Next Article in Journal
Correlation between Urban Commercial Nodes and the Development of Sci-Tech Enterprises in Hangzhou West High-Tech Corridor, China
Next Article in Special Issue
Valuation of Visitor Perception of Urban Forest Ecosystem Services in Kuala Lumpur
Previous Article in Journal
Spatiotemporal Evolution Characteristics of Carbon Emissions from Industrial Land in Anhui Province, China
Previous Article in Special Issue
An Approach to Developing the Multicriteria Optimal Forest Management Plan: The “Fruska Gora” National Park Case Study
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Opportunity Costs of In Situ Carbon Storage Derived by Multiple-Objective Stand-Level Optimization—Results from Case Studies in Portugal and Germany

1
Institute of Forest Management, TUM School of Life Sciences Weihenstephan, Technical University of Munich, Hans-Carl-von-Carlowitz-Platz 2, D-85354 Freising, Germany
2
Forest Research Centre and Laboratory TERRA, School of Agriculture, University of Lisbon, 1649-004 Lisbon, Portugal
3
Faculty of Environmental Sciences and Natural Resource Management, Norwegian University of Life Sciences, 1432 Ås, Norway
4
Department of Forest Resource Management, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, 901 83 Umeå, Sweden
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Land 2022, 11(11), 2085; https://doi.org/10.3390/land11112085
Submission received: 31 October 2022 / Revised: 12 November 2022 / Accepted: 14 November 2022 / Published: 18 November 2022

Abstract

:
Considering in situ carbon storage in forest management has gained momentum under increasing pressure to decarbonize our economies. Here, we present results from case studies in Portugal and Germany showing the opportunity costs of in situ carbon storage derived by multiple-objective optimization. We used a stand-level model to optimize land expectation value under uncertainty as a reference, then derived opportunity costs by including the enhancement of the average carbon storage in aboveground biomass as a second objective. Using the optimal (compromise) solution when considering both objectives simultaneously, we show opportunity costs of EUR 119 (Portugal) and EUR 68 (Germany) per Mg CO2eq. These opportunity costs are higher than conservative, but lower than alternative cost estimates for future damages caused by current CO2 emissions. An important result was that suggested reference solutions in both countries (though only for low discount rates in Portugal) were mixed forests without clearfelling. In Germany, this implicitly elevated carbon storage. Such “closer-to-nature-forest-management” systems were also mostly suggested by the optimization tool when carbon storage was an objective.

1. Introduction

Increased atmospheric greenhouse gas emissions such as carbon dioxide remain a major global issue [1]. As carbon dioxide concentrations rise, so does the global temperature, causing more severe storms, increased drought, rising oceans, loss of species, and more health risks [2,3]. In response to this, multiple international initiatives aim to reduce the amount of carbon dioxide present in the atmosphere by reducing emissions and stimulating carbon storage in terrestrial ecosystems [4].
Carbon sequestration and storage in forest ecosystems is often promoted as a solution for reducing carbon dioxide concentrations in the atmosphere. Globally, forests play a major role as a significant carbon sink [5,6,7], storing nearly half of the carbon found in terrestrial ecosystems [8]. As a result, enhancing carbon sequestration and storage in forest ecosystems is increasingly becoming a fundamental goal for sustainable forest management [9,10,11].
Considering in situ carbon storage in forest management has gained momentum [12,13,14,15] under the increasing pressure to decarbonize our economies [16]. Carbon forestry often employs silvicultural prescriptions intended to improve growth and productivity and/or enhance aboveground carbon storage [17,18]. However, there is ongoing discussion regarding the effects of different silvicultural approaches on carbon storage [11,19]. In this regard, there is still a need for developing optimization tools and assessment frameworks to guide informed decision making.
Dynamic models to maximize the sum of discounted cash flows from timber production and the value of carbon storage in size-structured, mixed forest stands represent the forefront in current optimization approaches (e.g., [20]). Common approaches build on economic maxima, where one objective function aggregates all discounted cash or value flows, but commonly ignore the impact of uncertainty on decision making. Kolo et al. [21] provide an example of how to integrate uncertainty into multi-objective optimization, while discounted value flows from carbon sequestration and water supply enter one objective function in addition to discounted cash flows from timber harvesting.
Here, we adopt an alternative approach and consider the economic return from timber production and average carbon storage as separate objective functions, ruling out any compensation among both objectives. Using the optimal (compromise) solution when considering both objectives simultaneously, opportunity costs become available relative to optimizing only economic return from timber production. Such optimization of economic return provides a consistent “business-as-usual” reference, against which opportunity costs and increases in carbon storage can be assessed [22]. The opportunity costs provide important information to evaluate whether storing more carbon in existing forests might be efficient, and whether forest owners would accept a given carbon price. In addition, our modelling approach suggests the optimal silvicultural system (either clearfelling of forest stands consisting of just one tree species, or partial harvesting with early establishment of new age cohorts in mixed forests). These different silvicultural systems can influence carbon storage as well. The aim of our alternative optimization method is to show economic trade-offs of in situ carbon storage and the associated opportunity costs, and the variation of carbon storage with different silvicultural systems, derived by multiple-objective, stand-level optimization. We compare the resulting silvicultural systems with standard clearfelling systems using results from case studies in Portugal and Germany.

2. Materials and Methods

We used a stand-level optimization model developed by Knoke et al. [23] to include carbon storage as a second objective together with economic return as the first objective in an optimization process. We define opportunity costs, O C , as the decline of the economic return with the increase in the carbon stored in a forest stand.
O C = E c o n o m i c   r e t u r n C a r b o n
As indicators, i , included in the optimization process, we use the average storage of carbon and the associated CO2 equivalents in the forest stand’s aboveground biomass and the soil expectation value, S E V , to represent the economic return [24]. The optimization builds on second-order cone programming to allocate stand area proportions, a s t , to various tree species, s , and to harvesting periods, t , simultaneously. For example, a B e e c h , 50 = 0.1 would mean establishing beech at 10% of the stand’s area to harvest and replant at age 50. This means that our method allows partial harvesting to establish young tree cohorts in each considered period [25,26]. The optimization uses distances, D i u s t , between most desirable indicator levels, Y i u * , and indicator levels achieved by an actual decision, y i u s t , as criteria for finding the optimal solution. u symbolizes a specific uncertainty scenario, as we consider an expected and a pessimistic achievable indicator level for all possible decisions.
D i u s t = Y i u * y i u s t Y i u * Y i u * · 100
The absolute distances Y i u * y i u s t are normalized between zero (least desirable outcome Y i u * ) and 100% (most desirable outcome Y i u * ). The achieved decision outcomes, y i u s t , are the actual contributions of any decision to an indicator, i , when establishing a certain tree species, s , to harvest and replant at period t .
The optimization seeks to minimize the Euclidian distance between the most desirable and the achieved level across all considered indicators and uncertainty scenarios. Minimizing Euclidian distances is compatible with risk avoidance, as it considers uncertainty reductions by diversification. Risk-avoidant people use diversification to buffer uncertainty when making decisions [27]. Euclidian distances consider such diversification effects and imply that decision outcomes behave similarly to uncorrelated random variables. Euclidian distances for our decision simulations were computed as follows:
D i u = s S t T w i · a s t · D i u s t 2
The constant w i is a weighting factor used to vary the importance of each objective. For example, we use w S E V = 0 ,   0.1 ,   ,   0.9 ,   1.0 and w C a r b o n = 1 w S E V . These variations allow us to analyze different levels of carbon stored and associated levels of opportunity costs. Finally, to quantify opportunity costs, we use results corresponding to the weighting factors, w i , that led to minimum opportunity costs.
Then, the final optimization problem was:
min a s t β
s.t.
β = m a x D i u
β D i u     i , u
s S t T a s t = 1
a s t 0
For both indicators, we consider eight different uncertainty scenarios, u , for different combinations of optimistic and pessimistic indicator levels among three tree species, possibly mixed at stand level, to represent the uncertainty forest managers are confronted with. The carbon storage and soil expectation values used for reporting opportunity costs and for the trade-off analyses refer to the expected indicator levels. A detailed description of the stand-level optimization model can be found in Knoke et al. [23].

2.1. Portuguese Case Study Data

The Portuguese case study data (Table 1) reflects the forest conditions in Northwest Portugal. The growth of the forest species was simulated using the StandsSIM-MD module [28] of the sIMfLOR platform [29]. It uses the GLOBULUS 3.0 model for Eucalyptus globulus L. [30] and the PINASTER model for Pinus pinaster A. [31,32]. The simulations for Castanea sativa were obtained from yield tables [33]. Silvicultural costs and prices were obtained from the CAOF table [34] and from relevant stakeholders in the sector. For a detailed characterization of stakeholders in forested landscape in Northwest Portugal, refer to Marques et al. [35].

2.2. German Case Study Data

The German biophysical data were obtained from empirical growth functions published by Pretzsch et al. [36] (for spruce and beech). For silver fir, the spruce function was used, but adapted (see Knoke et al. [23]). Survival probabilities were taken from Brandl et al. [37] and stumpage prices from Paul et al. [38]. Further information concerning the growth response after partial harvesting and the growth suppression of young tree cohorts growing in gaps are provided in Knoke et al. [23].

2.3. Discount Rate

It is well known that the discount rate has an enormous impact on any carbon cost assessment [39]. Benítez et al. [40] published a regression function which suggests risk-adjusted discount rates for different countries, assessing the carbon sequestration potential worldwide. Their function proposes discount rates of 4.2% and 2.1% for Portugal and Germany, respectively. We corrected these rates downwards (3% for Portugal and 1.5% for Germany) while retaining a similar relation according to lower discount rates. For example, see the rates were suggested by [41] to describe the decision behavior of German forest owners. Finally, we used Portugal’s discount rate to optimize German forests and Germany’s discount rate to optimize Portuguese forests to obtain information concerning the sensitivity of our results to changes in the discount rate.

2.4. Social Costs of Carbon as a Benchmark

The social cost of carbon (SCC) provides a concept to support decision makers in finding appropriate climate change mitigation policies. SCC represents the change in the appropriately discounted value of economic welfare caused by damages associated with the additional units of CO2 emitted presently [39]. In theory, the SCC corresponds to the maximum amount society should be willing to pay in order to avoid the damages associated carbon emissions [42]. We used conservative published values for the SCC [39,43] to obtain a benchmark with which we can compare the opportunity costs of forest owners who enhance the average carbon storage in their stands.

3. Results

3.1. Opportunity Costs

For both case studies, we refer to optimal solutions for risk-avoidant forest owners seeking to optimize their economic return under uncertainty as a normative reference solution. This means that our program suggests how risk-avoidant decision makers could achieve the best compromise between economic return and mitigating the consequences of uncertainty. We assume that such forest owners prefer economically robust forest outcomes, not only for the expected indicator outcomes, but also for pessimistic ones.
The opportunity costs of storing additional carbon were lower in Germany than in Portugal. Discount rate sensitivity was also highest in Germany, where opportunity costs dropped from EUR 68 to EUR 19 per additional Mg CO2eq stored in the forest when changing the discount rate from 1.5% to 3% (Table 2).
Our optimization of the reference scenario for the Portuguese case study suggested an average storage of 46.72 Mg CO2eq per hectare and a land expectation value of EUR 5739 per hectare (discount rate 3%). The reference stand consists only of eucalyptus (100%) and is managed as a clearfelling coppice system. When considering the average carbon storage as an additional objective, we obtained mixed forests without clearfelling, which we classify as “closer-to-nature-forest-management” (CrNFM) [44], for w C a r b o n < 1 , but the minimum opportunity costs were obtained for w C a r b o n = 1 . This solution increased the average carbon storage by +52.97 Mg CO2eq per hectare. Increasing the carbon storage reduced the soil expectation value from EUR 5739 to −553 per hectare, representing opportunity costs of EUR 119 per additional Mg CO2eq stored in the forest.
The reference scenario without considering carbon as an objective for the German case study was a classical CrNFM system, dominated by silver fir (49.6%), while spruce covered 38.9% and beech covered 11.5%. Considering carbon as a second objective and using w C a r b o n = 0.4 to obtain minimum opportunity costs, the average carbon storage was elevated by +7.13 Mg CO2eq per hectare, while the soil expectation value (discount rate 1.5%) decreased by EUR 468 per hectare. This corresponds to an opportunity cost of EUR 119 per additional Mg CO2eq stored (Table 2).
In both case studies, elevated carbon storage went hand-in-hand with enhanced proportions of less-profitable broadleaves (with chestnut increasing from 19.2% to 100% in Portugal, and beech from 11.5% to 16.4% in Germany). In addition, more standing volume accumulated over time as a result of postponed harvests.

3.2. Trade-Offs between Economic Return and Carbon Storage

Economic return and carbon storage were strongly negatively correlated ( ρ = 0.85   t o 0.97 , Figure 1). In Portugal, carbon storage–economic return trajectories were long and had small slopes, indicating high economic losses to be accepted for enhancing carbon stored in the forest. The silvicultural systems were mainly CrNFM systems when considering carbon as an objective. This produced mixed forests managed without clearfelling, except when maximizing carbon storage, which allocated 100% of the stand to chestnut. However, the carbon stored in the Portuguese CrNFM systems was not necessarily higher than in the clearfelling system, particularly when the carbon objective had low weight, e.g., w C a r b o n = 0.1 .
In Germany, the suggested silvicultural systems stored more carbon than in the case of Portuguese forests. Shifting from clearfelled silviculture to CrNFM alone significantly enhances carbon storage (+53 to +58 Mg CO2eq per hectare), associated with EUR −607 (3% discount rate) and EUR−1723 (1.5% discount rate). These costs can, at least theoretically, be considered insurance premia which forest owners accept to pay to obtain robust solutions and protection against uncertainty. They are not associated with considering carbon storage as an objective. Rather, the enhanced carbon storage that results from applying CrNFM systems is a positive externality provided by forest owners to global societies. For the sake of comparison, the additional carbon stored by CrNFM systems could be represented as entailing low opportunity costs of EUR −11 (3% discount rate) and EUR −30 (1.5% discount rate) per Mg CO2eq. Again, however, this ignores the benefit of increased robustness.
For the 1.5% discount rate, the carbon storage–economic return trajectory had a small slope, showing that enhancing carbon within CrNFM systems is relatively expensive. Given a 3.0% discount rate, enhancing carbon in CrNFM systems was more cost-effective, as indicated by the greater slope of the trajectory.

3.3. Social Costs of Carbon as a Benchmark

The carbon opportunity costs for the Portuguese and German case studies exceed the SCC published by United States Government [45] (discount rate 3%) and Nordhaus [39] (average discount rate 4.25%) (Figure 2). However, the SCC published by Nordhaus [39] for a discount rate of 3% already more than covers carbon opportunity costs. Given a discount rate of 3%, the SCC grows according to United States Government [45] until 2050; only then would it reach the carbon opportunity costs for the Portuguese and German case studies today.

4. Discussion and Conclusions

Our study presents a new method to assess the increase in carbon stored in situ against an optimized reference scenario. The use of optimization tools to derive counterfactual reference scenarios was originally proposed by Knoke and Weber [46] as a possible solution to the additionality problem, which is a major obstacle to rigorously assessing the performance of nature-based solutions for carbon storage [22]. However, multiple-objective, stand-level models have rarely been used for this purpose, especially when considering the influence of uncertainty and disturbance risk.
Our baseline solutions for the German case suggest adopting CrNFM systems, which can offer advantages over clearfelling systems in terms of carbon storage and economic resilience [47]. For instance, Assmuth et al. [20] show that pricing carbon stored in a forest generates an unlimited rotation period consistent with continuous cover forestry; a classical CrNFM system. Our results suggest that by applying CrNFM systems to buffer uncertainties, risk-avoidant forest owners in Germany will provide carbon storage as a positive externality in much the same way that some farmers seek to promote agrobiodiversity to obtain natural insurance [48,49]. Despite these advantages, CrNFM systems have not yet been widely adopted. Developing tailored policies to support forest owners transitioning to these systems thus might support forest carbon stocks that are larger and more robust.
Empirically, our results show that opportunities to enhance in situ forest carbon at minimum opportunity cost are more prevalent in Germany than in Portugal. In Portugal, the economic superiority of eucalyptus coppice over alternative forest types entails a high marginal cost for allocating more area to oak or chestnut, which store more carbon. We had to exclude the economic objective completely ( w C a r b o n = 1 ) to enhance the carbon storage under minimum average opportunity costs for the Portuguese case. In the German case, by contrast, this was achievable with modest values of w C a r b o n = 0.4 and w C a r b o n = 0.2 .
Our carbon storage opportunity costs were higher than conservative, but lower than alternative cost estimates for future damages caused by current CO2 emissions. If the social cost of carbon (SCC) represents society’s maximum willingness to pay to avoid climate-related damages [42], enhancing forest carbon stocks is economical as long as the opportunity cost of doing so does not exceed the SCC. In both Portugal and Germany, the opportunity cost of compromise solutions often exceeded the SCC values suggested by Nordhaus [39] and the US government [45]. We used these values as a reference point because they are well-known and widely cited, but acknowledge that they remain controversial in both scholarly [50,51] and popular [52,53] discourse. Political and ethical issues aside, SCC estimates are significantly—even extraordinarily [54]—sensitive to scenario definitions and model specifications because they integrate modules for climate, socioeconomic trends, discounting, and damages [55,56]. For instance, a prominent controversy involves the damage functions used by integrated environmental-economic models [57,58], which produce estimates that Keen et al. [59] consider “impossible to reconcile” with the scientific literature on tipping points (see also [60,61,62]).
Consequently, some sources recommend much higher SCC valuations than the US does. German guidance suggests an SCC that starts at USD 218 in 2016 and climbs to USD 291 by 2050 (i.e., within our planning horizon), while France recommends ramping up from USD 103 to USD 916 over the same period [56,63,64]. Both figures consider global damages and are compatible with the range of global median estimates by Ricke et al. [65]. Our calculated opportunity costs for both Germany and Portugal satisfy these SCC estimates by a much larger margin than they exceed the Nordhaus/US reference values. This means that high-opportunity-cost carbon enhancement (e.g., in Portugal) could be uneconomical relative to the Nordhaus/US figures, but highly affordable if measured against German or French SCC guidance.
Our results should be interpreted normatively as a reference solution for understanding environmental–economic trade-offs in two very different forest systems [38,66,67]. We evaluated easy-to-generalize silvicultural systems typical of each case country without tailoring examples to a particular landscape, which requires treating disturbance as endogenous to stand type and neglecting spatial dimensions. In applied contexts, however, forest managers face a range of spatial disturbances such as fire, wind, and pest outbreaks [68,69,70]. Exploring how spatial allocation influences the performance of our portfolios would be an interesting but challenging problem for future research, although simultaneously optimizing for species selection and harvest scheduling while also accounting for spatially contingent uncertainty scenarios would likely only be computationally tractable through heuristic algorithms [71,72,73]. By contrast, our method offers an exact solution highlighting the “multicriteria premium”: the economic opportunity cost incurred through the addition of competing non-economic objectives [23]. While it would be possible to apply the same method to evaluate trade-offs in (for instance) landscape mosaics that include agricultural land use types, for the purposes of this study, we concentrate specifically on management changes in forested areas.
The magnitude of the trade-off between SEV and carbon also depends on indicator selection and accounting methods. We used a climate indicator based on the average carbon storage in aboveground biomass across the planning period. Although we follow standard practice by discounting financial flows but not carbon storage, doing so implicitly weights the undiscounted objective, especially when uncertainty is high [74]. Our carbon indicator ignores product pools and substitution effects, but we expect that life-cycle analysis (LCA) would magnify the opportunity cost discrepancy between our case examples. In Germany, forestry largely feeds into long-lived timber products and bioenergy that substitutes for fossil fuels [21,75], whereas Portuguese eucalyptus coppices are mainly used for pulpwood production [76,77]. Thus, LCA would presumably mitigate the carbon–SEV trade-off to a greater extent in Germany than Portugal. While we support incorporating LCA more consistently into forest carbon accounting [78,79,80], our focus here is on the perspective of forest owners. Introducing additional assumptions about product assortments and lifetimes conflicts with this decision perspective, so we concentrate narrowly on carbon storage in standing timber.
Beyond these case studies, our approach offers an intuitive method for assessing forest-based carbon storage solutions, which have been criticized for low additionality, lack of permanence, and vulnerability to climate-linked disturbance risk [81,82]. We address these concerns by deriving reference scenarios that are robust to future uncertainty, observing how the optimal distributions of species and age classes shift to generate compromise solutions balancing economic performance against enhanced carbon storage, and then comparing the resulting opportunity costs to the marginal cost of emissions (SCC). This workflow can offer insight not only about how a climate-smart forest portfolio might look, but also about where and how policies can be targeted to support management changes at least cost.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.K. and T.K.; methodology, T.K.; formal analysis, M.K. and T.K.; data curation, M.K., T.K., L.R.B., J.G.B., S.M., O.N. and J.E.; writing—original draft preparation, T.K., M.K. and L.R.B.; writing—review and editing, M.K., T.K., L.R.B., J.G.B., S.M., O.N. and J.E.; visualization, M.K., L.R.B. and T.K.; supervision, T.K.; project administration, M.K. and T.K.; funding acquisition, T.K. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The study has emerged from the project NOBEL, “Novel business model and mechanisms for the sustainable supply of and payment for forest ecosystem services”, which is part of the ERA- NET Co-fund Forest Value. Forest Value is a project of European Union’s Horizon 2020 Program, grant agreement # 773324.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the European Union’s Horizon 2020 Program for the financial support in the frame of the NOBEL, “Novel business model and mechanisms for the sustainable supply of and payment for forest ecosystem services” project, which is part of the ERA- NET Co-fund Forest Value. Forest Value is a project of European Union’s Horizon 2020 Program, grant agreement # 773324. M.K. receives funding from NOBEL. L.R.B. receives from the European Commission Training Network (project Skill-For.Action, Grant agreement ID: 956355). J.G.B. and S.M receives funding from the Forest Research Centre, a research unit funded by Fundação para a Ciência e a Tecnologia I.P. (FCT), Portugal (UIDB/00239/2020) and Associated Laboratory TERRA. They recieved funds in the scope of Norma Transitória DL57/2016/CP1382/CT15 funded by FCT. Finally, we would like to thank two anonymous reviewers for their insightful and constructive feedback on our paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Lamb, W.F.; Wiedmann, T.; Pongratz, J.; Andrew, R.; Crippa, M.; Olivier, J.G.J.; Wiedenhofer, D.; Mattioli, G.; Khourdajie, A.A.; House, J.; et al. A review of trends and drivers of greenhouse gas emissions by sector from 1990 to 2018. Environ. Res. Lett. 2021, 16, 73005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Hinzman, L.; Bettez, N.; Bolton, W.; Chapin, F.; Dyurgerov, M.; Fastie, C.L.; Griffith, B.; Hollister, R.D.; Hope, A.; Huntington, H.P.; et al. Evidence and implications of recent climate change in Northern Alaska and other arctic regions. Clim. Change 2005, 72, 251–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. IPCC. Summary for policymakers. In Global Warming of 1.5 °C; An IPCC Special Report on the Impacts of Global Warming of 1.5 °C above Pre-industrial Levels and Related Global Greenhouse Gas Emission Pathways, in The Context of Strengthening the Global Response; World Meteorological Organization: Geneva, Switzerland, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  4. Karlsson, I.; Rootzén, J.; Johnsson, F.; Erlandsson, M. Achieving net-zero carbon emissions in construction supply chains—A multidimensional analysis of residential building systems. Dev. Built Environ. 2021, 8, 100059. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Canadell, J.G.; Raupach, M.R. Managing forests for climate change mitigation. Science 2008, 320, 1456–1457. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Pan, Y.; Birdsey, R.A.; Fang, J.; Houghton, R.; Kauppi, P.E.; Kurz, W.A.; Phillips, O.L.; Shvidenko, A.; Lewis, S.L.; Canadell, J.G.; et al. A Large and Persistent Carbon Sink in the World’s Forests. Science 2011, 333, 988–993. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Sedjo, R.; Sohngen, B. Carbon Sequestration in Forests and Soils. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2012, 4, 127–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bonan, G.B. Forests and climate change: Forcings, feedbacks, and the climate benefits of forests. Science 2008, 320, 1444–1449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Gunn, J.S.; Ducey, M.J.; Whitman, A.A. Late-successional and old-growth forest carbon temporal dynamics in the Northern Forest (Northeastern USA). For. Ecol. Manag. 2014, 312, 40–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Noormets, A.; Epron, D.; Domec, J.C.; McNulty, S.G.; Fox, T.; Sun, G.; King, J.S. Effects of forest management on productivity and carbon sequestration: A review and hypothesis. For. Ecol. Manag. 2015, 355, 124–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Ontl, T.A.; Janowiak, M.K.; Swanston, C.W.; Daley, J.; Handler, S.; Cornett, M.; Hagenbuch, S.; Handrick, C.; Mccarthy, L.; Patch, N. Forest Management for Carbon Sequestration and Climate Adaptation. J. For. 2020, 118, 86–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Köthke, M.; Dieter, M. Effects of carbon sequestration rewards on forest management—An empirical application of adjusted Faustmann Formulae. For. Policy Econ. 2010, 12, 589–597. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. West, T.A.; Wilson, C.; Vrachioli, M.; Grogan, K.A. Carbon payments for extended rotations in forest plantations: Conflicting insights from a theoretical model. Ecol. Econ. 2019, 163, 70–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Price, C. Declining discount rate and the social cost of carbon: Forestry consequences. J. For. Econ. 2018, 31, 39–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Pukkala, T. Carbon forestry is surprising. For. Ecosyst. 2018, 5, 11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Rockström, J.; Gaffney, O.; Rogelj, J.; Meinshausen, M.; Nakicenovic, N.; Schellnhuber, H.J. A roadmap for rapid decarbonization. Science 2017, 355, 1269–1271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  17. Nunery, J.S.; Keeton, W.S. Forest carbon storage in the northeastern United States: Net effects of harvesting frequency, post-harvest retention, and wood products. For. Ecol. Manag. 2010, 259, 1363–1375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Achim, A.; Moreau, G.; Coops, N.C.; Axelson, J.N.; Barrette, J.; Bédard, S.; Byrne, K.E.; Caspersen, J.; Dick, A.R.; D’Orangeville, L.; et al. The changing culture of silviculture. For. Int. J. For. Res. 2022, 95, 143–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ledermann, T.; Braun, M.; Kindermann, G.; Jandl, R.; Ludvig, A.; Schadauer, K.; Schwarzbauer, P.; Weiss, P. Effects of Silvicultural Adaptation Measures on Carbon Stock of Austrian Forests. Forests 2022, 13, 565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Assmuth, A.; Rämö, J.; Tahvonen, O. Optimal Carbon Storage in Mixed-Species Size-Structured Forests. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2021, 79, 249–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Kolo, H.; Kindu, M.; Knoke, T. Optimizing forest management for timber production, carbon sequestration and groundwater recharge. Ecosyst. Serv. 2020, 44, 101147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Cattaneo, A.; Lubowski, R.; Busch, J.; Creed, A.; Strassburg, B.; Boltz, F.; Ashton, R. On international equity in reducing emissions from deforestation. Environ. Sci. Policy 2010, 13, 742–753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Knoke, T.; Kindu, M.; Jarisch, I.; Gosling, E.; Friedrich, S.; Bödeker, K.; Paul, C. How considering multiple criteria, uncertainty scenarios and biological interactions may influence the optimal silvicultural strategy for a mixed forest. For. Policy Econ. 2020, 118, 102239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Knoke, T.; Paul, C.; Friedrich, S.; Borchert, H.; Härtl, F.; Chang, S.J. The optimal rotation for a fully regulated forest is the same as, or shorter than, the rotation for a single even-aged forest stand: Comments on Helmedag’s (2018) paper. Eur. J. For. Res. 2020, 139, 133–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Roessiger, J.; Griess, V.C.; Knoke, T. May risk aversion lead to near-natural forestry? A simulation study. For. Int. J. For. Res. 2011, 84, 527–537. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Messerer, K.; Pretzsch, H.; Knoke, T. A non-stochastic portfolio model for optimizing the transformation of an even-aged forest stand to continuous cover forestry when information about return fluctuation is incomplete. Ann. For. Sci. 2017, 74, 45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Bikhchandani, S.; Hirshleifer, J.; Riley, J.G. The Analytics of Uncertainty and Information, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2015; ISBN 9780521834087. [Google Scholar]
  28. Barreiro, S.; Rua, J.; Tomé, M. StandsSIM-MD: A Management Driven forest SIMulator. For. Syst. 2016, 25, eRC07. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Faias, S.P.; Palma, J.H.N.; Barreiro, S.M.; Paulo, J.A.; Tomé, M. Resource communication. sIMfLOR—Platform for Portuguese forest simulators. For. Syst. 2012, 21, 543. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Tomé, M.; Oliveira, T.; Soares, P. O Modelo GLOBULUS 3.0 Dados e Equações. Universidade Técnica de Lisboa, Instituto Superior de Agronomia, Centro de Estudos Florestais, Lisboa. Available online: https://www.repository.utl.pt/bitstream/10400.5/1760/1/REP-DEF-RC2%202006.pdf (accessed on 10 September 2022).
  31. Nunes, L.; Patrício, M.; Tomé, J.; Tomé, M. Modeling dominant height growth of maritime pine in Portugal using GADA methodology with parameters depending on soil and climate variables. Ann. For. Sci. 2011, 68, 311–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  32. Nunes, L.; Tomé, J.; Tomé, M. Prediction of annual tree growth and survival for thinned and unthinned even-aged maritime pine stands in Portugal from data with different time measurement intervals. For. Ecol. Manag. 2011, 262, 1491–1499. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Monteiro, M.L.; Patrício, M.S. O castanheiro: Modelos de gestão. Rev. Florest. 1996, 9, 51–56. [Google Scholar]
  34. DGADR. CAOF—Comissão de Acompanhamento Para as Operações Florestais Acessível. Available online: https://www.dgadr.gov.pt/18-mecanizacao-agraria/127-caof (accessed on 10 September 2022).
  35. Marques, M.; Juerges, N.; Borges, J.G. Appraisal framework for actor interest and power analysis in forest management—Insights from Northern Portugal. For. Policy Econ. 2020, 111, 102049. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Pretzsch, H.; Biber, P.; Schütze, G.; Uhl, E.; Rötzer, T. Forest stand growth dynamics in Central Europe have accelerated since 1870. Nat. Commun. 2014, 5, 4964. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  37. Brandl, S.; Paul, C.; Knoke, T.; Falk, W. The influence of climate and management on survival probability for Germany’s most important tree species. For. Ecol. Manag. 2020, 458, 117652. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Paul, C.; Brandl, S.; Friedrich, S.; Falk, W.; Härtl, F.; Knoke, T. Climate change and mixed forests: How do altered survival probabilities impact economically desirable species proportions of Norway spruce and European beech? Ann. For. Sci. 2019, 76, 14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Nordhaus, W.D. Revisiting the social cost of carbon. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2017, 114, 1518–1523. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Benítez, P.C.; McCallum, I.; Obersteiner, M.; Yamagata, Y. Global potential for carbon sequestration: Geographical distribution, country risk and policy implications. Ecol. Econ. 2007, 60, 572–583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Möhring, B.; Rüping, U.; Leefken, G.; Ziegeler, M. The annuity—A “missing link” of the forest economy? Allg. Forst-Jagdztg. 2006, 177, 21–29. [Google Scholar]
  42. Price, R.; Thornton, S.; Nelson, S. The Social Cost of Carbon and the Shadow Price of Carbon: What They Are, and How to Use Them in Economic Appraisal in the UK; Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs: London, UK, 2007.
  43. United States Government. Table 1.1.9. Implicit Price Deflators for Gross Domestic Product. Available online: https://apps.bea.gov/iTable/iTable.cfm?reqid=19&step=3&isuri=1&1921=survey&1903=13#reqid=19&step=3&isuri=1&1921=survey&1903=13 (accessed on 16 June 2022).
  44. Larsen, J.B.; Angelstam, P.; Bauhus, J.; Carvalho, J.F.; Diaci, J.; Dobrowolska, D.; Gazda, A.; Gustafsson, L.; Krumm, F.; Knoke, T.; et al. From Science to Policy; European Forest Institute: Joensuu, Finland, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  45. United States Government. Technical Support Document: Social Cost of Carbon, Methane, and Nitrous Oxide Interim Estimates Under Executive Order 13990. Available online: https://www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2021/02/TechnicalSupportDocument_SocialCostofCarbonMethaneNitrousOxide.pdf (accessed on 29 May 2022).
  46. Knoke, T.; Weber, M. Expanding Carbon Stocks in Existing Forests—A Methodological Approach for Cost Appraisal at the Enterprise Level. Mitig. Adapt. Strateg. Glob. Change 2006, 11, 579–605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Knoke, T.; Paul, C.; Gosling, E.; Jarisch, I.; Mohr, J.; Seidl, R. Assessing the Economic Resilience of Different Management Systems to Severe Forest Disturbance. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2022, in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Di Falco, S.; Perrings, C. Crop biodiversity, risk management and the implications of agricultural assistance. Ecol. Econ. 2005, 55, 459–466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Baumgärtner, S.; Quaas, M.F. Managing increasing environmental risks through agrobiodiversity and agrienvironmental policies. Agric. Econ. 2010, 41, 483–496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  50. Espagne, E.; Pottier, A.; Fabert, B.P.; Nadaud, F.; Dumas, P. SCCs and the use of IAMs: Let’s separate the wheat from the chaff. Int. Econ. 2018, 155, 29–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Van den Bergh, J.; Botzen, W. Monetary valuation of the social cost of CO2 emissions: A critical survey. Ecol. Econ. 2015, 114, 33–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. DePillis, L. Pace of Climate Change Sends Economists Back to Drawing Board; New York Times: New York, NY, USA, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  53. Roberts, D. The “Uncertainty Loop” Haunting Our Climate Models. Available online: https://www.vox.com/2015/10/23/9604120/climate-models-uncertainty (accessed on 15 September 2022).
  54. Stern, N.; Stiglitz, J.; Taylor, C. The economics of immense risk, urgent action and radical change: Towards new approaches to the economics of climate change. J. Econ. Methodol. 2022, 29, 181–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Lemoine, D. The Climate Risk Premium: How Uncertainty Affects the Social Cost of Carbon. J. Assoc. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2020, 8, 27–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. US GAO. Social Cost of Carbon: Identifying a Federal Entity to Address the National Academies’ Recommendations Could Strengthen Regulatory Analysis; United States Government Accountability Office Report to Congressional Requesters No. GAO-20-254; US GAO: Washington, DC, USA, 2020.
  57. Dietz, S.; Rising, J.; Stoerk, T.; Wagner, G. Reply to Keen et al.: Dietz et al. modeling of climate tipping points is informative even if estimates are a probable lower bound. Earth Atmos. Planet. Sci. 2022, 119, e2201191119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Dietz, S.; Rising, J.; Stoerk, T.; Wagner, G. Economic impacts of tipping points in the climate system. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2021, 118, e2103081118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Keen, S.; Lenton, T.M.; Garrett, T.J.; Rae, J.W.B.; Hanley, B.P.; Grasselli, M. Estimates of economic and environmental damages from tipping points cannot be reconciled with the scientific literature. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2022, 119, e2117308119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Franzke, C.L.E.; Ciullo, A.; Gilmore, E.A.; Matias, D.M.; Nagabhatla, N.; Orlov, A.; Paterson, S.K.; Scheffran, J.; Sillmann, J. Perspectives on tipping points in integrated models of the natural and human Earth system: Cascading effects and telecoupling. Environ. Res. Lett. 2022, 17, 15004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Kemp, L.; Xu, C.; Depledge, J.; Ebi, K.L.; Gibbins, G.; Kohler, T.A.; Rockström, J.; Scheffer, M.; Schellnhuber, H.J.; Steffen, W.; et al. Climate Endgame: Exploring catastrophic climate change scenarios. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2022, 119, e2108146119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Rising, J.A.; Taylor, C.; Ives, M.C.; Ward, R.E. Challenges and innovations in the economic evaluation of the risks of climate change. Ecol. Econ. 2022, 197, 107437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Matthey, A.; Bünger, B. Methodological Convention 3.0 for the Assessment of Environmental Costs; No. Cost Rates Version 02/2019; Umwelt Bundesamt: Dessau-Roßlau, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  64. Wagner, G.; Anthoff, D.; Cropper, M.; Dietz, S.; Gillingham, K.T.; Groom, B.; Kelleher, J.P.; Moore, F.C.; Stock, J.H. Eight priorities for calculating the social cost of carbon. Nature 2021, 590, 548–550. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  65. Ricke, K.; Drouet, L.; Caldeira, K.; Tavoni, M. Country-level social cost of carbon. Nat. Clim. Change 2018, 8, 895–900. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  66. Augustynczik, A.L.; Asbeck, T.; Basile, M.; Jonker, M.; Knuff, A.; Yousefpour, R.; Hanewinkel, M. Reconciling forest profitability and biodiversity conservation under disturbance risk: The role of forest management and salvage logging. Environ. Res. Lett. 2020, 15, 0940a3. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Reith, E.; Gosling, E.; Knoke, T.; Paul, C. How Much Agroforestry Is Needed to Achieve Multifunctional Landscapes at the Forest Frontier?—Coupling Expert Opinion with Robust Goal Programming. Sustainability 2020, 12, 6077. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Aparício, B.A.; Alcasena, F.; Ager, A.; Chung, W.; Pereira, J.M.; Sá, A.C. Evaluating priority locations and potential benefits for building a nation-wide fuel break network in Portugal. J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 320, 115920. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Dobor, L.; Hlásny, T.; Rammer, W.; Zimová, S.; Barka, I.; Seidl, R. Spatial configuration matters when removing windfelled trees to manage bark beetle disturbances in Central European forest landscapes. J. Environ. Manag. 2020, 254, 109792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Quine, C.P.; Gardiner, B.A.; Moore, J. Wind disturbance in forests: The process of wind created gaps, tree overturning, and stem breakage. In Plant Disturbance Ecology; Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2021; pp. 117–184. [Google Scholar]
  71. Augustynczik, A.L.D.; Arce, J.E.; Yousefpour, R.; da Silva, A.C.L. Promoting harvesting stands connectivity and its economic implications in Brazilian forest plantations applying integer linear programming and simulated annealing. For. Policy Econ. 2016, 73, 120–129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Bellavenutte, P.; Chung, W.; Diaz-Balteiro, L. Partitioning and solving large-scale tac-tical harvest scheduling problems for industrial plantation forests. Can. J. For. Res. 2020, 50, 811–818. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. St John, R.; Tóth, S.F.; Zabinsky, Z.B. Optimizing the geometry of wildlife corridors in conservation reserve design. Oper. Res. 2018, 66, 1471–1485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  74. Jarisch, I.; Bödeker, K.; Bingham, L.R.; Friedrich, S.; Kindu, M.; Knoke, T. The influence of discounting ecosystem services in robust multi-objective optimization—An application to a forestry-avocado land-use portfolio. For. Policy Econ. 2022, 141, 102761. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Schulze, E.D.; Sierra, C.A.; Egenolf, V.; Woerdehoff, R.; Irslinger, R.; Baldamus, C.; Stupak, I.; Spellmann, H. The climate change mitigation effect of bioenergy from sustaina-bly managed forests in Central Europe. GCB Bioenergy 2020, 12, 186–197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Borges, J.G.; Marques, S.; Garcia-Gonzalo, J.; Rahman, A.U.; Bushenkov, V.; Sottomayor, M.; Carvalho, P.O.; Nordström, E.-M. A multiple criteria approach for negotiating ecosystem services supply targets and forest owners’ programs. For. Sci. 2017, 63, 49–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Garcia-Gonzalo, J.; Borges, J.G.; Palma, J.H.N.; Zubizarreta-Gerendiain, A. A decision support system for management planning of Eucalyptus plantations facing climate change. Ann. For. Sci. 2014, 71, 187–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  78. Cabiyo, B.; Fried, J.S.; Collins, B.M.; Stewart, W.; Wong, J.; Sanchez, D.L. Innovative wood use can enable carbon-beneficial forest management in California. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2021, 118, e2019073118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Gunn, J.S.; Ducey, M.J.; Buchholz, T.; Belair, E.P. Forest carbon resilience of eastern spruce budworm (Choristoneura fumiferana) salvage harvesting in the Northeastern United States. Front. For. Glob. Change 2020, 3, 14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  80. Härtl, F.H.; Höllerl, S.; Knoke, T. A new way of carbon accounting emphasises the crucial role of sustainable timber use for successful carbon mitigation strategies. Mitig. Adapt. Strateg. Glob. Change 2017, 22, 1163–1192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Badgley, G.; Freeman, J.; Hamman, J.J.; Haya, B.; Trugman, A.T.; Anderegg, W.R.L.; Cullenward, D. Systematic over-crediting in California’s forest carbon offsets program. Glob. Change Biol. 2022, 28, 1433–1445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Gifford, L. “You can’t value what you can’t measure”: A critical look at forest carbon accounting. Clim. Change 2020, 161, 291–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Trade-offs between the storage of carbon dioxide and the soil expectation value. The different carbon–SEV pairs were obtained using different weightings of the carbon and economic return objectives.
Figure 1. Trade-offs between the storage of carbon dioxide and the soil expectation value. The different carbon–SEV pairs were obtained using different weightings of the carbon and economic return objectives.
Land 11 02085 g001
Figure 2. Comparison of forest owner’s opportunity costs with published social costs of carbon (SCC). We used SCC published by United States Government [45] and Nordhaus [39]. SCC adopted from Nordhaus [39] were converted from 2010 to 2020 USD by the factor of 1.181789822 [43] and opportunity costs in EUR into USD by the factor of 1.04. r is the discount rate.
Figure 2. Comparison of forest owner’s opportunity costs with published social costs of carbon (SCC). We used SCC published by United States Government [45] and Nordhaus [39]. SCC adopted from Nordhaus [39] were converted from 2010 to 2020 USD by the factor of 1.181789822 [43] and opportunity costs in EUR into USD by the factor of 1.04. r is the discount rate.
Land 11 02085 g002
Table 1. List of species and data sources used for our simulations.
Table 1. List of species and data sources used for our simulations.
Portuguese Case Study
SpeciesData Sources
Maritime pine[28,29,31,32,34,35]
Chestnut[28,29,31,32,34,35]
Eucalyptus[28,29,30,34,35]
Germany Case Study
SpeciesData Sources
Spruce[23,36,37,38]
Silver fir[23,37,38]
Beech[23,36,37,38]
Table 2. Opportunity costs off additional carbon in forest stands in Portugal and Germany. Default discount rates 3.0% and 1.5% for Portugal and Germany, respectively (corresponding results in bold and italics).
Table 2. Opportunity costs off additional carbon in forest stands in Portugal and Germany. Default discount rates 3.0% and 1.5% for Portugal and Germany, respectively (corresponding results in bold and italics).
Discount Rate
1.53.0
Carbon Is No ObjectiveCarbon Is an ObjectiveCarbon Is No ObjectiveCarbon Is an Objective
PortugalTree species [%] w C a r b o n = 0 w C a r b o n = 1 w C a r b o n = 0 w C a r b o n = 1
Maritime pine17.5000
Chestnut5.81000100
Eucalyptus76.701000
Soil expectation value
[EUR per hectare]
754522495739−533
Average carbon storage
[Mg CO2 equivalent per hectare]
46.6199.6944.6499.69
Opportunity costs
[EUR per Mg CO2 equivalent]
99.97118.79
GermanyTree species [%] w C a r b o n = 0 w C a r b o n = 0.4 w C a r b o n = 0 w C a r b o n = 0.2
Spruce38.937.347.343.2
Silver fir49.646.350.348.9
Beech11.516.42.47.9
Soil expectation value
[EUR per hectare]
856080771012541
Average carbon storage
[Mg CO2 equivalent per hectare]
279.02297.23242.19266.94
Opportunity costs
[EUR per Mg CO2 equivalent]
68.1218.95
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kindu, M.; Bingham, L.R.; Borges, J.G.; Marques, S.; Nahorna, O.; Eggers, J.; Knoke, T. Opportunity Costs of In Situ Carbon Storage Derived by Multiple-Objective Stand-Level Optimization—Results from Case Studies in Portugal and Germany. Land 2022, 11, 2085. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11112085

AMA Style

Kindu M, Bingham LR, Borges JG, Marques S, Nahorna O, Eggers J, Knoke T. Opportunity Costs of In Situ Carbon Storage Derived by Multiple-Objective Stand-Level Optimization—Results from Case Studies in Portugal and Germany. Land. 2022; 11(11):2085. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11112085

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kindu, Mengistie, Logan Robert Bingham, José G. Borges, Susete Marques, Olha Nahorna, Jeannette Eggers, and Thomas Knoke. 2022. "Opportunity Costs of In Situ Carbon Storage Derived by Multiple-Objective Stand-Level Optimization—Results from Case Studies in Portugal and Germany" Land 11, no. 11: 2085. https://doi.org/10.3390/land11112085

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop