under Stochastic Demand. Appl. Math Model 2022, 108, 840–868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Sarkar, B.; Saren, S. Product Inspection Policy for an Imperfect Production System with Inspection Errors and Warranty Cost. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 248, 263–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Rad, M.A.; Khoshalhan, F.; Glock, C.H. Optimal Production and Distribution Policies for a Two-Stage Supply Chain with Imperfect Items and Price-and Advertisement-Sensitive Demand: A Note. Appl. Math Model 2018, 57, 625–632. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Kim, M.-S.; Kim, J.-S.; Sarkar, B.; Sarkar, M.; Iqbal, M.W. An Improved Way to Calculate Imperfect Items during Long-Run Production in an Integrated Inventory Model with Backorders. J. Manuf. Syst. 2018, 47, 153–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. De Giovanni, P.; Karray, S.; Martín-Herrán, G. Vendor Management Inventory with Consignment Contracts and the Benefits of Cooperative Advertising. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 272, 465–480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Phan, D.A.; Vo, T.L.H.; Lai, A.N.; Nguyen, T.L.A. Coordinating Contracts for VMI Systems under Manufacturer-CSR and Retailer-Marketing Efforts. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 211, 98–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Ben-Daya, M.; As’ad, R.; Nabi, K.A. A Single-Vendor Multi-Buyer Production Remanufacturing Inventory System under a Centralized Consignment Arrangement. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2019, 135, 10–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Tarhini, H.; Karam, M.; Jaber, M.Y. An Integrated Single-Vendor Multi-Buyer Production Inventory Model with Transshipments between Buyers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2020, 225, 107568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Dey, O.; Giri, B.C. A New Approach to Deal with Learning in Inspection in an Integrated Vendor-Buyer Model with Imperfect Production Process. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2019, 131, 515–523. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Giri, B.C.; Chakraborty, A.; Maiti, T. Consignment Stock Policy with Unequal Shipments and Process Unreliability for a Two-Level Supply Chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2017, 55, 2489–2505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Jauhari, W.A.; Sofiana, A.; Kurdhi, N.A.; Laksono, P.W. An Integrated Inventory Model for Supplier-Manufacturer-Retailer System with Imperfect Quality and Inspection Errors. Int. J. Logist. Syst. Manag. 2016, 24, 383–407. [Google Scholar]
  52. Khan, M.; Hussain, M.; Cárdenas-Barrón, L.E. Learning and Screening Errors in an EPQ Inventory Model for Supply Chains with Stochastic Lead Time Demands. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2017, 55, 4816–4832. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Pal, S.; Mahapatra, G.S. A Manufacturing-Oriented Supply Chain Model for Imperfect Quality with Inspection Errors, Stochastic Demand under Rework and Shortages. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2017, 106, 299–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Tiwari, S.; Kazemi, N.; Modak, N.M.; Cárdenas-Barrón, L.E.; Sarkar, S. The Effect of Human Errors on an Integrated Stochastic Supply Chain Model with Setup Cost Reduction and Backorder Price Discount. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2020, 226, 107643. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Jaggi, C.K.; Tiwari, S.; Shafi, A.A. Effect of Deterioration on Two-Warehouse Inventory Model with Imperfect Quality. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2015, 88, 378–385. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Alamri, A.A. Carbon Emissions Effect on Vendor-Managed Inventory System Considering Displaced Re-Start-Up Production Time. Logistics 2023, 7, 67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Konur, D. Carbon Constrained Integrated Inventory Control and Truckload Transportation with Heterogeneous Freight Trucks. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 153, 268–279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Bouchery, Y.; Ghaffari, A.; Jemai, Z.; Tan, T. Impact of Coordination on Costs and Carbon Emissions for a Two-Echelon Serial Economic Order Quantity Problem. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 260, 520–533. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Alamri, A.A. A Sustainable Closed-Loop Supply Chains Inventory Model Considering Optimal Number of Remanufacturing Times. Sustainability 2023, 15, 9517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Alamri, A.A. Exploring the Effect of the First Cycle on the Economic Production Quantity Repair and Waste Disposal Model. Appl. Math Model 2021, 89, 519–540. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Lippman, S.A. Economic Order Quantities and Multiple Set-up Costs. Manag. Sci. 1971, 18, 39–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Venkatachalam, S.; Narayanan, A. Efficient Formulation and Heuristics for Multi-Item Single Source Ordering Problem with Transportation Cost. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016, 54, 4087–4103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Kazemi, N.; Abdul-Rashid, S.H.; Ghazilla, R.A.R.; Shekarian, E.; Zanoni, S. Economic Order Quantity Models for Items with Imperfect Quality and Emission Considerations. Int. J. Syst. Sci. Oper. Logist. 2018, 5, 99–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Fandel, G. Production and Cost Theory; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1991; Volume 10, pp. 973–978. [Google Scholar]
  65. Narita, H. Environmental Burden Analyzer for Machine Tool Operations and Its Application. In Manufacturing System; InTech Europe: Rijeka, Croatia, 2012; pp. 247–260. [Google Scholar]
  66. Stewart, G.W. Introduction to Matrix Computations, Computer Science and Applied Mathematics; Academic Press: New York, NY, USA, 1973. [Google Scholar]
  67. Balkhi, Z.T.; Benkherouf, L. A Production Lot Size Inventory Model for Deteriorating Items and Arbitrary Production and Demand Rates. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 1996, 92, 302–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Emet, S. An Mixed Integer Approach for Optimizing Production Planning. In Proceedings of the 13th WSEAS International Conference on Applied Mathematics, Puerto De La Cruz, Spain, 15–17 December 2008; pp. 361–364. [Google Scholar]
  69. Alamri, A.A. Theory and Methodology on the Global Optimal Solution to a General Reverse Logistics Inventory Model for Deteriorating Items and Time-Varying Rates. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2011, 60, 236–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Inventory variation for a coordinated two-echelon supply chain in the first cycle T s 1 .
Figure 1. Inventory variation for a coordinated two-echelon supply chain in the first cycle T s 1 .
Axioms 12 01104 g001
Figure 2. Inventory variation for a coordinated two-echelon supply chain in the subsequent cycles T s s .
Figure 2. Inventory variation for a coordinated two-echelon supply chain in the subsequent cycles T s s .
Axioms 12 01104 g002
Figure 3. Classification of CO2 emissions of the joint hybrid model for the vendor and the buyer.
Figure 3. Classification of CO2 emissions of the joint hybrid model for the vendor and the buyer.
Axioms 12 01104 g003
Figure 4. The behavior of the optimal production quantity given different settings.
Figure 4. The behavior of the optimal production quantity given different settings.
Axioms 12 01104 g004
Figure 5. The behavior of CO2 emissions given different settings.
Figure 5. The behavior of CO2 emissions given different settings.
Axioms 12 01104 g005
Figure 6. The behavior of the minimum total cost per unit time given different settings.
Figure 6. The behavior of the minimum total cost per unit time given different settings.
Axioms 12 01104 g006
Figure 7. The behavior of the optimal production rate given different settings.
Figure 7. The behavior of the optimal production rate given different settings.
Axioms 12 01104 g007
Figure 8. The behavior of the optimal allocation fraction of green production given different settings.
Figure 8. The behavior of the optimal allocation fraction of green production given different settings.
Axioms 12 01104 g008
Figure 9. A comparison of the optimal production quantity with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Figure 9. A comparison of the optimal production quantity with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Axioms 12 01104 g009
Figure 10. A comparison of the optimal production rate with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Figure 10. A comparison of the optimal production rate with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Axioms 12 01104 g010
Figure 11. A comparison of the carbon emissions generated by the system with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Figure 11. A comparison of the carbon emissions generated by the system with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Axioms 12 01104 g011
Figure 12. A comparison of the optimal total cost of the system with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Figure 12. A comparison of the optimal total cost of the system with respect to hybrid, regular, and green production methods.
Axioms 12 01104 g012
Table 1. A comparison between the proposed model with respect to some selected previous studies.
Table 1. A comparison between the proposed model with respect to some selected previous studies.
NoAuthorsFirst CycleAdjustable ParametersAdjustable Production RateHybrid ProductionEmissionsCarbon Regulations
1Wahab et al. [21] × × × × TransportationCarbon tax
2Hariga et al. [25] × × × × Storage, transportationCarbon tax
3Jaber et al. [36] × × × ProductionCarbon tax, penalty
4Bazan et al. [38] × × × Production, transportationCarbon tax, penalty
5Kumar and Uthayakumar [34] × × × × ProductionCarbon tax, penalty
6Zanoni et al. [35] × × × × ProductionCarbon tax, penalty
7Konur [61] × × × × TransportationCarbon cap
8Astanti et al. [39] × × × × Production, transportationCarbon tax
9Malik and Kim [40] × × × ProductionCarbon tax
10Bouchery [56] × × × TransportationCarbon tax
11Jauhari et al. [41] × × Production, transportation, storageCarbon tax
13Alamri [57] × × Production, transportation, storageCarbon tax, carbon cap
14Proposed model Production, transportation, storageCarbon tax, carbon cap, penalty
Table 2. List of notations used to develop the hybrid green and regular production joint model.
