Next Article in Journal
Variation in Cropping Intensity in Northern China from 1982 to 2012 Based on GIMMS-NDVI Data
Next Article in Special Issue
The Delimitation of Urban Growth Boundaries Using the CLUE-S Land-Use Change Model: Study on Xinzhuang Town, Changshu City, China
Previous Article in Journal
Thinking about Smart Cities: The Travels of a Policy Idea that Promises a Great Deal, but So Far Has Delivered Modest Results
Previous Article in Special Issue
Exploring Land Use and Land Cover of Geotagged Social-Sensing Images Using Naive Bayes Classifier
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Using Machine Learning in Environmental Tax Reform Assessment for Sustainable Development: A Case Study of Hubei Province, China

1
Department of Urban and Economic Geography, College of Urban and Environmental Sciences, Peking University, Beijing 100871, China
2
Lincoln Institute Center for Urban Development and Land Policy, Peking University, Beijing 100871, China
3
Agricultural Information Institute, Chinese Academy of Agricultural Sciences, Beijing 100081, China
4
Department of Business Administration, College of Management, Beijing Union University, Beijing 100101, China
5
Department of Geography, Kent State University, Kent, OH 44242, USA
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2016, 8(11), 1124; https://doi.org/10.3390/su8111124
Submission received: 26 September 2016 / Revised: 28 October 2016 / Accepted: 29 October 2016 / Published: 1 November 2016
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sustainable Ecosystems and Society in the Context of Big and New Data)

Abstract

:
During the past 30 year of economic growth, China has also accumulated a huge environmental pollution debt. China’s government attempts to use a variety of means, including tax instruments to control environmental pollution. After nine years of repeated debates, the State Council Legislative Affairs Office released the Environmental Protection Tax Law (Draft) in June 2015. As China’s first environmental tax law, whether this conservative “Environmental Fee to Tax (EFT)” reform could improve the environment has generated controversy. In this paper, we seek insights to this controversial issue using the machine learning approach, a powerful tool for environmental policy assessment. We take Hubei Province, the first pilot area as a case of EFT, and analyze the institutional incentive, behavior transformation and emission intensity reduction performance. Twelve pilot cities located in Hubei Province were selected to estimate the effect of the reform by using synthetic control and a rapid developing machine learning method for policy evaluation. We find that the EFT reform can promote emission intensity reduction. Especially, relative to comparable synthetic cities in the absence of the reform, the average annual emission intensity of Sulfur Dioxide (SO2) in the pilot cities dropped by 0.13 ton/million Yuan with a reduction rate of 10%–32%. Our findings also show that the impact of environmental tax reform varies across cities due to the administrative level and economic development. The results of our study are also supported by enterprise interviews. The EFT improves the overall environmental costs, and encourages enterprises to reduce emissions pollution. These results provide valuable experience and policy implications for the implementation of China’s Environmental Protection Tax Law.

1. Introduction

Frequent large-scale environmental disasters, such as haze and water pollution, have raised concerns among researchers and the public [1]. Such social pressure forces the government to actively explore new instruments of governance to control environmental pollutions [2,3], and employ new methods such as machine learning to evaluate its policies.
Environmental Taxes are a particular type of economic instrument to handle environmental problems by internalizing environmental costs and creating economic incentives for the public and businesses to promote ecologically sustainable activities [1,4].
For thirty years, environmental tax reform has developed rapidly in the globe [4]. European Union (EU) has implemented series of green growth policies since 1990s [5,6,7]. In Canada, British Columbia (BC) became the first jurisdiction to approve a revenue-neutral carbon tax in 2008 [8]. Environmental tax reform has also spread to developing countries in Asia [9]. The major concern of environment tax in these countries is to adjust the tax bases and to bring about “double dividend” [10], as to improve the environment and economic efficiency simultaneously. Since having gradually getting rid of the dilemma of “treatment after pollution”, the object of taxation in developed countries is mainly carbon [11]. Likewise, the research on the environmental tax has also focused on relationship between environmental management, economic development and social activities [12,13,14]. Typical evaluation methods include CGE (Computable General Equilibrium) [6] such as General Equilibrium Model for Economy-Energy-Environment (GEM-E3, http://www.gem-e3.net), Asia-Pacific Integrated Model (AIM, http://www-iam.nies.go.jp) and Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP, http://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/models), and time-series-based macro-econometric models [15], such as GINFORS [16] and E3ME [17].
With the growing prominence of environmental issues, the study of environmental tax reform in China has also followed the international trends [3]. China’s environmental policy assessment originated from the study of pollution levy system [18,19,20,21], focusing on the analysis of the effect, mechanism of sewage fees and collection system aiming to reduce the charges. With the internationalization of China’s environmental problems, the central focus has also shifted to environmental taxes [2] and the interaction between environmental policy and economic development [22], such as double dividend [23] and the theoretical mechanism on EFT reform. CGE [24,25] and other simulation methods are applied in the evaluations. The research on environmental tax in China is still in its infancy and focuses mainly on tracking research on international hot topics and methods while lacks in-depth quantitative analysis on China’s own environmental pollution control policy assessment. China is still suffering from serious environmental pollution. Unlike developed countries that focus on carbon emissions, China pays more attention on SO2 and other pollutants control in its Environmental Protection Tax Law (Draft) and other environmental policies. In China, environmental taxes were first introduced in “Energy Saving and Emission Reduction Comprehensive Work Plan, 2007”. Essentially, the most important part of the environmental tax reform is the “Environmental Fee to Tax (EFT)” reform. This EFT reform was first piloted in Hubei Province in October 2007. After years of repeated debates, the State Council Legislative Affairs Office released the Environmental Protection Tax Law (Draft) in June 2015 and officially extended Hubei Province’s EFT reform mode nationwide.
The environmental implication of this EFT reform is still in controversy [1]. Supporters of this law believe that EFT is changing the pollutant discharge fees, a soft constraint into environmental taxes, an obligatory constraint, greatly enhancing the intensity and rigidity of law enforcement. EFT is an effective way to avoid rent-seeking in the environmental protection departments and interference to the collection of pollutant discharge fees by protectionisms, and reduce the shelter to polluters, so as to promote polluting enterprises to make efforts on reducing emissions [22,24].
Opponents argued that the main reason for the poor effect of pollutant discharge fees is that the fee rate of pollutants is too low; this cannot generate incentives for emission reductions. Enterprises would rather pay than reduce emissions [21]. When the pollutant discharge fees are changed into environmental taxes, while pollutant tax rates are not greatly increased, the emission reduction will not be promoted. Therefore, a reasonable assessment of the policy effect of EFT not only has theoretical significance but also has important practical meaning for the legislation of environmental protection tax [1,23].
As many important reforms in China, China’s legislation on environmental taxes follows the line of thinking—from pilot to popularization. Ordinary measurement methods are difficult to have performance for the implementation of pilot policy on a small scale. The limitations of CGE model and macroeconomic model in the environmental emissions effect evaluation are also prompting China to seek another way to assess the effect of environmental tax reform [24,25].
Experimental economics presents an objective and effective evaluation of experimental results, and provides a new perspective and solution for the policy makers and scholars [26,27]. The reasonable environment system design can change the behavior of pollution through both of constraint and incentive, and then reach the expected goal of environmental performance, and therefore, the organic combination of system, behavior and performance is an effective strategy for the research and analysis of EFT policy.
Experimental economics has a quasi-natural experimental method. The experimental group, where the policy is implemented, is compared with the control group, where the policy is not implemented. The effect of policy can be seen by the difference of the two groups. The core of quasi-natural experiment method is to find the appropriate control group, and the main methods include difference-in-differences (DIDS), regression discontinuity design (RD design), synthetic control method (SCM), etc. Among them, the DIDS is the longest method costing most study efforts, and moreover its credibility is higher [27]. However, DIDS has two major problems for the performance study of EFT as follows: (1) subjectivity of control group select; and (2) policy endogenesis [28].
RD design is the most widely used in the specific space or in a field, there are obvious natural boundaries. SCM has the shortest time of birth which uses machine learning for fitting; this is a method highly suitable for the study of small samples [29,30].
SCM is a new policy evaluation method proposed by Abadie [29], and its basic idea is to construct a good control city through a weighted combination of multi control cities, so as to seek for a control city that is completely similar to the target city; this is still an important and difficult problem, which has long plagued the research of policy assessment. SCM’s advantages are as follows: (1) SCM is suitable for fine quantitative analysis of small samples; (2) by machine learning method based on big data, SCM can determine the weight of control city group to decrease the error of subjective choice [30]; and (3) SCM uses independent modeling, provides corresponding control object for the study of individual, and avoids average evaluation [31].
The basic logic of this method is that it is difficult to find a similar comparison city for each city in the treatment group, but we can construct a good comparison city with other no-EFT cities outside Hubei Province by multiple computing iterations in machine learning algorithm. Because synthetic control avoids the limitation of the traditional method, it has been widely used in the field of policy evaluation in recent years, including crime interventions [32], tropical deforestation [33] and local impacts of nuclear power facilities [34]. In the field of environmental policy, Zhang [35] has used the synthetic control method to evaluate whether the 2008 Olympic Games improved Beijing’s air quality.
In this study, we employ the synthetic control method, a new approach based on machine learning algorithm, to assess the impacts of EFT reform among 12 cities in Hubei Province. By creating a synthetic city with multi cities to replicate the target city, we obtained the excess reductions of SO2 emission caused by the reform. The results demonstrate that the EFT reform can effectively restrain the pollutant discharge, but the effect has regional heterogeneity.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 is background of policy. Section 3 introduces the method and data. Section 4 estimates the influence of EFT reform on the SO2 emission intensity. Finally, Section 5 is the discussion and conclusions.

2. Policy Background

2.1. Background of Hubei Province EFT

Since the end of 1990s, the voice of pollutant discharge fees reform continues nationwide. Hubei Province is the first and the only pilot area; this has its profound inner background. First of all, Hubei Province has experienced a process of high growth and high pollution since 2004. Stimulated by the policy of the rise of central China, Hubei Province’s GDP has been in a rapid growth since 2004. From 2008 to present, GDP growth rate in Hubei Province has been higher than the average level in other regions of the country. With economic development, pollution problems became increasingly prominent. During 2004–2005, pollutant emissions generally declined throughout the country; in this context, Hubei Province had a substantial increase in emissions of pollutants [9]. Secondly, Hubei Province’s collection of pollutant discharge fees was inadequate for a long time, and the effect of pollution emission reduction was not good [10].
The inadequate collection of pollutant discharge fees in Hubei Province is related to the local government’s serious interference with the pollutant discharge fees in order to protect the economic development. Some local governments introduced their own policy to distort pollutant discharge fees in order to develop their local economy.
In addition to improving the collection enforcement of pollutant discharge fees, another impetus to the reform in Hubei Province is that irregularities in the use of local pollutant discharge fees are expected to be changed [11]. The situation of illegal use of pollutant discharge fees in Hubei Province was repeatedly exposed. Under the pressure of public opinion, Hubei Province tried to correct the use of pollutant discharge fees by means of reform. Therefore, in order to reduce local protectionism and power abuse of environmental protection department, improve the collection efficiency of pollutant discharge fees, and give play to the role of encouragement of pollutant discharge fees, Hubei Province actively reported to the central government, and the pilot of EFT was carried out in Hubei Province.

2.2. Current EFT Pilot Tax System

In view of failure of pollutant discharge fees, on 1 October 2007, Hubei Province started implementing the reform of EFT (http://www.hbepb.gov.cn/hbfg/szfgz/200710/t20071012_8814.html). In the past, “the environmental protection department was responsible for approval and collection of pollutant discharge fees”, after the reform of EFT, “the environmental protection department is in charge of approval while local tax department is in charge of collection”. The pattern of collection and supervision is that “the environmental protection department is responsible for approval while the tax department is responsible for collection, and the bank is for storage while the financial system is for unified management”, making collection, management and use of pollutant discharge fees separate. Accordingly, a new collection and supervision pattern of pollutant discharge fees is formed, namely four-sector linkage of environmental protection, tax, finance and bank, and joint supervision, which pioneered the reform of collection and supervision of pollutant discharge fees in the county [9,10]. The specific differences before and after EFT in Hubei Province are shown in Table 1.

3. Method and Data

3.1. Synthetic Control Method and Machining Learning

In the public domain, from the national level, a series of policy intervention may be implemented. How to identify the path and influence size of a correct policy is very difficult, especially the effect of a pilot policy [28]. There are two main reasons:
(1)
Policy endogeneity, which means that there is a systematic difference between pilot cities and other cities, and this difference is exactly the reason for why the cities to become pilot cities;
(2)
The time and regional restrictions of the pilot areas cannot provide a large number of policy implementation samples; this is not applicable to the traditional econometric methods. Synthetic control method provides a new approach to identifying the effectiveness of the policy. This approach conducts classification and clustering learning according to the characteristics of a large number of non-pilot cities through machine learning, and extracts the core elements to establish a multidimensional model image of pilot cities. By means of linkage of small samples of pilot and big data, the effective assessment of performance on the pilot cities is implemented.
In this section, we attempt to reveal the causal effect of EFT reform by imputing the missing potential emission intensity reductions, which is the counterfactual outcome that would have prevailed if cities had not implemented the EFT reform. For this purpose, we invoke the synthetic control method, first developed by Abadie and Gardeazabal [29] and then extended by Abadie et al. [31].
EFT reform in Hubei Province began at the end of 2007. Since other provinces did not adopt the reform policy, we can take the environmental tax reform in Hubei Province as a natural experiment. In accordance with the theory of policy evaluation, we put the pilot cities after 2007 into the treatment group, other cities into the control group, and then by comparing the differences between the control group and the treatment group, we will be able to assess the effect of the EFT reform. Suppose there are K + 1 cities, as indexed by i = 1, 2, …, K + 1 over all T periods, t = 1, 2, …, T. Only city i = 1 passed the EFT reform and the remaining K cities are the potential control cities that did not pass the reform, also called the donor pool. Then there are T0 number of pre-reform periods, and T1 number of post-reform periods so T0 + T1 = T. The general effect of tax reform for city i at period t is then given by α i t = Y i t I Y i t N where Y i t I is the pollutants emission intensity of city i if the reform is started in T0 + 1 to T and Y i t N is the pollutants emission intensity in the absence of the reform. Since only city i = 1 starts EFT reform, we need to estimate ( α 1 T 0 + 1 , , α 1 T ). We can first estimate Y i t N by the factor model:
Y i t N = δ t + θ t Z i + λ t μ i + ε i t
where δ t is an unidentified common factor invariant across the units, Z i is the covariate vector not affected by the reform, θ t is a vector of unidentified time-specific parameters, λ t is a vector of unidentified common factors, while μ i is the city-specific non-observable and also the error term ϵ i t is the zero-mean variable following the random distribution. The existence of anticipatory effects are irrelevant in this case, indicating that all the essential elements in Z i that belong to pre-reform period are not impacted by the reform. Equation (1) allows the effect of non-observable city heterogeneity to differ over time.
In our study, all the factors, such as economic factors, population factors, factors of openness, administrative factors, technological factors and industrial structure factors , are the inputs, as the Z i of the model from Equation (1).
With the panel DIDS estimator, the consequence of non-observable heterogeneity, λ t is supposed to be fixed over time. Thus, the synthetic control method makes a substantial improvement on the DIDS method and handles endogeneity caused by the existence of non-observable confounders varying over time.
The method intends to construct the missing counterfactual, Y i t N from the cities not impacted by the reform. Let W = ( w 2 , ... , w k + 1 ) be ( k × 1 ) vector of weights such that 0 w j 1 for i = 2 , 3 , ... , k + 1 and k = 2 k + 1 w k = 1 . Each vector W presents a possible synthetic control, which means a distinct weighted average of control cities. The outcome variable value for each particular synthetic control is:
k = 2 k + 1 W k Y k t = δ t + θ t k = 2 k + 1 W k Z k + λ t k = 2 k + 1 W k μ k + k = 2 k + 1 W k ε k t
Suppose that there are ( w 2 * , , w k + 1 * ) such that:
k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k 1 = Y 11 ,   k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k 2 = Y 12 , , k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k T 0 = Y 1 T 0   and k = 2 k + 1 w k z k = z 1
Abadie et al. [28] prove if t = 1 T 0 λ t λ t is non-singular, then
Y 1 t N k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k 1 = k = 2 k + 1 w k * s = 1 T 0 λ t ( n = 1 T 0 λ n λ n ) 1 λ s ( ε k s ε 1 s ) k = 2 k + 1 w k * ( ε k s ε 1 s )  
λ t is applied as unidentified common factors to present the unknown variables, which may also influence the model. There are many ways to guarantee that non-singular condition is satisfied, such as feeding the vectors as constant.
Abadie et al. [30] shows the estimate of the effect of the reform for the enacted cities, Equation (5) is an unbiased estimator of α ^ 1 t :
α ^ 1 t = Y i t k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k t    t [ T 0 + 1 , , T ]
where w j * the weight is assigned to the kt cities that did not enact the reform.
Equation (4) can hold exactly only if ( Y ¯ 1 k , Z 1 ) actually belongs to the convex hull of [ ( Y ¯ 2 k , Z 2 ) , , ( Y ¯ p + 1 k , Z P + 1 ) ] . This means it is possible that the pre-reform SO2 emissions intensity of some of the reform-enacted states will not be synthetized properly using the pre-reform features of the cities that did not enact such reform.
The vector W * is designed to minimize the distance relationship between the vector of pre-reform features for the exposed city ( X 1 ) and the weighted matrix that does contain the pre-reform features of the unexposed cities
( X 0 ) : X 1 X 0 W = ( X 1 X 0 W ) V ( X 1 X 0 W )
where V is a positive semi-definite symmetric matrix. The minimization procedure is strictly subject to certain constraints that the weight specifically assigned to unexposed city varies between zero and one, and the sum of weights is bounded by one.
For Equation (6), we used the quadratic programming, which is a typical optimization method in machine learning [36], in order to optimize the minimization process of the loss function of the weights. The machine learning method in the synthetic control method enables us to evaluate the model not only with big size of samples, but also with small ones by constructing a virtual synthetic match groups.
Synthetic control method promotes the effective usage of data-driven processes to automatically generate suitable comparison groups. This enables researchers to use quantitative and qualitative methodologies, to effectively analyze similarities and differences between the participating units representing the particular case of interest and the synthetic control, to evaluate the impact of the individual cases rather than a single average value of impact [34]. This method can be particularly useful for our study, of which the sample data are relatively small and evaluation of an average effect could be rather difficult or potentially misleading. However, we notice the limitations of the analytical method, and make recommendations for empirical practice. Although synthetic controls are defined as convex combinations of unexposed individual units, weights above one or negative weights can also be used by allowing the extrapolation. For example, for either China’s highest industrial sulfur dioxide emissions intensity city Chongqing or the lowest emission intensity city Sanya, the control group cannot be weighted to reach the same industrial sulfur dioxide emissions, so synthetic control method is no longer appropriate in this case. Fortunately, most of the cities in Hubei Province does not have this problem; it is suitable for synthetic control method.

3.2. Data and Sample Selection

We used balanced panel data during 2003–2013 of 12 pilot cities in Hubei Province (Figure 1) and the other 262 cities in China. The city data come from the CHINA CITY STATISTICAL YEARBOOK [37] and the official websites of these cities’ Statistics Bureaus, while national and provincial data come from the CHINA ENVIRONMENT YEARBOOK [38].
According to lots of previous work, such as the study of Peng et al. [39] and Lehoczki and Sleszynski [40], this study chooses industrial SO2 emissions intensity (GDP and per capita GDP used in this paper are based on the benchmark of 2003 at constant price) as an EFT reform evaluation indicator, and the specific equation such as Equation (7). Due to the difference of each city’s SO2 emission intensity, the direct use of the difference of emission reduction intensity is not scientific. This study takes β difference ratio to represent the effect of EFT, named decline rate hereinafter referred to as the emission reduction effect, and the specific equation such as Equation (8).
SO 2   emissions   intensity = SO 2 GDP
β = ( SO 2   real   emissions   intensity SO 2   synth   emissions   intensity ) ( SO 2   real   emissions   intensity )
China is currently the world’s largest source of SO2 emissions; meanwhile, SO2 is the main air pollutant [41] in China, causing various environmental disasters such as acid rain [42] and haze weather [43]. Industrial SO2 emissions accounted for more than 90% of China’s total pollutant emissions. Thus, controlling such pollution is an urgent task for environmental protection authorities. This study chooses industrial SO2 emission intensity, namely the ratio of SO2 emissions to GDP, and the tax reform effect in improving the regional environment.
The sample of this study has the typical “treatment after pollution” characteristics. In March 2004, Premier Wen Jiabao proposed the “Rise of Central China” [44], followed by a series of plans to stimulate the central region’s economy, including Hubei Province. Correspondingly, Hubei Province experienced rapid economic growth—its GDP grew at an average annual rate of 13.2% between 2004 and 2007. We have also found that Hubei Province’s GDP growth rate has been higher than the national average from 2008 onwards.
With the rapid economic development, pollution has become more and more serious in central China. From 2004 to 2005, emissions of pollutants in Hubei Province rose despite a national trend of decline. In order to improve the environment, Hubei Province implemented the EFT reform in all the subordinate cities. This spontaneous policy represents a clear endogeneity, and in this case, the synthetic control method has the advantage over traditional DIDS method. Due to data availability, 12 cities in Hubei Province are included into this research: Wuhan, Xiangyang, Ezhou, Jingzhou, Jingmen, Xianning, Xiaogan, Huangshi, Huanggang, Yichang, Suizhou and Shiyan. We define these 12 cities as the target cities, and select 262 other cities outside Hubei Province as the control group. Because October 2007 is the EFT reform’s starting point, the annual data before 2008 are used for the synthesis control cities, and data from 2008 onwards are used for assessing the policy effect.
Predictive variables are good indicators for measuring the effect of fitting results [31].
(a)
Economic factors: Grossman and Krueger [45] first discovered inverted U shape curve of relationship between the degree of environmental pollution and per capita GDP, during the research on the environmental effect of North American Free Trade Agreement, which was later called “Environmental Kuznets Curve” (EKC). Shen [46] found that China’s SO2 emissions are also in line with the characteristics of EKC. In this paper, we use per capita GDP to measure economic development level, recorded as GDP.
(b)
Population factors: Urbanization promotes population concentration, which may lead to the scale effect of energy use and reduce pollution emissions [46,47], while the increase of per capita emissions may appear in sparsely populated areas due to the reduction of environmental regulations [48]. In addition, Wang [21] found that people with higher educational degrees to have a stronger awareness of environmental protection, and also to actively fight against pollution. This paper uses the population density, which is the ratio of population at the end of a year and the area of the administrative area, to measure population concentration, and the education population ratio, which is the ratio of number of college students and population at the end of a year, to measure education level. The two variables are recorded as population (pop, thereafter) and education (edu, thereafter) respectively.
(c)
Factors of openness: In accordance with the principle of comparative advantage, the pollution intensive industries will be transferred from developed countries to developing countries, or from countries with strong environmental regulations to control weak countries. This is called Pollution Haven Hypothesis [49]. Research [50,51] found that the opening up to foreign investment and the trade openness [52] are related to the SO2 pollution. This paper uses the ratio of foreign industrial output and industrial output to measure the degree of economic openness, recorded as open.
(d)
Administrative factors: Wang et al. [53] pointed out that the Chinese enterprises have a strong bargaining power with local environmental protection agencies, resulting in environmental legislation not being fully implemented. The will and enforcement of environmental protection agencies have a great influence on the actual effects of policies. This paper uses the local fiscal dependence on industries, that is, the ratio of VAT payable of Industrial Enterprises above Designated Size and budgetary revenue for measurement, recorded as dependence (dep, thereafter).
(e)
Technological factors: Progress of environmental protection technologies and R&D investment will directly improve the environmental protection effects. [46] This paper uses the ratio of expenditure on science and technology to government’s budgeted expenditures for measurement, recorded as technologies (tech, thereafter).
(f)
Industrial structure factors: EKC curve shows that environmental pollution is closely related to transformation of industrial structure [54]. Industrialization in the early stage of economic development often leads to rapid increase of natural resources consumption and waste emissions. At later stages of development, the proportion of service industry normally increases, reducing the dependence on the exploitation of resources and energy consumption. The environmental pressure of industrial production is also reduced by technological and management innovation. In this paper, the environmental effect of industrial structure adjustment is measured by the ratio of second industry GDP to the tertiary industry GDP, recorded as second industry (seci, thereafter) and tertiary industry (teri, thereafter).

3.3. Enterprise Interview

In this paper, semi-structured in-depth interview method is adopted to conduct research on 27 enterprises from 12 pilot cities of Hubei Province. The aim of interview is to understand the specific changes with regard to the government’s management of enterprise pollution behavior, and learn whether the changes of regulatory actions can bring corresponding changes of enterprise emission strategy.
We mainly focus on studying EFT’s effect on enterprise pollution emissions, thus we select some enterprises with serious pollution emissions. The surveyed enterprises cover a plurality of polluting industries including thermal power, steel, chemical industry, etc. In addition, enterprises in different scales have different pollution abatement strategies, meanwhile, the scale of enterprises will also affect the degree of game between the enterprise and government, and therefore we survey enterprises in the different scale. Enterprise scale is divided into large enterprises (listing corporation; the number of employees is more than 2000), medium-sized enterprises (the number of employees is more than 300 people) and small businesses (the number of employees is below 300). Respondents are mostly administrators from the enterprise’s governmental affairs department and the technical department.

4. Results

4.1. Constructing a Synthetic Version of City

In view of the differences in administrative enforcement and subjective initiative, this paper does not take the methods of the previous studies to mix all the pilot cities, but uses the method of city-by-city analysis by constructing the synthetic control city for each pilot city. Effect of EFT reform is measured by the difference in SO2 emission intensity between each pilot city and its synthetic control city. Taking Wuhan for example, this paper utilizes SO2 emission intensity and predictive control variable (per capita GDP, industrial structure, population density, etc.) from 2003 to 2007 to synthesize the control city of Wuhan. The effect of EFT reform on Wuhan is measured with the difference in SO2 emission intensity after 2008. The principle of choosing the weight of cities is the minimum of the mean square error of SO2 emission intensity before the EFT reform. Based on Equation (5), the weight of the synthetic control group of Wuhan can be calculated as shown in Table 2.
Table 3 compares the pre-reform features of Wuhan to the synthetic Wuhan, and to those of an average of the 262 cities in our donor pool. Results in Table 3 suggest that the synthetic Wuhan draws a better comparison for Wuhan than the average of the sample of other cities. The synthetic Wuhan is very similar to the real Wuhan for the pre-2008 period. In particular, SO2 emissions in 2003, 2005, and 2007 of the synthetic of Wuhan all fit very well with that of real Wuhan.
Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4 show the SO2 emission intensity of each treated city and the corresponding synthetic city, in which the vertical dashed line represents the beginning year of the EFT reform. The SO2 emission intensity in most of the pilot cities and their synthetic control cities are very close on the left side of the line, while they gradually deviate on the right side. For example, the results of SO2 emission intensity in Wuhan and synthetic Wuhan are very close to each other between 2003 and 2007, but from 2008 onwards, the latter is higher, with the gap between them representing the effect of the EFT reform. Depending on the reform’s impact on SO2 emission intensity, the results of the 12 pilot cities are divided into three groups. The first group includes cities that are sensitive to the reform with a significant reduction of SO2 emission. These cities are Wuhan, Shiyan, Xiangyang and Ezhou (Figure 2). The second group includes Xiaogan, Jingmen, Xianning, and Jingzhou (Figure 3), which have obtained good synthetic objects before the reform but show relatively weak effects after that. The third group includes Yichang, Huangshi, Huanggang and Suizhou (Figure 4) with poor fitting results before the reform.
At the same time, we notice that: (1) SO2 emissions in some cities and their synthetic control cities reached the lowest point in 2010, followed by a slight rebound. The possible reason is that SO2 emissions serve as one of the pollution assessment indicators according to the government’s 11th Five-Year Plan. As a result, the reduction is a mandatory task for local authorities. Since 2010 is the final and the evaluation year of the 11th Five-Year Plan, cities across the country took a variety of measures to cut SO2 emissions, including shutting down high-emission plants. With the lifting of such temporary measures, the intensity of SO2 emissions rebounded in 2011. (2) Not all target cities can find a suitable synthetic control object. Because of the low SO2 emissions, it is difficult to find adequate control cities for Huanggang and Suizhou. As to Huangshi and Yichang, the synthetic control method is unable to reproduce the pre-reform trajectory, making it difficult to determine whether the difference is caused by the EFT reform.
The effect of the EFT reform is evaluated according to the decline in emission of the actual city compared to the synthetic city after the implementation of the policy. The average reductions of the emission intensity of SO2 in the treated cities from 2008 to 2013 are listed in Table 4. The average reduction is of 0.11 tons/million Yuan, with an average decline rate of 19.6%. SO2 emission intensity in Shiyan, Xiangyang and Xianning dropped more relative to the target cities in the past six years, with the average decline rate of over 30%.

4.2. Placebo Studies

To estimate the reliability and validity of the results, and to identify the effect of EFT reform on the reduction of SO2 emissions, we perform placebo studies as in [31], where the particular treatment of interest is reassigned in the research data to cities different from pilot cities. Thus, we can acquire synthetic control estimates for cities that did not implement the reform. Applying the idea to each city in the donor pool enables us to compare the assessed effects of the EFT reform on the treatment cities, to the particular distribution of placebo effects obtained from other cities. We will define the effects of the EFT reform significant if the assessed impact on treatment cities is unusually highly related to the particular distribution of placebo effects.
The Root Mean Square Prediction Error (RMSPE, thereafter) [31] estimates the actual magnitude of the gap in the primary outcome variable of interest between each city and its equivalent synthetic counterpart. Figure 5 indicates ratio distributions of post-reform RMSPE, the specific equation such as Equation (9), to pre-reform RMSPE, the specific equation such as Equation (10), for the treatment units and for the cities in the donor pool.
Post reform   RMSPE   = ( 1 T 1 t = T 0 + 1 T ( Y i t k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k t ) 2 ) 1 2
Pre reform   RMSPE = ( 1 T 0 t = 1 T 0 ( Y i t k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k t ) 2 ) 1 2
where T is the total periods number; T0 is the number of pre-reform periods; T1 is the number of post-reform periods, so T0 + T1 = T; and Y i t k = 2 k + 1 w k * Y k t is the representation of α ^ 1 t (see Equation (5)).
A large numeric post-intervention RMSPE is not indicative of a large main effect of the particular intervention, as if the synthetic control does not rather closely reproduce the primary outcome of interest prior to the particular intervention [31]. In other words, a large numeric post-reform RMSPE is not generally indicative of a large main effect of the reform if the pre-period RMSPE is also rather large. As for each city, we simply divide the post-reform RMSPE by its pre-reform RMSPE. In Figure 5, Wuhan obviously stands out as the city with the largest RMSPE ratio. For Wuhan, the post-reform gap is about 3.76 times bigger than the pre-reform gap, which means that the reduction in SO2 emissions is indeed indicative of the effects of EFT reform.
Results indicate that RMSPE rates of four cities, Wuhan, Xiangyang, Ezhou and Shiyan, are measurably higher than others, which means the EFT reform effects are more workable in these four cities.

4.3. Robustness Evaluation

To examine the sensitivity of the main results, we run a robustness check to the changes in the city weights. Taking Wuhan for example, the synthetic Wuhan is currently constructed by the weighted average of ten cities, namely Shanghai, Beijing, Changsha, Shantou, Haikou, Daqing, Xiangtan, Jiayuguan, Benxi, and Jinzhou, with weights decreasing orderly (Table 3). Iteratively, we re-estimate our baseline model, to properly construct a synthetic Wuhan that omit in each iteration one of the cities that had a positive weight in Table 2. The robustness evaluation enables us to estimate to what extent the results are driven by any control city. Figure 6 shows the results and reproduces itself (solid and dashed black lines), while incorporating the leave-one-out estimates (dot-dashed lines). The figure indicates that the results of the previous statistical analysis are robust to the exclusion of any city of the comparison unit. The leave-one-out estimates of Xiangyang (Figure 6b), Shiyan (Figure 6c) and Ezhou (Figure 6d) also yield good fits, consistent with the conclusions mentioned above, suggesting the synthetic control method is robust to our case study.

4.4. Spatial and Temporal Variation of EFT Effect

We notice that EFT has a different effect in the different space and time. We use decline rate to estimate the effect of EFT on emission intensity reduction by which the “extra” contribution of EFT policy to the environmental improvements of the target city is measured. The effect of EFT policy is divided into eight grades, less than −50%, −50%–−40%, −40%–−30%, −30%–−20%, −20%–−10%, −10%–0, and more than 0. Accordingly, the spatial variation of emission intensity reduction effect in Hubei Province from 2007 to 2013 is presented (see Figure 7). From the spatial transfer path of emission intensity reduction effect, it can be seen that the emission intensity reduction ability is embodied as following spatial differentiation and evolution characteristics of three stages.
Start-up Phase (2007–2009): Hubei Province’s EFT had an effect on enhancing the capacity of emission intensity reductions; this shows characteristics of diffusion from the Wuhan metropolitan circle and Western Hubei region. Since 2007, EFT policy started in Hubei Province, the emission intensity reduction effect of pilot cities and synthetic control is close to 0. In 2008 Wuhan metropolitan circle and Western Hubei region took on significant governance effect, among them, the emission intensity of Xianning reached −20.9%, and the emission intensity of Shiyan reached to −19.5%. In 2009, Xianning further enhanced to −48.2%, and the emission intensity difference of Xiangyang located in Western Hubei region also reached −20.2%.
Mature Stage (2010–2012): Since 2010, the effect of EFT on pollution emission intensity reductions in the most of pilot cities in Hubei Province has been significantly improved, and Wuhan metropolitan circle and Western Hubei region have showed “double” spatial agglomeration effect and obvious regional spillover effect. The emission intensity reduction strength of Wuhan and Xiangyang, the two major urban centers in Hubei Province, reached −28.7% and −43.9%. Xiaogan in Wuhan metropolitan circle, and Shiyan and Jingzhou in Western Hubei region reached −52%, −30% and −23%, respectively, and Xianning in Wuhan metropolitan circle even reached −52%. Hence, we can draw the conclusion that, after EFT policy has been implemented for 2–3 years, its effect on regional environmental governance is generally substantively improved. During 2011 and 2012, the effect of emission intensity reduction policy continued to enlarge, and Western Hubei region became a center of emission intensity reductions instead of Wuhan metropolitan circle. Xiangyang continued to maintain a high ratio of −40%, and moreover Shiyan in Western Hubei region even reached −53% and −57.4%, a high ratio of “extra” effect, correspondingly, only Ezhou in the Wuhan metropolitan circle reached −30.7% and −40.8%, and Xianning reached −27.2% and −28.6%, respectively.
Continuous Phase (2013): After a rapid increase of 2010–2012 pollution emission intensity reductions, the effect of reductions in the pilot cities of Hubei Province began to enter the stationary phase. In 2013, Xiangyang, the center city in Western Hubei region, remained a high level of −30%, Shiyan continued to maintain an extremely high “extra” effect of −57.8%, and Jingmen and Xianning in Wuhan metropolitan circle reached a high level of −26.6% and −29.2%, respectively. For the rest of cities, the effect of reductions kept balanced or declined slightly; this shows those cities have sustained substantial emission intensity reduction effect compared with synthetic control cities without the implementation of EFT.

4.5. Results of Enterprise Interview

Based on 27 enterprises interview in Hubei Province, this study shows that all enterprises claimed that, after EFT, the environmental protection departments have strengthened their supervision, increasing the cost of the overall environment. After EFT, many environmental protection departments have increased the frequency and scope of on-site supervision. The initiative has a significant impact on enterprises and directly effects enterprises’ emissions. We find that, through the comparison between enterprises of different cities, in the region where there is a more adequate financial security or the city where the local economy is relatively developed, the supervision is more powerful; this is consistent with the survey results of the Environmental Planning Institute.
At the same time, the study shows that the open information of pollutant discharge fees has enhanced the justice and transparent of fees collection, not only making the enterprises realize the seriousness and righteousness to pay the pollutant discharge fees, but also making the public understand the situation of enterprise pollution to strengthen the pressure of public opinion. Open mechanism is relatively good in such areas as Ezhou, Wuhan, Xiangyang and Shiyan, where the effect is obvious.
Additionally, EFT got rid of a lot of intervention from local government to the collection of pollutant discharge fees. Taking Xianning as an example, the local tax authorities abolished the local government's own policy on the reduction of pollutant discharge fees, improving the environmental tax levy rate, and thus promoting the reduction of pollutants.
From the perspective of enterprise behavior, most enterprises reduced emissions by means of the replacement of fuel, such as natural gas instead of coal fuel, sewage equipment purchase, technology research and development, unified treatment of pollutants in the industrial park. Some enterprises relocated to other regions or shut down, reflecting the truth that they could not afford to increase the cost of environmental tax after EFT.
Interview results show that different scale enterprises adopt different coping mechanisms after the implementation of EFT policy. Listing corporations and large enterprises strengthened their pollution control and increased their investment in environmental protection and facilities, and tried for more environmental subsidies from the government. Some medium-sized enterprises were required by the local government to move into a special industrial park and take a unified approach to pollutant emission intensity reductions. A large number of small enterprises, which were unable to carry out the improvement of facilities, are still a direct part of the pollution and they will face closure.

5. Discussion

This study finds that the EFT reform has significant effects in cities with relatively developed economy and higher administrative level, such as Wuhan, Xiangyang, Ezhou and Shiyan. Specifically, Wuhan and Xiangyang are the traditional economic centers of Hubei Province, while Ezhou and Shiyan also have a record of rapid economic development in recent years. The previous studies on Provincial EFT reform are rare, partly because the official research report of Chinese Academy for Environmental Planning and Provincial Academy of Environmental Science were not usually published. Liu [55] and Feng [56] used qualitative research method as interview and find that EFT reform can benefit the tax stability, so our research first use machine learning enabled quantitative method to evaluate EFT reform effect in Hubei Province, China. Wang [57] points out that the political power is very important in the implementation of environmental policies in China. Government departments with high administrative levels have relatively more authority in the game versus the polluting enterprises, making them more conducive to the implementation of environmental policies. Wuhan is the capital city of Hubei Province, and Xiangyang is the provincial sub-center, where obvious effects of the tax reform are observed. In addition, Costantini [58] proposes that environmental regulations have a spillover effect. Since Ezhou and Shiyan are close to Wuhan and Xiangyang, they also demonstrate relatively significant effects of the reform.
In respect to the methodology, the synthetic control method proposed by Abadie et al. [31] has been applied to policy evaluation in developed countries with large time span and small sample data. Our work provides another perspective on the applicability of synthetic control method for developing countries, such as China. The sample data in that regard are always rich in individuals, short in time but large in space span, and the synthetic control method suggests a better applicability to such cases compared to traditional method, resulting in a robust and effective estimate.

6. Conclusions

The EFT reform is an important measure for the Chinese government to deal with environmental problems along with the economic development. The policy experiences derived from the pilot cities are of great implications to improve the environmental protection tax system. For the first time, this study quantitatively assesses the impact of Hubei Province’s environmental tax reform on SO2 emissions. By creating a synthetic control city for every pilot city, this study simulates the pollutant trend under a scenario with no EFT reform for each target city, which allows us to assess the actual impact of pollution intensity.
Built on top of the previous work, our research presents the following contributions:
First, the machine learning theory is suggested to be a novel application in the policy evaluation area. Compared with the traditional DIDS method, the Synthetic control method can provide a flexibility to evaluate the model on both big and small size of samples without considering the control group selection and policy endogenesis problems.
Second, the results demonstrate that the EFT reform can effectively restrain pollutant discharges, but the effects vary with regional heterogeneity. In cities with higher administrative and economic development levels, the policy has been implemented more efficiently. For example, in the four cities of Wuhan, Xiangyang, Ezhou and Shiyan, the intensity of SO2 emissions decreased significantly after the EFT reform. While other pilot cities show similar trends, the results are not statistically significant. The findings indicate that nationwide promotion of the environmental tax reform may show a wave-like progressive trend from more developed regions compared to less developed regions.
Third, EFT reform is found to benefit the global environmental tax reform.
Based on our results, we propose the following suggestions for the implementation of China’s Environmental Protection Tax Law:
The first is to take the regional heterogeneity issue into consideration during the nationwide implementation process. To improve China's environment overall, we should not only focus on the environmental policies implementation in more developed cities, but also improve the administrative capacity and incentives of the environmental protection agencies in underdeveloped areas.
The second is to enhance information openness and promote public participation. The cooperation among different departments is necessary. In addition, the pollution fee of different companies can be published by the media and Internet to draw public attention in monitoring environment pollution.
The third is to improve and optimize the environment monitoring system and build information sharing platform. The automatic online monitoring system, which is currently only available in big cities, should also be expanded to small cities to improve its spatial coverage and information sharing.

Acknowledgments

Project supported by National Natural Science Foundation of Chinese “Benefit Transfer for Wetland Ecosystem Services Based on Meta-analysis and GIS: Valuing the Influence of Climate Change on Wetlands (41271527), the Social Sciences Research Program under the Ministry of Education (11YJC790300), Beijing Social Sciences Research Program (13CSB007), Project supported by Peking University-Lincoln Institute Center for Urban Development and Land Policy.

Author Contributions

Yinger Zheng, Haixia Zheng and Xinyue Ye co-designed and performed research. Yinger Zheng interviewed enterprise, interpreted the data, wrote the draft paper and revised it until its final version. Haixia Zheng contributed research ideas and revised the paper. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Zhang, S. Environmental Tax: Arrows on the String with Right Target?—A Discussion on Some Key Issues for Environmental Taxation Policy in China. Environ. Prot. 2015, 43, 31–35. [Google Scholar]
  2. Ge, C.; Gao, S.; Ren, Y.; Sun, G.; Long, F. Study on the design of wastewater environmental tax in China: From wastewater pollutant discharge fee to environmental tax. In Environmental Taxation in China and Asia-Pacific: Achieving Environmental Sustainability through Fiscal Policy; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  3. Brys, B.; Matthews, S.; Herd, R.; Wang, X. Tax Policy and Tax Reform in the People's Republic of China; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  4. Brys, B.; Matthews, S.; Owens, J. Tax Reform Trends in OECD Countries; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  5. Hoerner, J.; Bosquet, B. Environmental Tax Reform: The European Experience; Center for a Sustainable Economy: Washington, DC, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  6. Ekins, P.; Speck, S. Environmental Tax Reform (ETR); Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  7. Withana, S.; Brink, P.; Illes, A.; Nanni, S.; Watkins, E. Environmental tax reform in Europe: Opportunities for the future final report. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2005, 49, 174–196. [Google Scholar]
  8. Harrison, K. A tale of two taxes: The fate of environmental tax reform in Canada. Rev. Policy Res. 2012, 29, 383–407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Seung-Joon, P.; Ogawa, Y.; Kawakatsu, T.; Pollitt, H. The double dividend of an environmental tax reform in East Asian economies. In Low-Carbon, Sustainable Future in East Asia: Improving Energy Systems; Lee, S., Pollitt, H., Park, S., Eds.; Taxation and Policy Cooperation: London, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  10. Ciaschini, M.; Pretaroli, R.; Severini, F.; Socci, C. Regional double dividend from environmental tax reform: An application for the Italian economy. Res. Econ. 2012, 66, 273–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Parry, I.; Norregaard, J.; Heine, D. Environmental tax reform: Principles from theory and practice. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2012, 4, 101–125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Ekins, P.; Pollitt, H.; Barton, J.; Blobel, D. The implications for households of environmental tax reform (ETR) in Europe. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 2472–2485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Ekins, P.; Summerton, P.; Thoung, C.; Lee, D. A major environmental tax reform for the UK: Results for the economy, employment and the environment. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2011, 50, 447–474. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Ekins, P.; Pollitt, H.; Summerton, P.; Chewpreecha, U. Increasing carbon and material productivity through environmental tax reform. Energy Policy 2012, 42, 365–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Barker, T.; Junankar, S.; Pollitt, H.; Summerton, P. The macroeconomic effects of unilateral environmental tax reforms in Europe, 1995–2012. In Critical Issues in Environmental Taxation 1995–2005; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  16. Lutz, C.; Meyer, B. Environmental and economic effects of post-Kyoto carbon regimes: Results of simulations with the global model GINFORS. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 1758–1766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Barker, T.; Junankar, S.; Pollitt, H.; Summerton, P. The effects of environmental tax reform on international competitiveness in the European Union: Modelling with E3ME. In Carbon-Energy Taxation: Lessons from Europe; Andersen, M., Ekins, P., Eds.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  18. Dasgupta, S.; Huq, M.; Wheeler, D.; Zhang, C. Water pollution abatement by Chinese industry: Cost estimates and policy implications. Appl. Econ. 2001, 33, 547–557. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Wang, H.; Wheeler, D. Pricing Industrial Pollution in China: An Econometric Analysis of the Levy System; World Bank Publications: Washington, DC, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  20. Wang, H.; Wheeler, D. Endogenous Enforcement and Effectiveness of China’s Pollution Levy System; World Bank Publications: Washington, DC, USA, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  21. Wang, H.; Wheeler, D. Financial incentives and endogenous enforcement in China’s pollution levy system. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2005, 49, 174–196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Chen, S. Marginal abatement cost and environmental tax reform in China. Soc. Sci. China 2011, 3, 6–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Tong, J.; Zhu, B. A Study on “Environmental Dividend” as the Primary Objective in Environmental Tax Reform in China. Int. Tax. China 2011, 8, 11–21. [Google Scholar]
  24. Xiao, B.; Niu, D.; Guo, X.; Xu, X. The Impacts of Environmental Tax in China: A Dynamic Recursive Multi-Sector CGE Model. Energies 2015, 8, 7777–7804. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Liang, Q.; Yao, Y.; Zhao, L.; Yao, Y.; Wang, C.; Yang, R.; Wei, Y. Platform for China Energy and Environmental Policy Analysis: A general design and its application. Environ. Model. Softw. 2014, 51, 195–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Blanchard, O.; Kahn, C. The Solution of Linear Difference Models under Rational Expectations. Econometrica 1980, 48, 1305–1311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Puhani, P. The treatment effect, the cross difference, and the interaction term in nonlinear “difference-in-differences” models. Econ. Lett. 2012, 115, 85–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Abadie, A.; Diamond, A.; Hainmueller, J. Synthetic Control Methods for Comparative Case Studies: Estimating the Effect of California’s Tobacco Control Program. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 2010, 105, 493–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Abadie, A.; Gardeazabal, J. The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country. Am. Econ. Rev. 2003, 93, 113–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Abadie, A.; Diamond, A.; Hainmueller, J. Synth: An r package for synthetic control methods in comparative case studies. J. Stat. Softw. 2011, 42, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Abadie, A.; Diamond, A.; Hainmueller, J. Comparative Politics and the Synthetic Control Method. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 2015, 59, 495–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Saunders, J.; Lundberg, R.; Braga, A.; Ridgeway, G.; Miles, J. A Synthetic Control Approach to Evaluating Place-Based Crime Interventions. J. Quant. Criminol. 2014, 31, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Sills, E.; Herrera, D.; Kirkpatrick, A.; Brandão, A.; Dickson, R.; Hall, S.; Pattanayak, S.; Shoch, D.; Vedoveto, M.; Young, L.; et al. Estimating the Impacts of Local Policy Innovation: The Synthetic Control Method Applied to Tropical Deforestation. PLoS ONE 2015, 10, e0132590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  34. Ando, M. Dreams of urbanization: Quantitative case studies on the local impacts of nuclear power facilities using the synthetic control method. J. Urban Econ. 2015, 85, 68–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Zhang, J.; Zhong, C.; Yi, M. Did Olympic Games improve air quality in Beijing? Based on the synthetic control method. Environ. Econ. Policy Stud. 2015, 18, 21–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Sra, S.; Nowozin, S.; Wright, S.J. Optimization for Machine Learning; Mit Press: Cambridge, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  37. National Bureau of Statistics of China. China City Statistical Yearbook; Chinese Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2014.
  38. China Environment Yearbook Editing Committee. China Environment Yearbook; China Environment Yearbook Press: Beijing, China, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  39. Peng, Y.; Cui, J.; Cao, Y. Impact of Manufacturing Transfer on SO2 Emissions in Jiangsu Province, China. Atmosphere 2016, 7, 69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Lehoczki, Z.; Sleszynski, J. Sulphur Dioxide Emission Charge in Poland. In Economic Instruments for Environmental Management: A Worldwide Compendium of Case Studies; Routledge: London, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  41. Nam, K.; Waugh, C.; Paltsev, S.; Reilly, J.; Karplus, V. Synergy between pollution and carbon emissions control: Comparing China and the United States. Energy Econ. 2014, 46, 186–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Zhao, Y.; Duan, L.; Larssen, T.; Nielsen, C.; Hao, J. Soil acidification in China: Is controlling SO2 emissions enough? Environ. Sci. Technol. 2009, 43, 8021–8026. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  43. Xie, Y.; Zhao, B.; Zhang, L.; Luo, R. Spatiotemporal variations of PM2.5 and PM10 concentrations between 31 Chinese cities and their relationships with SO2, NO2, CO and O3. Particuology 2015, 20, 141–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Lai, H. Developing Central China: A new regional programme. China Int. J. 2007, 5, 109–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Grossman, G.; Krueger, A. Environmental Impacts of a North American Free Trade Agreement. 1991. Available online: http://www.nber.org/papers/w3914.pdf?newwindow=l (accessed on 31 October 2016).
  46. Shen, J. A Simultaneous Estimation of Environmental Kuznets Curve: Evidence from China. China Econ. Rev. 2006, 17, 383–394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Liu, Y.; Zhou, Y.; Wu, W. Assessing the impact of population, income and technology on energy consumption and industrial pollutant emissions in China. Appl. Energy 2015, 155, 904–917. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Selden, T.; Song, D. Environmental quality and development: Is there a Kuznets curve for air pollution emissions? J. Environ. Manag. 1994, 27, 147–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Copeland, B.; Taylor, M. Trade and transboundary pollution. Am. Econ. Rev. 1995, 85, 716–737. [Google Scholar]
  50. Lan, J.; Kakinaka, M.; Huang, X. Foreign direct investment, human capital and environmental pollution in China. Environ. Res. Econ. 2012, 51, 255–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Bao, Q.; Chen, Y.; Song, L. Foreign direct investment and environmental pollution in China: A simultaneous equations estimation. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2011, 16, 71–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Jayanthakumaran, K.; Liu, Y. Openness and the environmental Kuznets curve: Evidence from China. Econ. Model. 2012, 29, 566–576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Wang, H.; Mamingi, N.; Laplante, B.; Dasgupta, S. Incomplete enforcement of pollution regulation: Bargaining power of Chinese factories. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2003, 24, 245–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Dasgupta, S.; Laplante, B.; Wang, H.; Wheeler, D. Confronting the environmental Kuznets curve. J. Econ. Perspect. 2002, 16, 147–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Chen, Y. Research of Environmental Taxation Reform in China. Master’s Thesis, Central China Normal University, Wuhan, China, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  56. Feng, Y. Research on Green Development & Environmental Tax System Reform in China. Master’s Thesis, Central China Normal University, Wuhan, China, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  57. Wang, A. The search for sustainable legitimacy: Environmental law and bureaucracy in China. Harv. Environ. Law Rev. 2013, 37, 365–589. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Costantini, V.; Mazzanti, M.; Montini, A. Environmental performance, innovation and spillovers. Evidence from a regional NAMEA. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 89, 101–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Twelve Target Cities in Hubei Province in central China. Notes: The gray parts are the pilot cities in this paper.
Figure 1. Twelve Target Cities in Hubei Province in central China. Notes: The gray parts are the pilot cities in this paper.
Sustainability 08 01124 g001
Figure 2. Trends in SO2 Emissions Intensity: Target Cities versus Synthetic Cities (Wuhan, Xiangyang, Shiyan and Ezhou). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. (ad) Wuhan, Xiangyang, Shiyan and Ezhou, respectively, all of which have good fitting and obvious emission intensity reduction effects. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Figure 2. Trends in SO2 Emissions Intensity: Target Cities versus Synthetic Cities (Wuhan, Xiangyang, Shiyan and Ezhou). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. (ad) Wuhan, Xiangyang, Shiyan and Ezhou, respectively, all of which have good fitting and obvious emission intensity reduction effects. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Sustainability 08 01124 g002
Figure 3. Trends in SO2 Emissions Intensity: Target Cities versus Synthetic Cities (Jingzhou, Jingmen, Xiaogan and Xianning). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. (ad) Jingmen, Jingzhou, Xiaogan and Xianning, respectively, all of which have good fitting but no great emission intensity reduction effects. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Figure 3. Trends in SO2 Emissions Intensity: Target Cities versus Synthetic Cities (Jingzhou, Jingmen, Xiaogan and Xianning). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. (ad) Jingmen, Jingzhou, Xiaogan and Xianning, respectively, all of which have good fitting but no great emission intensity reduction effects. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Sustainability 08 01124 g003
Figure 4. Trends in SO2 Emissions Intensity: Target Cities versus Synthetic Cities (Yichang, Suizhou, Huanggang and Huangshi). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. (ad) Yichang, Suizhou, Huanggang and Huangshi, respectively, none of which has good fitting. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Figure 4. Trends in SO2 Emissions Intensity: Target Cities versus Synthetic Cities (Yichang, Suizhou, Huanggang and Huangshi). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. (ad) Yichang, Suizhou, Huanggang and Huangshi, respectively, none of which has good fitting. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Sustainability 08 01124 g004
Figure 5. Ratio Distributions of Post-reform RMSPE to Pre-reform RMSPE: Target Cities and Control Cities. Notes: We remove bad fitting placebo results whose Pre-reform RMSPE exceeds three times the overall RMSPE, and the rest of results are made into a frequency histogram, in which a gray bar represents target cities falling in that interval. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Figure 5. Ratio Distributions of Post-reform RMSPE to Pre-reform RMSPE: Target Cities and Control Cities. Notes: We remove bad fitting placebo results whose Pre-reform RMSPE exceeds three times the overall RMSPE, and the rest of results are made into a frequency histogram, in which a gray bar represents target cities falling in that interval. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Sustainability 08 01124 g005
Figure 6. Leave-One-Out Distributions of the Synthetic Control for Target Cities (Wuhan, Xiangyang, Shiyan and Ezhou, ad). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. Each dot-dashed line represents the trend of a new synthetic city’s SO2 Emissions Intensity, after removing a city that contributes to the previous synthetic city from control group. This figure shows whether the EFT reform effects are affected by synthetic cities’ weights or missing a certain control group city. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Figure 6. Leave-One-Out Distributions of the Synthetic Control for Target Cities (Wuhan, Xiangyang, Shiyan and Ezhou, ad). Notes: Solid lines represent the target cities. Dash lines correspond to the synthetic cities. Vertical dash lines delineate time of reform. Each dot-dashed line represents the trend of a new synthetic city’s SO2 Emissions Intensity, after removing a city that contributes to the previous synthetic city from control group. This figure shows whether the EFT reform effects are affected by synthetic cities’ weights or missing a certain control group city. Source: authors’ computation by synthetic control program in STATA 12.
Sustainability 08 01124 g006
Figure 7. Temporal and spatial changes of the intensity rise of SO2 emission intensity reductions in Hubei Province during 2007–2013.
Figure 7. Temporal and spatial changes of the intensity rise of SO2 emission intensity reductions in Hubei Province during 2007–2013.
Sustainability 08 01124 g007
Table 1. Comparison before and after EFT in Hubei Province.
Table 1. Comparison before and after EFT in Hubei Province.
Item ComparedPollutant Discharge FeesEnvironmental Taxes
Collection departmentEnvironmental protection department of province, city, countyProvincial local tax department
Collection cycleHalf of year or a yearMonth or season
Funds useFunds are used for environment governance; however, irregularities led to self-use funds for the environmental protection department or the local government.Funds are under the unified management of public finance budget.
Collection procedureThe environmental protection department is responsible for the approval and collection, and the payment is into the local financial budget account. A strict monitoring and evaluation mechanism is absent.It is approved by the environmental protection department, and collected into the treasury by the tax department under the same tax assessment mechanism.
EnforcementIts enforcement is weaker than that of tax. As a soft constraint, its law enforcement is relatively large at random.As an obligatory constraint, it has law enforcement with rigid features.
Superior leadershipLocal governmentProvincial government
Sources: compiled during the research project.
Table 2. Synthetic Weights for Wuhan.
Table 2. Synthetic Weights for Wuhan.
CityWeight
Xian0.420
Shanghai0.132
Beijing0.125
Changsha0.078
Shantou0.066
Haikou0.064
Daqing0.057
Xiangtan0.021
Jiayuguan0.017
Benxi0.012
Jinzhou0.010
Notes: The synthetic weight is the cities weight assigned in the synthetic control method. We list all the cities, which have positive weights for synthetic Wuhan, excluding 0-weights cities. Source: Authors’ computation STATA12 by synthetic control program.
Table 3. SO2 Emission Intensity Predictor Means before EFT Reform.
Table 3. SO2 Emission Intensity Predictor Means before EFT Reform.
WuhanSynthetic WuhanAverage of 262 Control Cities
Per capita GDP2.76282.82061.6247
seci0.45660.45780.4706
teri0.49440.49500.3599
pop945.5945.4414.0
dep0.17800.17880.2091
tech0.00890.00890.0049
edu0.08220.08190.0113
open2.96012.97481.8989
SO2 emissions intensity (2003)0.00670.00670.0187
SO2 emissions intensity (2005)0.00600.00600.0167
SO2 emissions intensity (2007)0.00410.00410.0117
Note: Per capita GDP, seci, teri, pop, dep, tech, edu, and open are averaged equally for the 2003–2007 period. The last column indicates an average of the 262 cities in our donor pool. Source: Authors’ computation STATA12 by synthetic control program.
Table 4. SO2 Emission intensity reduction of Target Cities, 2008–2013.
Table 4. SO2 Emission intensity reduction of Target Cities, 2008–2013.
CityAverage Reduction
(Ton/Million Yuan)
Average Decline Rate (%)
Wuhan0.032916.82
Xiangyang0.128030.21
Ezhou0.193619.16
Shiyan0.149032.42
Xianning0.185734.34
Jingzhou−0.0051−3.04
Xiaogan0.060410.37
Jingmen0.096316.68

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zheng, Y.; Zheng, H.; Ye, X. Using Machine Learning in Environmental Tax Reform Assessment for Sustainable Development: A Case Study of Hubei Province, China. Sustainability 2016, 8, 1124. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8111124

AMA Style

Zheng Y, Zheng H, Ye X. Using Machine Learning in Environmental Tax Reform Assessment for Sustainable Development: A Case Study of Hubei Province, China. Sustainability. 2016; 8(11):1124. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8111124

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zheng, Yinger, Haixia Zheng, and Xinyue Ye. 2016. "Using Machine Learning in Environmental Tax Reform Assessment for Sustainable Development: A Case Study of Hubei Province, China" Sustainability 8, no. 11: 1124. https://doi.org/10.3390/su8111124

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop