1. Introduction
Traditional energy systems are planned and operated independently, with low energy efficiency and serious resource waste [
1]. With the increasing depletion of traditional fossil energy sources, the development of multiple energy complementary technologies to improve energy efficiency has become urgent [
2]. In the context of carbon neutrality goals, integrated energy systems are one of the typical applications of multi-energy coupling to improve energy efficiency [
3]. The grid integration of distributed renewable energy sources, including photovoltaic and wind power, has grown significantly in recent years [
4]. However, the inherent variability and uncertainty of renewable energy sources bring new challenges to the safe and stable operation of power systems [
5]. Therefore, there is an urgent need to find a feasible method to effectively integrate regional flexible resources, match the renewable energy output, and support the dynamic and balanced operation of the new power system.
Integrated energy systems optimize the scheduling of regional flexible resources by complementing multiple energy sources to effectively respond to the production of renewable energy sources, while their application has become an inevitable trend. With the development of technologies such as Combined Heat and Power (CHP) and Concentrated Solar Thermal Power (CSP), the use of CHP technology to provide energy is a sustainable and economical strategy to reduce fuel consumption [
6]. Many studies have decoupled the electro-thermal characteristics of CHP by coupling the system with thermal energy storage (TES), electric boiler (EB), or both to improve the flexibility of CHP [
7]. Li [
8] proposes a hybrid CSP-CHP energy flow framework to provide additional operational flexibility for renewable energy sources in an integrated energy system (IES). Generating electricity with hybrid CHP-CSP can reduce wind abandonment compared to other renewable energy generation [
9]. The configuration plays a crucially important role in the improvement of energy efficiency, flexibility and sustainability of the IES [
10]. Therefore, improving the primary energy utilization and renewable energy flexibility in IES and further reducing the primary consumption of energy in the system is the focus of this paper.
Operation optimization is an important technical support for IES practice, and for the IES energy complementary optimal scheduling problem, Liu [
11] uses an enhanced Wasserstein deep convolution generative adversarial network with gradient penalty to simulate extreme scenarios and analyze the impact of source-load correlation on the IES economy with respect to source-load uncertainty. Peng [
12] proposed an exergoeconomic optimization scheduling method for the IES based on a novel performance indicator, namely, the specific exergy cost, in response to the challenge that traditional scheduling methods can hardly coexist by considering only the operational efficiency or economic performance. When faced with a large number of electric vehicle charge stations (EVCS) joining the construction and use of IESs, there are computationally complex problems of inter-feeding with the grid, system stability, revenue and environmental pollution between EVCS and IESs [
13]. To solve this, Fang [
14] using improved NSGA-III algorithm combined with fuzzy evaluation, Liao [
15] proposes a future value competition strategy for wind and photovoltaic allocation based on goal optimization, Liu [
16] proposes a Multi-Objective Sand Cat Swarm Optimization Algorithm based on a mutation-dominated selection strategy, Yin [
17] proposes a Many-objective Stochastic Competition Optimization algorithm, Wang [
18] introduced an improved moth-flame optimization algorithm.
However, with the continuous and in-depth study of IES, the elements of the system’s internal subject optimization and participation in external energy interactions are becoming more and more complex, which puts forward new requirements for the development of IES in the energy market environment. Game theory is a key technology that can help achieve regional resource integration and dispatch optimization and support the operation of new power systems [
19]. Li [
20] considers a Stackelberg game energy optimization scheduling framework that balances the interests of operators and users under integrated energy demand response and renewable energy generation uncertainty conditions. Wang [
21] developed a Stackelberg game model based on energy pre-transaction behavior between energy service providers and users. Wang [
22] established a Stackelberg game model based on the one-master-multiple-slave to maximize the profit of integrated energy operators and minimize the cost of distributed integrated energy. Zhang [
23] developed a two-layer Stackelberg game model for integrated energy operators with IESs and integrated energy operators with IESs. Li [
24] established an urban community energy optimization model for city managers and community operators based on master-slave game theory. Tan [
25] developed a one-master-many-slave Stackelberg game model with a regional energy operator as the leader, building producers and distributors and electric vehicle aggregators as the followers. However, since the energy operator or the master network has a monopoly on IES, most of the previous studies that take advantage of this feature use the leader-follower framework to construct the model, but this also puts the followers in a disadvantageous position, which in turn harms their interests.
To motivate followers to participate in the above mutual feedforward process with increased flexibility, it is necessary to coordinate and avoid conflicts of interest, which can be compensated by game theory. Tan [
26] developed a cooperative game model for IES-HGESS and designed a revenue-sharing strategy to stabilize long-term cooperation. Wang [
27] established a Nash game-based energy trading model by studying the benefits of cooperation between IES and electric vehicle charge stations. Shi [
28] proposed an electricity-hydrogen-heat IES cluster energy scheduling mechanism based on the consideration of peer-to-peer (P2P) electricity and heat transactions between production and sales users. Yang [
29] introduced Stackelberg theory and cooperative game theory to establish a two-level game optimal scheduling model for supply and demand equilibrium, respectively. Wang [
30] established an IES cooperative game model based on cooperative game theory to minimize carbon emissions and cost. Although the above studies have fully explored the flexible potential of IES in managing regional grids, there are still fewer distributed energy demand response (DR) strategy studies. The installation of renewable energy in the local grid transforms from a traditional electricity consumer to a producer and seller (prosumer, producer and consumer), which makes it challenging to coordinate the producer and seller with the operator while reducing the impact on the local grid [
31]. Kotowicz [
32] proposes the concept of integrated residential energy systems with rooftop PV as a prosumer, and they can change, to some extent, the consumption patterns of the residential users themselves. Jiang [
33] proposes a cooperative model between PV producers and sellers and community energy managers based on Nash bargaining. Kuehnbach [
34] establishes a framework for considering households as producers and sellers in local energy markets. In addition to renewable energy sources, producers and sellers, represented by distributed battery storage systems, are a key part of IES flexibility [
35]. Zhang [
36] investigated a shared energy storage system (SESS) through P2P with a multi-user trading mechanism and modeled a multi-player cooperative game to ensure the distribution of reasonable benefits among the participating parties. Ding [
37] established a cooperative game model to collect electricity-heat-hydrogen multi-energy transactions by taking the hydrogen energy generated at the load side as the transaction object. Therefore, it is especially critical to establish an appropriate Stackelberg game model to improve the flexibility of IES and prosumers.
Li [
38] proposes a one-master-multiple-slave multi-intelligentsia game operation strategy for energy retailers, suppliers, and users considering demand response and incorporating a non-cooperative game among energy suppliers. Li [
39] developed a non-cooperative game model between coupled electricity-heat producers and sellers, taking into account the impact of renewable energy uncertainty on the total cost and verified the effectiveness of the model optimization approach in reducing the consumption cost while increasing the renewable energy penetration. Chen [
40] proposes a pre-day cooperative game model for SESS in regional IES and converts it into a two-step optimization problem with a profit-maximizing scheduling strategy for cooperative alliances and an optimal pricing strategy for SESS. Since each member in the alliance of prosumers (APs) belongs to different stakeholders and rationally pursues the minimization of their respective energy purchase costs, there is a need to ensure the fairness of transactions and promote the balance between electricity supply and demand. Therefore, power sharing among APs can be regarded as a cooperative game problem. Chen [
41] investigated the cooperative surplus allocation mechanism based on the asymmetric Nash bargaining theory and established a cooperative model for P2P energy trading based on Nash bargaining, which can effectively balance the individual and overall costs of members after cooperation. However, the above studies either only consider the competitive relationship between IESs and APs or only consider the potential for APs to cooperate without seeking cooperation in the context of competition and are unable to further explore the impact of cooperation on their benefits when the producers and sellers are in the situation of being monopolized by IESs. In response to the complex problem of coordination and optimization among subjects of interest., Liu [
42] constructed a novel two-layer energy dispatching and collaborative optimization model for a regional integrated energy system considering stakeholders game and flexible load management based on the master-slave game. Li [
43] proposes the three-layer Nash-Stackelberg-Nash mixed game model for the IES operator and energy prosumer. Therefore, in addition to constructing SESS-IES and IES-APs as two Stackelberg games, this paper also embeds the Nash game between different producers and sellers, thus forming a Stackelberg-Stackelberg-Nash three-layer game in
Table 1, a comparison of key technologies with previous literature is given.
The main innovations and contributions of this paper are mainly in the following three aspects.
An integrated SESS-IES-Prosumers energy dispatch model is developed. The model takes into account WT, PV generation uncertainty, and CHP-CSP cooperation and describes the actual operation mechanisms of SESS, IES, and different prosumer energy scheduling. In addition, the potential for utilizing waste heat recovery to improve natural gas utilization is presented.
In response to the fact that the above SESS-IES-Prosumers model needs to simultaneously consider the self-interests of each independent subject, convey energy price information, and reach a feasible solution for energy trading, a three-layer Stackelberg-Stackelberg-Nash game framework with embedded power sharing among multiple prosumers is proposed for Nash bargaining.
The three-layer game framework proposed in this paper leads to the following conclusions: the study case can reduce the natural gas loss by 9.32% and the total energy purchase cost of APs by 12.16% under the premise of guaranteeing the interests of each subject and ultimately achieve the source, storage, load multi-interested subjects sustainability co-optimization and mutual benefit and benefit.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 establishes a three-layer master-slave game model of SESS-IES-APs based on the Stackelberg game and establishes a method for distributing the revenues after the cooperation of different prosumers in the lower-layer APs;
Section 3 describes the solution method based on this three-layer game model;
Section 4 gives the results of the arithmetic example simulation and the analysis; and
Section 5 sums up the whole paper and gives an outlook on the next direction of the research.
4. Simulation Experiment and Comparison
In this section, the reasonableness of the proposed model is verified through arithmetic simulations on a computer equipped with a 3.1 GHz Intel Core i5 and 16 GB of RAM. The arithmetic simulation is performed using the MATLAB R2021b platform using Yalmip (
https://yalmip.github.io/) to invoke the Gurobi solver 11.0.3 (Gurobi Optimization, 2022) and solve the model using the dichotomous method combined with ADMM. References [
13,
14,
15,
16,
17,
18] set the simulation parameters, and the energy prices for each period are shown in
Table 2, and the parameters used in the SESS-IES-APs three-layer hybrid game model are listed in
Table 3,
Table 4 and
Table 5, including each unit of equipment. In addition, each electric and thermal energy input/demand in the simulation experiment is shown in
Figure A1a–d in
Appendix A.
Since whether the lower-level prosumers involve electricity and heat energy DR and whether cooperative alliances are formed among prosumers are important factors affecting the prosumer’s costs, they are also key to directly affecting the outcome of the benefits of the upper-level game players. Therefore, this paper sets up the following four different scenarios and compares and analyzes the optimization results in
Section 4.1 and
Section 4.2.
Scenario 1: DR of APs is not considered, and cooperative game of APs is not considered.
Scenario 2: DR of APs is not considered, but cooperative game of APs is considered.
Scenario 3: DR of APs is considered, but cooperative game of APs is not considered.
Scenario 4: Consider the DR of APs and consider the cooperative game of APs.
4.1. Analysis of the Results of Energy Optimization Scheduling
In this section, the impacts of different scenarios on the optimal energy scheduling results of the SESS-IES-APs three-tier subject energy optimization are investigated, including the SESS charging and discharging strategy, the IES intra-unit inter-unit scheduling strategy, and the prosumer energy consumption strategy.
Compared with Scenario 1, the cooperative alliance between prosumers in Scenario 2 can theoretically provide more flexible energy scheduling strategies for subjects at all levels. In
Figure 5a, due to the dual influence of grid time-of-day tariffs and IES energy purchase and sale strategies, the SESS can purchase electricity as a reserve when the IES residual energy is sufficient and sell it to the grid during peak periods (11:00–14:00; 18:00–20:00). In
Figure 5b,c, the total electrical and thermal energy load profiles of the APs are the same before and after optimization because they do not consider the energy demand side response. Since the CSP has a large supply of concentrating heat energy in the 07:00–17:00 time period, a part of it is transferred to the TES to be used as a thermal energy reserve, and the high tariff period set by the SESS is in the 9:00–15:00 time period, at this time, the extra output energy from the CHP and the CSP is converted to electrical energy output to compensate for the electrical energy demand; in the 16:00–20:00 time period which is still a high tariff period, the APs’ larger electric load demand, and at this time GB and CHP output is limited, TES in CSP will produce heat or convert it to electric energy output to compensate for electric energy demand, thus improving the economic efficiency of IES. Compared to
Figure 5b,c and
Figure 6b,c, the total energy consumption demand remains the same despite the presence of inter-prosumer power sharing. Compared to Scenario 2, the prosumer energy DR is considered in Scenario 3, providing a more flexible energy consumption strategy. Comparing
Figure 6a and
Figure 7a, SESS no longer provides power to IES during peak power periods (18:00–20:00) and sells surplus energy directly to the grid. Comparing
Figure 6b,c and
Figure 7b,c, there is a significant change in the energy consumption of the APs, with the largest period of decrease in electrical energy demand being 647.16 kw from 19:00 to 20:00 and the largest period of decrease in thermal energy demand being 294.696 kw from 13:00 to 14:00. In addition, the largest increase in electrical energy demand is 260.14 kw (23:00–24:00), which needs to further explore the effect of adding electrical energy sharing among prosumers on the energy scheduling results.
Compared to
Figure 7a and
Figure 8a, the maximum reduction of power purchase from SESS by IES is 149.51 kw (1:00–2:00) due to the further decrease of power needed by IES to satisfy APs. Comparing with
Figure 7b,c and
Figure 8b,c, the maximum decrease of APs power demand is 166.658 kw (13:00–14:00), and the maximum increase of power demand is 263.17 kw (9:00–10:00), which verifies the validity of the inter-prosumer power-sharing energy on the reduction of its own energy consumption cost. In addition, as AP’s electric demand side response and inter-member electric energy sharing are considered, the amount of electricity that IES needs to satisfy under different periods of the SESS tariff is further adjusted. In the 1:00–4:00 h, the electricity demand is increased by 30.5 kw, 89.18 kw, and 118.92 kw, respectively, and at this time, the portion of electricity that could have been available for ESS to be used as an electric energy reserve is used to compensate for the adjusted increase in the demand for electric energy. During the 9:00–10:00 h, due to the 263.17 kw increase in adjusted load, CHP increased its generation output from 236.829 kw to 500 kw to meet the additional load demand. During the 13:00–14:00 h, due to a decrease in electrical load demand of 167.658 kw, the CHP is reduced from 128.022 kw to 47.582 kw, and the CSP is reduced from 250 kw to 163.782 kw. Similarly, the IES does not need to purchase electrical energy from the SESS during the non-valley hours of 8:00–23:00 to compensate for the load, and in turn, during the 10:00–10:00 h, it does not need to purchase electrical energy from the SESS to pay for the load. Similarly, IES is not required to purchase power from SESS during the off-valley hours of 8:00–23:00 to compensate for the load and, in turn, utilizes the output of ESS, CHP, and CSP during the hours of 10:00–14:00 and sells it to SESS for profit. And the thermal output is reduced from 192.034 kw to 71.3726 kw. It is worth noting that compared with Scenario 1, the IES daily natural gas losses in Scenario 4 are reduced by 9.32%.
4.2. Analysis of Economic Performance Results
In this section, the economics of each subject after optimal scheduling of SESS-IES-APs under different scenarios are investigated. The cost information of the operation results under different scenarios is shown in
Table 6, and the cost comparison before and after prosumers’ cooperation is shown in
Table 7, where positive values indicate costs and negative values indicate benefits. Finally, in this paper, ADMM combined with a distributed algorithm is used to solve the subproblem
, the penalty factor is set to 100, the convergence accuracy is set to 0.001, and the results are shown in
Figure 9a,b.
Observing
Table 6, it can be seen that the SESS gain decreases significantly, which is due to the indirect influence of the lowest level prosumer by changing its energy consumption strategy, but still manages to maintain high economics due to its highest position. However, compared with Scenario 1, IES gains in Scenario 4 are instead boosted by 604.931, which is because the prosumer, by changing its energy consumption strategy, makes the combined cost of the APs lower by 4171.938 at the same time as the IES gradually reduces the amount of power purchased when the SESS sets a high price. Observing
Table 7 shows that whether or not the DR of the prosumer is taken into account, its post-cooperation integrated cost is always lower than the original purchased energy cost before the cooperation, but when comparing Scenario 4 with Scenario 1 in combination with
Table 6, the integrated purchased energy cost of APs is reduced by 12.16%.
Observing
Figure 9a, the electricity sharing tariffs among Prosumer 1–2, Prosumer 1–3, and Prosumer 2–3 fluctuate within the intervals of [0.2195–0.2715], [0.2083–0.4832], [0.2041–0.4011], respectively, which satisfy the constraint intervals set in this paper. Observing
Figure 9b, the algorithm converges after 38 iterations of solving, with Prosumer 1 converging to −868.734 from the initial −261.995, Prosumer 2 converging to −980.856 from the initial −470.849, and Prosumer3 converging to 1848.71 from the initial 1830.93. Combining
Table 3 and
Table 4, the cost of Prosumer 1 and 2 is significantly lower, although it increases the post-cooperation cost of Prosumer 3, which will be compensated by the bargaining portion redistribution, which ensures that Prosumer 3 will not jeopardize its interest by cooperating.
5. Conclusions
For different energy subjects participating in cooperative optimization scheduling involving conflict of interests, how to meet the possible existence of different hierarchical status relationships, cooperation, and competition, etc., so that the interests of multiple subjects participating in the situation will not be damaged, and to achieve the sustainability of participation in the cooperative optimization, high efficiency of energy utilization, and flexibility of the system scheduling. In this study, a Stackelberg-Stackelberg-Nash three-layer game framework is proposed for use in the three-layer optimal scheduling of SESS-IES-APs under the same distribution network. The energy interactions among the regional grid, SESS, IES, and APs are studied, especially the impact of each prosumer energy consumption strategy in APs on other subjects, and the main conclusions are as follows:
Compared with Scenario 1, the cost of IES energy purchase in Scenarios 3 and 4 is reduced by 4.94% and 3.95%. At this time, IES reduces natural gas consumption by 9.32% after considering certain scenery output uncertainty and adopting CHP-CSP synergistic operation used to realize X2P. TES saves waste heat while gas is powered and uses ST to generate electricity at night when there is excess heat and insufficient electricity, which verifies the validity of the three-layer optimization model proposed in this paper.
Comparing the simulation results of APs’ energy purchase cost in scenarios 4 and 1, prosumer 1, 2, and 3 reduce their own energy purchase cost by 11.61%, 12.1%, and 12.7%, respectively, and the total energy purchase cost of APs is reduced by 12.16% when considering the cooperation between DR and other prosumers. It is verified that the producers and sellers in the master-slave game framework can further reduce the cost of purchasing energy when they are in the monopolized position by realizing the power-sharing among members to explore cooperation and adjusting the energy consumption strategy by utilizing their energy DR.
This paper provides methodological support for the application of CHP-CSP and producers and sellers to optimize the operation of IES in the future. In addition, the IES model in this paper does not consider the impact of low carbon emissions and P2G on IES energy optimization and economic efficiency. Therefore, in future work, we aim to further explore the enhancement of IES benefits by multi-energy complementarity.