Table 2. List of notations used to develop the hybrid green and regular production joint model.
z ( z = g ,   r )   g denotes green production and r denotes regular production
k ( k = 1 ,   s )   1 refers to the first cycle and s refers to the subsequent cycles
t k The time to produce q k units
T k The time to consume q k units
T s k Cycle time
T s 1 The time to consume q s 1 units
t d The idle time before commencing the production process for subsequent cycles
t l The lead time (order point) to deliver the order quantity of size q k
E e CO2 emissions related to electricity (ton CO2/kWh)
E w b Buyer’s energy consumption for keeping items in storage (kWh/unit/unit time)
E w z Vendor’s energy consumption for keeping items in storage (kWh/unit/unit time)
e b k CO2 emissions related to the buyer’s facility (ton CO2/unit)
E b Buyer’s CO2 emissions tax ($/ton CO2)
v c The truck capacity (units/truck)
v t Fixed transportation cost per truck ($/truck)
c t Fixed transportation cost per unit ($/unit), where v t v c < c t
T w Product’s weight (ton/unit)
T f Distance from the freight to the vendor (km)
T v Distance from the vendor to the buyer (km)
f e The amount of fuel consumed by an empty truck (liters/km)
f The amount of fuel consumed by a truckload (liters/km/ton)
v v Variable transportation cost associated with fuel consumption ($/liter)
E T CO2 emissions from truck fuel (ton CO2/liter)
E z k CO2 emissions generated by the vendor’s facility (ton CO2/unit)
E s k The total amount of CO2 emissions (ton CO2/unit), where E s k = e b k + E z k
E l i CO2 emissions limit i (ton CO2/unit time)
E p i CO2 emissions penalty that the system incurs for exceeding emissions limit i ($/unit time)
E c CO2 emissions cap (ton CO2), where E c = E l 1
E v z Vendor’s CO2 emissions tax ($/ton CO2)
E v Vendor’s CO2 emissions revenue earned for selling excess quota ($/ton CO2)
E v T Vendor’s CO2 emissions tax for transportation ($/ton CO2)
a z CO2 emissions function parameter for production (kg CO2 · unit time2/unit3)
b z CO2 emissions function parameter for production (kg CO2 · unit time/unit2)
c z CO2 emissions function parameter for production (kg CO2/unit)
E m z The per unit time cost to run the machine independent of production rate ($/unit time)
E p z The increase in unit machining cost associated with the increase of one unit in production rate ($ · unit time/unit2)
S b Buyer’s ordering cost
S z Vendor’s set-up cost
h z Vendor’s holding cost, where h v represents the base model
d Buyer’s demand rate (units/unit time)
Decision variables:
λ Vendor’s coordination multiplier, where λ 1 and is an integer
ξ Vendor’s allocation fraction of green production, where 0 ζ 1
p z Production rate (units/unit time), where p m i n p z p m a x
p Production rate (units/unit time), where p m i n p p m a x and p = p g + p r
q k Order quantity (units), where q k = q g k + q r k
n Number of trucks required to deliver q k , where n 0 and is an integer
Table 3. Input parameters for Example 1.
Table 3. Input parameters for Example 1.
E m g E m r E p g E p r E v g E v r
250020000.00080.00041.62
USD/monthUSD/monthUSD · month/unit2USD · month/unit2USD/ton CO2USD/ton CO2
E T f f e T w E v T v v
0.00260.0640.320.0120.75
ton CO2/literliters/km/tonliters/kmton/unitUSD/ton CO2USD/liter
T f T v E c h g h r h b
80300400543
kmkmton CO2/monthUSD/unit/monthUSD/unit/monthUSD/unit/month
t l E b E v d p m a x p m i n
0.0822100040001200
monthUSD/ton CO2USD/ton CO2units/monthunits/monthunits/month
S g S r S b v t v c c t
12008004005003002
USD/set-upUSD/set-upUSD/orderUSD/truckunits/truckUSD/unit
a g b g c g a r b r c r
0.00000030.00121.40.00000050.00081.5
ton CO2 · month 2/unit3ton CO2 · month/unit2ton CO2/unitton CO2 · month 2/unit3ton CO2 · month/unit2ton CO2/unit
E w b E w g E w r E e
1.4411.440.0005
kWh/unit/monthkWh/unit/monthkWh/unit/monthton CO2/kWh
Table 4. CO2 emissions penalties scheme.
Table 4. CO2 emissions penalties scheme.
i E l i (ton CO2/Unit Time)Penalty Scheme E p i (USD/Unit Time)
1400 E s k < E c = E l 1 0
2500 E l 1 E s k < E l 2 500
3600 E l 2 E s k < E l 3 1000
4700 E l 3 E s k < E l 4 1500
5800 E l 4 E s k < E l 5 2000
6800 E s k E l 6 2500
Table 5. Optimal results for a hybrid production system for Example 1.
Table 5. Optimal results for a hybrid production system for Example 1.
First cycle ξ 1 p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policy
0.6862635.15755.7622516.7410,663.86
Subsequent cycles ξ s p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
0.6473427.721053.7913586.3911,697.82
Table 6. Optimal results for Example 1 when the demand rate increased to 1200 units in the third cycle.
Table 6. Optimal results for Example 1 when the demand rate increased to 1200 units in the third cycle.
First cycle ξ 1 p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policy
0.6862635.15755.7622516.7410,663.86
Second cycle ξ 2 p 2 q 2 λ 2 n 2 E s 2 W E s 2
0.6473427.721053.7913586.3911,697.82
Subsequent cycles ξ s p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
0.6543102.71667.0122663.8114,776.23
Table 7. Sensitivity analysis for optimal results for a hybrid production system in different settings.
Table 7. Sensitivity analysis for optimal results for a hybrid production system in different settings.
ParameterFirst cycle ξ 1 p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policy
h r = h g = 4 0.6972644.95789.5122503.0110,537.37
Subsequent cycles ξ s p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
0.6663083.21636.7022537.8311,500.38
S r = S g = 800 First cycle ξ 1 p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policy
0.6483221.851189.0014566.8910,713.34 ×
Subsequent cycles ξ s p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
0.6483403.90961.6513582.2711,273.99
d = 900 First cycle ξ 1 p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policy
0.6553166.621235.9514499.758862.99
Subsequent cycles ξ s p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
0.6473423.411015.4413526.9210,823.63
p m g = p m g = 2000 First cycle ξ 1 p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policy
0.7012476.57767.3022508.6710,468.41
Subsequent cycles ξ s p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
0.6493367.311050.7913577.9011,550.79
Table 8. Optimal results for regular production scenario for Example 1 when p m g = S g = ζ = 0 .
Table 8. Optimal results for regular production scenario for Example 1 when p m g = S g = ζ = 0 .
First cycle p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policySaving due to hybrid production
2000.00652.06221900.0817,245.98 38.16%
Subsequent cycles p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
1200.00385.46411261.0017,265.70 32.25%
Table 9. Optimal results for green production scenario for Example 1 when p m r = S r = 0 and ζ = 1 .
Table 9. Optimal results for green production scenario for Example 1 when p m r = S r = 0 and ζ = 1 .
First cycle p 1 q 1 λ 1 n 1 E s 1 W E S 1 Mixed policySaving compared with hybrid production Saving compared with regular production
2000.03684.1322200.87108.19 33.34%58.78%
Subsequent cycles p s q s λ s n s E s s W E s s
1889.09504.7421204.638491.07 27.41%50.82%
Table 10. CO2 emissions penalties scheme for comparison.
Table 10. CO2 emissions penalties scheme for comparison.
i E l i (ton CO2/Unit Time)Penalty Scheme E p i (USD/Unit Time)
1220 E s k < E c = E l 1 0
2330 E l 1 E s k < E l 2 1000
3440 E l 2 E s k < E l 3 2000
4550 E l 3 E s k < E l 4 3000
5600 E l 4 E s k < E l 5 4000
6600 E s k E l 6 5000
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Alamri, A.A. Efficient Formulation for Vendor–Buyer System Considering Optimal Allocation Fraction of Green Production. Axioms 2023, 12, 1104. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12121104

AMA Style

Alamri AA. Efficient Formulation for Vendor–Buyer System Considering Optimal Allocation Fraction of Green Production. Axioms. 2023; 12(12):1104. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12121104

Chicago/Turabian Style

Alamri, Adel A. 2023. "Efficient Formulation for Vendor–Buyer System Considering Optimal Allocation Fraction of Green Production" Axioms 12, no. 12: 1104. https://doi.org/10.3390/axioms12121104

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop