A Note on Disbelief in Others regarding Backward Induction
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Experimental Procedure and Design
3. Results
4. Conclusions
Acknowledgments
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Race Game-Instructions
- On each turn, no more than 4 balls are allowed to be removed.
- On each turn, at least 1 or 2 balls have to be removed (this can vary depending on the round).
- (A)
- You and your team member take the last ball: You get a lottery ticket that wins with a probability of 100%. Otherwise, you will get a lottery ticket that wins with a probability of 0%.
- (B)
- You and your team member take the last ball: You get a lottery ticket that wins with a probability of 70%. Otherwise, you will get a lottery ticket that wins with a probability of 30%.
References
- Rosenthal, R.W. Games of perfect information, predatory pricing and the chain-store paradox. J. Econ. Theory 1981, 25, 92–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McKelvey, R.D.; Palfrey, T.R. An experimental study of the centipede game. Econometrica 1992, 60, 803–836. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nagel, R. Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study. Am. Econ. Rev. 1995, 85, 1313–1326. [Google Scholar]
- Fey, M.; McKelvey, R.D.; Palfrey, T.R. An experimental study of Constant-Sum centipede games. Int. J. Game Theory 1996, 25, 269–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ho, T.H.; Camerer, C.F.; Weigelt, K. Iterated dominance and iterated best response in experimental “p-beauty contests”. Am. Econ. Rev. 1998, 88, 947–969. [Google Scholar]
- Nagel, R.; Tang, F.F. Experimental results on the centipede game in normal form: An investigation on learning. J. Math. Psychol. 1998, 42, 356–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Bosch-Domènech, A.; Montalvo, J.G.; Nagel, R.; Satorra, A. One, two, (three), infinity, ... newspaper and lab beauty-contest experiments. Am. Econ. Rev. 2002, 92, 1687–1701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Burnham, T.C.; Cesarini, D.; Johannesson, M.; Lichtenstein, P.; Wallace, B. Higher cognitive ability is associated with lower entries in a p-beauty contest. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2009, 72, 171–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Palacios-Huerta, I.; Volij, O. Field centipedes. Am. Econ. Rev. 2009, 99, 1619–1635. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levitt, S.D.; List, J.A.; Sadoff, S.E. Checkmate: Exploring backward induction among chess players. Am. Econ. Rev. 2011, 101, 975–990. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Agranov, M.; Caplin, A.; Tergiman, C. Naive play and the process of choice in guessing games. J. Econ. Sci. Assoc. 2015, 1, 146–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crawford, V.P.; Costa-Gomes, M.A.; Iriberri, N. Structural models of nonequilibrium strategic thinking: Theory, evidence, and applications. J. Econ. Lit. 2013, 51, 5–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chou, E.; McConnell, M.; Nagel, R.; Plott, C.R. The control of game form recognition in experiments: Understanding dominant strategy failures in a simple two person “Guessing” game. Exp. Econ. 2009, 12, 159–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Devetag, G.; Warglien, M. Playing the wrong game: An experimental analysis of relational complexity and strategic misrepresentation. Games Econ. Behav. 2008, 62, 364–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Aumann, R.J. Irrationality in game theory. In Economic Analysis of Markets and Games; Dasgupta, P., Gale, D., Hart, O., Maskin, E., Eds.; MIT Press: Cambridge, UK, 1992; pp. 214–227. [Google Scholar]
- Reny, P.J. Common knowledge and games with perfect information. In Proceedings of the Biennial Meeting of the Philosophy of Science Association; The University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 1988; Volume 2, pp. 363–369. [Google Scholar]
- Georganas, S.; Healy, P.J.; Weber, R.A. On the persistence of strategic sophistication. J. Econ. Theory 2015, 159, 369–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levitt, S.D.; List, J.A.; Reiley, D.H. What happens in the field stays in the field: Exploring whether professionals play minimax in laboratory experiments. Econometrica 2010, 78, 1413–1434. [Google Scholar]
- Gneezy, U.; Rustichini, A.; Vostroknutov, A. Experience and insight in the race game. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2010, 75, 144–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dufwenberg, M.; Sundaram, R.; Butler, D.J. Epiphany in the game of 21. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2010, 75, 132–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Brosig-Koch, J.; Heinrich, T.; Helbach, C. Exploring the capability to reason backwards: An experimental study with children, adolescents, and young adults. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2015, 74, 286–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bock, O.; Nicklisch, A.; Baetge, I. hroot: Hamburg Recruitment and Organization Online Tool. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2014, 71, 117–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fischbacher, U. z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-made Economic Experiments. Exp. Econ. 2007, 10, 171–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1. | |
2. | The instructions can be found in the Appendix. |
3. | Due to our research interest in initial responses, we aim at impeding learning as much as possible; therefore, each game is unique. |
4. | Of course, subjects could always observe their own performance in the extended race games. |
5. | The variable “father’s education” is ordinal and takes the following values depending on the highest degree of education the subject’s father obtained: 1 = Certificate of Secondary Education (Hauptschulabschluss), 2 = General Certificate of Secondary Education (Realschulabschluss), 3 = Restricted qualification for university entrance (Fachschulabitur), 4 = General qualification for university entrance (Abitur), 5 = Bachelor degree, 6 = Master degree (Diplom/Magister). Results do not change if we work with dummies for each type of educational level. |
Series | Parameter | Game Number | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
0 * | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | ||
FirstERG1 | ℓ | 1 | 2 | 1 | 2 | 1 | 2 | 1 | 2 |
u | 3 | ||||||||
m | 6 | 6 | 11 | 11 | 13 | 13 | 18 | 18 | |
SecondERG2 | ℓ | 1 | 2 | 1 | 2 | 1 | 2 | 1 | 2 |
u | 4 | ||||||||
m | 7 | 10 | 12 | 13 | 14 | 16 | 17 | 19 |
Treatment | First Series | Second Series | Subjects | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Single | ERG1 (308) | ERG2 single (308) | ||||
Team | ERG1 (448) | ERG2 team (448) | ||||
Team-info | ERG1 (560) | ERG2 team-info (560) |
Choosing Option B? | Model | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | |||||
Team condition? (no = 0, yes = 1) | 0 | 579 (0.253) ** | 0 | 580 (0.253) ** | 0 | 596 (0.274) ** | |
Info condition? (no = 0, yes = 1) | 0 | 768 (0.241) *** | 0 | 468 (0.332) | 0 | 393 (0.345) | |
Second series? (no = 0, yes = 1) | 0 | 917 (0.193) *** | 0 | 918 (0.193) *** | 0 | 953 (0.206) *** | |
Info. examined? (no = 0, yes = 1) | 2 | 564 (0.583) *** | 2 | 681 (0.607) *** | |||
If info. examined: Team member’s BI-score | −0 | 812 (0.174) *** | −0 | 828 (0.181) *** | |||
Male (no = 0, yes = 1) | −0 | 449 (0.296) | |||||
Age (in years) | −0 | 058 (0.044) | |||||
Father’s education (1 [low]−6 [high]) | 0 | 105 (0.073) | |||||
Constant | 0 | 007 (0.135) | 0 | 006 (0.136) | 1 | 126 (1.116) | |
Observations | 2632 | 2632 | 2352 |
© 2017 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Tutić, A.; Grehl, S. A Note on Disbelief in Others regarding Backward Induction. Games 2017, 8, 33. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8030033
Tutić A, Grehl S. A Note on Disbelief in Others regarding Backward Induction. Games. 2017; 8(3):33. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8030033
Chicago/Turabian StyleTutić, Andreas, and Sascha Grehl. 2017. "A Note on Disbelief in Others regarding Backward Induction" Games 8, no. 3: 33. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8030033
APA StyleTutić, A., & Grehl, S. (2017). A Note on Disbelief in Others regarding Backward Induction. Games, 8(3), 33. https://doi.org/10.3390/g8030033