Next Article in Journal
How Fintech Impacts Enterprises’ Digital–Green Synergy
Previous Article in Journal
Use of Sands from Wastewater Treatment Plants as a Substitute for Natural Aggregate in the Context of a Circular Economy
Previous Article in Special Issue
Innovative Pathways for Collaborative Governance in Technology-Driven Smart Communities
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Evolutionary Game Analysis of Customs Supervision Mechanisms for Sustainable Green Port Development

by
Wenbing Shui
and
Wenhui Song
*
School of Transportation Engineering, Kunming University of Science and Technology, Kunming 650550, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2025, 17(12), 5470; https://doi.org/10.3390/su17125470
Submission received: 17 April 2025 / Revised: 4 June 2025 / Accepted: 12 June 2025 / Published: 13 June 2025
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Impact of Management Innovation on Sustainable Development)

Abstract

Against the backdrop of rapidly expanding international trade and escalating environmental challenges, the development of green ports has emerged as a pivotal element of sustainable development. This study addresses the critical issues of insufficient corporate motivation for transformation and inadequate regulatory mechanisms by establishing a tripartite evolutionary game model involving government, customs, and port enterprises. Key findings demonstrate that customs supervision significantly reduces enterprises’ transition costs and enhances environmental compliance willingness, though its effectiveness depends on complementary government policies including environmental taxation and fiscal incentives. When regulatory intensity is weak, enterprises persist with conventional practices; conversely, strengthened supervision accelerates strategic convergence toward sustainable governance. This research provides a theoretical foundation for policymakers to formulate green port initiatives while offering practical guidance for enterprises to align with sustainability objectives, thereby contributing to environmentally responsible port development.

1. Introduction

Amidst the tide of globalization, international trade is flourishing, and ports, as the frontier of national openness, are closely linked to economic growth and the international image of a country [1]. With environmental issues becoming increasingly prominent, the concept of green development has gained widespread acceptance, becoming a global consensus [2]. Against this backdrop, the “National Five-Year Plan for Port Development (2021–2025)” has envisioned an ambitious blueprint for the construction of green ports, emphasizing the urgency and significance of promoting greening and low-carbon transformation of ports in the new era. The Ministry of Transport, in conjunction with the General Administration of Customs and several other departments, has issued the “Guidelines on Building World-Class Ports”. These guidelines clearly state that by 2025, significant breakthroughs in the green development of major ports should be achieved, and by 2035, these ports are expected to lead the global development of green ports. The tasks involved include improving the collection and distribution system, preventing and controlling ship pollution, and constructing a low-carbon energy use system. Local customs authorities are actively implementing these measures. For instance, Tianjin Customs has promoted the optimization of operational processes at Tianjin Port, embedding customs instructions into the port system to achieve synchronized operations, reducing energy consumption, and supporting innovation in pilot free trade zones to enhance logistics efficiency. Ningbo Customs, on the other hand, focuses on ensuring the security of green energy, opening a “green channel” for LNG refueling, optimizing regulatory processes, and promoting convenient measures such as “one-time inspection” to assist the green transformation of the port. The construction of green ports is not only a strong reflection of China’s commitment to addressing global environmental issues but also an internal imperative for optimizing the domestic economic structure and advancing towards high-quality development [3].
Port logistics, serving as a crucial link in international trade, occupies a central position in the process of green port construction [4]. Numerous scholars, such as Lam and Yap, have identified market participants and public policy makers as significant categories in their analysis of stakeholders in green port construction [5]. Among them, port logistics enterprises, as typical market participants, engage in operations that span the entire process of physical goods flow, including collection and distribution, customs clearance, loading and unloading, handling, storage, distribution processing, transportation, and delivery [6]. These stages are closely related to the utilization of port resources, energy consumption, and emission of pollutants. However, research by Liu, Zhao, and Li has found that enterprises face the dilemma of high costs and long return periods when adopting green technologies to update basic facilities like storage facilities and transportation tools, as well as implementing green operational processes [7]. Li and Wang, focusing on enterprise logistics and green transformation, have studied the obstacles and strategies in the transition from traditional logistics to green logistics, revealing conflicts of interest among the main actors involved in green logistics, mutual strategic games, and additional challenges such as insufficient internal motivation within enterprises, inadequate external pressure, and a lack of logistics capabilities and supporting equipment, making the process of greening enterprise logistics particularly arduous [8]. This short-term imbalance between economic benefits and environmental benefits significantly reduces the enthusiasm of port logistics enterprises to participate in the construction of green ports actively.
Therefore, relying solely on the spontaneous regulatory mechanisms of the market, it is challenging to effectively encourage port logistics enterprises to participate in the grand tide of green port construction; strong guidance and regulation from government sectors are imperative. Tseng and Pilcher proposed the regulatory approach of imposing emission taxes to reduce the emission of pollutants from ports and ships [9]. Wu, Junni, and others analyzed the decision-making regarding the use of shore power for ports and ships under the policy backdrop of government-imposed carbon taxes, demonstrating the incentive effect of carbon taxes in promoting the adoption of shore power facilities by ports [10]. Dai and colleagues suggested that the government should shift subsidies from the initial stage of shore power construction to the operational phase, attracting port enterprises and ships to retrofit shore power facilities by offering subsidies on electricity prices [11]. Lu and Wang Huibo used evolutionary game theory to explore the ways for the government to guide port enterprises to participate in the construction of green ports [12]. The aforementioned studies have proven that the government can lower the cost of green transformation for enterprises and enhance their enthusiasm through financial incentives such as subsidies and tax preferences. However, the implementation of government policies faces numerous challenges in practice, such as insufficient subsidy strength due to limited local finances and regulatory loopholes in the policy execution process, which affect the effectiveness of policy implementation.
Customs, as a significant force in port management, has been somewhat overlooked in previous research regarding its unique impact on the green transformation process of port logistics enterprises. Acting as a vertically managed department established by the central government to supervise and manage the import and export activities at the local level, customs play an indispensable role in port construction [13]. Liang Xingying has proposed that to meet the strategic demands of port cities and port economies, as well as regional economic development under the globalized context, customs must accurately position themselves in terms of regulatory philosophy, regulatory space, methods, and tools, thereby promoting rapid port economic growth [14]. Xu Dao has studied the situation and challenges faced by customs in terms of clearance supervision, suggesting the active exploration of new regulatory approaches and methods that integrate with modern logistics and align with international standards, aiming to establish a new model for convenient and efficient port clearance [15]. However, traditional research has primarily focused on the essential functions of customs, such as the supervision of import and export goods and the collection of tariffs, neglecting its potential influence in the construction of green ports. In recent years, a small number of studies have begun to focus on this area. Tao Weilian and Cai Ying have suggested that customs, as a national agency for exit supervision and management, should leverage its functional advantages, promptly incorporate the “dual carbon” goals into policy objectives, actively participate in the construction of a green trade system, vigorously promote the green development of the foreign trade industry chain, and advance the optimization and sustainable development of China’s foreign trade structure [16]. Han Chengguo and Zhao Jiuxian, among others, have pointed out that customs, with its direct jurisdiction over bonded warehouses and frequent inspection activities, has a deep reach into every corner of these facilities, enabling it to grasp the operational details of port logistics enterprises in real-time [17]. Consequently, customs have an informational advantage over environmental protection departments. They can promptly identify logistics operations that do not meet green standards, such as excessive use of packaging materials and energy waste in storage environments. Additionally, customs possess unique management strengths. Its vertical management model ensures the independence, authority, and unity of its regulatory powers [13], allowing it to execute green regulatory policies strictly and avoid improper interference from local governments when faced with complex local interests. For instance, customs can integrate green logistics requirements into the declaration standards for bonded warehouses, and issue targeted green transformation directives for existing bonded warehouses, effectively promoting the green transformation of port logistics. Tianjin Customs has carried out reforms for the logistics customs clearance of import and export goods at maritime ports, embedding customs operation instructions into the port operation system to achieve synchronized and concurrent operations between customs and the port. This has facilitated the simultaneous unloading, sorting, and removal of imported goods, and the intelligent dispatching of exported goods through the port’s “dual-gate channel”, significantly enhancing inspection efficiency, reducing the frequency of cargo handling and transportation, and minimizing unnecessary losses, thereby promoting the construction of green ports from a practical operational perspective. Therefore, introducing customs as a player in the game theory analysis of green port construction, which involves multiple parties, is of vital importance for perfecting the theoretical framework and guiding practical operations. However, there is currently no mature theoretical system regarding how customs can systematically participate in the construction of green ports, especially concerning its role in the tripartite interaction among local governments, customs, and port logistics enterprises.
Therefore, this study focuses on the local government, customs, and port logistics enterprises as three key players, delving deeply into their decision-making behaviors and evolutionary strategies in the context of green port construction. By dissecting the complex interplay of interests and collaborative relationships among these three parties, the aim is to fill the existing research gaps and provide innovative theoretical support and practical guidance for promoting green port construction. Through the construction of a tripartite evolutionary game model, this study will offer theoretical guidance and practical recommendations for green port construction, facilitate the green transformation of port logistics enterprises, achieve sustainable development of ports, and support China’s steady progress on the dual track of international trade and environmental protection.
The remaining parts of the paper are structured as follows: Section 2 presents the literature review. Section 3 proposes assumptions and calculates the payoff matrix. Section 4 calculates the equilibrium strategies of the local government, customs, and port logistics enterprises and conducts a stability analysis of the game system. Section 5 uses simulation to verify the theoretical analysis conducted earlier. Section 6 discusses the main conclusions and indicates future research directions.

