Next Article in Journal
Spatial Distribution Patterns, Eco-Environmental Risk Assessment, and Human Health Impacts of Uranium and Thorium in Beach Sediments in the Central Gulf of Gabes (Southern Mediterranean Sea)
Previous Article in Journal
Increasing Carbon Sequestration, Land-Use Efficiency, and Building Decarbonization with Short Rotation Eucalyptus
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Impact of Environmental Subsidies and Enforcement on Green Innovation: Evidence from Heavy-Polluting Enterprises in China

The College of Economics and Management, Shenyang Agricultural University, Shenyang 110866, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2025, 17(3), 1280; https://doi.org/10.3390/su17031280
Submission received: 1 January 2025 / Revised: 31 January 2025 / Accepted: 4 February 2025 / Published: 5 February 2025

Abstract

:
This paper investigates the critical role of government policies in promoting green development through enterprise-level green innovation (GI). We specifically examine the impact of environmental subsidies (ES) on heavily polluting enterprises and analyze how government environmental enforcement (EE) moderates this relationship. Furthermore, we explore how these effects vary across different ES characteristics and allocation patterns. Using data from heavy-polluting enterprises listed on China’s A-share market from 2012 to 2021, our analysis reveals several key findings. First, ES has unexpectedly hindered GI in heavily polluting enterprises. This negative effect stems from both ES characteristics and allocation patterns. Specifically, advance subsidies, targeted subsidies, and pollution prevention subsidies prove ineffective. The adverse impact of ES on GI is particularly pronounced in state-owned enterprises, companies lacking environmental protection investments, and firms engaging in earnings management practices. However, our findings indicate that strong environmental enforcement (EE) can effectively mitigate these ES-related issues. Under strict EE, ES demonstrates a positive effect on GI and addresses problems associated with both ES design characteristics and allocation patterns. These results offer valuable insights for government policymakers, particularly in developing countries undergoing green transition, to design and implement more effective environmental policies.

1. Introduction

As China experiences sustained economic growth, the nation faces increasingly severe environmental challenges, particularly in water and air pollution [1,2]. These environmental issues stem primarily from heavy-polluting industries characterized by excessive resource consumption, high emission levels, and substantial environmental degradation [3,4]. Research from the Center for Energy & Environmental Policy Research at the Beijing Institute of Technology reveals that, since China’s reform and opening up, enterprises generating 40% of industrial GDP have consumed approximately 70% of the country’s energy resources. Among 41 national industries, the electricity and thermal production sector, non-metallic mineral industry, and ferrous smelting and calendering industry are the top three contributors to SO2 and nitrogen oxide emissions. These three industries alone account for more than 60% of SO2 emissions, 75% of nitrogen oxide emissions, and 70% of smoke and powder emissions from key industrial firms. Therefore, facilitating the green transformation of heavy-polluting industries has become a critical imperative for advancing China’s transition toward a green economy.
For heavy-polluting enterprises in China, green innovation (GI) represents a critical pathway toward sustainable development through the implementation of environmentally friendly practices. GI encompasses scientific and technological innovation activities undertaken by relevant entities to mitigate environmental risks [5,6]. The primary objective of GI is to advance the development of green technologies that enhance energy efficiency, reduce emissions, promote clean production processes, and maximize the utilization of renewable energy sources. These advancements enable firms to enhance their environmental sustainability [6,7,8]. Through GI implementation, heavy-polluting enterprises can achieve multiple benefits, including gaining competitive advantages and long-term sustainable development [9,10].
However, there is currently a lack of GI incentives for heavy-polluting enterprises [11]. GI is marked by long cycles, significant technological uncertainties, and substantial early-stage investments [12]. Furthermore, GI demonstrates dual externalities, including positive environmental impacts and knowledge spillovers comparable to conventional innovations [13,14]. The market mechanism alone proves insufficient to support GI initiatives due to their inherent high risks and substantial capital requirements [15]. This is particularly evident in China, where heavy-polluting enterprises continue to rely predominantly on pollution-intensive technologies during the country’s transition toward a green economy [16]. Statistical evidence underscores this challenge, as more than 65% of heavy-polluting companies in China did not file any green patent applications between 2010 and 2020 [17].
Environmental subsidies (ES) serve as a critical policy instrument for governments to promote GI among heavy-polluting enterprises [18,19,20]. The inherent externalities of GI often create financial barriers for firms, as the private implementation costs typically exceed potential returns [21,22]. ES, provided as unconditional government support, offers enterprises essential external resources to pursue GI initiatives [23,24,25]. While scholarly attention on the relationship between ES and GI has increased, research findings remain inconclusive. Numerous studies demonstrate that ES effectively stimulates GI [19,26,27,28,29], while other research suggests contrary effects [18,30,31].
Similar to ES, environmental enforcement (EE) serves as another crucial policy tool for governments to regulate enterprise environmental protection behavior, and it has been widely implemented globally [32,33]. EE effectively and directly regulates corporate environmental damage behaviors [32]. However, the relationship between EE and corporate GI remains ambiguous. Some studies suggest that, under government EE pressure, enterprises tend to adopt environmentally friendly technologies to meet regulatory requirements [34,35,36]. Conversely, other research indicates that EE’s impact is limited and insufficient to fundamentally transform enterprise production patterns [24,37].
As a developing country undergoing green transformation, China’s ES and EE are experiencing a distinctive evolutionary phase. While the intensity of ES initially increased, it has subsequently shown a consistent declining trend. According to the National Bureau of Statistics of China, fiscal expenditures for environmental protection demonstrated an overall upward trajectory from 2007 to 2023, yet averaged only 2.48% of total fiscal expenditures annually. Furthermore, the China Ecological Environment Statistical Yearbook, published by the Ministry of Ecology and Environment, reveals that, from 2007 to 2022, China’s total social investment in environmental pollution control averaged just 1.25% of GDP, declining to 0.7% in 2022. This stands in stark contrast to Sweden, where the corresponding figure ranged between 2% and 10% from 1998 to 2002. International experience suggests that, when social environmental protection investment reaches 1–1.5% of GDP, it can effectively curb environmental degradation, while a 2–3% investment can actively improve environmental quality. Conversely, China’s EE intensity has been steadily increasing. In the past decade, heavy-polluting enterprises have faced increasingly rigorous environmental regulations, most notably through the implementation of the new environmental protection law in 2015, widely regarded as “the most stringent environmental protection law in history” [38].
In this study, we examine the impact of ES on GI among China’s heavy-polluting listed enterprises from 2012 to 2021, while investigating the moderating role of EE. Our findings reveal that ES negatively affects GI in heavy-polluting enterprises. However, EE serves as a positive moderator, mitigating this negative impact. Through analyzing the timing, form, and content of ES, we discover that the negative effects on GI primarily stem from ES beforehand, targeted ES, and prevention-focused ES initiatives. Furthermore, our research explores how ES impacts GI differently across various enterprise characteristics, including property rights, environmental investment situations, and earnings management levels. The results indicate that ES’s effectiveness is particularly diminished in state-owned enterprises, companies lacking environmental investments, and firms with high earnings management levels. Notably, EE demonstrates its ability to moderate these adverse effects.
Our research significantly expands upon the “narrow” version of the Porter hypothesis, which suggests that specific government policies can stimulate innovation [39,40,41,42]. Firstly, we demonstrate that various design features of ES differently impact GI in heavy-polluting enterprises, providing valuable insights for ES policy design. Secondly, our findings reveal that stringent EE can effectively mitigate the negative effects of ES, highlighting the critical importance of synergy between environmental policies. Lastly, our analysis of different groups based on property rights, environmental investments, and earnings management levels. These findings offer meaningful implications for regional green development during environmental transformation periods.
The following section reviews the existing literature and develops hypotheses. Section 3 describes the sample, data, variables, and research methodology. Section 4 presents and analyzes the research findings. Finally, the concluding section provides policy recommendations to address the identified issues.

2. Literature Review and Hypothesis Development

2.1. The Impact of Environmental Subsidy on Green Innovation

GI refers to scientific and technological innovation activities undertaken by stakeholders to promote environmental protection [5]. For firms, GI exhibits unique dual externalities, environmental positive externality due to its green development objectives, and knowledge spillover effects [13,14,20]. These externalities often make GI activities financially unfavorable for firms, as the private costs typically exceed potential revenues [27]. Consequently, enterprises frequently lack adequate incentives to pursue GI initiatives.
Heavy-polluting enterprises are critical subjects in the GI research literature. These enterprises face significant challenges, including high implementation costs and technical barriers [41]. And, environmental pressures compel heavy-polluting industries to adopt GI practices for sustainable growth [43]. Researchers have extensively investigated various approaches to promote GI within heavy-polluting enterprises [3,15,44]. Moreover, numerous studies have examined the feasibility and effectiveness of policy measures designed to stimulate GI implementation in heavy-polluting enterprises [4,28,41,45].
ES are non-repayable financial support subsidies provided by governments, aimed at promoting environmental protection and governance activities [27,31,46]. These subsidies incentivize enterprises to enhance their products and processing technologies [18,19,29]. The effects of ES remain unclear. Some studies support a clear positive correlation between ES and GI. As supplementary financial resources, ES can help enterprises alleviate operational pressures, enabling them to increase their GI practices [19]. Shao and Chen [27] delved into the impacts of government subsidies, encompassing environmental protection subsidies, R&D subsidies, and talent subsidies, on the green innovation transformation of Chinese enterprises during the period from 2007 to 2019. Their research validated the positive influences of these subsidies. Similarly, Wei et al. [28] utilized the data of 825 A—share listed enterprises from 2009 to 2020 to analyze the correlation between environmental subsidies and GI. Their findings revealed the promotional environmental subsidies on GI.
However, the effectiveness of ES in fostering corporate GI has notable limitations [30]. Some scholars have emphasized that ES is not always an ideal choice for the government, because they only have a positive impact on GI under certain specific circumstances [18,47]. Osorio and Zhang [48] conducted a comparative analysis of product feature subsidies and CO2 abatement subsidies on corporate environmental investments, revealing that CO2 abatement subsidies proved beneficial only under conditions of low emission levels. Furthermore, some other scholars believe that ES may hinder corporate GI [30]. Li and Xiao [31] identified that ES can actually impede GI due to companies’ opportunistic behaviors and their tendency to align with government preferences rather than genuine innovation goals.
ES, as a crucial government tool for supporting and guiding enterprises’ green development, theoretically plays a significant role in facilitating the green development of heavily polluting enterprises. However, in China, ES’ effects are limited. First, China’s ES intensity remains inadequate. In 2006, the “Expenditure on Environmental Protection” category-level account was set up in China’s budget system for the first time. According to data from the National Bureau of Statistics, from 2007 to 2023, the proportion of environmental protection expenditure in GDP in China ranged from 0.37% to 0.75%. In developed countries such as the United States, Germany, and Japan, this proportion exceeded 2% as early as the 1970s. Second, ES are broadly targeted at environmental protection activities rather than specifically designed for GI initiatives. Given that GI projects typically involve higher risks, greater costs, and longer payback periods compared to other environmental practices [34]. Finally, the inefficient distribution of ES can lead to distorted allocation of funds both within and between enterprises [31,49,50]. Based on these observations, this article proposes the following hypothesis.
H1. 
ES negatively impacts the GI of heavy-polluting enterprises in China.

2.2. Environmental Subsidy Characteristics and Green Innovation

Various scholars have highlighted the influential effects of environmental policy characteristics on GI [12,51,52]. According to the allocation process and behavioral targets, the design characteristics of ES can be explained from three perspectives [34,53,54]. The first aspect is the subsidy timing [55]. The distinction lies in whether the intended goals are anticipated or achieved, or whether the projects are still ongoing or completed [56]. ES beforehand (ESB) is provided to companies before their project initiation, whereas ES afterwards (ESA) is provided thereafter [47,51,57,58]. The second category is the subsidy form [21,59]. ES can be divided into two categories: general ES (GES) and targeted ES (TES). TES tends to have more explicit guidelines for application, allocation, and investment decisions. GES is ES with no specific goals [21]. The last type of subsidy content. Enterprises have two primary methods of reducing emissions: pollution prevention and end-of-pipe control [60,61]. Correspondingly, ES can be divided into pollution prevention subsidy (PES) and end-of-pipe control subsidy (EES).
ES with different characteristics influences GI differently among China’s heavy-polluting enterprises. Firstly, compared to ESA, ESB provides clearer objectives and more substantial initial funding to guide firms’ GI. However, ESB may introduce challenges absent in ESA, including inequitable distribution, unclear implementation guidelines, and potential subsidy fraud [56,62,63]. Secondly, different forms of ES offer varying degrees of flexibility [21]. GES allows enterprises to determine their optimal approach to green innovation, while TES provides more specific direction and guidance [21,64]. Thirdly, the content of environmental subsidies differently impacts enterprise operations. PES are more directly integrated with production processes compared to EES. Companies receiving PES typically need to implement comprehensive changes across their production systems, requiring greater organizational effort and commitment. Heavy-polluting enterprises may adopt different strategies based on the characteristics of received subsidies. For instance, when faced with EES, TES, or PES, enterprises often experience increased pressure, potentially leading them to prioritize short-term compliance over long-term GI strategies. Based on these observations, this paper presents the following hypotheses.
H2. 
ES with different characteristics has different impacts on GI.

2.3. Heterogeneity of Property Rights, Environmental Investments, and Earnings Management

From the perspective of ES allocation, several factors influence the effectiveness of ES on GI, including enterprise property rights, environmental investment, and earnings management practices. In China, enterprises are categorized into state-owned and non-state-owned entities [65], with state-owned enterprises typically demonstrating greater commitment to social performance than their non-state-owned counterparts [27,44,66]. Environmental investment, defined as direct expenditure on environmental protection to reduce pollution and enhance resource utilization efficiency [67], plays a crucial role. ES can effectively motivate enterprises with environmental investments to implement GI measures and enhance their innovation capabilities [68]. Corporate earnings manipulation also impacts the relationship between ES and GI. This practice involves deliberately manipulating financial statements to reduce costs and increase profits for private benefits [69]. Due to information asymmetry between governmental authorities and enterprises, companies may secure ES through earnings manipulation, potentially disrupting the optimal allocation of environmental subsidies among enterprises [70,71].
The effects of ES on GI vary depending on enterprises’ property rights structures, environmental investments, and earnings management practices. First, state-owned enterprises, due to their close governmental ties, bear greater social responsibilities and tend to favor traditional projects over GI [61]. In contrast, non-state-owned enterprises demonstrate a stronger inclination to expand their market presence through GI [27]. Second, the high-risk nature of GI makes it particularly sensitive to corporate environmental investments [67]. Drawing on data from the China Ecological Environment Statistical Bulletin 2022, it is evident that the environmental governance expenditure for the completion and acceptance of industrial pollution source treatment and construction projects constituted 33.7% of the total expenditure. Social environmental governance expenditure primarily took the form of investment in urban environmental infrastructure construction. Notably, the industrial sector’s relatively low inclination to invest in environmental protection combined with high transformation costs, may diminish the effectiveness of ES. Some enterprises even view ES primarily as an additional revenue stream. Finally, some enterprises employ earnings management strategies to secure more ES, which undermines GI efforts by companies genuinely committed to environmental sustainability [31]. Moreover, enterprises engaging in earnings management typically prioritize short-term financial objectives [71].
H3. 
Impacts of ES on GI are different for heavy polluting enterprises with different property rights, environmental investments and earnings management levels.

2.4. Moderating Effect of Environmental Enforcement

EE is a process through which public agents detect and sanction violations of environmental protection laws [36,72]. As a typical environmental regulation, EE is considered an effective command-control policy tool [30,73]. According to the deterrence mechanism, enterprises subject to EE are likely to cease their environmental violations and adopt GI activities to maintain organizational legitimacy [74].
Scholars hold divergent views regarding the relationship between EE and GI in enterprises. Some researchers argue that EE can effectively promote GI [73]. For instance, Testa et al. [30] examined the relationship between environmental regulation and firms’ competitive performance, finding that frequent government inspections can stimulate enterprise technology adoption and product innovation. However, other studies suggest that EE may not effectively promote GI. Prechel and Zheng [75], analyzing data from Standard & Poor’s 500 corporations, found that government penalties did not motivate companies to invest in pollution reduction technologies. Furthermore, Liao [24] compared the effectiveness of various environmental policy tools on enterprises’ GI and concluded that strict penalties have limited impact on innovation compared to market measures and information-based instruments.
As a crucial incentive for promoting environmental protection among firms, EE significantly influences the effectiveness of ES for GI [76]. First, non-compliant enterprises often face severe penalties that can result in costs far exceeding the initial investment required for implementing GI [35]. Consequently, heavy-polluting enterprises tend to allocate more ES towards GI activities. Second, EE can lead to market-based penalties, particularly affecting corporate reputation [77]. This motivates enterprises to utilize ES for GI to ensure compliance with regulations. Finally, EE enhances the effectiveness of ES by raising environmental awareness among enterprises [34,78]. These factors demonstrate the complementary relationship between ES and EE in promoting GI. Based on these observations, this paper proposes the following hypothesis.
Meanwhile, the government’s stringent EE can mitigate the inefficiencies in ES caused by property rights, environmental investments, and earnings management. Under environmental penalty policies, state-owned enterprises are typically held to higher standards, compelling them to actively pursue GI to prevent negative environmental impacts [62,79,80]. Furthermore, enhanced EE creates external pressure on heavy-polluting enterprises, forcing those with limited environmental investments to innovate and comply with regulatory requirements to avoid penalties [35]. Additionally, EE weakens the ability of heavy-polluting enterprises to manipulate earnings, limiting managers to earnings management through actual activities, which ultimately facilitates better implementation of GI initiatives [81]. Based on these observations, this article proposes the following hypothesis.
H4. 
EE can play a positive moderating role in the process of ES influencing GI.

3. Search Design

3.1. Sample and Data Resource

The sample for this study consists of enterprises from heavy-polluting industries listed in China’s A-share market. Based on the Environment Information Disclosure Guidance for Listed Companies issued by China’s Ministry of Environmental Protection in 2010 and the revised Guideline for the Industry Classification of Listed Companies by the Communication Science Research Center in 2012, sixteen categories of heavy-polluting industries were identified, including encompass thermal power, iron and steel, coal, metallurgy, chemicals, petrochemicals, building materials, paper making, pharmaceuticals, textiles, leather-making, and mining. These industries correspond to the 2-digit industry codes B06-10, C17, C19, C22, C25-32, and D44.
The study period spans from 2012 to 2021 to ensure sample selection consistency. Companies with ST, *ST, and PT status were excluded from the analysis. Additionally, firms with incomplete data or significant outliers were removed, specifically those with asset-liability ratios exceeding 1 or negative returns on total assets. After applying these screening criteria, the final sample comprises 1254 A-share companies from heavy-polluting industries, yielding a total of 8422 observations.
Data on environmental subsidies (ES) are collected through systematic manual analysis of annual reports from heavily polluting enterprises. To ensure data accuracy and reliability, we implemented a three-step collection process. First, we identified the scope of subsidies based on the primary types of ES received by enterprises, which encompass pollution monitoring subsidies, energy conservation subsidies, emission reduction subsidies, pollution abatement subsidies, other environmental subsidies, and environmental protection awards. The detailed definitions of these ES categories are presented in Table 1. Second, we divided our research team into two independent groups to analyze subsidy information in the annual reports and document the annual subsidy amounts received by each enterprise across all ES categories. Finally, we cross-validated the findings between the two groups to determine the definitive ES figures for each enterprise.
This article utilizes multiple data sources. The GI data is obtained from the Chinese Research Data Services Platform, which aggregates patents from both the China National Intellectual Property Administration and Google Patent. These patents are categorized according to the green patent criteria established by the World Intellectual Property Office [82,83]. EE data comes from the Institute of Public Environment Affairs (IPE), a nonprofit environmental research institute established in 2006. The IPE maintains a comprehensive enterprise environmental performance database that documents government environmental supervision, including detailed information about enterprises, violation specifics, and corresponding penalties. Additional enterprise-related data is extracted from the Wind database.

3.2. Variables

(1) The explained variable is GI. Due to its inherent complexity, measuring and quantifying GI presents significant challenges. While various metrics have been developed to assess GI, patents remain the most widely used indicator [38]. Although patents serve as intermediate measures, they effectively demonstrate the firms’ capabilities and commitment to scientific advancement in green development [62]. Patent-related measurements of GI encompass patent applications, granted patents, and more comprehensive metrics, such as patent ratios [84,85]. Green patent applications, however, typically undergo less rigorous review processes and may not fully validate the innovativeness or environmental benefits of the proposed technology. While patent ratios, which calculate the proportion of green patents, can indicate a company’s green development level, this metric is vulnerable to fluctuations in the firm’s overall innovation performance. Authorized green patents provide a direct measure of concrete scientific and technological innovation outcomes [85]. These patents undergo thorough examination, making them a more reliable indicator. The number of authorized green patents a company holds directly reflects its investment in green technology innovation and demonstrates its GI capabilities [86]. Therefore, this study employs the logarithm of authorized green patents as the measurement for GI.
(2) The explanatory variable ES represents government subsidies provided to enterprises for their environmental protection initiatives. We collected data on environment-related subsidies recorded in the non-operating income section of companies’ annual reports. The various categories of environmental subsidies received by companies are listed in Table 1. We summed these subsidies and took the logarithm to derive our core explanatory variable.
This paper further categorizes ES based on their timing, flexibility, and content characteristics. First, environmental subsidies are classified as ESB and ESA, depending on when they are granted. Second, subsidies are categorized as GES or TES based on whether they target specific environmental projects. Finally, considering the two types of environmental protection behaviors in relation to production activities, subsidies are divided into PES and EES. The specific characteristics of these environmental subsidies are detailed below.
  • ESB: Government funding provided directly to companies that implement environmentally protective measures.
  • ESA: Government awards granted to companies for implementing environmentally protective practices and initiatives.
  • TES: ES that define the project’s purpose and objectives.
  • GES: ES that does not specify a particular project purpose or scope.
  • PES: Subsidies provided for pollution prevention activities integrated into production processes.
  • EES: Subsidies specifically designed for end-of-pipe pollution control measures that operate independently of the main production processes.
By analyzing various types of environmental subsidies (ES) shown in Table 1 and their inherent characteristics, we have derived the subsidy characteristic variables. Table 2 categorizes five distinct types of ES based on their defining features. It should be noted that, due to limited disclosure of detailed subsidy information, environmental protection rewards have been excluded from our classification of subsidy form and content. Additionally, subsidies without specific targets have been omitted from the subsidy content classification.
There is a key point about the scope difference between ESB and ESA. The existing literature primarily distinguishes between ESB and ESA using two methods. The first method considers ESB as environmental subsidies in deferred revenue, while ESA are the ones in the current profit and loss [56]. The second approach distinguishes between tax-based and non-tax-based environmental subsidies [87,88]. However, both approaches have limitations. Under Chinese accounting standards, certain subsidies within current profit and loss can be classified as ESB, contradicting the first approach. Additionally, environmental tax-based subsidies are rarely disclosed separately from non-environmental tax-based subsidies, limiting the effectiveness of the second approach. In this paper, we define ESB as direct government funding intended to encourage future environmental protection initiatives, while ESA represents rewards for existing environmental protection achievements. Specifically, ESB is typically allocated before the completion of environmental protection projects, whereas ESA is disbursed upon project completion or near completion.
(3) Moderating variable: EE. EE has a moderating effect mainly through the compliance pressure it exerts on heavy-polluting enterprises [4,89,90]. In this study, EE is measured by examining whether companies have been subject to environmental penalties, administrative orders, or administrative ratings during the sample period and previous years. According to the Measures for Environmental Administrative Punishment (Ministry of Environment Protection, 2010), administrative penalties encompass fines, warnings, administrative detention, production restrictions, and facility shutdowns. Administrative orders require companies to cease polluting activities, implement corrective measures, or modify production processes to prevent environmental pollution. Administrative ratings identify companies that receive lower-tier classifications in government environmental performance evaluations. This includes enterprises issued yellow cards, red cards, or black cards due to hazardous operations. Additionally, it covers companies designated as C-level and D-level enterprises, which are identified as key concerns for emergency emission reductions during periods of severe pollution. And the situations associated with significant risks of sudden environmental are included.
(4) Control variables in this study primarily focus on enterprise characteristics [11,49]. The controlled variables include R&D intensity (RD), company size (Size), company age (Age), financial leverage (Lev), nature of equity (Soe), cash flow ratio (Cash), and return on assets (Roa). These variables significantly influence firms’ green innovation capabilities [27]. Size is measured by the natural logarithm of total assets, reflecting the advantages that large enterprises possess in resources and innovation activities. Age is calculated using the logarithm of the enterprise establishment period with the natural base. The relationship between age and innovation capability is complex: while accumulated experience and knowledge can enhance innovation capability over time, organizational inertia may impede innovation. Lev is determined by the ratio of liabilities to total assets, indicating a firm’s leverage level and financial risk. Soe differentiates between state-owned enterprises (SOE) and non-SOE, acknowledging that companies with different ownership structures demonstrate varying behaviors in GI. Cash measures a company’s liquidity and investment capacity for GI through the ratio of operating and investing activity cash to total assets. Roa is the ratio of net profit income after tax to total assets, evaluating corporate performance. Strong operational performance enables reinvestment and innovation activities. RD is represented by the natural logarithm of one plus R&D expenditure per employee, indicating the company’s research and development commitment.
This study also controls industry dummy variables. Heavy-polluting industries exhibit significant differences in pollution control difficulty and environmental protection technology levels, resulting in distinct challenges in green transformation across industries. This variation likely leads to substantial differences in ES application probabilities among enterprises in different heavy-polluting industries. Furthermore, government support may vary by industry, necessitating the control of heavy-polluting industry dummy variables. Regional factors are also significant. Heavy-polluting enterprises in different provincial regions face varying ecological environmental carrying capacities and local government environmental protection efforts, affecting their capabilities and probabilities of obtaining ES. Year fixed effects are equally important, as they control for the impact of macro-environmental policy adjustments and changes in environmental protection conditions on heavy-polluting enterprises’ motivation to apply for ES [91]. The variables and their measurements are shown in Table 3.

3.3. Model

To examine the relationships among ES, ES characteristics, and GI, as well as to analyze the moderating effects of EE, this study employs a four-model framework. First, Model (1) investigates the direct impact of ES on GI. Second, Model (2) analyzes how different ES characteristics influence GI through separate regression analyses, focusing on three aspects: time-point features (before and after subsidy, ESB and ESA), flexibility degrees (targeted and general subsidy, TES and GES), and content features (production prevention subsidy and end-of-pipe control subsidy, PES and EES). Finally, Models (3) and (4) assess the moderating effect of EE on these relationships.
G I i t = α 0 + α 1 E S i t 1 + α 2 C o n t r o l s i t + α 3 Y e a r + α 4 P r o v + α 5 I n d + ε i t
G I i t = β 0 + β 1 E S   C h a r a c t e r i s t i c s i t 1 + β 3 C o n t r o l s i t + β 4 Y e a r + β 5 P r o v + β 6 I n d + δ i t
G I i t = γ 0 + γ 1 E S i t 1 + γ 2 E E i t + γ 3 E S i t 1 # E E i t + γ 4 C o n t r o l s i t + γ 5 Y e a r + γ 6 P r o v + γ 7 I n d + ϵ i t
G I i t = δ 0 + δ 1 E S   C h a r a c t e r i s t i c s i t 1 + δ 2 E E i t + δ 3 E S   C h a r a c t e r i s t i c s i t 1 # E E i t + δ 4 C o n t r o l s i t + δ 5 Y e a r + δ 6 P r o v + δ 7 I n d + ϑ i t
For the above models, “i” represents enterprises, “t” indicates the year, and the symbol “#” represents interaction terms. “Controls” are those variables that may have impacts on GI. Additionally, this study controls for temporal effects through the “Year” variable, industry-specific characteristics (denoted as ‘Ind’), and regional factors (denoted as ‘Prov’).
To address potential endogeneity concerns in our research, we implemented two strategic approaches. First, we incorporated a one-period lag for ES and their various characteristics, which effectively mitigates reverse causality and spurious regression issues [92]. Second, we addressed the sample selection bias, where firms with stronger GI capabilities tend to be more proactive in seeking and securing ES. To resolve this, we utilized an instrumental variable approach, employing the average subsidy allocation at the 2-digit industry code level for ES and their characteristics. The higher the average level of industrial ES, the greater the probability that an enterprise will obtain environment-related subsidies, but it has no direct relationship with the enterprise’s GI [93]. Further, we employ the Two-Stage Least Squares (2SLS) estimation method to estimate the above models.

4. Results

4.1. Descriptive Statistics

The distribution of heavy-polluting enterprises in China across industries and time from 2012 to 2021 is shown in Table 4. The data reveals significant variations in enterprise numbers across different industrial sectors. The chemical and pharmaceutical industries demonstrate the highest concentration of enterprises, while the leather-making industry shows the lowest representation. Over this period, substantial growth in enterprise numbers has been observed in the chemical, pharmaceutical, metallurgical, and building material sectors. In contrast, industries such as thermal power, iron and steel, coal, mining, and petrochemicals have maintained relatively stable numbers. This trend may indicate that many heavy-polluting industries have begun transitioning toward green transformation.
Figure 1 illustrates the annual mean values of ES and EE. The average ES shows a declining trend since 2019, while the average EE consistently increases, particularly since 2015. These trends suggest a period of adjustment for ES and a growing stringency in EE.
The descriptive statistics for all variables are presented in Table 5. The data reveals that more than 50% of heavy-polluting enterprises filed no green patents during the study period, indicating a significant lack of enthusiasm for GI activities. Analysis of the mean values of ES across different categories shows that ESB is higher than ESA. Similarly, TES exceed general GES, while PES are greater than EES. These findings indicate that the majority of ES are disbursed before the completion of environmental projects, primarily in the form of targeted funding for pollution prevention initiatives. The median value (50th percentile) of EE remains at zero, suggesting that only a small proportion of enterprises have faced governmental enforcement actions during the study period.
Table 6 presents the correlations between various variables, including ES, ES characteristics, EE, and GI. All these variables show significant correlations significantly. This means that that environmental strategies, such as ES and EE, can affect GI ability of heavy-polluting firms significantly.

4.2. Empirical Results

4.2.1. Effects of ES on GI

We conducted regression analyses and computed variance inflation factors (VIFs) to evaluate potential multicollinearity. The results revealed that all VIFs fell well below the critical threshold of 10, indicating no significant multicollinearity concerns. Additionally, we performed a weak instrument test using the Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic. The analysis showed that all F values surpassed 10, confirming the robustness and validity of our chosen instrumental variables.
Table 7 demonstrates the impact of ES on GI among heavy-polluting firms. Due to substantial variations in characteristics and development patterns across heavy-polluting industries, the second column of regression results incorporates both year and industry fixed effects. Additionally, the third column accounts for provincial control variables, considering regional differences in industrial structure, economic development levels, and industrial policies.
The regression analysis reveals a significant negative correlation between ES and GI, indicating that heavy-polluting companies receiving higher ES are less likely to engage in GI activities. This finding supports Hypothesis H1, which demonstrates the inefficiency of ES in influencing GI for heavy-polluting enterprises in China. The negative impact of ES on GI has also been identified in some previous studies [18,30,31,47,49,50]. This negative outcome may indicate the following facts. First, the intensity of subsidies remains insufficient [49]. The relatively low levels of ES provided to heavy-polluting enterprises in China are insufficient to offset the costs and externalities associated with GI. Second, there may be issues in the design of ES. Only “well-designed” subsidies can better exert their effectiveness [30,47]. Third, there are problems in the allocation of ES. The misallocation of subsidy funds among enterprises weakens the effect of subsidies on GI [31,49,50]. The negative effect of ES on GI is exactly the opposite of the results of Shao and Chen [27] and Wei et al. [28]. This is because the above-mentioned studies analyzed all enterprises in China. This opposite result also demonstrates the particularity and importance of the role of ES heavy-polluting enterprises’ GI.
Table 8 illustrates the differential impacts of ES with varying characteristics on GI in heavy-polluting enterprises. The analysis focuses on key explanatory variables, with control variable results excluded for clarity. The impact of ES varies significantly across different characteristics. Regarding timing, ESB demonstrates a significant negative impact on GI, while ESA shows no significant effect. In terms of subsidy forms, TES exhibits a significant negative influence, whereas GES shows a significant positive impact. Similarly, for subsidy content, PES has a significant negative effect, while EES demonstrates a significant positive influence. These findings align with Hypothesis 2. When heavy-polluting enterprises receive ESB, TES, or PES, they must meet stringent acceptance criteria, requiring substantial financial allocation to achieve specific targets. Consequently, the heightened environmental pressure forces these enterprises to prioritize immediate pollution control over long-term GI investments.
To analyze the heterogeneous effects of ES on GI across different enterprises, this paper categorizes enterprises based on three criteria: property rights, environmental protection investment status, and earnings management practices. Heterogeneity analysis can reveal the problems of ES allocation. The empirical tests are conducted using models (1) and (3) with the following classification methodology: First, enterprises are categorized into state-owned enterprises (SOE) and non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOE). Second, they are classified as enterprises with environmental protection investment (EPI) and those without (non-EPI). Following Zhu and Mao’s [94] research methodology, environmental protection investment data is manually collected from enterprise annual reports. This includes environmental assessment fees, sewage discharge fees, and greening fees listed under “administrative expenses” in the income statement. Additionally, it encompasses expenditures for desulfurization and denitrification projects, sewage and waste gas treatment facilities, waste heat power generation, energy conservation initiatives, clean production lines, and dust removal systems detailed in the “construction in progress” section. Finally, enterprises are divided into high earnings management (REM) and low earnings management (non-REM) categories based on their earnings management levels. Following Roychowdhury’s [95] methodology, three types of real earnings management are measured using least squares regression while controlling for year and industry variables, sales manipulation, production manipulation, and discretionary expense manipulation. A comprehensive real earnings management index is constructed using Cohen [96] approach. Subsequently, a dummy variable REM is established to measure enterprise earnings management. Enterprises with real earnings management levels above the sample median are classified as REM enterprises, while those below are designated as non-REM enterprises.
Then, we analyzed the impact of ES on GI across different groups (Table 9). The finding supports Hypothesis H3. The results reveal that ES has a significant negative effect on GI in SOE enterprises. The SOE enterprises have lower motivation for GI and poorer utilization of ES, which has been observed in the previous literature [27,66]. For non-EPI enterprises, the negative impact is particularly significant, as these companies lack the fundamental environmental protection infrastructure and technology. Consequently, even when receiving subsidies, they struggle to implement GI projects effectively. Similarly, the effect of ES on GI in enterprises engaging in earnings management shows a significant negative relationship, indicating that such practices may obscure their true operational conditions and financial risks. These companies tend to manipulate profits to achieve short-term performance targets while neglecting investments in long-term green development. As Li and Xiao [31] and Bai et al. [49] stressed, enterprises spent more time and effort on obtaining subsidies rather than innovation, which weaken the effectiveness of the policy.

4.2.2. Moderating Effects of EE

Table 10 presents the results of the moderating effect of EE corresponding to models (3) and (4). In the process where ES influences GI, EE demonstrates a significantly positive moderating effect, confirming Hypothesis H4. This indicates that stringent EE not only mitigates potential adverse impacts of ES, but also substantially enhances its positive influence on GI. When examining the moderating effect of EE on subsidy effectiveness across different characteristics, the regression coefficients for the interaction terms between ESB, TES, and PES are all significantly positive, validating Hypothesis H4. These findings indicate that various types of ES, when coupled with strict EE, demonstrate more pronounced facilitative effects. This suggests that stringent EE motivates enterprises to prioritize GI, thereby improving the efficiency and effectiveness of subsidy utilization. Additionally, our study reveals that flexible policy frameworks are more effective at stimulating GI compared to targeted policies. A flexible policy environment enables enterprises to explore diverse GI pathways aligned with their specific characteristics while maintaining basic environmental standards.
Table 11 presents the interaction effects between ES and EE on GI in heavily polluting enterprises. The results reveal that the interaction coefficient is significantly positive for SOE enterprises, non-EPI enterprises and REM enterprises. This finding suggests that stringent environmental penalties compel heavily polluting enterprises to pursue GI, thereby enhancing the effectiveness of ES. Consequently, EE serves as an effective mechanism to address the inefficient allocation of ES. These results in Table 8 and Table 9 align with the conclusions drawn by some studies focusing on the green transition issues in developing countries [21,28,97,98]. EE is widely recognized as one of the most effective drivers of GI. Therefore, relying solely on subsidies to promote corporate GI is insufficient [30]; it must be complemented by stringent EE to create a robust policy package that can more effectively stimulate corporate GI activities [24].

4.3. Robustness Tests

4.3.1. Heckman Two-Step Method

When analyzing the relationship between GI and ES, there exists a potential sample selection bias. Firms may receive subsidies based on specific characteristics, such as size, age, or state ownership status, which could simultaneously influence their patent authorization behavior. If not properly addressed, this bias could lead to inaccurate estimates. To mitigate this issue, we employ the Heckman two-step method [99]. This approach consists of two distinct stages. First, a Probit model predicts firm selection into the main regression model by estimating the probability of receiving subsidies based on observable firm characteristics. Second, the derived Mills ratio (or inverse Mills ratio) is incorporated as an additional explanatory variable in the main regression equation to control for sample selection bias. The Heckman correction effectively addresses estimation biases arising from sample selection issues, resulting in more accurate and reliable regression results. By accounting for the non-random selection process in subsidy allocation, this method ensures that the estimated relationships between GI and ES reflect genuine causal effects rather than spurious correlations driven by sample selection. We re-examined the relationship between ES and ES with different characteristics and GI using the Heckman two-step method, and the results are robust. The results are shown in Table 12.

4.3.2. Propensity Score Match

To validate our research findings and mitigate potential sample issues derived from EE, we implemented a robustness check using the Propensity Score Matching (PSM) method [84,85]. Since EE is not randomly distributed among firms, potential heterogeneity concerns needed to be addressed. We systematically matched firms with EE to comparable firms without EE, eliminating unmatched observations, and subsequently reassessed EE’s moderating effects. The validation process incorporated three distinct matching techniques, 1-to-1 nearest neighbor matching, radius caliper matching, and kernel matching. Across all three matching approaches, our primary findings remained robust and consistent, thereby substantiating the reliability and validity of our research conclusions. To simplify the presentation of the results, we have chosen to report only the findings from kernel matching in the main text (Table 13). It is noteworthy that the results produced by 1:1 matching and radius caliper matching are qualitatively identical to those obtained through kernel matching, with all relevant coefficients maintaining the same signs.

4.3.3. Alternative Explained Variable

As a robustness check, we employed the natural logarithm of green patent applications as an alternative dependent variable. The results remained consistent with our core findings, further confirming the reliability and stability of our research conclusions. The results are presented in Table 14 and Table 15.

4.3.4. Sample Period Adjustment

Due to the 2021 revision of China’s Patent Law, we adjusted our sample period to focus on data from 2012 to 2020. This modification did not affect the validity of our analysis, as our regression results remained robust and consistently supported our initial findings. Results are presented in Table 16 and Table 17.

5. Conclusions and Policy Implications

This study systematically examines the impact of environmental subsidies (ES) on green innovation (GI) among heavy-polluting listed companies in China from 2012 to 2021, while investigating the moderating role of environmental enforcement (EE). The study yields several significant findings. First, ES generally inhibits GI; however, stringent EE actively promotes GI and can mitigate the adverse effects of ES. Second, different characteristics of ES demonstrate varying impacts on corporate GI. The negative influence primarily originates from ES beforehand, targeted ES, and pollution prevention ES. Strict EE can effectively compensate for these ES-related deficiencies, thereby fostering corporate GI. Furthermore, the study explores the allocation efficiency of ES and its interaction with EE through the lens of corporate ownership structure, environmental investment, and earnings management quality. The findings reveal that state-owned enterprises, companies lacking environmental investments, and those with higher earnings management levels demonstrate negative responses to ES. However, robust EE can transform these outcomes, indicating its potential to improve ES allocation issues and enhance overall GI levels among heavy-polluting enterprises.
Based on the findings, several policy implications emerge for China to promote the green transition of heavily polluting firms and achieve a sustainable economy. First, ES has proven insufficient in encouraging GI in these companies. Therefore, the government should strengthen the implementation of ES policies. Second, the design of ES must consider critical factors such as timing, form, and content, as these aspects significantly influence GI success. While many ES policies with more flexibility have shown greater efficiency in promoting GI. Thus, ES policies should be made more flexible and grant companies greater decision-making autonomy. Third, subsidy allocation directly impacts ES efficiency. Specifically, state-owned enterprises, companies lacking environmental protection foundations, and those obtaining subsidies through earnings management practices do not effectively utilize ES. Fourth, EE serves as a vital tool for addressing insufficient government investment in ES, as well as ES design and allocation challenges. The observed synergy between ES and EE measures strengthens the case for stricter environmental regulations in China. These suggestions offer valuable insights for other developing countries in their green transition phase. Subsidy-based policy tools require more rigorous design and must fully consider each country’s stage of green development. Most importantly, strict government enforcement remains crucial for ensuring the effectiveness of subsidy policies. In addition to providing recommendations for governments and policymakers, strategies targeted at internal managers within companies are equally important. Based on the results of our study, we offer the following specific advice to corporate managers: First, corporate managers should carefully evaluate the use of environmental subsidies and ensure that these funds are effectively allocated to promote green innovation projects rather than serving merely as short-term economic support. Second, companies should actively implement environmental protection measures to ensure that their production and business activities comply with current regulatory requirements. Third, managers should increase investment in environmental protection, viewing it as a crucial component of the company’s long-term development strategy, thereby enhancing the company’s green innovation capabilities. Fourth, managers need to review current financial management and reporting processes, aiming to improve transparency and accuracy. This will help in utilizing environmental subsidies more effectively to drive green innovation. Fifth, compared to non-state-owned enterprises, managers in state-owned enterprises should pay closer attention to how internal reforms and external collaborations can be used to enhance green innovation capabilities and overcome potential systemic barriers. This translation accurately conveys the original content, offering clear and actionable advice for corporate managers based on the study’s findings.
One limitation of our study is that we have not distinguished between innovation ES and non-innovation ES. The former refers to ES that is associated with innovation activities related to environmental protection, while the latter refers to ES that is related to non-innovation activities. By differentiating between these two types of ES, we could potentially identify different effects of ES on various externalities of GI. In particular, innovation ES may have a positive impact on both environmental protection externality and knowledge spillover externality, while non-innovation ES may primarily address environmental protection externality. Exploring this distinction will be an important topic for our future research. Meanwhile, ES and EE can influence each other. This study has investigated the moderating role of EE in the process ES affecting GI. Future research should further explore the results and mechanisms of how ES affects the effects of EE.

Author Contributions

Z.X. and D.H. conceived and designed the study. Y.W. and Y.Q. performed the empirical analysis. X.S., Y.Q. and C.S. analyzed the results. Z.X. and Y.W. wrote the manuscript. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by a grant from the National Nature Science Foundation of China (no. 72103142); Fundamental scientific research project of Liaoning Provincial Department of Education (no. JYTQN2024018); Fundamental scientific research project of Liaoning Provincial Department of Education (no. LJKMR20221068).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in this study are included in the article. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Miao, C.; Fang, D.; Sun, L.; Luo, Q. Natural resources utilization efficiency under the influence of green technological innovation. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2017, 126, 153–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Yuan, H.; Feng, Y.; Lee, C.C.; Cen, Y. How does manufacturing agglomeration affect green economic efficiency? Energy Econ. 2020, 92, 104944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Chen, J.; Li, Q.; Wang, X. Does the government’s environmental attention improve enterprise green innovation?—Evidence from China. Front. Environ. Sci. 2022, 10, 999492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Shi, J.; Yu, C.; Li, Y.; Wang, T. Does green financial policy affect debt-financing cost of heavy-polluting enterprises? an empirical evidence based on Chinese pilot zones for green finance reform and innovations. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2022, 179, 121678. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Wagner, M. Empirical influence of environmental management on innovation: Evidence from Europe. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 66, 392–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Schiederig, T.; Tietze, F.; Herstatt, C. Green innovation in technology and innovation management—An exploratory literature review. R&D Manag. 2012, 42, 180–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Cuerva, M.C.; Triguero-Cano, Á.; Córcoles, D. Drivers of green and non-green innovation: Empirical evidence in low-tech SMES. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 68, 104–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Saunila, M.; Ukko, J.; Rantala, T. Sustainability as a driver of green innovation investment and exploitation. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 179, 631–641. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Chen, Y.S. The driver of green innovation and green image—Green core competence. J. Bus. Ethics 2008, 81, 531–543. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Zhang, F.; Zhu, L. Enhancing corporate sustainable development: Stakeholder pressures, organizational learning, and green innovation. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2019, 28, 1012–1026. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Chen, Z.; Zhang, X.; Chen, F. Do carbon emission trading schemes stimulate green innovation in enterprises? Evidence from China. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2021, 168, 120744. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Caravella, S.; Crespi, F. Unfolding heterogeneity: The different policy drivers of different eco-innovation modes. Environ. Sci. Policy 2020, 114, 182–193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Rennings, K.; Ziegler, A.; Ankele, K.; Hoffmann, E. The influence of different characteristics of the EU environmental management and auditing scheme on technical environmental innovations and economic performance. Ecol. Econ. 2006, 57, 45–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Li, J.; Yu, L. Double externalities, market structure and performance: An empirical study of Chinese unrenewable resource industries. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 126, 299–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Fang, Z.; Bai, H.; Bilan, Y. Evaluation research of green innovation efficiency in China’s heavy polluting industries. Sustainability 2019, 12, 146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Horbach, J. Empirical determinants of eco-innovation in European countries using the community innovation survey. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transit. 2016, 19, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Li, H.; Liu, Q.; Li, S.; Fu, S. Environmental, Social and Governance Information Disclosure and Corporate Green Innovation Performance. Stat. Res. 2022, 39, 38–54. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  18. Li, Y.; Tong, Y.; Ye, F.; Song, J. The choice of the government green subsidy scheme: Innovation subsidy vs. product subsidy. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2020, 58, 4932–4946. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Huang, Z.; Liao, G.; Li, Z. Loaning scale and government subsidy for promoting green innovation. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2019, 144, 148–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Bai, Y.; Song, S.; Jiao, J.; Yang, R. The impacts of government R&D subsidies on green innovation: Evidence from Chinese energy-intensive firms. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 233, 819–829. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Johnstone, N.; Ivan, H.; Kalamova, M. Environmental policy characteristics and technological innovation. Econ. Politica 2010, 27, 277–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Wang, C.; Nie, P.; Peng, D.; Li, Z. Green insurance subsidy for promoting clean production innovation. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 148, 111–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Monasterolo, I.; Raberto, M. The eirin flow-of-funds behavioural model of green fiscal policies and green sovereign bonds. Ecol. Econ. 2018, 144, 228–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Liao, Z. Environmental policy instruments, environmental innovation and the reputation of enterprises. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 171 Pt 2, 1111–1117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Yi, Y.; Wei, Z.; Fu, C. An optimal combination of emissions tax and green innovation subsidies for polluting oligopolies. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 284, 124693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Joo, H.Y.; Seo, Y.W.; Min, H. Examining the effects of government intervention on the firm’s environmental and technological innovation capabilities and export performance. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2018, 56, 6090–6111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Shao, Y.; Chen, Z. Can government subsidies promote the green technology innovation transformation? Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Econ. Anal. Policy 2022, 74, 716–727. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Wei, L.; Liu, Z.; Cao, P.; Zhang, H. Environmental subsidies and green innovation: The role of environmental regulation and chief executive officer green background. Clean Technol. Environ. Policy 2024, 27, 389–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Acemoglu, D.; Akcigit, U.; Hanley, D.; Kerr, W. Transition to clean technology. J. Political Econ. 2016, 124, 52–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Testa, F.; Iraldo, F.; Frey, M. The effect of environmental regulation on firms’ competitive performance: The case of the building & construction sector in some EU regions. J. Environ. Manag. 2011, 92, 2136–2144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Li, Q.Y.; Xiao, Z.H. Heterogeneous Environmental Regulation Tools and Green Innovation incentives: Evidence from green patents of listed companies. Econ. Res. J. 2020, 55, 192–208. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  32. Gray, W.B.; Shimshack, J. The Effectiveness of Environmental Monitoring and Enforcement: A Review of the Empirical Evidence. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2011, 5, 3–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Böcher, M. A theoretical framework for explaining the choice of instruments in environmental policy. For. Policy Econ. 2012, 16, 14–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Berrone, P.; Fosfuri, A.; Gelabert, L.; Gomez-Mejia, L.R. Necessity as the mother of ‘green’ inventions: Institutional pressures and environmental innovations. Strateg. Manag. J. 2013, 34, 891–909. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Taschini, L.; Chesney, M.; Wang, M. Experimental comparison between markets on dynamic permit trading and investment in irreversible abatement with and without non-regulated companies. J. Regul. Econ. 2014, 46, 23–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Shimshack, J.P. The economics of environmental monitoring and enforcement. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2014, 6, 339–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Stretesky, P.B.; Long, M.A.; Lynch, M.J. Does environmental enforcement slow the treadmill of production? The relationship between large monetary penalties, ecological disorganization and toxic releases within offending corporations. J. Crime Justice 2012, 36, 233–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Liu, Y.; Wang, A.; Wu, Y. Environmental regulation and green innovation: Evidence from China’s new environmental protection law. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 297, 126698. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Leeuwen, G.V.; Mohnen, P. Revisiting the porter hypothesis: An empirical analysis of green innovation for the Netherlands. SSRN Electron. J. 2013, 67, 295–319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Jaffe, A.B.; Palmer, K. Environmental regulation and innovation: A panel data study. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1997, 79, 610–619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Ambec, S.; Cohen, M.A.; Elgie, S.; Lanoie, P. The porter hypothesis at 20: Can environmental regulation enhance innovation and competitiveness? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2013, 7, 2–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Mi, Z.; Zeng, G.; Xin, X.; Shang, Y.; Hai, J. The extension of the porter hypothesis: Can the role of environmental regulation on economic development be affected by other dimensional regulations? J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 203, 933–942. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Shaheen, R.; Luo, Q. Green innovation and political embeddedness in China’s heavily polluted industry: Role of environmental disclosure, gender diversity, and enterprise growth. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2023, 30, 97498–97517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Zhong, Z.; Li, K. “Crowding Out” or “Reservoir Effect”? Unraveling the Impact of Financialization on Green Innovation in Heavy Polluting Enterprises: Evidence from China’s Listed Companies. Sustainability 2024, 16, 7192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Guo, L.; Hu, C.; Fan, M.; Mao, J.; Tian, M.; Wang, Z.; Wei, Y. Does informal environmental regulation matter? Evidence on the different impacts of communities and ENGOs on heavy-polluting firms’ green technology innovation. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2023, 67, 2668–2694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Xie, X.; Zhu, Q.; Wang, R. Turning green subsidies into sustainability: How green process innovation improves firms’ green image. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2019, 28, 1416–1433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Liu, D.; Chen, T.; Liu, X.; Yu, Y. Do more subsidies promote greater innovation? Evidence from the Chinese electronic manufacturing industry. Econ. Model. 2019, 80, 441–452. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Osorio, A.; Zhang, M. Incentivizing environmental investments: The contest-based subsidy allocation mechanism. J. Clean. Prod. 2022, 380, 135132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Bai, Y.; Hua, C.; Jiao, J.; Yang, M.; Li, F. Green efficiency and environmental subsidy: Evidence from thermal power firms in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 188, 49–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Xia, L.; Gao, S.; Wei, J.; Ding, Q. Government subsidy and corporate green innovation—Does board governance play a role? Energy Policy 2021, 161, 112720. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Costantini, V.; Crespia, F.; Palmad, A. Characterizing the policy mix and its impact on eco-innovation: A patent analysis of energy-efficient technologies. Res. Policy 2017, 46, 799–819. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Costantini, V.; Mazzanti, M. On the green and innovative side of trade competitiveness? the impact of environmental policies and innovation on EU exports. Res. Policy 2012, 41, 132–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Groot, J.I.M.D.; Schuitema, G. How to make the unpopular popular? policy characteristics, social norms and the acceptability of environmental policies. Environ. Sci. Policy 2012, 19–20, 100–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Blanes, J.; Busom, I. Who participates in R&D subsidy programs?: The case of Spanish manufacturing firms. Res. Policy 2004, 33, 1459–1476. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Hud, M.; Hussinger, K. The impact of RD subsidies during the crisis. Res. Policy 2015, 44, 1844–1855. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Peng, H.; Liu, Y. How government subsidies promote the growth of entrepreneurial companies in clean energy industry: An empirical study in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 188, 508–520. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Xie, X.; Wang, R.; Huo, J. Green Process Innovation and Enterprise Performance under Government Financial Incentive: An Empirical Research Based on Content Analysis Method. Manag. Rev. 2020, 32, 109–124. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  58. Li, L.; Li, H. Technological innovation, energy conservation and emission reduction, and urban green development. Soft Sci. 2021, 35, 46–51. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  59. Betcherman, G.; Daysal, N.M.; Carmen, P. Do employment subsidies work? evidence from regionally targeted subsidies in turkey. Labour Econ. 2010, 17, 710–722. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Khanna, M.; Deltas, G.; Harrington, D.R. Adoption of pollution prevention techniques: The role of management systems and regulatory pressures. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2009, 44, 85–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Wu, H.; Guo, H.; Zhang, B.; Bu, M. Westward movement of new polluting firms in China: Pollution reduction mandates and location choice. J. Comp. Econ. 2017, 45, 119–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Lee, E.; Walker, M.; Zeng, C. Do Chinese government subsidies affect firm value? Account. Organ. Soc. 2014, 39, 149–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Newell, R.G.; Pizer, W.A.; Raimi, D.U.S. federal government subsidies for clean energy: Design choices and implications. Energy Econ. 2019, 80, 831–841. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Takalo, T.; Tanayama, T.; Toivanen, O. Estimating the benefits of targeted R&D subsidies. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2013, 95, 255–272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Gao, S.; Li, W.; Meng, J.; Shi, J.; Zhu, J. A Study on the Impact Mechanism of Digitalization on Corporate Green Innovation. Sustainability 2023, 15, 6407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Wu, A. The signal effect of Government R&D Subsidies in China: Does ownership matter? Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 2017, 117, 339–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Xue, Q.; Yi, S. Analysis of influencing factors of enterprise environmental protection investment—From external system to internal resources and incentives. Soft Sci. 2015, 3, 1–4+51. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  68. Wu, H.; Hu, S. The impact of synergy effect between government subsidies and slack resources on green technology innovation. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 274, 122682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Owjimehr, S.; Dastfroosh, H.H. Uncertainty governance in the stock market during the COVID-19: Evidence of the strictest economies in the world. China Financ. Rev. Int. 2023, 13, 362–387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Zhang, J.; Su, T.; Meng, L. Corporate earnings management strategy under environmental regulation: Evidence from China. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2023, 90, 154–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Song, Y.; Cai, L.; Zhang, M. Earnings pressure and corporate carbon emissions: Empirical evidence from listed firms in China. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2024, 206, 107657. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Polinsky, A.M.; Shavell, S. The Economic Theory of Public Enforcement of Law. J. Econ. Lit. 2000, 38, 45–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Qiu, L.; Hu, D.; Wang, Y. How do firms achieve sustainability through green innovation under external pressures of environmental regulation and market turbulence? Bus. Strategy Environ. 2020, 29, 2695–2714. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Chen, X.; Xiao, H.; Zhang, G. Does environmental punishment promote enterprise environmental governance?—Analysis based on the two dimensions of the process and the outcome. Econ. Manag. 2021, 6, 136–155. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Prechel, H.; Zheng, L. Corporate Characteristics, Political Embeddedness and Environmental Pollution by Large U.S. Corporations. Soc. Forces 2012, 90, 947–970. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Sam, A.G.; Zhang, X. Value relevance of the new environmental enforcement regime in China. J. Corp. Financ. 2020, 62, 101573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Chu, J.; Fang, J.X. Punish One, Teach a Hundred? A Study on the Failure of the Indirect Deterrence Effects of Regulatory Punishments. Account. Res. 2021, 1, 44–54. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Kneller, R.; Manderson, E. Environmental regulations and innovation activity in UK manufacturing industries. Resour. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 211–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Tao, S.; Hai, M.; Fang, Z.; Zheng, D. The role of environmental justice reform in corporate green transformation: Evidence from the establishment of China’s environmental courts. Front. Environ. Sci. 2023, 11, 1090853. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Lan, M.; Zhang, G.; Yan, W.; Qi, F.; Qin, L. Greening Through Courts: Environmental Law Enforcement and Corporate Green Innovation. Econ. Anal. Policy 2024, 83, 223–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Zhang, H.; Shen, Q. Mixed ownership reform of state-owned enterprises promotes green innovation of enterprises—Based on the empirical evidence of the shareholding structure of listed state-owned enterprises. Financ. Rev. 2024, 16, 131–154+158. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  82. Huang, C.Y. How to Enhance the Green Innovation of Sports Goods? Micro- and Macro-Level Evidence From China’s Manufacturing Enterprises. Front. Environ. Sci. 2022, 9, 809156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Cheng, C.C.; Shiu, E.C. Validation of a proposed instrument for measuring eco-innovation: An implementation perspective. Technovation 2012, 32, 329–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Hussain, M.; Yang, S.; Maqsood, U.S.; Zahid, R.M.A. Tapping into the green potential: The power of artificial intelligence adoption in corporate green innovation drive. Bus. Strategy Environ. 2024, 33, 4375–4396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Li, X.; Wu, M.; Shi, C.V.; Chen, Y. Impacts of green credit policies and information asymmetry: From market perspective. Resour. Policy 2023, 81, 103395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Wu, J.; Liu, B.; Zeng, Y.; Luo, H. Good for the firm, good for the society? Causal evidence of the impact of equity incentives on a firm’s green investment. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2021, 77, 435–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Boeing, P. The allocation and effectiveness of China’s R&D subsidies—Evidence from listed firms. Res. Policy 2016, 45, 1774–1789. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Huang, S.; Fan, Z.P.; Wang, X. Optimal financing and operational decisions of capital-constrained manufacturer under green credit and subsidy. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2021, 17, 261–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Shimshack, J.P.; Ward, M.B. Enforcement and over-compliance. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2007, 55, 90–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Ye, D.; Ng, Y.K.; Lian, Y. Culture and happiness. Soc. Indic. Res. 2015, 123, 519–547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Zhang, J.; Chen, Z.; Yang, L.; Xin, F. Performance evaluation of innovation subsidy policy in China: Theory and evidence. Econ. Res. 2015, 50, 4–17+33. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  92. Sun, Y.; Shi, S.; Peng, F.; Wu, H. R & D subsidies and progressive innovation lock: Patent text analysis based on machine learning. Econ. Res. 2024, 59, 89–105. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  93. Heutel, G. Crowding out and crowding in of private donations and government grants. Public Financ. Rev. 2014, 42, 143–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Zhu, Y.; Mao, C. Environmental decentralization, environmental protection investment and enterprise green innovation: A multiple parallel intermediary model with regulation. Sci. Technol. Prog. Countermeas 2023, 40, 78–88. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  95. Roychowdhury, S. Earnings management through real activities manipulation. J. Account. Econ. 2006, 42, 335–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Cohen, D.; Zarowin, P. Accrual-Based and Real Earnings Management Activities Around Seasoned Equity Offerings. J. Account. Econ. 2010, 50, 2–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Liu, J.; Zhao, M.; Wang, Y. Impacts of government subsidies and environmental regulations on green process innovation: A nonlinear approach. Technol. Soc. 2020, 63, 101417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Kathuria, V. Controlling water pollution in developing and transition countries--lessons from three successful cases. J. Environ. Manag. 2006, 78, 405–426. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. Gao, L.; Yang, X. Green R&D subsidies and green technology innovalion: An examination of helerogeneous ellects from a cateredperspective. J. Technol. Econ. 2024, 43, 23–35. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Annual mean value of ES and EE.
Figure 1. Annual mean value of ES and EE.
Sustainability 17 01280 g001
Table 1. ES types.
Table 1. ES types.
ES TypeContent
Pollution monitoring subsidySubsidy for pollution prevention equipment and technology.
Energy conservation subsidySubsidy for activities including conservation in energy use and the recycling and comprehensive utilization of pollutants and secondary energy sources (waste heat, waste gas, etc.).
Emission reduction subsidySubsidy for activities including the use of clean energy, desulfurization, denitration, emission reduction in volatile organic compounds, elimination of vehicles with high-pollution emissions.
Pollution abatement subsidySubsidy for the treatment of environmental pollution caused by pollutants (waste solid, water, and gas).
Subsidy with no specific targetsSubsidy that does not specify the purpose of the project (e.g., funds for environmental protection projects and subsidies for green economic development).
Environmental protection awardsFinancial awards granted to enterprises or individuals for their outstanding contributions to environmental protection.
Table 2. ES and ES characteristics.
Table 2. ES and ES characteristics.
ES TypesES Characteristics
ClassificationSubsidy TimingSubsidy FormSubsidy Content
ESBESATESGESPESEES
Pollution monitoring subsidy
Energy conservation subsidy
Emission reduction subsidy
Pollution abatement subsidy
Subsidy with no specific targets
Environmental protection awards
Note: This table shows the results after reclassifying the different forms of ES by time, form, and content. “√” explains the type of each subsidy in the first column according to time, form and content. The backgraound color means that the corresponding ES are not considered in the classification process.
Table 3. Variables and measurements.
Table 3. Variables and measurements.
TypeVariableSymbolsMeasurement
Explanatory VariableEnvironmental SubsidiesESNatural logarithm of (1 + environmental-related subsidies)
ES characteristicESBNatural logarithm of (1 + ES beforehand in Table 1)
ESANatural logarithm of (1 + ES afterwards in Table 1)
TESNatural logarithm of (1 + targeted ES in Table 1)
GESNatural logarithm of (1 + general ES in Table 1)
PESNatural logarithm of (1 + pollution prevention ES in Table 1)
EESNatural logarithm of (1 + end-of-pipe ES in Table 1)
Explained VariableGreen innovationGINatural logarithm of 1 plus the application number of green patent
Moderating VariableEnvironmental enforcementEE1 for the year that the firm is enforced and all subsequent years, otherwise, 0 (dummy)
Control VariableFinancial leverageLevLiabilities/total assets
R&D intensityRDNatural logarithm of 1 plus the R&D expenditures per employee
Company sizeSizeNatural logarithms of total assets
Cash flow ratioCashOperating activity cash and investing activity cash/total assets
Return on assetsRoaNet profit income after tax/total assets
Company ageAgeLogarithm of the enterprise establishment period using the natural base
Natural of equitySoe1 for the state-owned firm, otherwise, 0
YearYearAnnual control dummy variable
ProvinceProvProvince control dummy variable
IndustryIndIndustry control dummy variable
Table 4. Statistics of Listed Companies in Heavy-polluting Industries (2012–2021).
Table 4. Statistics of Listed Companies in Heavy-polluting Industries (2012–2021).
Thermal PowerIron and SteelCoalMetallurgyBuilding MaterialsMiningChemicalsPetrochemicalsPharmaceuticalsPapermakingTextilesLeather-Making
20125728214265271961612620586
20135829244664302051612824626
20145928245174302191713823566
20156129255577322361515323588
20166229235678302591516628598
201767262266813028817195285911
201863282369783029016201296111
201963292263793129415209275410
202066292269923332716233326011
202174302276973236217257357011
Table 5. Variable Descriptive Statistics (N = 8422).
Table 5. Variable Descriptive Statistics (N = 8422).
VariablesMeanStd. Dev.10% Quantile50% Quantile90% Quantile
GI3.6625.230.000.006.00
ES7.726.940.0011.0015.61
ESB7.356.930.0010.4915.42
ESA1.594.310.000.0010.82
GES2.615.270.000.0012.78
TES6.636.860.000.0015.08
PES5.956.750.000.0014.81
EES2.545.160.000.0012.76
EE0.270.440.000.001.00
Size12.740.3212.2812.7413.23
Age2.970.292.643.003.30
Lev45.254.3340.4344.4455.82
Roa0.010.01−0.010.010.03
Cash−0.020.02−0.06−0.020.00
Soe0.360.480.000.001.00
RD1.260.820.051.302.31
Table 6. Correlations.
Table 6. Correlations.
GIESESBESAGESTESPESEESEE
GI1
ES0.2152 *1
ESB0.2219 *0.9597 *1
ESA0.0750 *0.3697 *0.2287 *1
GES0.1857 *0.4923 *0.5111 *0.1731 *1
TES0.1866 *0.8798 *0.9159 *0.2421 *0.2984 *1
PES0.1906 *0.8136 *0.8462 *0.2535 *0.2872 *0.9241 *1
EES0.1232 *0.4812 *0.5003 *0.1708 *0.2567 *0.5436 *0.3522 *1
EE0.1501 *0.1312 *0.1351 *0.0327 *0.0966 *0.1274 *0.1182 *0.1129 *1
Note: The symbol * denotes significance at the 10% levels.
Table 7. The impact of ES on GI.
Table 7. The impact of ES on GI.
Explained Variable: GI
ES −0.0625 **−0.0583 **
(−2.1802)(−2.1733)
Size0.4285 ***0.35500.3608
(8.1299)(1.0723)(1.1344)
Age0.0809 **0.08970.1849 **
(1.9895)(1.1398)(2.1779)
Roa0.82880.16440.1604
(0.7969)(0.1161)(0.1180)
Soe0.3050 ***0.5264 ***0.4393 ***
(12.8685)(7.0887)(6.4085)
Lev0.00530.00530.0055
(1.1007)(0.8548)(0.9299)
Cash0.26450.58310.5613
(0.2158)(0.2171)(0.2175)
RD0.1797 ***0.1826 ***0.1669 ***
(12.1609)(7.2986)(7.4962)
_cons−5.3141 ***−3.6311−4.3303
(−6.5913)(−0.8205)(−1.0224)
Year dummyYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYes
Province dummyYesNoYes
Cragg-Donalf Wald F 124.543117.33
N829869986998
Note: The symbols *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 8. The impacts of ES characteristics on GI.
Table 8. The impacts of ES characteristics on GI.
Explained Variable: GI
ES TimingES FormES Content
ESB−0.0527 ***
(−3.7016)
ESA0.0161
(0.6467)
TES −0.0681 ***
(−4.0695)
GES 0.0679 ***
(3.3689)
PES −0.0489 ***
(−2.9927)
EES 0.0402 **
(2.4649)
Note: The symbols *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 9. Heterogeneity of the effects of ES on GI.
Table 9. Heterogeneity of the effects of ES on GI.
Explained Variable: GI
SOENon-SOEEPINon-EPIREMNon-REM
ES−0.1243 ***0.0536 ***0.0191−0.1395 ***−0.1025 ***−0.0056
(−3.8713)(3.2428)(0.8483)(−3.0539)(−2.9132)(−0.2144)
ControlsYes
Year dummyYes
Industry dummyYes
Province dummyYes
N256344353050394835473451
Note: The symbol *** denotes significance at the 1% levels.
Table 10. The moderating effects of EE.
Table 10. The moderating effects of EE.
Explained Variable: GI
Overall EffectES TimingES FormES Content
ES#EE0.1213 ***
(5.9909)
ESB#EE 0.1148 ***
(5.5154)
ESA#EE −0.0076
(−0.2265)
TES#EE 0.1039 ***
(4.7071)
GES#EE −0.0178
(−0.6419)
PES#EE 0.0866 ***
(4.1659)
EES#EE −0.0168
(−0.7397)
Note: The symbol *** denotes significance at the 1% levels. Symbol “#” means variable interaction.
Table 11. Heterogeneity of the moderating effects of EE.
Table 11. Heterogeneity of the moderating effects of EE.
Explained Variable: GI
SOENon-SOEEPINon-EPIREMNon-REM
ES−0.1664 ***0.0631 ***0.0074−0.1813 ***−0.1628 ***−0.0159
(−4.1874)(2.6186)(0.2536)(−3.1156)(−3.3794)(−0.5010)
ES#EE0.1000 ***−0.01870.02020.1248 ***0.1070 ***0.0306 *
(5.4240)(−1.3045)(1.5411)(3.5397)(4.3600)(1.7112)
ControlsYes
Year dummyYes
Industry dummyYes
Province dummyYes
N256344353050394835473451
Note: The symbols *** and * denote significance at the 1% and 10% levels, respectively. Symbol “#” means variable interaction.
Table 12. Heckman two-step method Robustness tests.
Table 12. Heckman two-step method Robustness tests.
Explained Variable: GI
ES−0.0583 ***
(−4.1378)
ESA 0.0161
(0.6467)
ESB −0.0527 ***
(−3.7016)
TES −0.0681 ***
(−4.0695)
GES 0.0679 ***
(3.3689)
PES −0.0489 ***
(−2.9927)
EES 0.0402 **
(2.4649)
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYesYes
Province dummyYesYesYesYes
ControlsYesYesYesYes
N6998.00006998.00006998.00006998.0000
Note: The symbols *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 13. Kernel matching robustness tests.
Table 13. Kernel matching robustness tests.
Explained Variable: GI
ES−0.1179 ***
(−4.7875)
ES#EE0.1389 ***
(6.0431)
ESB −0.1118 ***
(−4.3948)
ESA 0.0149
(0.4028)
ESB#EE 0.1337 ***
(5.5291)
ESA#EE −0.0130
(−0.3482)
TES −0.1170 ***
(−4.4633)
GES 0.0551 *
(1.7796)
TES#EE 0.1245 ***
(4.9261)
GES#EE −0.0252
(−0.8318)
PES −0.0901 ***
(−3.6939)
EES 0.0308
(1.1968)
PES#EE 0.1052 ***
(4.4823)
EES#EE −0.0216
(−0.8543)
EE−0.8814 ***−0.7787 ***−0.5929 ***−0.4010 ***
(−5.0898)(−4.6928)(−3.7758)(−2.8539)
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYesYes
Province dummyYesYesYesYes
ControlsYesYesYesYes
N6928.00006928.00006928.00006928.0000
Note: The symbols *** and * denote significance at the 1% and 10% levels, respectively. Symbol “#” means variable interaction.
Table 14. Alternative explained variable for effects of ES and ES characteristics on GI.
Table 14. Alternative explained variable for effects of ES and ES characteristics on GI.
Explained Variable: GI (Green Patent Applications)
ES−0.0344 ***
(−2.6175)
ESA 0.0115
(0.4898)
ESB −0.0285 **
(−2.1439)
TES −0.0572 ***
(−3.4689)
GES 0.0842 ***
(4.2167)
PES −0.0493 ***
(−2.9749)
EES 0.0655 ***
(3.9351)
ControlsYesYesYesYes
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYesYes
Province dummyYesYesYesYes
N7056.00007056.00007056.00007056.0000
Note: The symbols *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 15. Alternative explained variable for the moderating effects of EE.
Table 15. Alternative explained variable for the moderating effects of EE.
Explained Variable: Green Patent Applications
ES−0.0652 ***
(−3.3789)
ES#EE0.0935 ***
(5.1795)
ESB −0.0573 ***
(−2.9283)
ESA 0.0061
(0.2008)
ESB#EE 0.0850 ***
(4.5691)
ESA#EE −0.0005
(−0.0166)
TES −0.0816 ***
(−3.6947)
GES 0.0769 ***
(2.7832)
TES#EE 0.0949 ***
(4.4501)
GES#EE −0.0445 *
(−1.6490)
PES −0.0701 ***
(−3.2526)
EES 0.0618 ***
(2.6714)
PES#EE 0.0888 ***
(4.2846)
EES#EE −0.0478 **
(−2.0956)
EE−0.5408 ***−0.4487 ***−0.3510 ***−0.2376 *
(−3.9682)(−3.4493)(−2.6512)(−1.8764)
ControlsYesYesYesYes
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYesYes
Province dummyYesYesYesYes
N7056.00007056.00007056.00007056.0000
Note: The symbols ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. Symbol “#” means variable interaction.
Table 16. Sample period adjustment for effects of ES and ES characteristics on GI.
Table 16. Sample period adjustment for effects of ES and ES characteristics on GI.
Explained Variable: GI
ES−0.0797 ***
(−4.8637)
ESA 0.0286
(1.0032)
ESB −0.0778 ***
(−4.6185)
TES −0.0985 ***
(−4.8926)
GES 0.0905 ***
(3.7371)
PES −0.0850 ***
(−4.1062)
EES 0.0544 ***
(2.8362)
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYesYes
Province dummyYesYesYesYes
ControlsYesYesYesYes
N6036.00006036.00006036.00006036.0000
Note: The symbol *** denotes significance at the 1% levels.
Table 17. Sample period adjustment for moderating effects of EE.
Table 17. Sample period adjustment for moderating effects of EE.
Explained Variable: GI
ES−0.1237 ***
(−4.9706)
ES#EE0.1431 ***
(6.1255)
ESB −0.1183 ***
(−4.7923)
ESA 0.0149
(0.3729)
ESB#EE 0.1385 ***
(5.8950)
ESA#EE −0.0130
(−0.3250)
TES −0.1296 ***
(−4.8569)
GES 0.0725 **
(2.2012)
TES#EE 0.1340 ***
(5.1743)
GES#EE −0.0421
(−1.3108)
PES −0.1108 ***
(−4.2029)
EES 0.0369
(1.3571)
PES#EE 0.1237 ***
(4.8477)
EES#EE −0.0301
(−1.1215)
EE−0.9198 ***−0.8142 ***−0.5942 ***−0.4648 ***
(−5.1169)(−4.7938)(−3.6338)(−3.1039)
Year dummyYesYesYesYes
Industry dummyYesYesYesYes
Province dummyYesYesYesYes
ControlsYesYesYesYes
N6036.00006036.00006036.00006036.0000
Note: The symbols *** and ** denote significance at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively. Symbol “#” means variable interaction.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Xu, Z.; Wang, Y.; Shi, X.; Qiu, Y.; Su, C.; He, D. The Impact of Environmental Subsidies and Enforcement on Green Innovation: Evidence from Heavy-Polluting Enterprises in China. Sustainability 2025, 17, 1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17031280

AMA Style

Xu Z, Wang Y, Shi X, Qiu Y, Su C, He D. The Impact of Environmental Subsidies and Enforcement on Green Innovation: Evidence from Heavy-Polluting Enterprises in China. Sustainability. 2025; 17(3):1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17031280

Chicago/Turabian Style

Xu, Zhe, Ying Wang, Xiaoliang Shi, Yingying Qiu, Chunzi Su, and Dan He. 2025. "The Impact of Environmental Subsidies and Enforcement on Green Innovation: Evidence from Heavy-Polluting Enterprises in China" Sustainability 17, no. 3: 1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17031280

APA Style

Xu, Z., Wang, Y., Shi, X., Qiu, Y., Su, C., & He, D. (2025). The Impact of Environmental Subsidies and Enforcement on Green Innovation: Evidence from Heavy-Polluting Enterprises in China. Sustainability, 17(3), 1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17031280

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop