Moral Entitlements and Aspiration Formation in Asymmetric Bargaining: Experimental Evidence from Germany and China
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Experimental Methods
2.1. Experimental Design
2.2. Procedure
2.3. Videotaping
2.4. Data Coding and Categories
3. Results
3.1. Descriptive Results of the Negotiations
3.2. Motives in Aspiration Formation
3.2.1. Initial Aspiration Levels
3.2.2. Adaption of Aspiration Levels
3.3.3. Final Aspiration Levels
3.3. Fairness-Related Aspiration Levels
3.4. Subject Pool Comparison
3.4.1. Equity
3.4.2. Negotiation Characteristics
4. Discussion
Acknowledgments
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
English translation of the instructions
Introduction into the experiment
Bargaining Protocol | Date | Session No. | |||||
Starting time | Group No. | ||||||
End | Page 1 | ||||||
Actual Proposal | Payoffs | ||||||
Proposal | Group 1 | Group 2 | Signatures | Coalition | Alternative | ||
No. | made by group no. | receives | receives | value | Group 1 | Group 2 | |
1 | 1 | 320 | 128 | 32 | |||
2 | 2 | ||||||
3 | 1 | ||||||
4 | 2 | ||||||
5 | 1 | ||||||
6 | 2 | ||||||
7 | 1 | ||||||
8 | 2 | ||||||
9 | 1 | ||||||
10 | 2 | ||||||
… |
Appendix B
Appendix B1. Equity Principle
Appendix B2. Prominence
Appendix B3. Additional Categories
Appendix C
Category | Kappa in GER | Kappa in CHI |
---|---|---|
Equal Split (ES) | 1.000 | 1.000 |
Split the Difference (SD) | 0.949 | 0.987 |
Proportional Split (PS) | 1.000 | 1.000 |
Middle between Proposals (MP) | 0.844 | 0.856 |
Prominence (P) | 0.825 | 0.936 |
Middle between Split the Difference and Equal Split (MSDES) | 1.000 | - |
Middle between aspiration levels (MAL) | 1.000 | - |
Prominence in combination with other categories (PC) | 0.930 | 0.894 |
Accept proposal of opponent group (AP) | 1.000 | 0.961 |
No reasoning (NR) | 0.854 | 1.000 |
Appendix D
Category/Group | GS | GW | CS | CW |
---|---|---|---|---|
ES | 50.00 | 33.33 | 33.33 | |
SD | 50.00 | 16.67 | 55.56 | 33.33 |
PS | 16.67 | 11.11 | 11.11 | |
MP | 33.33 | 50.00 | 22.22 | 33.33 |
MSDES | 16.67 | |||
MAL | 16.67 | |||
P | 66.67 | 83.33 | 66.67 | 66.67 |
PC(ES) | 16.67 | 50.00 | 33.33 | |
PC(SD) | 50.00 | 44.44 | 22.22 | |
PC(PS) | 16.67 | |||
PC(MAL) | 16.67 |
Appendix E
References
- Schlicht, E. On Custom in the Economy; Clarendon Press: Oxford, UK, 1998. [Google Scholar]
- Kahneman, D.; Knetsch, J.L.; Thaler, R. Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. Am. Econ. Rev. 1986, 76, 728–741. [Google Scholar]
- Gächter, S.; Riedl, A. Moral property rights in bargaining. Manag. Sci. 2005, 51, 249–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roth, A.E.; Murnighan, J.K.; Schoumaker, F. The deadline effect in bargaining: Some experimental evidence. Am. Econ. Rev. 1988, 78, 155–162. [Google Scholar]
- Sauermann, H.; Selten, R. Anspruchsanpassungstheorie der Unternehmung. Z. Ges. Staatswiss. 1962, 118, 577–597. [Google Scholar]
- Selten, R. A Non-cooperative model of characteristic-function bargaining. In Essays in Game Theory and Mathematical Economics: in Honor of Oskar Morgenstern; Böhm, V., Nachtkamp, H.H., Eds.; Bibliographisches Institut AG: Mannheim, Germany, 1981; pp. 131–151. [Google Scholar]
- Ståhl, I. Bargaining Theory; Stockholm School of Economics: Stockholm, Sweden, 1972. [Google Scholar]
- Krelle, W. A New Theory of Bargaining: Applied to the Problem of Wage Determination and Strikes; Bonn University: Bonn, Germany, 1975; unpublished manuscript. [Google Scholar]
- Rubinstein, A. Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica 1982, 50, 97–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roth, A.E. (Ed.) Game-Theoretic Models of Bargaining; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; 1985. [Google Scholar]
- Fudenberg, D.; Levine, D.K.; Tirole, J. Incomplete information bargaining with outside opportunities. Q. J. Econ. 1987, 102, 37–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Binmore, K.; Morgan, P.; Shaked, A.; Sutton, J. Do people exploit their bargaining power? An experimental study. Game Econ. Behav. 1991, 3, 295–322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Asheim, G.B. A unique solution to n–person sequential bargaining. Games Econ. Behav. 1992, 4, 169–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tsiropoulou, E.E.; Kapoukakis, A.; Papavassiliou, S. Energy-efficient subcarrier allocation in SC–FDMA wireless networks based on multilateral model of bargaining. In Proceedings of the 2013 IFIP Networking Conference, Brooklyn, NY, USA, 22–24 May 2013; pp. 1–9. [Google Scholar]
- Tsiropoulou, E.E.; Ziras, I.; Papavassiliou, S. Service differentiation and resource allocation in SC–FDMA wireless networks through user-centric distributed non-cooperative multilateral bargaining. In Proceedings of the 7th International Conference, AdHocHets 2015, San Remo, Italy, 1–2 September 2015; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Tietz, R. An experimental analysis of wage bargaining behavior. Z. Ges. Staatswiss. 1975, 131, 44–91. [Google Scholar]
- Tietz, R. Entscheidungsprinzipien der bilateralen Anspruchsanpassung. In Neuere Entwicklungen in den Wirtschaftswissenschaften, Schriften des Vereins für Socialpolitik; N.F. 98; Helmstädter, E., Ed.; Duncker und Humblot: Berlin, Germany, 1978; pp. 431–453. [Google Scholar]
- Gächter, S.; Riedl, A. Dividing justly in bargaining problems with claims—Normative judgments and actual negotiations. Soc. Choice Welf. 2006, 27, 571–594. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fischer, S. Inequality Aversion in Ultimatum Games with Asymmetric Conflict Payoffs: A Theoretical and Experimental Analysis. Discussion Paper 2005-36; Max Planck Institute of Economics: Jena, Germany, 2005; Available online: http://papers.econ.mpg.de/esi/discussionpapers/2005-36.pdf (accessed on 24 September 2017).
- Rodriguez-Lara, I. Equity and bargaining power in ultimatum games. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2016, 130, 144–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hennig-Schmidt, H.; Irlenbusch, B.; Rilke, R.M.; Walkowitz, G. Asymmetric outside options in ultimatum bargaining: A systematic analysis. Int. J. Game Theory 2017, forthcoming. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kuon, B. Two–Person Bargaining Experiments with Incomplete Information; Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany; New York, NY, USA; London, UK; Paris, France; Tokyo, Japan; 1994; Volume 412. [Google Scholar]
- Knez, M.J.; Camerer, C.F. Outside options and social comparison in three-player ultimatum game experiments. Game Econ. Behav. 1995, 10, 65–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kagel, J.H.; Kim, C.; Moser, D. Fairness in ultimatum games with asymmetric information and asymmetric payoffs. Game Econ. Behav. 1996, 13, 100–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kohnz, S.; Hennig-Schmidt, H. Asymmetric Outside Options in Ultimatum Games—An Experimental Study; Unpublished manuscript; Bonn University: Bonn, Germany, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Schelling, T.C. Bargaining, communication, and limited war. J. Confl. Resolut. 1957, 1, 19–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Selten, R. The equity principle in economic behavior. In Decision Theory, Social Ethics, Issues in Social Choice; Gottinger, H.W., Leinfellner, W., Eds.; D. Reidel Publishing Company: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 1978; pp. 289–301. [Google Scholar]
- Selten, R. Equity and coalition bargaining in experimental three-person games. In Laboratory Experimentation in Economics; Roth, A.E., Ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK; 1987; pp. 42–98. [Google Scholar]
- Schelling, T.C. The Strategy of Conflict; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1960. [Google Scholar]
- Homans, G.C. Social Behaviour; Routledge and Kegan Paul: London, UK, 1961. [Google Scholar]
- Adams, J.S. Inequity in social exchange. In Advances in Experimental Social Psychology; Berkowitz, L., Ed.; Academic Press: New York, NY, USA, 1965; Volume 2, pp. 265–299. [Google Scholar]
- Konow, J. Fair Shares: Accountability and Cognitive Dissonance in Allocation Decisions. Am. Econ. Rev. 2000, 90, 1072–1091. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Konow, J. Which is the fairest one of all? A positive analysis of justice theories. J. Econ. Lit. 2003, 41, 1188–1239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Joachim, H.H.; Rees, D.A. Aristotle: The Nicomachean Ethics; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Mintu-Wimsatt, A. Equity sensitivity and negotiation behaviors: A look at Mexican exporters. Acad. Mark. Sci. Rev. 2005, 2005, 1. [Google Scholar]
- Narlikar, A. Fairness in international trade negotiations. World Econ. 2006, 29, 1005–1028. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sheikhmohammady, M.; Kilgour, D.M.; Hipel, K.W. Modeling the Caspian Sea negotiations. Group Decis. Negot. 2010, 19, 149–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Babcock, L.; Loewenstein, G. Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. J. Econ. Perspect. 1997, 11, 109–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cappelen, A.; Hole, A.; Sørensen, E.; Tungodden, B. The pluralism of fairness ideals: An experimental approach. Am. Econ. Rev. 2007, 97, 818–827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gantner, A.; Güth, W.; Königstein, M. Equitable choices in bargaining games with joint production. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2001, 46, 209–225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Clark, J. Fairness in public good provision: An investigation of preferences for equality and proportionality. Can. J. Econ. 1998, 31, 708–729. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Albers, W.; Albers, G. On the prominence structure of the decimal system. In Decision Making under Uncertainty; Scholz, R.W., Ed.; Elsevier Science Publishers B.V.: Amsterdam, The Netherlands; 1983; pp. 271–287. [Google Scholar]
- Jullien, F. Über die ‘Zeit’: Elemente einer Philosophie des Lebens; Diaphanes: Zürich, Switzerland; Berlin, Germany, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Li, Sh. The History of Chinese Confucianism; Peoples Publishing House: Shanghai, China, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Faure, G.O.; Fang, T. Changing Chinese values: Keeping up with paradoxes. Int. Bus. Rev. 2008, 17, 194–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roth, A.E.; Prasnikar, V.; Okuno-Fujiwara, M.; Zamir, S. Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An experimental study. Am. Econ. Rev. 1991, 81, 1068–1095. [Google Scholar]
- Herrmann, B.; Thöni, C.; Gächter, S. Anti-social punishment across societies. Science 2008, 319, 1362–1367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Herrmann, B.; Thöni, C.; Gächter, S. Supporting Material for Anti-social punishment across societies. Science 2008, 319, 1362–1367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Brislin, R.W. Back-translation for cross-cultural research. J. Cross Cult. Psychol. 1970, 1, 185–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hennig-Schmidt, H.; Leopold-Wildburger, U.; Ostmann, A.; van Winden, F. Understanding negotiations: A video approach in experimental gaming. In The Selten School of Behavioral Economics—A Collection of Essays in Honor of Reinhard Selten; Ockenfels, A., Sadrieh, A., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2010; pp. 127–166. [Google Scholar]
- Bakeman, R. Behavioral observation and coding. In Handbook of Research Methods in Social and Personality Psychology; Reis, H.T., Judd, Ch.M., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000; pp. 138–159. [Google Scholar]
- Bosman, R.; Hennig-Schmidt, H.; van Winden, F. Exploring group decision making in a power-to-take experiment. Exp. Econ. 2006, 9, 35–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kerr, N.L.; Aronoff, J.; Messé, L.A. Methods of Small Group Research. In Handbook of Research Methods in Social and Personality Psychology; Reis, H.T., Judd, C.M., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000; pp. 160–189. [Google Scholar]
- Smith, Ch.P. Content Analysis and Narrative Analysis. In Handbook of Research Methods in Social and Personality Psychology; Reis, H.T., Judd, Ch.M., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000; pp. 313–335. [Google Scholar]
- Siegel, S.; Castellan, N.J., Jr. Nonparametric Statistics for the Behavioral Sciences, 2nd ed.; McGraw-Hill: New York, NY, USA; Toronto, ON, Canada, 1988. [Google Scholar]
- Krippendorff, K. Content Analysis: An Introduction to Its Methodology; Sage Publications: Beverly Hills, CA, USA, 1980. [Google Scholar]
- Merten, K. Inhaltsanalyse: Einführung in Theorie, Methode und Praxis; Springer: Heidelberg, Germany, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Bartholomew, K.; Henderson, A.J.Z.; Marcia, J.A. Coding semistructured interviews in social psychological research. In Handbook of Research Methods in Social and Personality Psychology; Reis, H.T., Judd, C.M., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000; pp. 286–312. [Google Scholar]
- Kuon, B.; Uhlich, G.R. The Negotiation Agreement Area: An experimental analysis of two-person characteristic function games. Group Decis. Negot. 1993, 2, 323–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hennig-Schmidt, H.; Walkowitz, G. Negotiations among Chinese and GermansAn experimental case study. Homo Oecon. 2015, 32, 451–488. [Google Scholar]
- Fehr, E.; Schmidt, K.M. A Theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Q. J. Econ. 1999, 14, 815–868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bolton, G.E.; Ockenfels, A. ERC: A theory of equity, reciprocity, and competition. Am. Econ. Rev. 2000, 90, 166–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Okada, A.; Riedl, A. When Culture Does not Matter: Experimental Evidence from Coalition Formation Ultimatum Games in Austria and Japan; Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 99-043/1; Tinbergen Institute: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Brandts, J.; Saijo, T.; Schram, A. How universal is behavior? A four country comparison of spite and cooperation in voluntary contribution mechanisms. Public Choice 2004, 119, 381–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Leung, K.; Bond, M.H. The impact of cultural collectivism on reward allocation. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 1984, 47, 793–804. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bian, W.Q.; Keller, L.R. Patterns of fairness judgments in North America and the People’s Republic of China. J. Consum. Psychol. 1999, 8, 301–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hennig-Schmidt, H. The impact of fairness on decision making—An analysis of different video experiments. In Experimental Economics: Financial Markets, Auctions, and Decision Making; Andersson, F., Holm, H., Eds.; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Boston, MA, USA; Dordrecht, The Netherlands; London, UK, 2002; pp. 185–210. [Google Scholar]
- Konow, J. A positive theory of economic fairness. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 1996, 31, 13–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frohlich, N.; Oppenheimer, J.; Kurki, A. Modeling other-regarding preferences and an experimental test. Public Choice 2004, 119, 91–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cappelen, A.W.; Sørensen, E.Ø.; Tungodden, B. Responsibility for what? Fairness and individual responsibility. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2010, 54, 429–441. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rode, J.; Le Menestrel, M. The influence of decision power on distributive fairness. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2011, 79, 246–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Franco-Watkins, A.M.; Edwards, B.D.; Acuff, R.E. Effort and fairness in bargaining games. J. Behav. Decis. Mak. 2013, 26, 79–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rodriguez-Lara, I.; Moreno-Garrido, L. Self-interest and fairness: Self-serving choices of justice principles. Exp. Econ. 2012, 15, 158–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Karagözoğlu, E.; Riedl, A. Performance information, production uncertainty, and subjective entitlements in bargaining. Manag. Sci. 2014, 61, 2611–2626. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Falk, A.; Heckman, J.J. Lab experiments are a major source of knowledge in social sciences. Science 2009, 326, 535–538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Falk, A.; Meier, S.; Zehnder, C. Do lab experiments misrepresent social preferences? The case of self-selected student samples. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2013, 11, 839–852. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kulich, S.J.; Zhang, R. The multiple frames of ‘Chinese’ values: From tradition to modernity and beyond. In The Handbook of Chinese People; Bond, M.H., Ed.; Oxford University Press: New York, NY, USA, 2010; pp. 241–278. [Google Scholar]
- Von Senger, H. Strategeme: Lebens—Und Überlebenslisten der Chinesen—Die Berühmten 36 Strategeme aus Drei Jahrtausenden; Scherz: Bern, Switzerland; München, Germany; Wien, Austria, 1988. [Google Scholar]
- Von Senger, H. The 36 Stratagems for Managers; Carl Hanser Verlag: Munich, Germany, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Faure, G.O. Negotiation: The Chinese concept. Negot. J. 1998, 14, 137–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bond, M.H.; Hwang, K.-K. The Social Psychology of Chinese People. In The Psychology of Chinese People; Bond, M.H., Ed.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1986; pp. 211–266. [Google Scholar]
- Salacuse, J.W. Intercultural negotiation in international business. Group Decis. Negot. 1999, 8, 217–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | |
2 | Due to a no-show, one German weak group consisted of only two participants. |
3 | See the English translations in Appendix A. |
4 | Because of the extensive negotiations between the Chinese groups (the first session lasted for nearly four hours) and organizational requirements (some sessions had to be run in the evening and the buildings closed at 11 p.m.), the experiment in China had to be changed with regard to the time limit. After 2.5 h of bargaining—the longest time period of bargaining in the German experiment—the Chinese participants were informed that they would be paid the outside options if they did not come to an agreement within the next 20 min. Initially, no time limit was announced beforehand. |
5 | Hennig-Schmidt. |
6 | Average payoffs may be considered as low. Note, however, that the averages include the payoffs from four negotiations (i.e., eight groups) without agreement. In these cases, the subjects earned their outside option only. |
7 | For our analyses, Chinese transcripts were translated into German. |
8 | For an extensive discussion, see Hennig-Schmidt et al. [50]. |
9 | Participants seem to feel relaxed and to forget the camera after several minutes. They talk about private matters, and sometimes they even comment negatively on their university teachers. |
10 | Sessions are divided into negotiation rounds. Each negotiation round comprises a discussion, a decision (i, ii, iii, iii, or iv) and a subsequent discussion until the next decision of the opponent is transmitted. |
11 | For a detailed description of the categories, see Appendix B. |
12 | Κ is the ratio of the proportion of times the coders agree, P(A) (corrected for chance agreement P(E)), to the maximum proportion of times they could have agreed (corrected for chance agreement), thus Κ = [P(A) − P(E)]/[(1 − P(E)]. |
13 | We exclude this case from the following analysis. |
14 | Recall that each player’s outside option amounts to less than 50% of the pie. |
15 | Opening proposals: both p ≤ 0.004; initial aspiration levels: both p ≤ 0.013, Mann–Whitney U test, (denoted as MWU in the following). |
16 | Except for GS (p = 0.500), these differences are statistically significant (all p ≤ 0.031, Wilcoxon matched pairs sign test, denoted as WM in the following). |
17 | |
18 | All p ≥ 0.250, WM. |
19 | p = 0.063, WM. |
20 | All p ≤ 0.062, WM. |
21 | Other, less relevant, categories are “Time is money” and “Golden split”, which we subsume under the category “O: Other”. See Subsection 2.4. for the procedure and Appendix B for the detailed definition and explanation of the categories. |
22 | GER: p = 0.061, CHI: p = 0.131, Fisher’s Exact Test (in the following denoted as FET). |
23 | GER: p = 0.08, CHI: p = 0.05, FET. |
24 | All p ≥ 0.219, WM. |
25 | p = 0.016, WM. |
26 | Exact McNemar significance probability, all p ≥ 0.45. |
27 | p = 0.009, FET. |
28 | GS: MSDES, P and PC(SD): 16.67% each, Other—including AP and NR: 50.00%. GW: MP and PC(MAL): 16.67% each, Other— including AP and NR: 66.67%. |
29 | CS: ES, SD and P: 22.22% each, PC(SD): 11.11%, Other—including AP and NR:22.22%. CW: ES: 33.33% each, SD and MP: 11.11% each, P: 44.44%. |
30 | p = 0.067, FET. |
31 | All p ≥ 0.261, FET. |
32 | p = 0.058, FET. |
33 | In German: (Un)Fairness, (un)fair, (Un)Gerechtigkeit, (un)gerecht. |
34 | The coding process was the same as described in Subsection 2.4. |
35 | This difference is weakly significant (p = 0.079, FET). |
36 | Other categories rarely mentioned are “Middle between proposals” and “Other”. |
37 | All p ≥ 0.340, MWU, strong and weak German groups vs. the respective Chinese groups. No significant differences in outcomes across countries have been found either, for instance, between Austria and Japan by [63] in Coalition Formation Ultimatum Games nor by [64] between the Netherlands, Spain, the US, and Japan in public-goods games. |
38 | p = 0.052 for proposal rounds, p = 0.064 for minutes, MWU. |
39 | By this definition, we neglect threats negotiators sometimes make by reducing their current proposal relative to the previous one. |
40 | Strong groups: p = 0.026, weak groups: p = 0.285, both MWU. |
41 | Strong groups: p = 0.025; weak groups: p = 0.120, MWU. |
42 | See, e.g., Kuon and Uhlich [59], who arrive at quite different results even though their experimental study is based on the same game and the same parameters as ours. For instance, the authors have to infer initial aspiration levels from first offers, which—as we have seen—may include tactical reserves. |
43 | See also Falk et al. [76] for evidence on very similar behavioral patterns among students and non-students. |
44 | Note that 19 of the 34 different aspiration levels comprise allocations divisible by 5. |
Treatment | GER | CHI | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Strong/Weak Group | GS | GW | CS | CW | Total |
Subjects | 18 | 17 | 27 | 27 | 89 |
Groups | 6 | 6 | 9 | 9 | 30 |
Sessions | 6 | 6 | 9 | 9 | 15 |
Treatment | GER | CHI | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Variable/Player Type | GS | GW | CS | CW |
Negotiated outcome | 159.17 | 107.5 | 171.56 | 112.89 |
Opening proposal | 247.33 | 130.00 | 262.00 | 130.11 |
Final proposal | 198.17 | 177.17 | 190.33 | 185.00 |
Concession | 49.16 | 47.17 | 71.67 | 54.89 |
Initial aspiration level | 228.00 | 165.00 | 221.56 | 174.22 |
Final aspiration level | 189.67 | 184.50 | 191.11 | 182.56 |
Adaptation of aspiration level | 38.33 | 19.50 | 30.44 | 8.33 |
Number (%) agreements | 4 (66.67) | 7 (77.78) |
Country | Group | Opening Proposal | Initial AL | Aspiration Adaptation | Last Proposal | Final AL | Negotiated Outcome | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Points | Points | Category & | Category & | Points | Points | Category & | Points $ | Final Decision * | ||
Germany | G1S | 256 | 256 | PS | ES, P, SD, PC(SD), MP | 168 | 167 | AP | 167 | A |
G2S | 208 | 208 | SD | ES | 208 | 200 | PC(SD) | 128 | B | |
G3S | 280 | 280 | P | PS, SD | 250 | 240 | P | 128 | B | |
G4S | 264 | 208 | SD | PC(SD), P, MP, O | 200 | 172 | AP | 172 | A | |
G5S | 256 | 256 | PS | ES, SD | 188 | 184 | MSDES | 185 | A | |
G6S | 220 | 160 | ES | P, PC(ES), O | 175 | 175 | NR | 175 | A | |
G1W | 140 | 160 | ES | P, PC(ES) | 167 | 167 | NR | 153 | A | |
G2W | 140 | 160 | ES | PC(ES), P | 165 | 180 | MP | 32 | B | |
G3W | 130 | 160 | ES | PC(ES), P | 200 | 200 | O | 32 | B | |
G4W | 80 | 160 | ES | MP | 172 | 200 | O | 148 | A | |
G5W | 160 | 190 | O | SD, P | 185 | 185 | AP | 135 | A | |
G6W | 130 | 160 | ES | O, P, MP, MAL | 174 | 175 | PC(MAL) | 145 | A | |
China | C1S | 256 | 256 | PS | PC(SD), NR, P | 210 | 208 | SD | 208 | A |
C2S | 280 | 256 | PS | O, P(O), SD, MP | 185 | 200 | PC(SD) | 185 | A | |
C3S | 300 | 200 | P | P, SD, NR, PC(SD), MP | 195 | 194 | AP | 195 | A | |
C4S | 208 | 208 | SD | ES | 160 | 160 | ES | 160 | A | |
C5S | 285 | 252 | NR | P, PC(PS) | 210 | 210 | P | 128 | NT | |
C6S | 306 | 256 | PS | ES, P, | 195 | 190 | AP | 190 | AT | |
C7S | 278 | 208 | SD | P | 208 | 208 | SD | 128 | NT | |
C8S | 285 | 198 | O | SD, PS, PC(SD), NR | 190 | 190 | P | 190 | AT | |
C9S | 160 | 160 | ES | ES | 160 | 160 | ES | 160 | A | |
C1W | 168 | 208 | SD | P, PC(SD), NR | 208 | 208 | SD | 112 | A | |
C2W | 160 | 160 | ES | SD, O, PC(SD) | 180 | 185 | MP | 135 | A | |
C3W | 70 | 160 | ES | SD, O, PC(ES), MP | 194 | 195 | P | 125 | A | |
C4W | 128 | 200 | P | PS, AP, P, PC(ES) | 150 | 160 | ES | 160 | A | |
C5W | 80 | 160 | ES | P | 200 | 195 | P | 32 | NT | |
C6W | 110 | 160 | ES | P(ES), P, MP, O | 190 | 190 | P | 130 | AT | |
C7W | 135 | 160 | ES | ES | 192 | 160 | ES | 32 | NT | |
C8W | 160 | 200 | P | P | 191 | 190 | P | 130 | AT | |
C9W | 160 | 160 | ES | ES | 160 | 160 | ES | 160 | A |
© 2017 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Hennig-Schmidt, H.; Walkowitz, G. Moral Entitlements and Aspiration Formation in Asymmetric Bargaining: Experimental Evidence from Germany and China. Games 2017, 8, 44. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8040044
Hennig-Schmidt H, Walkowitz G. Moral Entitlements and Aspiration Formation in Asymmetric Bargaining: Experimental Evidence from Germany and China. Games. 2017; 8(4):44. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8040044
Chicago/Turabian StyleHennig-Schmidt, Heike, and Gari Walkowitz. 2017. "Moral Entitlements and Aspiration Formation in Asymmetric Bargaining: Experimental Evidence from Germany and China" Games 8, no. 4: 44. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8040044
APA StyleHennig-Schmidt, H., & Walkowitz, G. (2017). Moral Entitlements and Aspiration Formation in Asymmetric Bargaining: Experimental Evidence from Germany and China. Games, 8(4), 44. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8040044