2. Literature Review

With the increasing awareness of environmental protection, the construction of green ports has become a significant research topic in the field of maritime transportation. Green ports aim to minimize the negative environmental impacts of port operations while maximizing economic benefits. Studies have shown that green port initiatives can effectively reduce carbon emissions, pollution, and energy consumption, thereby promoting sustainable development. For example, Ye et al. developed a three-tier supply chain model to investigate the adoption of shore power by shipping companies, highlighting the importance of government subsidies in promoting green practices [18]. Similarly, Song et al. analyzed the impact of government subsidies on shipping companies’ shore power usage strategies, demonstrating that subsidies can significantly improve the utilization rate of shore power and mitigate the prisoner’s dilemma situation [19].
Building on the foundation of green port construction, research on green port logistics has gained momentum. Green port logistics focuses on optimizing the entire logistics chain within the port area to reduce environmental footprints. This includes the use of renewable energy, efficient transportation systems, and innovative logistics management practices. For instance, Zhang et al. proposed a mixed integer linear programming model to optimize the deployment of shore hydrogen in green ports, aiming to maximize port profits while promoting hydrogen energy consumption [20]. Additionally, Wang et al. investigated integrated energy management and operations planning in oil–electric hybrid container terminals, developing a heuristic algorithm to balance operational efficiency and energy management [21].
Customs play a crucial role in the development of green logistics. As the regulatory body overseeing international trade and transportation, customs have the authority to implement policies and regulations that promote sustainable practices. Over time, the functions of customs have evolved from traditional regulatory roles to more proactive roles in environmental protection and sustainability. For example, the implementation of “green channels” for environmentally friendly goods and the promotion of digital customs clearance systems have significantly improved the efficiency of green logistics operations [22]. Moreover, customs have been actively involved in the development of green port policies, working closely with port authorities and logistics companies to ensure compliance with environmental standards [23].
In recent years, the functions of customs in green logistics have undergone significant changes. Initially, customs primarily focused on regulatory compliance and trade facilitation. However, with growing environmental concerns, customs have expanded their scope of functions to include the promotion of green logistics practices and the enforcement of environmental regulations. This evolution has been driven by the recognition that sustainable practices not only benefit the environment but also enhance the overall efficiency of logistics operations [24]. For example, customs have implemented risk management systems to identify and prioritize high-risk shipments, thereby reducing the need for extensive inspections and improving the speed of green logistics operations. Additionally, customs have been at the forefront of adopting new technologies, such as blockchain and artificial intelligence, to enhance transparency and traceability in supply chains [25].
Given the complex interactions among various stakeholders in green logistics, game theory has emerged as a valuable research method. Game theory provides a framework for analyzing strategic interactions and decision-making processes among multiple players, such as governments, port operators, shipping companies, and customs authorities. For example, Deng et al. constructed a tripartite evolutionary game model to study the impact of environmental regulation on green port construction, emphasizing the importance of cooperation among different stakeholders [26]. Similarly, Xu et al. used an evolutionary game model to analyze the behavior strategies of multiple stakeholders in maritime shore power systems, demonstrating that government incentives play a crucial role in promoting the adoption of green technologies [27]. These studies show that game theory can provide valuable insights into the dynamics of green logistics and help identify effective strategies for promoting sustainable practices.
In conclusion, the construction of green ports and the development of green logistics have become essential for addressing environmental challenges in the port and logistics industry. The role of customs has significantly evolved in this process, with customs now actively promoting and enforcing green logistics practices. Game theory has proven to be a useful tool for analyzing the strategic interactions among stakeholders and identifying effective policy measures. Therefore, this paper introduces customs as a third-party regulator, working together with governments and port logistics enterprises to advance the development of green port logistics. It explores how the interactions among these three parties can further promote the sustainable development of ports and logistics transportation.

3. Model Assumptions and Construction

This study initially constructs a tripartite evolutionary game model involving local governments, customs, and port logistics enterprises to jointly promote the construction of green ports, exploring the necessity of customs intervention in this process, as illustrated in Figure 1.

3.1. Model Assumptions

Assumption 1:
The government has two strategic behaviors {active regulation, passive regulation}, customs have two strategic behaviors {participatory supervision, non-participatory supervision}, and port logistics enterprises have two strategic behaviors {traditional production, green transformation}. The government, customs, and port logistics enterprises are all decision-makers with incomplete information; they are unable to fully determine each other’s strategic choices and cannot accurately know each other’s potential benefits, thus preventing them from making fully rational decisions. Instead, they make optimal decisions through repeated game trials and adjustments to achieve equilibrium.
Assumption 2:
The government, customs, and port logistics enterprises are all decision-makers with “bounded rationality”, meaning that their decision-making is constrained by internal and external environments, preventing them from achieving “full rationality”. On one hand, their cognitive abilities are limited, and their optimal decisions are not made in one go but are sought through continuous learning and improvement in the game process. On the other hand, the decision-making environment is complex and dynamic, making it difficult for the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises to collect and predict all alternative plans, and challenging to make optimal decisions in different decision-making contexts.
Assumption 3:
When the government actively regulates, it promotes the green transformation of port logistics enterprises, and the green transformation will bring certain social benefits to the government, Na; the cost of active regulation for the government is denoted as Ga (a represents the government); if customs participates in supervision at this time, which is more conducive to the implementation of the government’s green policies, then the government’s cost becomes Gab (b represents the cost of customs), where Ga > Gab.
When local governments implement “passive regulation” while customs adopt “participatory supervision”, a policy conflict arises between local and customs authorities. This inconsistency leads to a partial loss of customs support and cooperation, resulting in inefficiencies in port economic development, increased government operational costs, and aggravated environmental pollution—all detrimental to the long-term development of the local port economy. In such cases, local governments incur potential losses (Fa). Taking Tianjin Port, China as an illustrative case, despite its remarkable achievements in green transformation, discrepancies between the Bohai Rim regional emission standards and customs’ cross-border carbon data requirements continue to constrain synergistic effectiveness, highlighting the urgency of policy coordination [28]. Failure to align local government and customs efforts in regulatory standards and subsidy mechanisms would not only delay port emission reduction initiatives but also undermine international competitiveness and hinder the achievement of “dual carbon” goals. Furthermore, due to the accountability mechanism between higher-level and local governments, the latter may face administrative penalties (E) imposed by the former, where E > Ga.
Assumption 4:
When local custom participates in supervision, it can promote the construction of green ports, helping the local government to better supervise whether enterprises are engaging in green production, receiving financial support from the government, Sba, and supervision rewards, Sbc; the green transformation of port logistics enterprises is complementary to the construction of green ports, which is not only beneficial for promoting the development of green ports but also facilitates more efficient execution of customs functions, from which customs can obtain certain economic benefits, Nb, but customs must pay a certain cost for green supervision, Gb.
If customs do not supervise, and the government actively regulates, then there will be a contradiction between customs’ policies and the local government’s policies, leading to a loss of some support and cooperation from the local government, resulting in lower efficiency in customs work, increased work costs, etc., which is not conducive to the long-term development of customs locally; at this time, customs will incur a potential loss, Fb.
Assumption 5:
When port logistics enterprises adopt the traditional operation mode, their income and costs are denoted as R and Gc, respectively. If the logistics enterprises undergo green transformation, the cost of green transformation is Gc1 (the cost of green operation); if customs participate in supervision at this time, promoting the construction of green port logistics, then the cost of green transformation for port logistics enterprises becomes Gcb, where Gc1 > Gcb. At this time, to encourage port logistics enterprises to undergo green transformation, the government provides subsidies to enterprises that have undertaken green transformation based on the green transformation costs they bear (either Gc1 or Gcb) at a rate of γGc1 (or γGcb) (0 ≤ γ ≤ 1) and imposes an environmental tax on port logistics enterprises that still adopt the traditional operation mode, denoted as T.
Assumption 6:
Actively promoting cooperation between local governments and customs not only promotes the green and sustainable development of ports but also brings a higher public reputation to the government and customs, with the social reputation coefficients denoted as φi, i = a, b. When the government chooses active regulation and customs participates in supervision, the social reputation benefits obtained by the government are φab, and the social reputation benefits obtained by customs are φba; when the government passively regulates, it no longer provides policy, financial, and other forms of assistance, but customs actively participates in supervision, its proactive actions will still gain public reputation, with social reputation benefits denoted as φb; and, when the government maintains a friendly cooperative attitude, actively regulates enterprises that have not undergone a green transformation, and customs do not supervise, the government’s proactive cooperation-seeking behavior will also gain a certain public reputation, with social reputation benefits denoted as φa; when both the government and customs passively regulate port logistics enterprises, failing to promote the construction of green ports, neither party will gain social reputation benefits. The social reputation benefits of cooperation between the two parties are greater than the social reputation benefits of a single party, denoted as φab > φa, φba > φb.
With increasing attention to regional environmental issues, the dual pressures of public opinion and environmental degradation are compelling governments and customs authorities to take an active role in the construction of green ports. Governments can strengthen policy guidance through the implementation of tiered environmental tax systems and the establishment of special subsidies for green transformation. Customs authorities, on the other hand, can introduce innovative regulatory models such as prioritized inspection and release through “green channels” and the development of intelligent carbon monitoring platforms. Together, these efforts will advance the construction of green ports. Therefore, enhancing social reputation and improving the ecological environment of port areas will become key priorities for governments and customs authorities, i.e., φa > Ga, φb > Gb.
Assumption 7:
The probabilities of the government adopting the active regulation strategy, customs adopting the participatory supervision strategy, and port logistics enterprises adopting the green transformation strategy are denoted as x, y, and z, respectively, and x, y, z ∈ [0, 1]. The initial intentions of the stakeholders refer to their subjective willingness (probability) to make a certain decision in the initial environment. In the process of green port construction, the initial intentions of the government and customs to adopt active regulation and participatory supervision strategies, and port logistics enterprises to adopt green transformation strategies, are denoted as x0, y0, and z0, respectively, and x0, y0, z0 ∈ [0, 1].

3.2. Parameters and Variables

All parameter symbols and their meanings within the paper are shown in Table 1.

3.3. Model Construction

Based on the assumptions above, a tripartite game matrix for the strategic interactions among local governments, customs, and port logistics enterprises is constructed, as shown in Table 2.

4. Model Analysis

4.1. Evolutionary Stability of the Local Government Strategy

The expected payoffs for the local government when adopting “active regulation” (E11) and “passive regulation” (E12) are as follows:
E 11 = ( N a + φ a b G a b S b a γ G c b ) y z + ( T + φ a b G a b S b a S b c ) y ( 1 z ) + ( N a + φ a G a γ G c 1 ) ( 1 y ) z + ( T + φ a G a ) ( 1 y ) ( 1 z )
E 12 = ( N a F a ) y z + ( F a E ) y ( 1 z ) + N a ( 1 y ) z E ( 1 y ) ( 1 z )
Subsequently, the average expected payoffs for these two strategies, denoted as E 1 ¯ , can be computed.
E 1 ¯ = x * E 11 + ( 1 x ) E 12 = x [ ( N a + φ a b G a b S b a γ G c b ) y z + ( T + φ a b G a b S b a S b c ) y ( 1 z ) + ( N a + φ a G a γ G c 1 ) ( 1 y ) z + ( T + φ a G a ) ( 1 y ) ( 1 z ) ] + ( 1 x ) [ ( N a F a ) y z + ( F a E ) y ( 1 z ) + N a ( 1 y ) z E ( 1 y ) ( 1 z ) ]
Therefore, the replicator dynamic equation for the local government’s strategy choice is given by the following:
F ( x ) = d x / d t = x ( E 11 E 1 ¯ ) = x ( 1 x ) ( E 11 E 12 ) = x ( 1 x ) [ ( φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c ) y + ( γ G c 1 T E ) z + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) y z + T + φ a + E G a ]
The first-order derivative of x and the function G(y) are defined as follows:
d ( F ( x ) ) / d x = ( 1 2 x ) [ ( φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c ) y + ( γ G c 1 T E ) z + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) y z + T + φ a + E G a ]
G ( y ) = ( φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c ) y + ( γ G c 1 T E ) z + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) y z + T + φ a + E G a
According to the Lyapunov stability theorem, for the probability of the local government adopting active regulation to be in a stable state, it must satisfy F(x) = 0 and d ( F ( x ) ) / d x < 0 .
If y = y 1 / y 2 = y * , y 1 = ( γ G c 1 + T + E ) z T φ a E + G a , y 2 = ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) z + φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c , then G(y) = 0, d ( F ( x ) ) / d x 0 ; hence, any strategic choice of the local government is a stable strategy and will not change over time.
If y y 1 / y 2 , to ensure F(x) = 0, the two equilibrium points corresponding to x = 0 and x = 1 can be further analyzed by differentiating the evolutionary equation concerning F(x), which leads to the following:
When x = 0, G(y) < 0. Given G ( y ) / y > 0 , it follows that G(y) is increasing concerning y; thus, if y < y*, when the local government’s strategy is located in space A1, x = 0 is an evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS), indicating that the government will choose to regulate passively.
When x = 1, G(y) > 0. Given G ( y ) / y > 0 , y > y*, when the local government’s strategy is located in space A2, x = 1 is an evolutionarily stable strategy(ESS), indicating that the government tends to regulate actively.
The evolutionary phase diagram for the strategy of the local government is shown in Figure 2.

4.2. Evolutionary Stability of the Customs Strategy

The expected payoffs for customs when choosing “participatory supervision” (E21) and “non-participatory supervision” (E22) are as follows:
E 21 = ( S b a + φ b a G b + N b ) x z + ( S b a + S b c + φ b a G b ) x ( 1 z ) + ( φ b G b + N b ) ( 1 x ) z + ( φ b G b ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 z )
E 22 = ( N b F b ) x z F b x ( 1 z ) + N b ( 1 x ) z
Subsequently, the average expected payoffs for these two strategies, denoted as E 2 ¯ , can be computed:
E 2 ¯ = y * E 21 + ( 1 y ) E 22 = y [ ( S b a + φ b a G b + N b ) x z + ( S b a + S b c + φ b a G b ) x ( 1 z ) + ( φ b G b + N b ) ( 1 x ) z + ( φ b G b ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 z ) ] + ( 1 y ) ( N b F b ) x z F b x ( 1 z ) + N b ( 1 x ) z
Therefore, the replicator dynamic equation for the customs’ strategy choice is given by the following:
F ( y ) = d y / d t = y ( E 21 E 2 ¯ ) = y ( 1 y ) ( E 21 E 22 ) = y ( 1 y ) ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b ) x S b c x z + φ b G b
The first-order derivative of y and the function J(x) are defined as follows:
d ( F ( y ) ) / d y = ( 1 2 y ) [ ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b ) x S b c x z + φ b G b ]
J ( x ) = ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b ) x S b c x z + φ b G b
According to the Lyapunov stability theorem, for the probability of customs adopting active regulation to be in a stable state, it must satisfy F(y) = 0 and d ( F ( y ) ) / d y < 0 .
If x = ( G b φ b ) / ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b S b c z ) = x * , then J(x) = 0, d ( F ( y ) ) / d y 0 ; hence, any strategic choice of the customs is a stable strategy and will not change over time.
If x ( G b φ b ) / ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b S b c z ) , to ensure F(y) = 0, the two equilibrium points corresponding to y = 0 and y = 1 can be further analyzed by differentiating the evolutionary equation concerning F(y), which leads to the following:
When y = 0, J(x) < 0. Given J ( x ) / x > 0 , it follows that J(x) is increasing concerning x; thus, if x < x*, when the customs authority’s strategy is located in space B1, y = 0 is an evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS), indicating that the customs authority tends to choose not to regulate.
When y = 1, J(x) > 0. Given J ( x ) / x > 0 , x > x*, when the customs authority’s strategy is located in space B2, y = 1 is an evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS) for the customs authority, indicating that it will choose to engage in regulation.
The evolutionary phase diagram for the strategy of the customs is shown in Figure 3.

4.3. Evolutionary Stability of the Port Logistics Enterprise Strategy

The expected payoffs for port logistics enterprises when choosing “green transformation” (E31) and “traditional production” (E32) are, respectively, as follows:
E 31 = ( R G c G c b + γ G c b ) x y + ( R G c G c 1 + γ G c 1 ) x ( 1 y ) + ( R G c G c b ) ( 1 x ) y + ( R G c G c 1 ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 y )
E 32 = ( R G c T ) x y + ( R G c T ) x ( 1 y ) + ( R G c ) ( 1 x ) y + ( R G c ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 y )
Subsequently, the average expected payoffs for these two strategies, denoted as E 3 ¯ , can be computed:
E 3 ¯ = z * E 31 + ( 1 z ) E 32 = z [ ( R G c G c b + γ G c b ) x y + ( R G c G c 1 + γ G c 1 ) x ( 1 y ) + ( R G c G c b ) ( 1 x ) y + ( R G c G c 1 ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 y ) ] + ( 1 z ) [ ( R G c T ) x y + ( R G c T ) x ( 1 y ) + ( R G c ) ( 1 x ) y + ( R G c ) ( 1 x ) ( 1 y )
Therefore, the replicator dynamic equation for port logistics enterprises’ strategy choice is given by the following:
F ( z ) = d z / d t = z ( E 31 E 3 ¯ ) = z ( 1 z ) ( E 31 E 32 ) = z ( 1 z ) [ ( T + γ G c 1 ) x + ( G c 1 G c b ) y + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) x y G c 1 ]
The first-order derivative of z and the function H(x) are defined as follows:
d ( F ( z ) ) / d z = ( 1 2 z ) [ ( T + γ G c 1 ) x + ( G c 1 G c b ) y + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) x y G c 1 ]
H ( x ) = ( T + γ G c 1 ) x + ( G c 1 G c b ) y + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) x y G c 1
According to the Lyapunov stability theorem, for the probability of port logistics enterprises adopting active regulation to be in a stable state, it must satisfy F(z) = 0 and d ( F ( z ) ) / d z < 0 .
If x = [ G c 1 ( G c 1 G c b ) y ] / [ T + γ G c 1 + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) y ] = x ** , then H(x) = 0, d ( F ( z ) ) / d z 0 ; hence, any strategic choice of the port logistics enterprises is a stable strategy and will not change over time.
If x [ G c 1 ( G c 1 G c b ) y ] / [ T + γ G c 1 + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) y ] , to ensure F(z) = 0, the two equilibrium points corresponding to z = 0 and z = 1 can be further analyzed by differentiating the evolutionary equation concerning F(z), which leads to the following:
When z = 0, H(x) < 0. Given H ( x ) / x > 0 , it follows that H(x) is increasing concerning x; thus, if x < x**, when the strategy of the port logistics enterprise is located in space C1, z = 0 is an evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS), indicating that the enterprise tends to choose traditional production. When z = 1, H(x) > 0. Given H ( x ) / x > 0 , x > x**, when the strategy of the port logistics enterprise is located in space C2, z = 1 is an evolutionarily stable strategy (ESS) for the port logistics enterprise, indicating that it will choose to undertake green transformation.
The evolutionary phase diagram for the strategy of the port logistics enterprises is shown in Figure 4.

4.4. Evolutionary Stability Analysis

4.4.1. Equilibrium Points

Equations (4), (10), and (16) form a three-dimensional dynamical system of evolutionary game theory. Let F ( x ) = 0 , F ( y ) = 0 , F ( z ) = 0 represent the equilibrium points, and we can obtain eight local equilibrium points for the three-dimensional dynamical system, which are E1(0,0,0), E2(1,0,0), E3(0,1,0), E4(0,0,1), E5(1,1,0), E6(1,0,1), E7(0,1,1), and E8(1,1,1). These eight equilibrium points constitute the boundary of the evolutionary game solution for the tripartite game, and the area enclosed by these boundaries (Ω) is the equilibrium solution domain of the three-party evolutionary game:
Ω = ( x , y , z ) | 0 < x < 1 ; 0 < y < 1 ; 0 < z < 1 , x ( 1 x ) [ ( φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c ) y + ( γ G c 1 T E ) z + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) y z + T + φ a + E G a ] = 0 y ( 1 y ) [ ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b ) x S b c x z + φ b G b ] = 0 z ( 1 z ) [ ( T + γ G c 1 ) x + ( G c 1 G c b ) y + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) x y G c 1 ] = 0
When a mixed strategy E9(x*, y*, z*) exists, satisfying Equation (4), and belongs to the equilibrium solution domain Ω, E9(x*, y*, z*) is a balance point within the system; otherwise, it is not [29].

4.4.2. Equilibrium Stability Analysis

The Jacobian matrix for the tripartite evolutionary game system is given by the following:
J = J 1 J 2 J 3 J 4 J 5 J 6 J 7 J 8 J 9 = F ( x ) / x F ( x ) / y F ( x ) / z F ( y ) / x F ( y ) / y F ( y ) / z F ( z ) / x F ( z ) / y F ( z ) / z
Wherein
F ( x ) / x = ( 1 2 x ) [ ( φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c ) y + ( γ G c 1 T E ) z + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) y z + T + φ a + E G a ]
F ( x ) / y = x ( 1 x ) [ φ a b φ a + G a G a b + F a S b a S b c + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) z
F ( x ) / z = x ( 1 x ) [ γ G c 1 T E + ( S b c + γ G c 1 γ G c b ) y
F ( y ) / x = y ( 1 y ) ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b S b c z )
F ( y ) / y = ( 1 2 y ) [ ( S b a + S b c + φ b a φ b + F b ) x S b c x z ) + φ b G b
F ( y ) / z = S b c x y ( 1 y )
F ( z ) / x = z ( 1 z ) [ T + γ G c 1 + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) y ]
F ( z ) / y = z ( 1 z ) [ G c 1 G c b + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) x ]
F ( z ) / z = ( 1 2 z ) [ ( T + γ G c 1 ) x + ( G c 1 G c b ) y + γ ( G c b G c 1 ) x y G c 1 ]
According to Wainwright’s perspective, evolutionarily stable strategies (ESSs) can only be achieved in a three-dimensional dynamical system when the equilibrium point is a pure strategy Nash equilibrium, whereas E9(x*, y*, z*) is a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium, so it can be directly disregarded [30]. The eight equilibrium points obtained from the replicator dynamic equations are introduced into the Jacobian matrix for analysis.
Using the Lyapunov first method, if all eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix have negative real parts, the equilibrium point is asymptotically stable; if at least one eigenvalue of the Jacobian matrix has a positive real part, the equilibrium point is unstable; if all eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix, except for those with zero real parts, have negative real parts, then the equilibrium point is in a critical state, and the stability cannot be determined by the sign of the eigenvalues. The stability analysis of each equilibrium point is shown in Table 3.
Scenario 1: When T G c b + γ G c b < 0 , the replicator dynamic system has only one stable equilibrium point E5(1,1,0); at this time, E5(1,1,0) is an evolutionarily stable strategy, meaning the government adopts an “active regulation” strategy, customs adopt a “participatory supervision” strategy, and port logistics enterprises choose the “traditional production” strategy. This indicates that, although customs’ “participatory supervision” reduces the cost of enterprise “green transformation”, the reduction is limited, and the actual “green transformation” cost is still higher than the environmental tax imposed by the government, leading to a lack of motivation for enterprises to undertake “green transformation”. At this point, it is necessary for the government to further increase the regulatory efforts on port logistics enterprises, such as raising environmental taxes and other measures, to encourage enterprises to move towards “green transformation”.
Scenario 2: When T G c b + γ G c b > 0 ,   G a b F a φ a b + S b a 2 γ G c 1 γ G c b < 0 , the replicator dynamic system has only one stable equilibrium point E8(1,1,1); at this time, E8(1,1,1) is an evolutionarily stable strategy, meaning the government adopts an “active regulation” strategy, customs adopt a “participatory supervision” strategy, and port logistics enterprises choose the “green transformation” strategy. This indicates that with the continuous improvement of government regulatory measures, more robust support is provided for customs “participatory supervision”, increasing the intensity of customs supervision, which further reduces the cost of enterprise “green transformation”. At the same time, the environmental tax imposed by the government is higher than the actual transformation cost when enterprises undertake “green transformation”, thus encouraging port logistics enterprises to prefer “green transformation”, achieving the joint promotion of green port construction by all three parties.

5. Numerical Simulation

To explore the effectiveness of government and customs regulatory measures in promoting port logistics enterprises to choose the “green transformation” strategy, this study uses the results of game theory stability analysis and conducts numerical simulations with Matlab 2023a to depict the conditions required for the evolution of stable strategies among stakeholders in green port construction. When selecting parameter values, multiple cases were referenced, and, based on the similarity of parameter meanings, values were taken from the Xiamen Port Hairun Terminal green transformation case. In July 2020, Hairun Terminal invested CNY 338 million, taking the lead nationwide in the comprehensive intelligent transformation project of traditional container terminals, independently developing and launching the intelligent terminal operating system iTOS, coordinating production elements of the terminal, and achieving full-process intelligent management of key links such as ship loading and unloading, and yard operations. After the upgrade, the overall operational efficiency of Hairun Terminal increased by 10%, and the variable cost per box has been decreasing year by year, with a total reduction of 15.1% over the past five years, saving the terminal about CNY 4 million in costs annually. Over the past five years, Xiamen Container Terminal Group has invested a total of CNY 230 million in green port construction, with a comprehensive single-box energy consumption reduction of 22.3%, saving energy 5276 tons of standard coal, and a reduction in carbon emission intensity of 32%. Referencing the “Shenzhen City Interim Management Measures for Green and Low-Carbon Port Construction Subsidy Funds”, it is mentioned that subsidies of 30% of the engine cost are provided for newly added Shenzhen-registered ships powered by natural gas or electricity, with a maximum subsidy amount not exceeding CNY 1 million per ship; for shore power facilities completed and passed acceptance inspection, financial support is provided up to 30% of the project construction costs; for existing Shenzhen-registered cargo ships undergoing shore power reception facility transformation, subsidies are provided at 30% of the transformation costs. Drawing on the above case data and parameter settings in references [31,32,33], reasonable modifications were made to the parameters in the text, striving to make the conclusions universal. The specific values do not represent actual amounts, indicating the relative magnitudes between parameters, with the focus of the analysis being on the relationships between different parameters.

5.1. Evolutionary Paths of Stakeholders

Scenario 1: The equilibrium point E5(1,1,0) is an evolutionarily stable strategy.
That is, T G c b + γ G c b < 0 . The related parameters are set as T G c b + γ G c b > 0 ,   G a b F a φ a b + S b a 2 γ G c 1 γ G c b < 0 , T = 3, Gcb = 16, γ = 0.3, Gb = 12, Fb = 15, φba = 25, Sba = 6, Gab = 10, Fa = 15, E = 75, φab = 25. As shown in Figure 5, regardless of how the initial intentions of the three parties change, the final evolutionary outcome is E5(1,1,0). At this time, due to the relatively high cost of green transformation, even with customs implementing regulatory measures, enterprises still choose the traditional operation mode. This phenomenon indicates that under the current circumstances, while customs supervision can influence corporate costs to some extent, it has not reached the level of changing corporate decisions. When weighing costs and benefits, enterprises still tend to maintain the status quo because the green transformation input–output ratio is not attractive. At this point, increasing government regulatory efforts become a key factor in driving enterprises towards green transformation. The government can promote green transformation by establishing stricter environmental standards and increasing penalties for violations, raising the cost of traditional operations, and thereby encouraging enterprises to reassess the feasibility of green transformation.
Scenario 2: The equilibrium point E8(1,1,1) is an evolutionarily stable strategy.
That is, T G c b + γ G c b > 0 ,   G a b F a φ a b + S b a 2 γ G c 1 γ G c b < 0 . The related parameters are set as T = 15, Gcb = 10, γ = 0.3, Gb = 12, Fb = 15, φba = 25, Sba = 6, Sbc = 3, Gab = 10, Fa = 15, E = 75, φab = 25. As shown in Figure 6, regardless of how the initial intentions of the three parties change, the final evolutionary outcome is E8(1,1,1). At this time, with the continuous improvement of government regulatory measures, more robust support can be provided for customs’ participatory supervision, increasing the intensity of customs supervision, and providing a more mature background and transformation conditions for the green transformation of port logistics enterprises. At this moment, the government regulation and customs supervision form a combined force, further reducing the cost of enterprise green transformation, and the environmental tax imposed by the government on port logistics enterprises is greater than the actual transformation cost when enterprises undertake green transformation, thus encouraging port logistics enterprises to gradually tend towards green transformation, achieving a good situation where all three parties jointly promote the construction of green ports.

5.2. Sensitivity Analysis of Parameters

In the early stages of green port construction, due to the low enthusiasm of port logistics enterprises for actively undertaking green transformation and the numerous difficulties in implementing green customs policies, government intervention is necessary at the beginning of the transformation. The purpose of government regulation is to encourage port logistics enterprises to actively participate in the construction of green ports, and Scenario 2 is a more appropriate choice (the parameter values in the following text are the same as Scenario 2); that is, the government chooses the “active regulation” strategy, customs adopt a “participatory supervision” strategy, and port logistics enterprises choose the “green transformation” strategy.

5.2.1. Environmental Tax

To further explore the impact of environmental taxes on the evolutionary behavior of the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises, sensitivity analysis is conducted through numerical simulation. Let T = 15, 35, 55; the results are shown in Figure 7.
The simulation reveals differentiated effects of environmental tax (T) on strategy evolution. Higher tax rates significantly accelerate the government’s adoption of “active regulation” by increasing direct fiscal benefits, while strongly promoting port logistics enterprises’ “green transformation” strategy when the tax exceeds their retrofitting costs. However, customs’ “participatory supervision” shows limited sensitivity to tax variations, exhibiting only marginal behavioral adjustments. The government should refine the tax mechanism by setting rates that accurately reflect environmental externalities, with tax revenues earmarked for green port infrastructure to create a policy loop. Customs authorities must maintain regulatory autonomy while collaborating with the government through information sharing to facilitate policy calibration. For cost-sensitive enterprises, policymakers should balance incentive intensity with corporate affordability, complemented by customs’ efforts to streamline compliance procedures—a synergistic approach essential for a sustainable transition.

5.2.2. Port Logistics Enterprise Green Transformation Cost

To further explore the impact of the green transformation cost of port logistics enterprises on the evolutionary behavior of the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises, sensitivity analysis was conducted through numerical simulation. Let Gcb = 1, 5, 10; the results are shown in Figure 8.
Figure 8 indicates that the lower the cost of green transformation for port logistics enterprises, the faster the evolution towards the “green transformation” strategy. Gcb represents the green transformation cost of port logistics enterprises when customs participate in supervision. It is evident that under customs supervision, a more convenient customs environment is provided for port logistics enterprises, which helps reduce the cost of green transformation and further encourages port logistics enterprises to choose the “green transformation” strategy. Therefore, as the key entity directly affecting the cost of enterprise green transformation, customs should fully leverage their functional advantages, actively improve regulatory methods, provide a convenient customs environment, reduce the tedious procedures for port logistics enterprises to handle customs business, and lower labor and time costs. At the same time, customs should strengthen collaboration with other port departments, establish an information-sharing platform, break down information barriers between departments, achieve information interconnectivity of enterprise logistics, and avoid increased costs for enterprises due to repeated submission of information and multiple inspections. Port logistics enterprises themselves should also actively respond to the cost reduction opportunities brought by customs supervision and accelerate the pace of green transformation.

5.2.3. Government Financial Support for Customs

To further explore the impact of government financial support for customs on the evolutionary behavior of the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises, sensitivity analysis was conducted through numerical simulation. Let Sba = 6, 18, 30; the results are shown in Figure 9.
From Figure 9, it can be observed that during the evolutionary process, the greater the financial support (Sba) provided by the government to customs, the faster the evolution of customs’ choice of the “participatory supervision” strategy. This means that the more additional benefits customs gain, the more it is conducive to enhancing the enthusiasm of customs participation in supervision; the increase in financial support from the government to customs also raises the probability of port logistics enterprises’ “green transformation”, and reduces the probability of the government’s “active regulation”. This is because the government does not want to bear excessive cost burdens, but the impact is limited; therefore, the government should set a reasonable amount of financial support and promote customs and port logistics enterprises to progress towards the construction of green ports while preventing the government from bearing excessive financial expenditures.

5.3. Initial Intentions of Stakeholders

To further explore the sensitivity of the evolutionary behavior of the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises to the initial intentions, sensitivity analysis was conducted through numerical simulation. Let x0 = 0.1, 0.5, 0.9, y0 = 0.1, 0.5, 0.9, and z0 = 0.1, 0.5, 0.9; the results are shown in Figure 10, Figure 11 and Figure 12.
As shown in Figure 10, when the government’s initial intention is low, port logistics enterprises initially favor the “traditional production” strategy but eventually shift to “green transformation”, experiencing a transitional hesitation. Higher government intention leads to the direct adoption of “green transformation”. Regardless of government intention, customs will evolve toward “participatory supervision” if the government demonstrates “active regulation”, reflecting cooperation in green port development. Ultimately, all parties will adopt “active regulation”, “participatory supervision”, and “green transformation”, but higher government intention accelerates this evolution.
As shown in Figure 11, when customs’ initial willingness (y0) is low, the government’s evolution toward the “active regulation” strategy progresses slowly but ultimately succeeds, demonstrating that green port construction requires customs support. Ambiguous customs and attitudes may lead to government hesitation. When y0 ≥ 0.5, the government rapidly adopts “active regulation”, with further willingness increases having limited impact on the speed. Securing customs cooperation strengthens the government’s resolve. Port logistics enterprises initially favor “traditional production” at low y0 levels before gradually transitioning to “green transformation”, while higher y0 prompts direct transformation, with speed accelerating as willingness increases. Figure 10 and Figure 11 indicate that green port development relies on government–customs collaboration—only when both exhibit strong willingness will enterprises decisively transform.
As shown in Figure 12, when facing varying initial willingness levels (z0) of port logistics enterprises, both the government and customs ultimately adopt “active regulation” and “participatory supervision” strategies, respectively. The government’s evolution toward “active regulation” first accelerates then decelerates: at lower z0 levels, regulation drives corporate green transformation, while, at higher z0 levels, the government considers gradual withdrawal to reduce costs and encourage autonomous transformation. Higher enterprise z0 values slow customs’ evolution toward “participatory supervision”, indicating their preference for spontaneous corporate transformation to minimize regulatory costs.

6. Discussion

6.1. Main Findings

Under the backdrop of globalization, the development of international trade has elevated the importance of port construction, and the concept of green development has propelled the construction of green ports as an inevitable trend. Although port logistics enterprises play a crucial role in port construction, they face difficulties in green transformation. The role of the government and customs in promoting the construction of green ports has not been fully leveraged, and previous research has limitations. Therefore, this study constructs a tripartite evolutionary game model involving the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises to deeply analyze the stability of each party’s strategic choices, the equilibrium strategy combinations of the game system, and the impact of various elements. Through simulation analysis, quantitative exploration of the mechanisms and evolutionary paths of green logistics development at ports can lead to the following significant conclusions.
Firstly, in the process of green port construction, port logistics enterprises face the dilemma of relatively high costs of green transformation. Even with customs’ regulatory measures in place, their impact on corporate costs is not sufficient to prompt enterprises to change their strategic choices towards green transformation. This indicates that when port logistics enterprises weigh costs against benefits, given the lack of attractiveness of the green transformation input–output ratio, they tend to maintain the status quo. However, the role of customs supervision is significantly effective in reducing the costs associated with the green transformation of port logistics enterprises. For instance, customs can implement differentiated regulatory measures based on the size and operational characteristics of the enterprises. For large enterprises that already have a certain green foundation, customs can provide a more lenient regulatory environment to encourage further green investments. In contrast, for small and medium-sized enterprises, customs can offer more guidance and support to help them overcome obstacles in the green transformation process. Additionally, by simplifying and accelerating customs clearance procedures, customs can reduce the time and costs associated with the import and export of goods for enterprises, making them more willing to invest in green technologies and equipment. This is because the overall improvement in operational efficiency can offset part of the initial costs of green investment. These measures can all assist enterprises in reducing costs and enhancing their enthusiasm for transformation. However, customs supervision alone is not enough; to achieve the shift of port logistics enterprises from traditional operations to green transformation, the cooperation of the government is indispensable. The government can update and establish stricter environmental protection regulations to ensure that they are aligned with international best practices while also reflecting the specific environmental needs of the local areas. Additionally, the government can offer financial subsidies and tax exemptions to support enterprises in investing in green technologies and renewable energy projects. Furthermore, the establishment of green funds could provide port logistics enterprises with low-interest loans or grants for green transformation projects, among other measures. These initiatives can all encourage enterprises to reassess the feasibility of green transformation. When government regulation and customs supervision form a combined force, it can effectively reduce the cost for port logistics enterprises, making them more likely to choose green transformation when facing environmental taxes higher than the cost of green transformation, thus achieving a good situation where all three parties jointly promote the construction of green ports. Only when there is consensus among the government, customs, and port logistics enterprises, and cooperation and coordination, can a solid foundation be laid for the long-term development of green ports, promoting the continuous, stable, and efficient progress of green port construction, and achieving a win-win situation for international trade and environmental protection.
Secondly, this study examines the complex interplay among government agencies, customs authorities, and port logistics enterprises in green port development. The findings reveal that the initial willingness of these three stakeholders is mutually influential and collectively shapes the transformation process. Government policy signals and regulatory determination directly affect enterprises’ green transition decisions. A strong governmental commitment significantly enhances corporate confidence in sustainable transformation, while customs supervision reinforces this effect through cost modulation and operational environment adjustments. Notably, customs’ regulatory willingness serves as a critical catalyst within this tripartite system. Enhanced customs engagement can substantially accelerate the coordinated evolution of all parties toward more proactive strategies. Conversely, enterprises’ transition willingness creates feedback effects on the regulatory framework. When firms demonstrate higher environmental initiative, governments may appropriately relax control measures and customs can correspondingly reduce the supervisory intensity, thereby establishing a virtuous interaction mechanism. This study suggests that these three parties should maintain active engagement to develop a coordinated governance system integrating government policies with customs supervision while encouraging enterprises to assume greater environmental responsibility. Such collaborative efforts will effectively promote the sustainable development of green ports.
Through an in-depth analysis of the tripartite evolutionary game model, this study elucidates the multidimensional impacts of customs supervision mechanisms in green port development. The findings demonstrate that customs regulation plays a pivotal role not only in directly influencing port logistics enterprises’ costs and facilitating their green transformation but also in coordinating with government policies and interacting with stakeholders’ initial willingness. This research provides comprehensive theoretical foundations and practical guidance for all parties involved in green port construction. The results enable policymakers and practitioners to formulate more effective strategies, achieving synergistic development between international trade and environmental protection. This study carries significant theoretical implications and offers substantial practical value for sustainable port development.

6.2. Limitations and Future Prospects

This study has several limitations that point to potential avenues for future research. First, the model overlooks regional differences (e.g., policy environments, levels of economic development) and adopts the assumption of homogeneous firms, failing to fully reflect the heterogeneous characteristics of firms in reality, such as size, technological endowment, and environmental responsibility awareness. For example, large logistics firms may be more inclined to actively invest in green technologies due to abundant capital, while small and medium-sized enterprises may rely on policy subsidies to complete the transformation, a difference that significantly affects the speed of strategic adjustments and equilibrium outcomes of the game players. This oversimplification of reality limits the general applicability of the model. Future work should incorporate these factors to enhance the accuracy of the model. Second, expanding the scope of stakeholders to include consumers and media could reveal multi-agent synergies, enabling a more holistic ecosystem model for green port development.

Author Contributions

W.S. (Wenbing Shui): conceptualization, writing—review and editing, supervision. W.S. (Wenhui Song): methodology, software, validation, formal analysis, writing—original draft preparation. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in this study are included in the article. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Abbreviations

The following abbreviation is used in this manuscript:
ESSEvolutionarily stable strategy

References

  1. Xu, L.L.; Ma, X.D. The role of land border ports in the construction of Chinese modernization. J. Yunnan Norm. Univ. Humanit. Soc. Sci. Ed. 2024, 56, 1–9. [Google Scholar]
  2. The new kinetic energy generated by green consensus. China Highw. 2022, 20, 2.
  3. Yu, D.S.; Zhang, H.; Min, S.X.; Cao, F. Construction and development of green ports in China. China Water Transp. 2014, 14, 55–56. [Google Scholar]
  4. Jin, H.X. Developing border port logistics to promote border economic growth. J. Eurasian Econ. 2008, 2, 40–45. [Google Scholar]
  5. Lam, J.S.L.; Yap, W.Y. A Stakeholder Perspective of Port City Sustainable Development. Sustainability 2019, 11, 447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Song, B.H.; Xu, S.B. Theory of logistics entities. J. Beijing Jiaotong Univ. Soc. Sci. Ed. 2009, 8, 23–27. [Google Scholar]
  7. Liu, J.G.; Zhao, H.D.; Li, J. Investment strategy of port and shipping supply chain based on green investment efficiency. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2021, 29, 33–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Li, S.H.; Wang, X.J. Exploration of obstacles and countermeasures for the greening development of enterprise logistics: An analysis from the perspective of stakeholders in enterprise logistics greening. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2014, 22, 788–793. [Google Scholar]
  9. Tseng, P.H.; Pilcher, N. Exploring the viability of an emission tax policy for ships at berth in Taiwanese ports. Int. J. Shipp. Transp. Logist. 2016, 8, 705–722. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Wu, J.N.; Lv, J.; Lin, Y. Study on port emission reduction strategies under shipshore power usage based on a three-stage game model. Math. Pract. Theory 2020, 50, 27–37. [Google Scholar]
  11. Dai, L.; Hu, H.; Wang, Z.; Shi, Y.; Ding, W. An environmental and techno-economic analysis of shore side electricity. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2019, 75, 223–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Lu, B.; Wang, H.P. Countermeasures for government promotion of green port construction based on the evolutionary game. East China Econ. Manag. 2017, 31, 153–159. [Google Scholar]
  13. Li, J.L. The role and function of customs in China’s macroeconomic regulation. China Econ. 2009, 5, 52–53. [Google Scholar]
  14. Liang, X.Y.; Wang, X.J. Positioning of customs in promoting port economic development. Econ. Outlook Bohai Sea 2011, 11, 14–18. [Google Scholar]
  15. Xu, D.W. Deepening customs clearance reform to promote the healthy development of port logistics. Port Econ. 2006, 5, 43–45. [Google Scholar]
  16. Tao, W.L.; Cai, Y. Analysis of the impact of carbon peak and carbon neutrality on China’s foreign trade and the initial exploration of customs support paths. J. Cust. Trade 2022, 43, 57–65. [Google Scholar]
  17. Han, C.G.; Zhao, J.X.; Qin, S.L. Research on business process optimization and information system integration of customs supervision warehouse. Comput. Era 2022, 2, 46–49. [Google Scholar]
  18. Ye, Z.; Wang, J.; Wang, J. Resilience solution to solve prisoner’s dilemma in port shore power usage: The value of government subsidies on port. J. Sea Res. 2025, 205, 102578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Song, Z.; Tang, W.; Zhao, R.; Zhang, G. Implications of government subsidies on shipping companies’ shore power usage strategies in port. Transp. Res. Part E 2022, 165, 102840. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Zhang, Q.; Tan, Z.; Wang, S.; Zhen, L. Shore hydrogen deployment problem in green ports. Comput. Oper. Res. 2024, 165, 106585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Wang, Z.; Qu, C.; Zeng, Q.; Qu, X. Integrated energy management and operations planning in oil-electric hybrid container terminals considering multi-energy supply. Adv. Eng. Inform. 2024, 60, 102391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Deng, G.; Chen, J.; Liu, Q. Influence Mechanism and Evolutionary Game of Environmental Regulation on Green Port Construction. Sustainability 2022, 14, 2930. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Xu, L.; Di, Z.; Chen, J.; Shi, J.; Yang, C. Evolutionary game analysis on behavior strategies of multiple stakeholders in maritime shore power system. Ocean. Coast. Manag. 2021, 202, 105508. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Taizhou Customs Research Group; Zhou, J.Q. A study on the path to improving the regulatory efficiency of customs by using new technologies from the perspective of “Three Intelligences”. J. Cust. Trade 2023, 44, 34–47. [Google Scholar]
  25. New measures of the General Administration of Customs to enhance the function of the international shipping logistics hub in the Greater Bay Area. China Shipp. Gaz. 2022, 39, 17.
  26. Li, S.J.; Li, C.Z.; Xi, Z. Design of an information management system for logistics supervision in special customs supervision zones. China Sci. Technol. Inf. 2020, Z1, 45–47. [Google Scholar]
  27. Liao, R.Q. Supernetwork-Based Risk Management of Customs Logistics Monitoring System. Complex Syst. Complex. Sci. 2017, 14, 39–45. [Google Scholar]
  28. Qi, J. Intelligence and Carbon Reduction in Harmony: Green Transformation Surging at Ports—Tianjin Port’s Practice in Port Energy and Carbon Management System Technology. Transp. Constr. Manag. 2024, 5, 42–45. [Google Scholar]
  29. Zhang, M.; Zhu, J.J.; Wang, H.H. Evolutionary game analysis of co-development of large passenger aircraft under main manufacturer–supplier mode. J. Syst. Eng. 2019, 34, 748–759. [Google Scholar]
  30. Wainwright, J. A dynamical systems approach to Bianchi cosmologies: Orthogonal models of class A. Class. Quantum Gravity 1989, 6, 1409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Wang, W.; Suo, J.T.; Han, L.H.; Ding, L.L.; Zhang, W.S. Evolutionary game analysis of green port development under government regulation. J. Syst. Eng. 2023, 38, 30–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Li, L.H.; Wang, Y.; Deng, Y.J.; Nan, T.J. Tripartite evolutionary game of green logistics development under carbon tax policy. J. Railw. Sci. Eng. 2023, 20, 3715–3726. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Zhu, L.L.; Rong, J.M.; Zhang, S.Y. Three-party Evolutionary Game and Simulation Analysis of Drug Quality Supervision under the Government Reward and Punishment Mechanism. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2021, 29, 55–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The tripartite game structure of green port logistics development.
Figure 1. The tripartite game structure of green port logistics development.
Sustainability 17 05470 g001
Figure 2. Phase diagram of the local government’s strategy evolution.
Figure 2. Phase diagram of the local government’s strategy evolution.
Sustainability 17 05470 g002
Figure 3. Phase diagram of the customs’ strategy evolution.
Figure 3. Phase diagram of the customs’ strategy evolution.
Sustainability 17 05470 g003
Figure 4. Phase diagram of the port logistics enterprises’ strategy evolution.
Figure 4. Phase diagram of the port logistics enterprises’ strategy evolution.
Sustainability 17 05470 g004
Figure 5. Result (1,1,0) of evolution for Scenario 1. (The conclusions in the text are only related to the trends of the lines).
Figure 5. Result (1,1,0) of evolution for Scenario 1. (The conclusions in the text are only related to the trends of the lines).
Sustainability 17 05470 g005
Figure 6. Result (1,1,1) of evolution for Scenario 2. (The conclusions in the text are only related to the trends of the lines.)
Figure 6. Result (1,1,1) of evolution for Scenario 2. (The conclusions in the text are only related to the trends of the lines.)
Sustainability 17 05470 g006
Figure 7. The influence of the (T): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Figure 7. The influence of the (T): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Sustainability 17 05470 g007
Figure 8. The influence of the (Gcb): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Figure 8. The influence of the (Gcb): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Sustainability 17 05470 g008
Figure 9. The influence of the (Sba): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Figure 9. The influence of the (Sba): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Sustainability 17 05470 g009
Figure 10. The influence of the (x0) (note: y0 = 0.5, z0 = 0.5): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Figure 10. The influence of the (x0) (note: y0 = 0.5, z0 = 0.5): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Sustainability 17 05470 g010
Figure 11. The influence of the (y0) (note: x0 = 0.5, z0 = 0.5): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Figure 11. The influence of the (y0) (note: x0 = 0.5, z0 = 0.5): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Sustainability 17 05470 g011
Figure 12. The influence of the (z0) (note: x0 = 0.5, y0 = 0.5): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Figure 12. The influence of the (z0) (note: x0 = 0.5, y0 = 0.5): (a) government; (b) customs; (c) port logistics enterprises.
Sustainability 17 05470 g012
Table 1. The meanings of the parameters.
Table 1. The meanings of the parameters.
ParameterMeaning
NaThe social benefits brought to the government after the port logistics enterprises undergo green transformation
NbThe economic benefits brought to the customs after the port logistics enterprises undergo green transformation
GaThe input cost of the government’s active regulation
GabThe input cost of the government’s active regulation when customs participate in supervision
FaThe potential loss of the government’s passive regulation when customs participate in supervision
FbThe potential loss of the government’s active regulation when customs do not supervise
EThe administrative penalty amount of the government’s passive regulation
SbaThe financial support from the government when customs participate in supervision
SbcThe supervision reward is given by the government to customs when port logistics enterprises engage in traditional operations
GbThe green supervision cost when customs participate in supervision
RThe income of port logistics enterprises when adopting the traditional operation mode
GcThe cost of port logistics enterprises when adopting the traditional operation mode
Gc1The cost of port logistics enterprises’ green transformation
GcbThe cost of port logistics enterprises’ green transformation when customs participate in supervision
γThe subsidy ratio coefficient of the government for the green transformation of port logistics enterprises
TThe environmental tax levied by the government on port logistics enterprises operating in the traditional operation mode
φabThe social reputation benefit of the government when the government actively regulates and customs participates in supervision
φbaThe social reputation benefit of customs when the government actively regulates and customs participate in supervision
φbThe social reputation benefit of customs when the government passively regulates and customs participate in supervision
φaThe social reputation benefit of the government when the government actively regulates and customs do not supervise
Table 2. Payoff matrix.
Table 2. Payoff matrix.
Strategy CombinationLocal Government
(x)
Customs
(y)
Port Logistics Enterprise
(z)
Active Regulation + Participatory Supervision + Green Transformation N a + φ a b G a b S b a γ G c b S b a + φ b a G b + N b R G c G c b + γ G c b
Active Regulation + Participatory Supervision + Traditional Production T + φ a b G a b S b a S b c S b a + S b c + φ b a G b R G c T
Active Regulation + Non-Supervision
+Green Transformation
N a + φ a G a γ G c 1 N b F b R G c G c 1 + γ G c 1
Active Regulation + Non-Supervision
+Traditional Production
T + φ a G a F b R G c T
Passive Regulation + Participatory Supervision + Green Transformation N a F a φ b G b + N b R G c G c b
Passive Regulation + Participatory Supervision + Traditional Production F a E φ b G b R G c
Passive Regulation + Non-Supervision
+Green Transformation
N a N b R G c G c 1
Passive Regulation + Non-Supervision
+Traditional Production
E 0 R G c
Table 3. Equilibrium point stability analysis.
Table 3. Equilibrium point stability analysis.
Equilibrium PointsJacobian Matrix EigenvaluesStability Conclusions
λ 1 , λ 2 , λ 3 Real Part Signs
E1(0,0,0) φ b G b , G c 1 , E G a + φ a + T (+,−,+)Instability point
E2(1,0,0) T G c 1 + γ G c 1 , G a E φ a T , F b G b + φ b a + S b a + S b c (×,−,+)Instability point
E3(0,1,0) G b φ b , G c b , E + F a G a b + φ a b S b a S b c + T (−,−,+)Instability point
E4(0,0,1) G c 1 , φ b G b , φ a G a + γ G c 1 (−,+,+)Instability point
E5(1,1,0) T G c b + γ G c b , G b F b φ b a S b a S b c , G a b F a E φ a b + S b a + S b c T (×,−,−)Potential ESS
E6(1,0,1) G a φ a γ G c 1 , G c 1 T γ G c 1 , F b G b + φ b a + S b a (−,×,+)Instability point
E7(0,1,1) G c b , G b φ b , F a G a b + φ a b S b a + 2 γ G c 1 γ G c b (+,−,×)Instability point
E8(1,1,1) G c b T γ G c b , G b F b φ b a S b a , G a b F a φ a b + S b a + 2 γ G c 1 + γ G c b (×,−,×)Potential ESS
Note: "+" indicates that the system is unstable in that direction; a "−" indicates that the system tends to be stable in that direction; "×" indicates uncertainty in the signs.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Shui, W.; Song, W. Evolutionary Game Analysis of Customs Supervision Mechanisms for Sustainable Green Port Development. Sustainability 2025, 17, 5470. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17125470

AMA Style

Shui W, Song W. Evolutionary Game Analysis of Customs Supervision Mechanisms for Sustainable Green Port Development. Sustainability. 2025; 17(12):5470. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17125470

Chicago/Turabian Style

Shui, Wenbing, and Wenhui Song. 2025. "Evolutionary Game Analysis of Customs Supervision Mechanisms for Sustainable Green Port Development" Sustainability 17, no. 12: 5470. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17125470

APA Style

Shui, W., & Song, W. (2025). Evolutionary Game Analysis of Customs Supervision Mechanisms for Sustainable Green Port Development. Sustainability, 17(12), 5470. https://doi.org/10.3390/su17125470

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop