Next Article in Journal
Carbon-Supported Nickel Catalysts—Comparison in Alpha-Pinene Oxidation Activity
Previous Article in Journal
When Do You Enter? Entrepreneurial Firms’ Entry Timing and Product Performance in the Digital Platform Market
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Economic Rationale for Manifestations of Asymmetry in the Global Trading System

1
Permanent Mission of Ukraine to the United Nations Office and other International Organizations in Geneva, 1202 Geneva, Switzerland
2
International Trade and Marketing Department, Kyiv National Economic University Named after Vadym Hetman, 03057 Kyiv, Ukraine
3
Mathematical Modeling and Statistics Department, Kyiv National Economic University Named after Vadym Hetman, 03057 Kyiv, Ukraine
4
Entrepreneurship and Marketing Department, Ivano-Frankivsk National Technical Oil and Gas University, 76019 Ivano-Frankivsk, Ukraine
5
Faculty of Business Management, Vilnius Gediminas Technical University, 10223 Vilnius, Lithuania
6
Laboratory of Energy Systems Research, Lithuanian Energy Institute, 44403 Kaunas, Lithuania
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(6), 5316; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065316
Submission received: 28 November 2022 / Revised: 12 March 2023 / Accepted: 13 March 2023 / Published: 16 March 2023

Abstract

:
The interconnected global trading system has proved to be both vulnerable and resistant to crises, despite its asymmetries. The global trading system is constantly changing under the influence of such factors as the digitalization of economic processes and the growing number of nontariff measures to regulate trade volumes, including trade protection measures introduced by countries in order to ensure national economic interests etc. This article analyzes the impact of the tariff and nontariff instruments of export and import regulation on the asymmetries of the global trading system across countries and separate customs territories, depending on their presence in geographical regions or groups of countries associated with different levels of economic development. In order to quantify the possible asymmetries in the global trading system, analysis of variance and regression analysis are applied to explain the variance in the volume of global trade. The regression models for the dependence of export volumes on a number of trade indicators are fitted for developed, developing, and least-developed countries alongside the global trading system as a whole. The research showed that asymmetries of the global trading system exist on the global, regional and bilateral levels. In this research, two types of asymmetries are discussed: asymmetry directly and indirectly linked to international trade processes. To ensure economic development, the global trading system must be modernized so as to reduce the asymmetry. Accordingly, in order to increase effectiveness of the World Trade Organization, suggestions are proposed in regards to reconsidering trade-dispute settling, improving the monitoring of members’ obligations, increasing negotiation process efficiency and defining criteria for categorizing members according to their economic development.

1. Introduction

Permanent aggravation of economic fragility, an increase in inequality in society, exacerbation of ecological problems, rise of political uncertainty and geopolitical tension raise the risks of crises of different natures around the world. As a rule, these risks are considered separately; however, they can interact and create cascade risks and disturbances to the environment, the economy and society, as well as cause a great number of social and ecological problems and considerable economic losses. Healthcare and economic crises caused by the pandemic have become major stress tests for the global trading system, causing unprecedented shocks to global supply chains and trade relations between countries. Nevertheless, the global trading system has proven to be steady. The global trading system has been, and continues to be, a source of flexibility and diversification and a major mechanism during the pandemic and other crises, helping countries to cope with them by simplifying access to vital goods and foods and supporting their economic recoveries. The interconnected global trading system has appeared to be both vulnerable and resistant to crises, although it has a big number of asymmetries and, as a rule, economic failures on the global scale mostly affect developing countries, particularly least-developed countries rather than developed economies.
Transformation of the trading system is taking place at an accelerated pace due to the comprehensive digitalization of economic processes. In particular, this includes the introduction of paperless trade; the spread of electronic payment systems; the growth of trade in digital products; the globalization of all trade aspects, which, in turn, expands the range of subjects of such a system; the comprehensive liberalization of trade, which coexists with the use of neoprotectionist tools for regulating foreign trade volumes by a number of countries, etc.
Against this background, the number of regional trade agreements concluded by countries and separate customs territories with different levels of economic development from all regions of the world is growing exponentially [1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8]. In such a case, there is not only a deepening of existing asymmetries, but also the emergence of new ones in the global trading system [9,10,11,12,13]. Under the current circumstances, the decline in the effectiveness of the functioning of the World Trade Organization signalizes the need for an urgent response from all system participants to the challenges of the 21st century, with the aim of developing current rules for world trade, taking into account all possible scenarios of the development of the trading system [14,15,16,17].
The transformation of the processes of international trade integration leads to the emergence of new trading systems [18,19,20,21], which can cause economic risks for the functioning of existing ones and changes in the structure of the world trade [22,23].
The interwar experience of beggar-thy-neighbor protectionism and the control over capital that was introduced by governments that sought to stimulate domestic economic activity and employment level has become the genesis of a multilateral trading system [24]. Its further evolution was caused by the introduction of the two trade-policy principles of reciprocity and nondiscrimination, which set a foundation for comprehensive trade liberalization. Implementing these principles let countries overcome historically rooted distrust for each other and make a deal to mutually and beneficially decrease tariff barriers. Mutuality manifested in making equivalent concessions, and it soothed governments’ fears of receiving less-favored regimes from other countries than the one they themselves provided to their trade partners, while nondiscrimination contributed to assuring countries’ governments that they would use the regime along with other rival countries. Neither of the principles became a sudden intellectual invention, as these notions had already been commonly known in international law. However, their implementation in the trading system was quite an innovative decision, which substantially boosted the strengthening of global trade liberalization [25,26].
According to Robert Keohane, currently, multilateralism is considered to be a partnership of all leading countries when making the most important decisions, which are based on commonly accepted norms, rules and principles, which direct and regulate interstate behavior [27]. However, considering modern tendencies, experts and scientists have gradually started using the global trading system as a research object within the concept of system multilateralism. Therefore, according to Christopher Chase-Dunn, Yukio Kawano and Benjamin Brewer, trade globalization refers to the degree to which long-distance goods exchange and global volume increased (or decreased) with regard to goods exchange in national societies [28].
According to experts of the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD), the following can be considered as global trading system components: trade agreements, trade negotiations, regional integration, challenges that arise before developing countries in the international trading system and entrance into the World Trade Organization (WTO) by new members [29].
Using the results from studying approaches to interpret the notion, in the research, the global trading system is defined as a multicomponent and multilateral system of international trade regulation, which is global in its number of members, volume of regulated export, coverage of trade spheres and integrated goal. Three stages of forming such a system have been distinguished: latent, active and modern, with the second one being the most efficient in forming variable rules of international trade in their coverage sphere.
Currently, the system regulatory framework includes 23 multilateral trade agreements, with a limited or unlimited number of parties, 349 effective regional trade agreements, 36 preferential trade agreements, a number of typical UNCITRAL laws, etc.
Based on the foregoing, the objective of the article is to study the impact of the use of tariff and nontariff export and import regulation tools by countries and separate customs territories on the asymmetries of the global trading system, depending on their belonging to a certain geographical region or group of countries with a certain level of economic development.
The object of the study is the transformation process of the global trading system within the conditions of global economic instability. The subject of the study is the asymmetries of the global trading system development, their manifestation, measurements, impacting factors and mechanisms for reaching balance.
In order to reach the set goal, it was vital to solve the following research tasks: the first task was to identify and systematize the existing asymmetries of the global trading system; the second was to investigate the impact of the use of tariff and nontariff tools of export and import regulation by countries and separate customs territories, depending on their belonging to a certain geographical region or group of countries with a certain level of economic development, on the asymmetries of the global trading system; the third, based on the methods of economic and mathematic modeling, was to distinguish the most substantial factors impacting the development of the global trading system; the fourth was to develop recommendations for improving normative and procedure principles of the World Trade Organization’s functioning, corresponding to modern realia.
Within the study, analysis of variance (ANOVA) of the following indices has been carried out: RTA, global export and import of products in 2020, the number of trade disputes within the WTO, general number of nontariff measures regulating trade in countries, as well as the number of tied tariff lines, average tied and PT duty rates and analogous indices for agricultural and nonagricultural products. One-way analysis was carried out for each index using ANOVA and Fisher’s test. Pairwise differences were tested with Tukey’s test, and regression equations for each country group were made.
The major contribution of the article is seen in a complex analysis, distinguishing and mathematically proving and grounding the existence of asymmetries of the global trading system as a subsystem of the global trading economic system, which exist on the global, regional and international levels; the systematization of the asymmetries was conducted by dividing them into two key groups: asymmetries directly linked to international trade processes and asymmetries indirectly linked to international trade processes. It has been grounded in the research that, in order to provide greater economic sustainability of countries and customs territories, the global trading system must be modernized. Accordingly, in order to increase the WTO’s functioning efficiency, some suggestions have been made for reconsidering trade-dispute settling, improving monitoring of members’ obligations, increasing negotiation process efficiency and defining the criteria for categorizing members according to their economic development.
Thus, within the framework of this study, the authors singled out the most important factors influencing the development of the global trading system, based on the methods of economic and mathematical modeling.
This study contains several sections: the introduction, followed by the literature review and hypotheses development and the results. The results are divided into three subsections devoted to studying the following issues: firstly, the theoretical basis and determinants of the asymmetries of the global trading system, in particular investigating the modern features of the global trading system and the asymmetries of the global trading system; secondly, analysis of variance of the influence of independent factors on the volume of global trade, in particular investigating the categorization of countries by the level of economic development and the grouping of countries according to location in a specific region; thirdly, econometric analysis of the influence of selected indicators of foreign trade activity on the volume of global exports. The remaining sections cover the novelty of the study and of the results, the discussion and the conclusions.

2. Literature Review and Hypothesis Development

A working hypothesis of the study is the supposition that the global trading system is subject to asymmetry in the development of various natures and the movement of the movement. In order to decrease social pressure, we want to bring that to level ecological dangers, hitches in business and economic losses caused by various shocks, and to secure economic sustainability, it is necessary mainly to level asymmetry influence and reach a balance in the global trading system.
Asymmetry is an objective feature of global economic system processes, which are interconnected and interdependent by their nature. Therefore, it is advisable to inquire into the semantics of the “asymmetry” notion in its general meaning, as well as within the global economic system.
Theoretical bases of emerging and characteristic asymmetries of the global economic system development have become the subject of study of numerous scientists.
The notion of “asymmetry” started to be actively used to refer to the global economic system in 2001; American economists George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz received the Nobel Prize for developing a theory and analyzing markets with asymmetrical information. According to these scientists, asymmetrical information generates issues of unfavorable decision making and aggravates risks [30,31].
Borts, Siebert and Myrdal identified major reasons for the emergence of socioeconomic development asymmetries, which lie in the disproportionate allocation of production factors among world regions, particularly capital, labor, land and technologies [32,33,34].
Moreover, the correlation of notions of “symmetry”, “asymmetry”, “disproportionality”, “disbalance”, etc., have also become a research object for scientists. Thus, Kravchuk has investigated the casual relationship of such terms: equilibrium (symmetry), asymmetry, disbalance, instability and crisis [35]. On this occasion, Stoliarchuk indicated that, unlike disproportionality, asymmetry possesses a system nature that reflects forms of global economic development and is a motive force of social progress, being a tool of both discovering and solving its contradictions through crises [36]. Therefore, versatile approaches to defining the notion of asymmetry by scientists are presented in Table 1.
The presence of asymmetries in the foreign trade interests of countries and separate customs territories may be determined as an objective feature of the global economy. It is primarily explained by the fact that, in having nominally equal opportunities in access to foreign markets of goods and services, countries and separate customs territories form their trade policies differently and define their directions, in particular, within the context of choosing priority trade partners or “focused on” goods, which are planned to be promoted in chosen markets or even choosing tools for regulating volumes of trade flows. The asymmetry of foreign trade interests of countries manifests in their foreign policy, which is realized as either liberal or protectionist. Thus, for instance, Virkovska and Ivashchuk legitimately consider that asymmetry of foreign trade interests of countries is caused by such external and internal factors as the aggravation of disbalances in international trade, the existence of risks of breaching set agreements or multilateral and bilateral commitments made by countries during negotiations, the violation of the integrity of global institutional structures in international trade, the trade expansion of particular countries (including China) and the breaching of principles of strategic partnership of trading system members, etc. [40].
In this study, the asymmetry of the global trading system is considered to be a trading system development state, which is characterized by the violation of balance in the regulation of trade processes on different levels, by the disproportionality of the trade, investment, informational and human flows distribution, as well as by tools employed by system members, considering differences in economic development level.
The issue of the classification of global economic development asymmetries has become the subject of study of Lukianenko and Stoliarchuk. Thus, they distinguish such major groups of symmetries: economic (particularly trade), financial and investment, production, infrastructural, technological, informational, social, cultural and geopolitical. Moreover, in the above-mentioned study, intercivilization, inter-regional and interstate asymmetries are also distinguished according to their levels [43]. At the same time, Kravchuk divides asymmetries into lateral, structural, functional and dynamic in the study “Global Development Divergency: Modern Paradigm of Geo-Financial Dimension Forming” [38].

3. Methods

In order to obtain mathematical rationale for the existence of the asymmetries outlined in the introductory part, analysis of variance was conducted, which allows one to confirm or refute the hypothesis that different average values of indicators (volumes of world exports and imports, average bound rates of customs duties and rates under the most-favored-nation (MFN) regime, both for agricultural and nonagricultural goods; and the number of regional trade agreements, nontariff trade measures the number of trade disputes) can really be explained by the fact that different countries and separate customs territories belong to different groups according to the level of economic development and by the criterion of geographical affiliation.
That is, in general, the results of the analysis of variance will make it possible to talk about the mathematically confirmed existence of asymmetry in the development of the global trading system and will also make it possible to determine directions for its elimination.
For the purposes of the study, 2 indicators were chosen as independent variables (categorical factors):
  • group_of_countries—groups of countries by the level of economic development (developed, developing and least-developed countries (LDCs) [44,45,46];
  • region—regions of the world (Asia, Africa, the Middle East, Europe, North America, South America and the Caribbean, the CIS).
The following set of indicators will be used as dependent variables:
  • RTAs—number of valid regional trade agreements [47];
  • Import—import of goods in 2020, USD million dollars;
  • Export—export of goods in 2020, USD million dollars [48];
  • Disputes_total—the total number of trade disputes between countries and separate customs territories that were resolved within the framework of the WTO [49];
  • SPS—number of sanitary and phytosanitary measures imposed by countries [50];
  • TBT—number of technical barriers to trade;
  • ADP—number of antidumping measures of countries;
  • CV—number of countervailing (compensatory) measures;
  • SG—number of safeguard measures;
  • SSG—number of special safeguard measures;
  • QR—number of quantitative restrictions introduced by countries;
  • TRQ—the total number of tariff quotas introduced by WTO members;
  • XS—number of export subsidies;
  • non_tarif_total—the total number of nontariff measures regulating the country’s trade volumes [51];
  • tariff_lines—the number of binding tariff lines of the WTO member, %;
  • total_rate_l—average customs duty rate (total, bound), %;
  • total_rate_mfn—average customs duty rate (total, most-favored-nation treatment (MFN)), %;
  • agr_rate_l—average tariff rate on agricultural goods (bound), % (World Bank 2021) [52];
  • agr_rate_mfn—average rate of customs duty on agricultural goods (MFN), %;
  • non_agr_rate_l—average rate of customs duty on nonagricultural goods (bound), %;
  • non_agr_rate_mfn—average rate of customs duty on nonagricultural goods (MFN), %.
In order to study the influence of each independent factor on the dependent variables separately, the one-factor analysis of variance method was used.
Firstly, we propose considering the results of the analysis of variance for the factor group_of_countries—a group of countries by the level of economic development. To do this, the ANOVA is used, which represents the statistical test used to analyze the difference between the average values for more than two groups of indicators. ANOVA determines whether groups formed by different values of a categorical independent variable are statistically different by calculating whether group means differ from the overall mean of the dependent variable. So, for each of the selected indicators, we will put forward two ANOVA hypotheses.
The null hypothesis (H0) of the ANOVA lies in the fact that there is no difference between the group means:
H0: μ1 = μ2 = … = μp,
that is, the average value of the selected indicator will not depend on which group by level of development or which region the country belongs to.
The alternative hypothesis (Ha) is that at least one group is significantly different from the general average value of the variable:
Ha: μ1 ≠ μ2 or μ1 ≠ μp or μ2 ≠ μp …,
that is, the selected indicator is truly asymmetric, and its average value directly depends on whether a country or a separate customs territory belongs to a group by level of development or a specific region of the world.
The ANOVA function uses the F-test (Fisher’s test), which allows for comparing multiple groups at once. The error is calculated for the entire set of comparisons, rather than for each separate two-sided comparison, as would be the case with the t-test (Student’s test). The F-statistic is calculated by the formula:
F = M S T R M S E
where MSTR and MSE are intergroup and intragroup variances, respectively. At the same time, the intergroup variance is calculated according to the formula:
M S T R = i n i ( X i ¯ X ¯ ) 2 k 1
and intragroup variance is calculated by the formula:
M S E = i j ( X i j X i ¯ ) 2 n k
where X i _ is the average value of the indicator X in group i, X _ is the average value of the X indicator, X i j is j-th value of indicator X in group i, n is total number of observations, n i is the number of observations in the group i, and k is the number of groups [53].
The null hypothesis (H0) is rejected if the calculated F-statistic is greater than the critical F-statistic (p-value ≤ 0.05). The critical F-statistic is determined by the degrees of freedom and the alpha value.

4. Theoretical Approach to Determinants of the Asymmetries of the Global Trading System

4.1. Modern Features of the Global Trading System

Attempts to start a trade organization gained momentum when the United States additionally proposed it for the UN’s consideration. This proposition led to passing the United Nations Economic and Social Council (ECOSOC) Resolution in February 1946 [46], calling to hold a conference to write the charter of the World Trade Organization. Thus, in 1946, a preparatory committee was created, and it started working on the charter of the future organization. The preparatory committee worked in Geneva till November 1947, but the charter was only completed in 1948 [26]. In 1947, GATT was negotiated, and it immediately gained its validity.
Although GATT was supposed to be added to the organization’s charter, it appeared to be impossible, and even after the charter was finally concluded in Havana in March 1948, it never gained its validity [26]. Therefore, in 1947, GATT was the only existing international document on trade relation issues. It was designed as a multilateral agreement on decreasing tariffs and was supposed to be eventually turned into an international organization.
Cardinal system transformation started from the Uruguay round of multilateral trade talks. In the Declaration Punta-del-Este, countries implicitly recognized the necessity to institutionally reform the GATT system [54]. In April 1990, Canada officially proposed founding the World Trade Organization, which would monitor various legal documents concerning international trade that were developed within the current negotiations [55]. In July 1990, the European community suggested creating effective institutional frames for GATT in order to provide efficient implementation of the Uruguay round results [56]. In 1991, the European community, Canada and Mexico prepared a joint proposal that served as a base for further negotiations, which led to writing a project of the agreement on creating a multilateral trade organization. This agreement was a part of the 1991 Final Act project, which embodied the results of Uruguay round.
The agreement for founding the World Trade Organization was finally signed in Marrakesh, in April 1994, and gained its validity on 1 January 1995. The universal significance of the Marrakesh agreement is stated in point 4 of its preamble, where the members normatively determined the intent “to develop an integrated, more viable and durable multilateral trading system encompassing the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, the results of past trade liberalization efforts, and all of the results of the Uruguay Round of Multilateral Trade Negotiations” [57].
The subject structure of the global trading system has been gradually broadening during its whole transformation period. Moreover, it is featured with both close cooperation among key players and institutions in the trading sphere and continuous contact with other subjects of the global economic system. Therefore, it is reasonable to distinguish such subjects of the global economic system on the current stage of the global trade development (Figure 1), which form tendencies, react against global challenges and determine major vectors of its evolution by their activity.
International economic organizations play a major role in the standard regulation of cross-border trade processes and in monitoring compliance with these generally accepted rules.
A central key subject of the global trading system is the World Trade Organization, the only international organization that deals with global trading rules among countries and separate customs territories [58]. As it has been mentioned, the organization in its current state started functioning in 1995, “with a view to raising standards of living, ensuring full employment and a large and steadily growing volume of real income and effective demand, and expanding the production of and trade in goods and services, while allowing for the optimal use of the world’s resources in accordance with the objective of sustainable development, seeking both to protect and preserve the environment and to enhance the means for doing so in a manner consistent with their respective needs and concerns at different levels of economic development” [57].
The agreement for founding the WTO defines five major functions that fully ensure adherence to the principles of the global trading system: nondiscrimination in trade (mutual provision of preferential treatment (PT) in trade and provision of national treatment to goods, services and intellectual property products originating abroad), regulation of trade (mostly by tariff methods), decrease or minimization of the implementation of quantitative and other limiting measures, transparency of trade policies of members and settling trade disputes by consulting, negotiations, etc.
Researching the features of the global trading system, seven key features may be distinguished, particularly hyperglobalization, which lies in the rapid intensification of trade integration, dematerialization of globalization, which highlights the significance of cross-border trade in service sphere, democratic globalization, which means a high level of openness of national markets, cross-globalization, which derives from similarity between North–South trade and investment torrents and torrents with other directions, upturn of a megatrader (China), ultrafast spreading of regional trade agreements and the approaching era of megaregional agreements, as well as a decrease in barriers in product trade under conditions of keeping high barriers in service trade.
Therefore, if the existing global trading system is observed as a system of rules and legal norms that regulate modern cross-border trade processes in multilateral, regional and bilateral dimensions, it will look as follows (Figure 2).
According to Figure 2, WTO system agreements and regional trade agreements are key components of the system. The legal base of the WTO system contains the agreement for founding the World Trade Organization (Marrakesh Agreement), signed in January 1995, which defines the basic foundations for the organization’s functioning (aims, principles, functions, content, management, etc.) and addenda to it. Among the addenda, so-called “umbrella” agreements are distinguished; they regulate international goods trading (General Agreement on Tarrifs and Trade—GATT [54]), service trading (General Agreement on Trade in Services—GATS [59]) and intellectual property products trading (Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights—TRIPS [60]).
There are numerous explanations for why the broadening of the global trade has visually become slower, from short-term cyclic influences such as continuous influence of a financial crisis on the demand level, to more long-term structural changes such as a slow-down of supply chain extensions. At the same time, one argument that has been paid little attention may be distinguished—a rapid transformation of the global trade itself and the inability of the existing system to cope with the modern blurring of trade boundaries. Although the global trading system has proved to be highly successful in opening goods and raw materials trading and thus prompting globalization in the 20th century, it was much less successful in opening markets for trading services and software products or cross-border transfer of data torrents, which are commonly recognized as globalization drivers in the 21st century.
The key idea is that global trade integration has not been completed. On the contrary, vivid signs of the inception of a completely new globalization stage are being seen, as well as the signs that a search of innovative ways to develop and promote global trading cooperation and management in the future, such as in the past, will be a key feature of the diversification of trade development directions, a decrease in poverty level and boost in economic growth [61].

4.2. Asymmetries of the Global Trading System

The research results established that asymmetry in trade and tools, which are used to regulate its volume, is observed between countries and separate customs territories that are located in geographically different regions (inter-regional) and groups of countries depending on their economic development (interstate). Moreover, all asymmetries characterized in the study should be divided into two groups—those that are directly linked to the trade process and those that are indirectly linked to some of its aspects. The following types of asymmetries have been distinguished for the sake of the research (Figure 3).
To be precise, in this research, global trading system asymmetries have been analyzed and systematized by being divided into two key groups—asymmetries that are directly linked to international trade processes (asymmetries in goods trading, caused by differences between levels of customs tariffs of countries and the number and variety of implemented nontariff measures of trade volume regulation, including the following trade protection measures: antidumping, compensational and special; in the degree of involvement of countries and separate customs territories in settling trade disputes; asymmetries in service trading that derive from differences between levels of specific commitments of countries to liberalize access to service markets) and asymmetries that are indirectly linked to international trade processes (technological and infrastructural, gender, informational, according to subjectivity and particularly considering the growing role of micro-, small and middle-sized enterprises in the export activity of countries).
In order to analyze regional asymmetries in trade, it is suggested to consider the division of countries into seven regions: Africa, Asia, CIS, Europe, Near East, North and Central America and South America and the Caribbean. Therefore, for the sake of the research, the values of all analyzed indices have been independently calculated for subject groups that are divided into world regions and economic development level groups. Data on Ukraine indicates that it is in the Europe geographic region and in the developing-countries group.
It has been found that in 2020, two out of seven world regions accounted for over 70% of the global goods and services export volume, particularly Asia (38.57%) and Europe (37.55%), while the export of the African group was under 2% and export of South America and the Caribbean (30 countries) was only 3%. The group of developed countries exported over 62% of the whole volume, while the fraction of the least-developed countries accounted for less than 1%.
It has also been established that five out of seven world regions tied the level of customs rates for over 94% of tariff lines listed in the plan of members’ concessions. The unprecedented number of tariff lines tied at 100% was demonstrated by the CIS countries, which is explained by the fact that they all belong to the so-called RAMs group. Similar commitments have also been made by Ukraine, the European Union, China and the United States.
At the same time, the average customs tariff for agricultural products is set at 15% in all three groups, according to development level, while it fluctuates from 11% in LDCs to 2.2% for nonagricultural products in developed countries. Ukraine is unique in this regard, as it tied its average tariff rate for agricultural products at 11% (practically using 9.2%) and 5% for other groups of products (practically using 3.7%).
An asymmetry is also observed in members choosing a system of nontariff tools. Thus, 51.4% of all implemented measures of this type are TBTs, and 35.7% are sanitary and phytosanitary measures. Studying the group of trade protection measures, it is observed that antidumping measures are used in 86% of cases.
Among the world regions, North America is an undisputed leader in implementing nontariff measures (average-weighted index is 5,077). European countries (2,198), Asian countries (1,612) and countries of Central and South America and the Caribbean (1,393) have twice fewer indices. The least-average-weighted index belongs to CIS countries (359) and Africa (274).
The amount of time spent on compliance with norms and the cost of customs formalities are other indices worth analyzing. A common tendency lies in the fact that the poorer the region, the longer it takes to get customs clearing. Thus, in 2019, passing formalities at products exported to LDCs took 85 h and cost USD 504, to OECD countries—13 h and USD 150 and to the EU—8 h and USD 87. According to the World Bank data, passing customs formalities in Ukraine requires 6 h and costs USD 75.
The maximum number of service subsectors that appropriate commitments are made for by WTO members is 147 out of 155 (Moldova), and the minimum number is 1 (Fiji and Tanzania). At the same time, countries belonging to the LDC group do not suppose absence of commitments. For instance, Gambia made commitments in 111 service subsectors, Sierra Leone in 110, Liberia in 108, Afghanistan in 103, Cambodia in 97, etc.
The most active parties in trade disputes are the countries of North America (on average 271 disputes in every country, while in Asia the number of disputes is 88 in a country). The least-involved region is Africa, and it is mostly involved as the third party.
As of December 2021, there were 351 effective RTAs existing in the world. According to the number of parties, 81% of RTAs are bilateral and 19% are multilateral. According to geographical extension, 59% are cross-regional and 41% are in-regional. As for RTA typification, 58% are free-trade agreements, 34% are economic integration agreements, 5% are agreements with partial sphere and 3% are customs unities. Having carried out the countries analysis, it is concluded that the European Union is the leader (45 agreements), which, in turn affirms the policy of “pressing” European standards along with international ones. Ukraine is one of top-ten countries possessing this index, having 19 effective FTAs with 47 world countries, including Great Britain, Georgia, the European Union, the EFTA, Israel, Canada, North Macedonia, Montenegro and each CIS country, separately, except for the Russian Federation.
“Mega trade” agreements (often also called “trade agreements of the 21st century”) deserve special attention. The Trans-Pacific Partnership, which includes 12 countries of the Asian–Pacific region, and the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership between the United States and the European Union, may be classified as such.
Technological and infrastructural asymmetries. In 2019, the vast majority of the population of developed countries (86.6%) had access to the Internet, and nearly two times less had it in developing countries (47%). This figure is minimal for LDCs (19.1%). As of 2020, generally, the availability of legislative acts in the electronic transactions sphere was 81%, 56% in protection of consumer rights, 66% in data confidentiality and 79% in cybersecurity. However, there are still countries (15), mostly in Africa, which lack any legal norms, while almost 20% of RTAs contain a chapter devoted to e-commerce.
Micro-, small and middle-sized enterprises, which on average account for 34% of exports in developed countries, are gaining more significance in the global trading system. There is a positive connection between the size of an enterprise and its participation in export: 9% for microenterprises, 38% for small, 59% for middle-sized and 66% for large. In developing countries, there is an inverse relationship between the number of employees that a firm has at the beginning of its activity and the number of years before it starts exporting. Large firms that started with five or fewer employees needed 17 years to start exporting products, compared to five years for those that had 60–100 employees.
Gender asymmetry. In the majority of countries, women are employed in service sectors, such as education or healthcare, which are less intensively supplied abroad. On average, enterprises led by women face 13% higher export expenses than those led by men.
All existing challenging aspects of WTO functioning may be grouped according to five key directions—inability to fully realize a mechanism for settling trade disputes, insufficient efficiency of monitoring the observance of obligations by members, low effectiveness of negotiation process, a necessity to define a country’s status within the WTO and low performance of WTO committees and working bodies.

5. Results

5.1. Analysis of Variance of the Influence of Independent Factors on the Volume of Global Trade

5.1.1. Categorization of Countries by the Level of Economic Development

The null hypothesis to be tested is formulated as follows: the country’s membership in a certain economic group has no influence on the value of selected indicators of the latter’s foreign economic activity. In other words, the null hypothesis states that the obtained differences between group means are insignificant and caused by the influence of random factors. Then, the alternative hypothesis states that the country’s membership in a certain economic group significantly affects the value of selected indicators of the country’s foreign economic activity. The average values of the studied indicators by country groups are presented in Figure A1, Figure A2, Figure A3, Figure A4, Figure A5, Figure A6, Figure A7, Figure A8, Figure A9, Figure A10, Figure A11, Figure A12, Figure A13, Figure A14, Figure A15, Figure A16, Figure A17, Figure A18, Figure A19, Figure A20 and Figure A21 (Appendix A).
The results of the one-factor analysis of variance, namely, the indicator for which the analysis of variance was performed, the calculated value of the F-statistic and its significance level, are presented in Table 2.
The obtained results allow us to conclude that, for most indicators, the null hypothesis is rejected. That is, the country’s membership in a certain economic group has a significant impact on the value of the studied foreign economic activity indicators of the countries. The null hypothesis was accepted for such indicators as TBT, ADP, CV, XS and agr_rate_mfn. That is, although such measures as nontariff regulation can be used as technical barriers to trade, antidumping and countervailing measures, export subsidies do not depend on the country’s membership in a certain economic group, but may be determined by the country’s geographical position (this hypothesis will be confirmed or refuted at the next stage of the research) or the specifics of the country’s foreign economic activity. The size of the average duty rate on agricultural goods within the framework of the most-favored-nation (MFN) regime also, as revealed by the results of the analysis of variance, does not depend on the country’s membership in the economic group.
Since the results of the analysis of variance showed the presence of statistically significant differences between the compared groups, we will perform a posteriori comparison using the Tukey test. Tukey’s test is a specialized parametric post hoc test for all pairwise comparisons, which is a modification of the Student’s test for pairwise comparisons. In the presented study, it was chosen because, in [62], it was proved that, when comparing the expediency of using different criteria for estimating the level of discreteness of statistics, the use of the Tukey approach shows satisfactory results for use in this study, in particular, proving to be better than using the Mud approach. The study in [63] indicated that using modifications of the Tukey test is not always the best possible method. For example, the Newman–Keuls test’s critical value, q, depends on the comparison interval. For the Tukey test, it is not the comparison interval that is used, but the number of groups, i.e., the critical value, q, is the same. The practical expediency of using Tukey’s criterion is that, by using studentized statistics for all pairwise comparisons between groups, it allows one to ensure the level of research error within the error level of the population of all pairwise comparisons. The hypotheses of the Tukey test are formulated as follows.
The null hypothesis (H0) is that the means in the two groups being compared are the same: μB = μA. The alternative hypothesis (Ha) is that the means in the two comparison groups differ: μB ≠ μA, where the subscripts A and B stand for any two comparison groups.
In case of unequal sizes of the compared groups, Tukey’s test is calculated by the formula:
q = X _ A X _ B M S E 2 ( 1 n A + 1 n B )  
where X _ A is greater than the average value between two compared samples, X _ B is less than the average value between two compared samples, and n A and n B are the numbers of observations in samples A and B, respectively. Null hypotheses of the Tukey test are accepted or rejected by comparing the calculated values obtained by Equation (4) with the determined critical value for the selected level of significance [64].
Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5 show p-values of Tukey’s test for each pair of groups of countries being compared. Tukey’s test was not performed for indicators for which, according to the results of the analysis of variance, the null hypothesis of equality of mean values was accepted.
From Table 3, it becomes obvious that the average values of the number of valid regional trade agreements differ significantly in each group of countries. The values of export and import differ significantly in the group of developed countries in comparison with others. On the other hand, although differences in the average values of these indicators in the groups of least-developed countries and developing countries exist, they cannot be called significant and explained by the country belonging to a certain economic category. Among other things, it was established that the number of trade disputes between countries and separate customs territories that were resolved within the framework of the WTO differs significantly between groups of developed and least-developed countries.
We conclude that significant differences in the number of nontariff regulatory measures are observed between the groups of developed and least-developed countries, with the exception for special safeguard measures, because this type of measure is most often used among representatives of the group of developing countries (Table 4). Between the group of developed countries and developing countries, there are also significant differences in the number of applied nontariff measures, except for sanitary and phytosanitary measures. At the same time, it was found that existing differences in the use of nontariff regulatory measures between the groups of the least-developed countries and developing countries are, as a rule, insignificant and are not explained by the country’s membership in one of the aforementioned economic groups.
As it is indicated in Table 5, the country’s membership in a certain economic group significantly affects the import duty rate, because between all groups of countries there are significant differences in the size of the import duty rate and the number of tariff lines. These differences can be explained precisely by the different levels of categorization factor of the countries by the level of economic development. The only exception is the number of bound tariff lines in developed and developing countries: existing minor differences are not due to the country’s membership in one economic group or another.
So, the following conclusions can be drawn on the basis of the results of the analysis of variance and by analyzing the average values of the studied indicators by groups of countries by the level of economic development. In general, the country’s membership within a certain economic group significantly affects the value of the indicators of the country’s foreign trade activity. In particular, developed countries are characterized by significantly higher volumes of exports and imports compared to other countries. They also conclude regional trade agreements much more often and are active participants of trade disputes (at the same time, no statistically significant difference between developed and developing countries was found for the last indicator). In addition, developed countries are the most active users of nontariff measures to regulate trade volumes. The average level of the duty rate, on the contrary, is the lowest in developed countries and the highest in the group of least-developed countries, which is a logical manifestation of the courses of trade policies of the countries’ economic leaders that aimed at the liberalization of trade in goods.

5.1.2. Grouping of Countries According to Location in a Specific Region

Results of the analysis of variance for the region factor—grouping of countries according to location in a specific region. The null hypothesis to be tested is formulated as follows: the belonging of a country to a certain geographical region has no influence on the value of selected indicators of the country’s foreign economic activity, and the obtained differences between the group average values are insignificant and caused by the influence of random factors. Then, the alternative hypothesis is that belonging to a certain geographical region significantly affects the value of selected indicators of the country’s foreign economic activity.
With the help of univariate analysis of variance, the following results were obtained for the region variable represented in Table 6.
According to the results of the conducted analysis of variance, we may conclude that the geographical position of the country significantly affects the studied indicators of the foreign economic activity of this country. Indicators such as export subsidies and the average rate of customs duties on agricultural goods under the most-favored-nation (MFN) regime are exceptions.
With the help of pairwise comparisons of the average values of the studied indicators by groups of countries using the Tukey test, we will check between which groups of countries there are significant differences due to the geographical location of the country or a separate customs territory (Table 7, Table 8 and Table 9).
According to the results of the Tukey test (Table 7), it can be noted that the countries of the European region are significantly ahead of the rest of the world in terms of the number of valid regional trade agreements. On the other hand, the differences between other regions according to this indicator cannot be considered significant and are due to the geographical location of the country. According to the indicators of the volumes of exports and imports and the number of trade disputes between countries and separate customs territories, which were resolved within the framework of the WTO, the countries of North America differ significantly. The differences between the rest of the world regions cannot be considered to be statistically significant and are due to the geographical location of the country.
According to the results of the calculations given in Table 8, the influence of the factor of the country belonging to the geographical region is most significantly observed for the countries of North America: the countries of this region occupy leading positions in terms of the number of nontariff measures used to regulate trade volumes. It was also found that the geographical position of the country determines the existence of significant differences in the frequency of use of such regulatory measures as technical barriers to trade for Middle Eastern countries and quantitative restrictions for WTO members located in Asia. For the remaining groups of countries, the existence of differences in the use of certain nontariff measures of foreign trade regulation does not depend on the country belonging to a certain geographical region and may be due to the influence of other factors, including random ones. Separately, it is worth noting that for such indicators as safeguard measures and tariff quotas, the regional factor has almost no influence, that is, the existing differences between the regions of the world in the use of such tools of trade policy are not due to the geographical location of the country.
According to the results of Tukey’s test (Table 9), the existence of statistically significant differences between the countries of the African region and other regions of the world in all indicators of tariff regulation of trade volumes was revealed. Significant differences due to the geographical location of the country were also found for WTO members representing the South American region.
Therefore, the conducted analysis allows us to conclude that the factor of belonging of a country or a separate customs territory to a certain geographical region significantly affects the indicators of foreign trade activity of such subjects. In particular, statistically significant differences from other regions of the world in terms of export and import volumes were found for the North America region. This region is also the most actively involved in trade disputes and uses nontariff trade regulation measures. The number of valid trade agreements is the highest among the countries of the European region. In addition, the regional factor determines the existence of statistically significant differences in the average customs duty rate in African and South American countries—in these regions, the customs duty rate is significantly higher compared to other regions of the world (Table 10).
That is, on the basis of the results of the analysis of variance, it becomes possible to draw the general conclusion that the level of development of the country and its geographical location significantly affect the value of all the studied indicators, with the exception of the average duty rate provided under the most-favored-nation (MFN) regime for agricultural goods. Such a difference is natural because this duty rate is actually applied by countries and separate customs territories to goods defined by the WTO members as necessary for the creation of state reserves for food security purposes, so it is a specific category of goods that are not subject to general trends and rules regarding elimination of trade barriers.

5.2. Econometric Analysis of the Influence of Selected Indicators of Foreign Trade Activity on the Volume of Global Exports

In addition, in order to evaluate the impact of selected indicators of foreign trade activity on the country’s export volume, an econometric analysis was conducted. For this purpose, a linear multivariable econometric model was used, the general form of which is described by the following equation [46]:
y = β 0 + β 1 x 1 + β 2 x 2 + + β k x k + ε
where y is the dependent variable, x1, …, xk are the independent variables, βk is the unknown estimates of model parameters, and ε is the stochastic component of the econometric model.
To carry out the econometric analysis, the same initial statistical data as for the analysis of variance were used. The amount of goods exported in USD million was chosen as the dependent variable—Export, and a number of indicators of the country’s foreign trade activity will act as independent variables, namely, RTAs, Disputes_total, SPS, TBT, ADP, CV, SG, SSG, QR, TRQ, XS, non_tarif_total, tariff_lines, total_rate_l, total_rate_mfn, agr_rate_l, agr_rate_mfn, non_agr_rate_l and non_agr_rate_mfn, which were characterized above in detail.
It should be noted that all the indicators that were measured in physical units, were previously logarithmized. This allows one, firstly, to reduce the asymmetry of the distribution of a statistical value. Secondly, using not the absolute values of the indicators but their natural logarithms, all estimates of the βk model parameters can be interpreted as elasticity coefficients, that is, to determine the percentage change in the dependent variable when the independent variable k increases by 1% [64].
To avoid the problem of multicollinearity, the correlation matrix (Figure A43) and the variance inflation factor (VIF) of the determined indicators were calculated in the previous stage of the research.
A visual analysis of the pairwise correlation coefficients between pairs of independent variables in the correlation matrix, as expected, showed a strong correlation between the average total tariff rate and the average tariff rates for agricultural and nonagricultural goods, as well as between the average MFN tariff rate and the average tariff rate for nonagricultural goods under the most-favored-nation regime. Accordingly, it can be assumed that the above-mentioned pairs of indicators can be collinear and to avoid multicollinearity in the array of independent variables, it is advisable to remove one or more of the mentioned indicators.
In order to conduct a more thorough analysis and make a decision on the removal of some independent variables, the variance inflation coefficients were calculated, step by step removing the indicators that had the largest VIF value until the VIF indicator for all independent variables did not exceed the recommended value of “10” [65]. The values of the VIF coefficients for the initial set of independent variables and after stepwise removal of the variables total_rate_mfn and total_rate_l are given in Table 11.
Thus, the total_rate_mfn variable was deleted in the first step, the total_rate_l variable was deleted in the second step and as a result, 16 variables remained in the array of independent variables. Their list and the calculated values of the VIF coefficients are given in Table 12 (values of VIF coefficients for SPS and TBT variables exceed 10 by less than 1, so they are taken into account in further analysis).
Four econometric models were built to analyze the impact of the selected indicators of the country’s foreign trade activity on the export value. The first one is a generalized model based on the entire data set, which includes information on 150 countries and separate customs territories of the world.
Among other things, since the results of the analysis of variance showed that the country’s membership in a certain category according to the level of economic development has a significant impact on most of the studied indicators of foreign trade activity, it is considered appropriate to separately build econometric models for groups of developed countries, developing countries and the least-developed countries. This will allow for a more detailed analysis of each group of countries and to determine a specific set of indicators that has the greatest impact on the number of exports in a particular economic group.
In addition to the results of the analysis of variance, the expediency of building econometric models for different groups of countries is also evidenced by the graphical presentation of regression lines for each economic group, separately, in the correlation field of points.
As it is shown in Figure A44 and Figure A45, the regression lines for the three groups of countries that are different in the level of economic development differ significantly. This means that the construction of econometric models for each group of countries is appropriate and will allow a more accurate approximation of the data.
A graphical presentation of the regression lines in the correlation field of points for the remaining independent variables is presented in Figure A46, Figure A47, Figure A48, Figure A49, Figure A50, Figure A51, Figure A52, Figure A53, Figure A54, Figure A55, Figure A56 and Figure A57 (Appendix C).
The following regression equation was obtained for the complete data set:
E x p o r t = 6.918 ( 0.000 ) + 2.465   R T A s ( 0.000 ) + 0.940   D i s p u t e s _ t o t a l ( 0.000 ) 0.014   t a r i f f _ l i n e s ( 0.003 ) 0.022 n o n _ a g r _ r a t e _ l ( 0.001 ) + 0.334 T B T ( 0.000 )
The value of the adjusted coefficient of determination is 0.650. The value of the F-statistic coefficient is 56.440. Verification by F- and t-tests showed that the model and estimates of its parameters are significant, which indicates the adequacy and satisfactory quality of the obtained model. The number of current regional trade agreements has the greatest influence on the volume of world exports—with a 1% increase in the number of concluded agreements, the volume of exports increases by almost 2.5%. In addition, the increase in the number of trade disputes between countries and separate customs territories that were resolved within the framework of the WTO and technical barriers to trade has a positive effect on the export volumes [66]. At the same time, the increase in the duty rate on nonagricultural goods somewhat slows down the growth of exports.
The regression equation for the group of developed countries looks like this:
E x p o r t = 8.160 ( 0.000 ) + 3.696   R T A s ( 0.001 ) + 2.368   D i s p u t e s _ t o t a l ( 0.000 ) 0.047   t a r i f f l i n e s   ( 0.035 ) 0.017   a g r r a t e l + ( 0.080 )   0.390   T B T + ( 0.000 )   0.288   S S G ( 0.041 ) 0.435   Q R ( 0.043 ) 0.457   T R Q ( 0.009 )
For this level, the value of the adjusted coefficient of determination is 0.692, and the value of the F-statistic is 11.940. According to the results of F- and t-tests, it was found that the model as a whole and the estimates of its parameters are statistically significant. Using the equation, it can be concluded that indicators such as the number of valid regional trade agreements and the number of trade disputes resolved within the WTO have the greatest positive impact on demand in developed countries: an increase in these indicators by 1% leads to an increase in exports in the country by 3.7% and 2.4%, respectively. It is worth noting that it is for developed countries that the above-mentioned indicators have the greatest stimulating effect on exports in comparison with other economic groups. In addition, such nontariff regulatory measures can act as technical barriers and safeguard measures (increasing the use of these regulatory measures by 1% allows exports to increase by 0.39% and 0.29%, respectively), as well as introduce of quantitative restrictions and tariff quotas (an increase in the use of these nontariff regulatory instruments by 1% can lead to a decrease in exports by 0.44% and 0.46%, respectively). At the same time, the increase in the average rate of customs duties on agricultural goods leads to a slight decrease in exports in developed countries.
For developing countries, the following regression equation was obtained:
E x p o r t = 8.179 ( 0.000 ) + 1.137   R T A s ( 0.049 ) 0.024   t a r i f f _ l i n e s ( 0.000 ) 0.015   a g r _ r a t e _ l ( 0.004 ) + 0.252   S P S ( 0.090 ) + 0.313   T B T + ( 0.029 ) 0.435   A D P ( 0.001 ) + 0.465   S G ( 0.097 )
For this model, the adjusted coefficient of determination is 0.675, and the value of Fisher’s F-statistic is 25.590. Verification by F- and t-tests showed that the model and the estimates of its parameters are significant, which indicates the adequacy and satisfactory quality of the obtained model. The number of valid regional trade agreements has a positive effect on the export volumes. It is worth noting that, in the group of developing countries, exports are the least-sensitive to changes in the number of trade agreements: a 1% increase in the number of concluded trade agreements causes an increase in exports by only 1.1%. Similar to developed countries, in developing countries, the increase in the average rate of customs duties on agricultural goods leads to a slight decrease in exports. It has also been established that the use of such nontariff instruments as sanitary and phytosanitary measures, technical barriers to trade, antidumping and special safeguard measures has a positive effect on the amount of exports in developing countries.
And the export regression equation for the least-developed countries looks like this:
E x p o r t = 5.765 ( 0.000 ) + 3.286   R T A s ( 0.001 ) + 0.010   a g r _ r a t e _ l ( 0.111 ) + 0.704   S G ( 0.223 )
It is immediately worth noting that the adjusted coefficient of determination is only 0.409, which is the lowest indicator among the four constructed models. The value of the Fisher statistic is 6.778.
The model constructed according to the results of the F-test is statistically significant and of sufficient quality. However, according to the results of the t-test, only the number of valid regional trade agreements has a statistically significant effect on the volume of exports in the least-developed countries. The rest of the considered indicators do not have a statistically significant effect on the amount of exports, which is explained by the minimal level of use of nontariff measures to regulate trade volumes by countries of this economic category.

6. Novelty of the Study and of the Results

This research identified and systematized the existing asymmetries of the global trade system, which have direct and indirect impacts on its development. Special attention is paid to the study of the impact of the global trade system asymmetries of the use of tariff and nontariff instruments of export and import regulation by countries and individual customs territories, depending on their belonging to a certain geographical region or group of countries with a certain level of economic development. Critically, taking into account the structure, scope and subject composition, the tendency for the increased number of regional trade agreements was analyzed, and the influence of the digitization of international trade, and the growing role of micro-, small and medium enterprises (MSMEs) and that of enterprises led by women on the growth volumes and degree were characterized as a diversification of trade flows.
In this study, the complex analysis and systematization of the asymmetries of the global trade system (as a subsystem of the global economic system at the global, regional and international levels) were further developed by assigning them to two key groups: asymmetries directly related to international trade processes (asymmetries in trade in goods, caused by differences in the levels of customs tariffs of countries, the number and variability of applied nontariff measures to regulate trade volumes, including such trade protection measures as antidumping, compensatory and special measures, the degree of involvement of countries and individual customs territories in the resolution of trade disputes; asymmetries in trade in services that proceed from differences in the levels of specific obligations of countries regarding the liberalization of access to service markets); asymmetries that are indirectly related to the processes of international trade (technological–infrastructural, gender, informational, by subjectivity, in particular, taking into account the growing role of micro-, small and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs) in the export activity of countries).

7. Discussion

The results of this study confirm the existence of asymmetries of different natures and origins. A significant number of asymmetries was observed precisely in the sphere of trade in goods, taking into account the tools used by countries. For example, the number of tariff lines in respect of which WTO members have bound customs rates, as well as the very levels of the bound and actually applied (under the most-favored nation (MFN)) duty rates for agricultural and nonagricultural goods, differ critically, depending on the regional and development belonging to a participant in the global trade system. The key reason for trade asymmetry is the use of nontariff regulatory measures, namely, sanitary and phytosanitary measures (SPM), technical barriers to trade (TBT), trade protection measures (antidumping, compensatory and special), quantitative restrictions, tariff quotas, etc., as well as frequency of introduction, which increases annually. Another characteristic difference between different groups of countries is their ability to protect their national economic interests, not only with the help of trade protection measures listed above, but also by initiating the consideration of trade disputes within the framework of the appropriate mechanism in the WTO. The specific obligations of WTO members to provide access to services markets have been the subject of discussions for more than a decade. This is because, out of 152 subsectors of services, some countries have opened only 1 and some 144, and such openness is not always characteristic of countries with a high level of economic development.
No less significant is research on the asymmetry of other aspects that have an indirect effect on trade processes. Thus, as of 2021, one of the global problems remains the so-called “digital divide” between developed and developing countries. That is, the lack of free and unhindered access to the Internet in a number of African, Asian and South American countries automatically deprives them of the opportunity to participate in the trade of digital products and electronic commerce, or simply the digitization of individual trade procedures in order to simplify and speed it up, for example, transferring trade to a paperless format—another trend of the 21st century. There is support for the export activities of micro-, small and medium-sized enterprises (MSMEs), which have significant difficulties accessing foreign markets due to the lack of up-to-date information about the trade regimes of other countries, as well as higher costs and risks for enterprises of this type when conducting international trade, etc. Gender asymmetry remains no less relevant, because women in trade still have difficulties with access to quality education and areas of trade in goods with high added value, and the export value of products from a company headed by a woman is still more than 10% higher in cost than a similar one headed by a man.
However, the key asymmetry of the global trade system in today’s conditions is the exponentially growing number of regional trade agreements (RTAs), which create alternative regional rules for regulating trade flows. In the context of the lack of significant practical results of multilateral trade negotiations within the framework of the WTO in the form of new multilateral agreements, this creates a threat to the existence of the entire global trade system in its usual format.
The results of this study confirm the previously obtained results indicating that RTA boosts trade between member countries. Anderson et al.’s last work [67] assessed the impact of regional trade agreement growth within the framework of general equilibrium. The main lesson of this study is that trade affects the growth of consumer and producer prices, which promotes or hinders the accumulation of physical capital. At the same time, growth affects trade directly through changes in the size of the country and indirectly by changes in the frequency of trade costs. In addition, the conducted study confirms that the active participation of the European Union in international trade is supported by its active participation in different RTAs. This idea is supported by Yatsenko et al. [15], who emphasize that, for many countries, a free-trade agreement with the European Union becomes a driver for economic and social development.
The research provides the conclusion that one of the advantages of FTAs is the possibility for the country to obtain the image of being the regional leader and can also be used as a platform for implementing new international trade rules. This idea is backed by Suominen [68], who describes RTAs as “incubators of new trade rules”. On the other hand, we should not leave out the possible restraining factors that suppress future RTA development and mostly deal with the fear of losing the country’s independence in some spheres connected with international trade. That is why some authors, Bazaluk et al. [69], in particular, support the idea that RTAs can be seen in both ways—as tools for trade liberalization and as tools for trade protectionism.
Bhagwati et al. [70] are some of the critics of regionalism trends. They describe regional integration as being “preferential” or even “discriminatory.” Although many international trade studies note that the net effect of international economic integration on economic welfare depends on the actual situation, Bhagwati et al. [70] argue that a negative net effect is more likely than a positive one and that regional integration is a stumbling block to global liberalization rather than its building block. In their opinion, economic integration entities such as the European Union lead to a significant diversification of trade rather than its development in quantitative and, especially, qualitative aspects. Economic synthesis among western European countries was discriminatory towards third countries for two reasons: due to the elimination of customs payments and other trade restrictions between members of the union and due to unilateral changes in customs tariffs when the European Commission introduced a single customs tariff in relation to all nonmember countries of the European Union.
Even before the establishment of the WTO, Bhagwati et al. [71] proposed a reform of the GATT with the aim of ensuring as little as possible redirection of the trade flows, necessarily caused by economic integration. They also believed that the formation of free-trade areas should be prohibited, and the formation of customs unions and common markets as the “lesser evil” could be allowed, provided that the single customs tariff for each customs category should be set at the lowest level among the previously applied tariffs and not the average level, as was usually done. These proposals, according to Bhagwati et al. [71], certainly made the new regional integrations more open and liberal towards other participants of the trade system that do not belong to them.
The latest wave of regionalism in the world has obviously raised concerns that it will slow down and weaken the global liberalization process. Regional integration can become a characteristic trap that “captures” its participants and prevents them from overcoming domestic political opposition to global free trade. Levy [72] believes that regional integration undermines political support for global free trade because bilateral and regional free-trade agreements cannot increase political support for multilateral free trade.
Bhagwati also tried to argue that regional integration can force GATT/WTO members to abandon multilateral negotiations for liberalization, partly because bureaucrats prefer to negotiate with neighboring countries, and partly because big capital expects to get better deals in the region. According to the views of similarly minded scientists, two points point to the conclusion that the participants of international economic integration entities are not interested in significant global liberalization. First, members of such integrations cannot achieve significant economies of scale outside of global liberalization—their integration cannot be large enough to fully satisfy their needs. Second, members of such integrations might prefer to use their political energy to create and manage their integrations rather than global negotiations [73].
Therefore, the issue of the coexistence of WTO and RTU agreements was raised even before the start of the organization’s operation. The parties to the GATT of 1947 foresaw the possibility of concluding RTUs by agreeing on the relevant rules, which, in turn, contributed to the signing of the first of such agreements in the 1950s and 1960s of the 20th century. However, since the 2000s, which in turn coincided with the start of the next round of multilateral trade negotiations within the framework of the WTO (“Doha-Development” round), the number of new RTUs began to grow at an accelerated pace.
There are countless theories that explain this pattern: some focus on the study of the pressure of lobby groups on exporters, others on the interests of developing countries when using RTUs as a tool to attract foreign direct investment, and others on geopolitical considerations. One of the explanations for the rapid spread of RTUs is the lack of significant progress in multilateral negotiations in the WTO system since its creation. Members negotiate under standard modalities with the principle of a single undertaking, according to which nothing is agreed-upon until all members agree on all provisions. Also complicating the course of multilateral negotiations and the conclusion of the Doha Development round, in particular, is the change in the dynamics of political economy among WTO members, caused by the accelerated growth of powerful developing countries, whose interests differ significantly from the interests of the advanced economies of the organization’s founding countries.
Thus, supporters of the conclusion of RTUs emphasize that agreements of this type offer a way out of the stalemate at the multilateral level. They allow countries to expand their access to markets, attract foreign direct investments and develop new regulations to meet new market needs. The RTU system itself encourages the conclusion of new agreements: as more and more countries become parties to such agreements, other countries and individual customs territories are faced with the urgent need to form their own agreements in order to not lose the benefits that the RTU provides to others. The traditional question is whether this relationship between the principle of granting the most-favored-nation treatment and preferences under the MFA helps or hinders multilateral agreements. This is an important issue, from both formal, legal and factual, economic points of view. The possible incompatibility of the RTU and the multilateral trading system could be interpreted as a violation of international trade law and could distort global trade flows, production chains and economic growth. This issue has remained problematic for WTO members for decades [68]. So currently, in the context of the crisis state of the functioning of the WTO, and against the background of the growth of other asymmetries of the global trade system, the problem of the correlation of such trade rules is extremely relevant and will be revealed within the framework of this study.
The results of the research and their mathematical interpretation corroborated the presence of a number of asymmetries in the global trading system; however, the most debatable and complicated issue is defining the status of a country within the WTO. This issue has been the most problematic ever since it appeared. It is generally accepted to divide all members into three categories: developed, developing and least-developed countries. The first category to which members belong, which is defined every three years by the United Nations Economic and Social Council, is a group of the least-developed countries, containing 46 countries, mostly from African and North American regions (as of December 2021). Belonging to the other two categories is defined by WTO members independently, which considerably complicates the functioning of the whole trading system due to attempts to gain significant privileges from exploiting special and differential regimes. Therefore, considering approaches of the UN, IMF and World Bank, considering membership of countries in informal groups and organizations accessible only to members with a high level of economic development, and considering the shares of countries and separate customs territories in the global trade, for the sake of the research objectives, defining thirty-nine countries and three customs territories (Hong Kong, Macao and Chinese Taipei) as developed WTO members is suggested, while the rest of the members are considered as developing.
Problematic aspects of the WTO’s performance may be divided into five key areas: the impossibility of the full realization of the trade-dispute settlement mechanism, which led to obstructing the activity of the WTO appellate body (AB); the inefficient effectiveness of monitoring the WTO members’ obligations is linked to noncompliance of WTO members with respect to notification submission requirements, which, in turn, effects the level of transparency and predictability of the trading environment; the low efficiency of the negotiation process (one new multilateral trade agreement—the Trade Facilitation Agreement (TFA)—in 25 years of the organization’s existence); the necessity to define the statuses of countries within the WTO; and the low efficiency of WTO committees and performance of working bodies.
As a result of the research, it has been established that reasons for inefficient effectiveness of monitoring WTO members’ obligations are noncompliance with the requirements of notifications, untimely responses to questions asked by other members, limited resources of countries, etc. The reasons for the low efficiency of the multilateral negotiations within the WTO are differences in interests, difficulties in making consensus decisions with all 164 members, etc.
Considering the above-mentioned, and in order to overcome the growing asymmetry in regulating cross-border trade using RTAs, it is suggested to incorporate the matter of signing regional trade agreements into the WTO’s legal regime by reaching the understanding that all RTA texts must be developed on the basis of valid rules and norms of the organization and by composing a model regional trade agreement (so called “Model Agreement”). As for recommendations about the WTO appellate body, it is necessary to bring changes to Dispute Settlement Understanding; particularly, have an exact 90-day term; increasing the number of AB members to nine; having one term that is, however, longer (6–8 years); using precedent for typical cases and using prohibition to make subjective conclusions. Notification recommendations: provide an opportunity to comment on notifications, ask questions and have sanctions for unintentional or untimely submissions. Agreement recommendations: only multilateral, if possible; when reaching a consensus is impossible, there should be active support of multilateral agreements, with a limited number of parties that are open for entrance by all members; there should be political support of agreements on all levels outside of the WTO.
Research results can be useful to representatives of the WTO, state authorities of countries and researcher and can also be applied in the practical activities of governments of countries. The practical significance of the obtained results can be conditioned by the formation of the strategy of the country(s) in the field of modernization of the activities of the World Trade Organization with the aim of leveling the impact of asymmetries in the development of the global trade system. In turn, this will directly or indirectly contribute to the reduction in social pressure, the avoidance and/or minimization of the negative impact of environmental threats and the elimination or reduction of business disruptions and economic losses caused by various shocks, which will ensure the “Economic Sustainability” of business entities.
The importance of further in-depth research on the chosen topic is related to the rather significant challenges that countries will have to face in the near future. This is both connected to the emergence of new issues on the agenda of international trade negotiations within the framework of the WTO and related to geopolitical aspects.

8. Conclusions

Therefore, the novelty of this research is the complex analysis and systematization of the asymmetries of the global trading system as a subsystem of the global economic system on the global, regional and interstate levels by dividing them into two key groups: asymmetries that are directly linked to international trade processes (asymmetries in goods trading that are caused by differences between levels of customs tariffs of countries; number and variety of implemented nontariff measures of trade volume regulation, including the following trade protection measures: antidumping, compensational and special; in the degree of involvement of countries and separate customs territories in settling trade disputes; in service trading that derives from differences between levels of specific obligations of countries to liberalize access to service markets) and asymmetries that are indirectly linked to international trade processes (technological and infrastructure; gender; informational; according to subjectivity; particularly considering the growing role of micro-, small and middle-sized enterprises in the export activity of countries).
Within the research, variance analysis for the following indices has been carried out: RTAs; the global export and import of products in 2020; the number of trade disputes within the WTO; the general number of nontariff measures regulating trade in countries, as well as the number of tied tariff lines, average tied and PT duty rates; and analogous indices for agricultural and nonagricultural products. One-way analysis was carried out for each index using ANOVA and Fisher’s test; pairwise differences were tested using Tukey’s test, and regression equations for each country group were made.
According to the results of the econometric analysis, it was determined that for all groups of countries, both in terms of geographical affiliation and the level of economic development, the export stimulating factor is the number of RTAs.
For developed countries, the number of trade disputes in which a country or a separate customs territory is involved also has a significant positive impact on the exports volume. In addition, a feature of developed and developing countries is the existence of a significant impact on export volumes of such nontariff measures as SPS measures; TBT, antidumping and special safeguard measures; and average-weighted customs duty rates on agricultural goods.
In addition, the regression equations obtained for the dependence of export volumes, both worldwide and for exports of developed countries, developing countries, and the least-developed countries on the specified influencing factors, confirm the existence of their stable, direct dependence on the number of concluded trade agreements, the frequency of participation in the resolution of trade disputes and the activity of the application of nontariff trade measures, and indirect dependency on the customs duty rates, in particular, on nonagricultural goods.
Therefore, in eliminating the asymmetries of the global trading system, key attention should be paid to the settlement of the issue of the relationship between the WTO and the RTA legal framework, as well as the improvement of the trade dispute resolution mechanism within the WTO and options for strengthening the monitoring function in order to better observe the application of nontariff measures to regulate trade volumes.
The research also comprises recommendations on modernizing the procedural and normative basis of the WTO’s functioning within five key directions, particularly to bring changes to Dispute Settlement Understanding in order to unblock WTO appellate body activity, to implement administrative penalties for members that do not comply or comply in an untimely manner with requirements of notifying the organization about significant changes in the trade legislation of a country, to improve the procedural basis of the activity of WTO working bodies, to concentrate on expediency of signing multilateral agreements with a limited number of parties that are open for entrance by all members, and criteria for how to define a country or a customs territory as developed have been suggested. The vital necessity to start multilateral negotiations has been accentuated; they must be started in order to sign multilateral agreements on such issues as e-commerce, inland regulation in the service industry, abolition (restriction) of subsidies in the fishing industry, boosting investments that will let the current negotiation round finish (the Doha Development round) and start a new round, whose warrant will contain topical issues on global trading development in order to react to 21st-century global challenges.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, T.T.; Methodology, O.Y.; Validation, O.O.; Formal analysis, V.N.; Writing—original draft, T.B.; Writing—review & editing, D.S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Statistical Analysis

Figure A1. Average values for the indicator of regional trade agreements, units.
Figure A1. Average values for the indicator of regional trade agreements, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a1
Figure A2. Average values for the indicator of import volumes, USD million.
Figure A2. Average values for the indicator of import volumes, USD million.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a2
Figure A3. Average values for the indicator of export volumes, USD million.
Figure A3. Average values for the indicator of export volumes, USD million.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a3
Figure A4. Average values for the indicator of the number of trade disputes.
Figure A4. Average values for the indicator of the number of trade disputes.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a4
Figure A5. Average values for the indicator of the number of SPS, units.
Figure A5. Average values for the indicator of the number of SPS, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a5
Figure A6. Average values for the indicator of the amount of TBT, units.
Figure A6. Average values for the indicator of the amount of TBT, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a6
Figure A7. Average values for the indicator of the number of antidumping measures, units.
Figure A7. Average values for the indicator of the number of antidumping measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a7
Figure A8. Average values for the indicator of the number of countervailing measures, units.
Figure A8. Average values for the indicator of the number of countervailing measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a8
Figure A9. Average values for the indicator of the number of safeguards, units.
Figure A9. Average values for the indicator of the number of safeguards, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a9
Figure A10. Average values for the indicator of the number of special safeguard measures, units.
Figure A10. Average values for the indicator of the number of special safeguard measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a10
Figure A11. Average values for the indicator of quantitative restrictions, units.
Figure A11. Average values for the indicator of quantitative restrictions, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a11
Figure A12. Average values for the indicator of the number of tariff quotas, units.
Figure A12. Average values for the indicator of the number of tariff quotas, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a12
Figure A13. Average values for the indicator of the number of export subsidies, units.
Figure A13. Average values for the indicator of the number of export subsidies, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a13
Figure A14. Average values for the indicator of the total number of nontariff measures, units.
Figure A14. Average values for the indicator of the total number of nontariff measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a14
Figure A15. Average values for the indicator of the number of bound tariff lines, %.
Figure A15. Average values for the indicator of the number of bound tariff lines, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a15
Figure A16. Average values for the indicator of the average bound duty rate, %.
Figure A16. Average values for the indicator of the average bound duty rate, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a16
Figure A17. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator, %.
Figure A17. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a17
Figure A18. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for agricultural goods, %.
Figure A18. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for agricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a18
Figure A19. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for agricultural goods, %.
Figure A19. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for agricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a19
Figure A20. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for nonagricultural goods, %.
Figure A20. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for nonagricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a20
Figure A21. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for nonagricultural goods, %.
Figure A21. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for nonagricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a21

Appendix B. Descriptive Analysis

Source: constructed by the author on the basis of his own calculations using data [47,48,49,50,51,52].
Figure A22. Average values for the indicator of regional trade agreements, units.
Figure A22. Average values for the indicator of regional trade agreements, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a22
Figure A23. Average values for the indicator of import volumes, USD million.
Figure A23. Average values for the indicator of import volumes, USD million.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a23
Figure A24. Average values for the indicator of export volumes, USD million.
Figure A24. Average values for the indicator of export volumes, USD million.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a24
Figure A25. Average values for the indicator of the number of trade disputes, units.
Figure A25. Average values for the indicator of the number of trade disputes, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a25
Figure A26. Average values for the indicator of the number of SPS, units.
Figure A26. Average values for the indicator of the number of SPS, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a26
Figure A27. Average values for the indicator of the amount of TBT, units.
Figure A27. Average values for the indicator of the amount of TBT, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a27
Figure A28. Average values for the indicator of the number of antidumping measures, units.
Figure A28. Average values for the indicator of the number of antidumping measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a28
Figure A29. Average values for the indicator of the number of compensatory measures, units.
Figure A29. Average values for the indicator of the number of compensatory measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a29
Figure A30. Average values for the indicator of the number of special events, units.
Figure A30. Average values for the indicator of the number of special events, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a30
Figure A31. Average values for the indicator of the number of special protective measures, units.
Figure A31. Average values for the indicator of the number of special protective measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a31
Figure A32. Average values for the indicator of quantitative restrictions, units.
Figure A32. Average values for the indicator of quantitative restrictions, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a32
Figure A33. Average values for the indicator of the number of tariff quotas, units.
Figure A33. Average values for the indicator of the number of tariff quotas, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a33
Figure A34. Average values for the indicator of the number of export subsidies, units.
Figure A34. Average values for the indicator of the number of export subsidies, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a34
Figure A35. Average values for the indicator of the total number of nontariff measures, units.
Figure A35. Average values for the indicator of the total number of nontariff measures, units.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a35
Figure A36. Average values for the indicator of the number of bound tariff lines, %.
Figure A36. Average values for the indicator of the number of bound tariff lines, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a36
Figure A37. Average values for the indicator of the average bound duty rate, %.
Figure A37. Average values for the indicator of the average bound duty rate, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a37
Figure A38. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator, %.
Figure A38. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a38
Figure A39. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for agricultural goods, %.
Figure A39. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for agricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a39
Figure A40. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for agricultural goods, %.
Figure A40. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for agricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a40
Figure A41. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for nonagricultural goods, %.
Figure A41. Average values for the indicator of the average bound tariff rate for nonagricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a41
Figure A42. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for nonagricultural goods, %.
Figure A42. Average values for the average MFN duty rate indicator for nonagricultural goods, %.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a42
Figure A43. Correlation matrix of paired correlation coefficients between selected indicators of foreign trade activity. Source: constructed by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Figure A43. Correlation matrix of paired correlation coefficients between selected indicators of foreign trade activity. Source: constructed by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a43
Figure A44. Regression line for the RTAs variable—the number of regional trade agreements for countries with different levels of economic development. Source: made by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Figure A44. Regression line for the RTAs variable—the number of regional trade agreements for countries with different levels of economic development. Source: made by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a44
Figure A45. Regression line for the Disputes variable—the number of trade disputes for countries with different levels of economic development. Source: made by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Figure A45. Regression line for the Disputes variable—the number of trade disputes for countries with different levels of economic development. Source: made by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a45

Appendix C

Source: built by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Figure A46. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of quantitative restrictions.
Figure A46. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of quantitative restrictions.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a46
Figure A47. Regression line of dependence of export volumes on the application of special safeguard measures.
Figure A47. Regression line of dependence of export volumes on the application of special safeguard measures.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a47
Figure A48. Regression line of dependence of export volumes on the application of special measures.
Figure A48. Regression line of dependence of export volumes on the application of special measures.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a48
Figure A49. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of compensatory measures.
Figure A49. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of compensatory measures.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a49
Figure A50. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of antidumping measures.
Figure A50. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of antidumping measures.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a50
Figure A51. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the use of technical barriers in trade.
Figure A51. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the use of technical barriers in trade.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a51
Figure A52. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of sanitary and phytosanitary measures.
Figure A52. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of sanitary and phytosanitary measures.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a52
Figure A53. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of tariff quotas.
Figure A53. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the application of tariff quotas.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a53
Figure A54. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the level of tariffs for nonagricultural goods (MFN).
Figure A54. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the level of tariffs for nonagricultural goods (MFN).
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a54
Figure A55. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the bound level of tariffs for nonagricultural goods.
Figure A55. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the bound level of tariffs for nonagricultural goods.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a55
Figure A56. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the level of tariffs on agricultural goods (MFN).
Figure A56. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the level of tariffs on agricultural goods (MFN).
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a56
Figure A57. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the bound level of tariffs on agricultural goods.
Figure A57. Regression line of the dependence of export volumes on the bound level of tariffs on agricultural goods.
Sustainability 15 05316 g0a57

References

  1. Koo, W.W.; Lynn Kennedy, P. Chapter 10. Multilateral Trade Negotiations and US Trade Policy. In International Trade and Agriculture; Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Harris, R.; Li, Q.C. Review of the Literature: The Role of International Trade and Investment in Business Growth and Development. Final Report: DTI Ref: UKTILITREV 05/01. 2005. Available online: https://www.gla.ac.uk/t4/economics/files/harris_UKTIFinalReport.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  3. Bernal, R.L. Participation of Small Developing Economies in the Governance of the Multilateral Trading System. Working Paper No. 44. The Centre for International Governance Innovation. 2009. Available online: https://www.cigionline.org/static/documents/participation_of_sde_in_the_governance_of_the_multilateral_trading_system.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  4. Desta, M.G.; Hirsch, M. African Countries in the World Trading System: International Trade, Domestic Institutions and the Role of International Law. Int. Comp. Law Q. 2012, 61, 127–170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Armstrong, S. Economic Cooperation in the Asia-Pacific and the Global Trading System. Asia Pac. Policy Stud. 2014, 1, 513–521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Jorzik, N.; Mueller-Langer, F. Multilateral stability and efficiency of trade agreements: A network formation approach. World Econ. 2019, 43, 355–370. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Yatsenko, O.; Nitsenko, V.; Tananaiko, T.; Szetela, B.; Kobylianska, A. Trade and economic integration dominants in North America countries’ interaction. J. Int. Stud. 2019, 12, 277–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Cardwell, R.; Kerr, W.A. President Biden’s international trade agenda: Implications for the Canadian agrifood sector. Can. J. Agric. Econ. 2021, 69, 19–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Copeland, D.C. Economic Interdependence and War: A Theory of Trade Expectations. Int. Secur. 1996, 20, 5–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Hoekman, B. Competition Policy and the Global Trading System: A Developing-Country Perspective. Policy Res. Work. Pap. 2013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Rzayeva, U. Asymmetric Changes in the World Economy. IOSR J. Econ. Financ. 2017, 8, 39–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Sriyana, J.; Afandi, A. Asymmetric Effects of Trade Openness on Economic Growth in Selected ASEAN Countries. EM Econ. Manag. 2020, 23, 66–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Pisani-Ferry, J. Bruegel Essay and Lecture Series: Global Asymmetries Strike Back; Bruegel: Brussels, Belgium, 2021; Available online: https://www.bruegel.org/wp-content/uploads/2021/08/Asymmetries_essay-2508-online.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  14. Ferraro, V.; Santos, A.C.; Ginocchio, J. The Global Trading System. 1994. Available online: https://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/intrel/bush/tradepaper.htm (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  15. Yatsenko, O.; Reznikova, N.; Karasova, N.; Musiiets, T.; Lavrinenko, O.; Nitsenko, V. Modernization of the Format of Ukraine’s Trade Integration with the EU in the Conditions of Implementation of the DCFTA. Probl. Zarządzania-Manag. Issues 2020, 18, 101–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Dastagiri, B.; Sindhuja, N. Agriculture trade policy measures and geopolitics in major regional trading blocs: Policy advocacy. World Food Policy 2021, 7, 62–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Timmer, M.P.; Los, B.; Stehrer, R.; de Vries, G.J. Supply Chain Fragmentation and the Global Trade Elasticity: A New Accounting Framework. IMF Econ. Rev. 2021, 69, 656–680. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Bergsten, C.F. The Global Trading System and the Developing Countries in 2000. 1999. Available online: https://www.piie.com/publications/working-papers/global-trading-system-and-developing-countries-2000 (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  19. Johansson, Å.; Olaberría, E. Global Trade and Specialisation PatteMGA over the Next 50 Years. OECD Econ. Policy Pap. 2014. Available online: https://www.oecd.org/economy/Trade-and-specialisation-patteMGA-for-the-next-fifty-years.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  20. Pangestu, M.; Ing, L.Y.; Hadiwidjaja, G. The Future of East Asia’s Trade: A Call for Better Globalization. Asian Econ. Policy Rev. 2018, 13, 219–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Raišienė, A.G.; Yatsenko, O.; Nitsenko, V.; Karasova, N.; Vojtovicova, A. Global dominants of Chinese trade policy development: Opportunities and threats for cooperation with Ukraine. J. Int. Stud. 2019, 12, 193–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. European Central Bank. Understanding the weakness in global trade. What is the new normal? Occas. Pap. Ser. 2016. Available online: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecbop178.en.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  23. Yatsenko, O.; Nitsenko, V.; Mardani, A.; Tananaiko, T. The impact of global risks on the world trade and economic environment. Financ. Credit Act. Probl. Theory Pract. 2018, 4, 435–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Hoekman, B.; Schuman, R. Bolstering Global Trade: Governance. A Work Program for the WTO presented by the High-Level Board of Experts on the Future of Global Trade Governance. 2017. Available online: http://aei.pitt.edu/102720/1/NW_Global_Trade_Governance_Interim_Report.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  25. Stern, R.M. The Multilateral Trading System; Working Papers 569; Research Seminar in International Economics; University of Michigan: Ann Arbor, MI, USA, 2007; Available online: http://www.fordschool.umich.edu/rsie/workingpapers/Papers551-575/r569.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  26. Den Bossche, P.V.; Zdouc, W. The Law and Policy of the World Trade Organization: Text, Cases and Materials, 4th ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  27. Keohane, R.O. Multilateralism: An Agenda for Research. Int. J. 1990, 45, 731–764. Available online: https://www.jstor.org/stable/40202705 (accessed on 27 November 2022). [CrossRef]
  28. Chase-Dunn, C.; Kawano, Y.; Brewer, B.D. Trade Globalization Since 1795: Waves of Integration in the World-System. Am. Sociol. Rev. 2000, 65, 77–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. UNCTAD. The International Trading System and Trade Negotiations. Available online: https://unctad.org/en/Pages/DITC/TNCD/International-trading-system.aspx (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  30. Löfgren, K.-G.; Persson, T.; Weibull, J.W. Markets with Asymmetric Information: The Contributions of George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz. Scand. J. Econ. 2002, 104, 195–211. Available online: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3441066 (accessed on 27 November 2022). [CrossRef]
  31. Rosser, J.B., Jr. A Nobel Prize for Asymmetric Information: The economic contributions of George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz. Rev. Political Econ. 2003, 15, 3–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Borts, G.H.; Stein, J.I. Economic Crowth in a Free Market; Columbia University Press: New York, NY, USA; London, UK, 1964. [Google Scholar]
  33. Siebert, H. Regional Economic Growth Theory and Policy; International Textbook Company: Scranton, PA, USA, 1969. [Google Scholar]
  34. Myrdal, G. Economic Theory and Under-Developed Regions; Gerald Duckworth: London, UK, 1957. [Google Scholar]
  35. Kravchuk, N.Y. Divergence of Global Development: Modern Paradigm of Formation of Geofinancial Space; Znannia: Kyiv, Ukraine, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  36. Stoliarchuk, Y.M. Global Asymmetries of Economic Development: Monograph; KNEU: Kyiv, Ukraine, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  37. Uskov, M.O. Methodological Bases of Identification of Asymmetry of Socio-Economic Development of Regions: Statistical Component. Nauk. Pr. Kirovohradskoho Natsionalnoho Tekhnichnoho Universytetu Seriia Ekon. Nauk. 2007, 12, 299–303. [Google Scholar]
  38. Kovalchuk, Y.; Kulyk, Y. Interregional asymmetry of socio-economic development of Ukraine. Bulletin of the Sumy National Agrarian University. Econ. Manag. 2017, 12, 77–80. [Google Scholar]
  39. Kravchuk, N. Conceptualization of global financial imbalances. Zovnìšnâ Torgìvlâ Ekon. Fìnansi Pravo 2013, 3, 153–159. [Google Scholar]
  40. Virkovska, A.A.; Ivashchuk, I.O. Asymmetries identification of foreign trade interests of european countries. East 2015, 5, 37–45. [Google Scholar]
  41. Bozhydarnik, N.V. Regional Asymmetry in the European Union and Mechanisms of Its Regulation: Abstract of the Dissertation for Obtaining the Scientific Degree of Candidate of Economic Sciences; KNEU: Kyiv, Ukraine, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  42. Storonianska, I.Z. Assessment of the asymmetry of the socio-economic development of the regions of Ukraine and justification of the priorities of the state regional policy. Reg. Econ. 2006, 4, 101–110. [Google Scholar]
  43. Lukianenko, D.H.; Poruchnyk, A.M.; Kolot, A.M. The Global Economy of the 21st Century: The Human Dimension; KNEU: Kyiv, Ukraine, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  44. IMF. Macroeconomic Developments and Prospects in Low-Income Developing Countries. 2018. Available online: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-Papers/Issues/2018/03/22/pp021518macroeconomic-developments-and-prospects-in-lidcs (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  45. World Bank. Published on Data Blog. New Country Classifications by Income Level: 2019–2020. 2020. Available online: https://blogs.worldbank.org/opendata/new-country-classifications-income-level-2019-2020 (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  46. United Nations Development Programme. Human Development Report 2020: The Next Frontier. Human Development and the Anthropocene. 2020. Available online: http://hdr.undp.org/sites/default/files/hdr_2020_overview_english.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  47. World Trade Organization. RTAs Currently in Force, 1948–2021. 2021. Available online: http://rtais.wto.org/UI/charts.aspx (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  48. UNCTADstat. Data Center. Merchandise. Goods and Services (BPM6): Exports and Imports of Goods and Services, Annual. 2021. Available online: https://unctadstat.unctad.org/wds/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=89795 (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  49. World Trade Organization. Dispute Settlement Activity—Some Figures. 2021. Available online: https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/dispu_e/dispustats_e.htm (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  50. World Trade Organization. TABLES by MEMBERS. 2021. Available online: http://i-tip.wto.org/goods/Forms/MemberView.aspx?mode=modify&action=search (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  51. World Trade Organization. Get Tariff Data. 2021. Available online: https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tariffs_e/tariff_data_e.htm (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  52. World Bank. Tariff Rate, Most Favored Nation, Simple Mean, All Products (%). 2021. Available online: https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/TM.TAX.MRCH.SM.FN.ZS (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  53. Kutner, M.H.; Nachtsheim, C.J.; Neter, J.; Li, W. Applied Linear Statistical Models; McGraw-Hill: Dubuque, IA, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  54. World Trade Organization. General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Ministerial Declaration of 20 September, 1986 . Available online: https://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/gatt47.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  55. Stewart, D.P. The Gatt Uruguay Round: A Negotiating History 1986-1992, 1st ed.; Kluwer Law International: Alphen aan den Rijn, The Netherlands, 1983. [Google Scholar]
  56. Shongwe, M.N. The Fragmentation of International Law Through Regionalism: Towards a New World Order? University of Johannesburg: Johannesburg, South Africa, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  57. World Trade Organization. Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization. Available online: https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/booksp_e/agrmntseries1_wto_e.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  58. World Trade Organization. Home Page. Global Trade. Available online: https://www.wto.org (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  59. World Trade Organization. General Agreement on Trade in Services. Available online: https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/serv_e/gatsintr_e.htm (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  60. World Trade Organization. Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights. Marrakesh, Morocco on 15 April 1994. Available online: https://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/27-trips_01_e.htm (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  61. Keck, A.; Hancock, J.; Nee, C. Perspectives for Global Trade and the International Trading System. Wirtschaftsdienst 2018, 98 (Suppl. 1), 16–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  62. Lemeshko, B.I.; Lemeshko, S.B.; Horbunova, A.A. On the application and power of criteria for testing the homogeneity of dispersions. Part II. Nonparametric criteria. Meas. Tech. 2010, 5, 11–18. Available online: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/315329375_O_primenenii_i_mosnosti_kriteriev_proverki_odnorodnosti_dispersij_C_II_Neparametriceskie_kriterii (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  63. Hlants, S. Biomedical Statistics. M., Practice. 1998. Available online: https://techlibrary.ru/b/2k1m1a1o1x_2z._2u1f1e1j1l1p-1b1j1p1m1p1d1j1y1f1s1l1a2g_1s1t1a1t1j1s1t1j1l1a._1999.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  64. Greene, W.H. Econometric Analysis, 7th ed.; Prentice Hall: New York, NY, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  65. James, G.; Witten, D.; Hastie, T.; Tibshirani, R. An Introduction to Statistical Learning: With Applications in R; 1st ed. 2013, Corr. 7th printing 2017 edition; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  66. Stašys, R.; Tananaiko, T. Analysis of factors influencing the world trade volumes. Sci. Notes 2019, 20, 5–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Anderson, J.E.; Yotov, Y.V. Terms of trade and global efficiency effects of free trade agreements, 1990-2002. J. Int. Econ. 2016, 99, 279–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  68. Suominen, K. Enhancing Coherence and Inclusiveness in the Global Trading System in the Era of Regionalism. E15 Expert Group on Regional Trade Agreements and Plurilateral Approaches—Policy Options Paper. E15Initiative. Geneva: International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development (ICTSD) and World Economic Forum. 2016. Available online: http://e15initiative.org/wp-content/uploads/2015/09/E15_no15_RTAs_final.pdf (accessed on 27 November 2022).
  69. Bazaluk, O.; Yatsenko, O.; Reznikova, N.; Bibla, I.; Karasova, N.; Nitsenko, V. International integration processes influence on welfare of country. J. Bus. Econ. Manag. 2022, 23, 382–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Bhagwati, J.; Panagariya, A. The Theory of Preferential Trade Agreements: Historical Evolution and Current Trends. Am. Econ. Rev. 1996, 86, 82–87. [Google Scholar]
  71. Bhagwati, J.; Greenaway, D.; Panagariya, A. Trading Preferentially: Theory and Policy. Econ. J. 1998, 108, 1128–1148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Levy, P.I. A political-economic analysis of free-trade agreements. Am. Econ. Rev. 1997, 87, 506–519. [Google Scholar]
  73. Bhagwati, J. The World Trading System. J. Int. Aff. 1994, 48, 279–285. Available online: http://www.jstor.org/stable/24357343 (accessed on 27 November 2022).
Figure 1. Subjects of the global trading system. Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of the own research.
Figure 1. Subjects of the global trading system. Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of the own research.
Sustainability 15 05316 g001
Figure 2. The structure of the global trading system in 2020. * Notes: Information Technology Agreement. Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of their own research.
Figure 2. The structure of the global trading system in 2020. * Notes: Information Technology Agreement. Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of their own research.
Sustainability 15 05316 g002
Figure 3. Global trading system asymmetry classification. Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of their own research.
Figure 3. Global trading system asymmetry classification. Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of their own research.
Sustainability 15 05316 g003
Table 1. Approaches to defining the notion of asymmetry concerning global economic processes.
Table 1. Approaches to defining the notion of asymmetry concerning global economic processes.
NotionDefinitionAuthor of an Approach
AsymmetryPermanent violation of the matter structure during its evolution in space and time. Economic content of this definition lies in the ascertained absence of structural balance of the global economic system and is manifested in the disproportionate development of its subsystems and components of the global industry due to objective contradictions among them.Stoliarchuk [36]
AsymmetrySuch a structural feature of a particular system on a particular level, which does not correspond to a condition of existing specific regularities that lie in repetition or similarity of a particular phenomenon, notion, process, characteristic, quality, etc.Uskov [37]
AsymmetryAbsence or violation of harmony; a notion opposite to symmetry that reflects system disbalance, abnormality and imbalance that are linked to changes and development of the system.Kovalchuk and Kulyk [38]
Asymmetries of global developmentObjectively existing violations of global centric economic system proportions, which are manifested in value and quantitative, space and time and social and cultural dimensions. One of conceptional methodological positions, within which geoeconomic space is characterized with inner structural and functional integrity on the one hand and submits to regularities of the development of global social relations system on the other, which is distinguished with asynchronous disproportionality and irregularity of development.Kravchuk [39]
Asymmetry of foreign trade interestsHeterogeneity of global economic space, which is manifested in multidirectedness of countries’ interests in foreign trade and is noticed in differences in their economic and human development.Virkovska and Ivashchuk [40]
Regional asymmetryThe process of differentiating local and global territorial taxonomic items, which occurs under the influence of intensification of uneven motion of production and competition factors and implementation of complementary multilevel (local, regional, national and supranational) policy of decreasing disproportionality of social and economic development and securing its sustainability.Bozhydarnik [41]
Regional development asymmetryExtent of inter-regional differences in economic development (economic activity) level and population life (quality) levelStoronianska [42]
Source: compiled by the authors.
Table 2. Results of the analysis of variance for selected indicators of different levels of the factor of countries, divided by the level of economic development.
Table 2. Results of the analysis of variance for selected indicators of different levels of the factor of countries, divided by the level of economic development.
IndicatorF-Criticalp-ValIndicatorF-Criticalp-Val
1.RTAs 179.4030.00012.TRQ6.6710.002
2.Import 10.4460.00013.XS1.2640.286
3.Export 8.9990.00014.non_tariff_total 3.4350.035
4.Disputes_total 2.6540.07515.tariff_lines 19.1340.000
5.SPS2.5860.07916.total_rate_l 33.0470.000
6.TBT2.0560.13217.total_rate_mfn 35.0040.000
7.ADP1.1870.30818.agr_rate_l 15.6140.000
8.CV2.1340.12219.agr_rate_mfn 1.0280.360
9.SG5.0040.00820.non_agr_rate_l 29.7800.000
10.SSG5.3590.00621.non_agr_rate_mfn 48.1610.000
11.QR6.6900.002
Source: compiled by the authors on the basis of their own calculations.
Table 3. The results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for significant indicators at different levels of the factor of groups of countries by the level of economic development according to the Tukey test.
Table 3. The results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for significant indicators at different levels of the factor of groups of countries by the level of economic development according to the Tukey test.
A Group of CountriesIndicator
Group 1Group 2RTAsImportExportDisputes
DevelopedDeveloping0.0010.0010.0010.277
DevelopedThe least-developed0.0010.0010.0010.077
DevelopingThe least-developed0.0220.5840.4860.359
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 4. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for indicators of nontariff trade measures of groups of countries by the level of economic development according to the Tukey test.
Table 4. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for indicators of nontariff trade measures of groups of countries by the level of economic development according to the Tukey test.
A Group of CountriesIndicator
Group 1Group 2SPSSGSSGQRTRQNontariff Total
DevelopedDeveloping0.3650.0120.0060.0050.0080.207
DevelopedThe least-developed0.0640.8510.0350.0040.0030.028
DevelopingThe least-developed0.3510.1220.90.6370.5040.314
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 5. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for indicators of the import duty rate at different levels of the factor of groups of countries by the level of economic development according to the Tukey test.
Table 5. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for indicators of the import duty rate at different levels of the factor of groups of countries by the level of economic development according to the Tukey test.
A Group of CountriesIndicator
Group 1Group 2tariff_
lines
total_
rate
total_rate_mfnagr_
rate_l
non_agr_
rate
non_agr_
rate_mfn
DevelopedDeveloping0.1630.0010.0010.0010.0010.001
DevelopedThe least-developed0.0010.0010.0010.0010.0010.001
DevelopingThe least-developed0.0010.0010.0010.0570.0870.001
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 6. Results of analysis of variance of selected indicators for different levels of the factor belonging to geographical regions of the world.
Table 6. Results of analysis of variance of selected indicators for different levels of the factor belonging to geographical regions of the world.
IndicatorFp-ValIndicatorFp-Val
1.RTAs 55.6000.00012.TRQ1.9730.074
2.Import 9.7590.00013.XS1.3270.249
3.Export 5.6940.00014.non_tariff_total 15.1690.000
4.Disputes_total 15.4170.00015.tariff_lines 14.5160.000
5.SPS16.6980.00016.total_rate_l 14.1230.000
6.TBT9.6830.00017total_rate_mfn 15.6440.000
7.ADP10.6220.00018.agr_rate_l 6.0620.000
8.CV20.5530.00019.agr_rate_mfn 1.4920.185
9.SG1.9390.07920.non_agr_rate_l 14.3000.000
10.SSG6.2560.00021.non_agr_rate_mfn 20.3090.000
11.QR8.2660.000
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 7. The results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for significant indicators at different levels of the factor of regional affiliation of the country according to the Tukey test.
Table 7. The results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for significant indicators at different levels of the factor of regional affiliation of the country according to the Tukey test.
Region 1Region 2RTAsImportExportDisputes
AfricaAsia0.3020.0390.0190.001
AfricaThe CIS0.7480.9000.9000.900
AfricaEurope0.0010.1030.1130.900
AfricaThe Middle East0.9000.9000.9000.900
AfricaNorth America0.5270.0010.0010.001
AfricaSouth America0.5580.9000.9000.677
AsiaThe CIS0.9000.7820.7860.143
AsiaEurope0.0010.9000.9000.001
AsiaThe Middle East0.9000.7070.7020.024
AsiaNorth America0.9000.0010.0290.001
AsiaSouth America0.9000.0700.0420.004
The CISEurope0.0010.9000.9000.900
The CISThe Middle East0.9000.9000.9000.900
The CISNorth America0.9000.0010.0080.001
The CISSouth America0.9000.9000.9000.900
EuropeThe Middle East0.0010.8940.9000.900
EuropeNorth America0.0010.0010.0090.001
EuropeSouth America0.0010.1710.2040.900
The Middle EastNorth America0.7860.0010.0040.001
The Middle EastSouth America0.9000.9000.9000.900
North AmericaSouth America0.9000.0010.0010.001
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 8. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for indicators of nontariff trade regulation measures at different levels of the country’s regional affiliation factor according to the Tukey test.
Table 8. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparison for indicators of nontariff trade regulation measures at different levels of the country’s regional affiliation factor according to the Tukey test.
Region 1Region 2SPSTBTADPCVSGSSGQRTRQNontariff Total
AfricaAsia0.1220.7310.2270.9000.9000.9000.0010.9000.155
AfricaThe CIS0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.6180.9000.900
AfricaEurope0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.0880.900
AfricaThe Middle East0.9000.0010.9000.9000.2240.9000.9000.9000.098
AfricaNorth America0.0010.0010.0010.0010.9000.0010.0130.5050.001
AfricaSouth America0.3810.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.700
AsiaThe CIS0.8740.8200.9000.9000.9000.9000.7850.9000.742
AsiaEurope0.1660.6770.4880.9000.8040.9000.0010.4510.268
AsiaThe Middle East0.9000.0120.6780.9000.6450.9000.0060.9000.900
AsiaNorth America0.0010.0010.0010.0010.9000.0010.9000.6770.001
AsiaSouth America0.9000.9000.7530.9000.4730.9000.0010.9000.900
The CISEurope0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.6850.6550.900
The CISThe Middle East0.9000.0070.9000.9000.9000.9000.7170.9000.439
The CISNorth America0.0010.0010.0010.0010.9000.0010.4910.6280.001
The CISSouth America0.9000.9000.9000.9000.7160.9000.7990.9000.900
EuropeThe Middle East0.9000.0010.9000.9000.1450.9000.9000.4970.147
EuropeNorth America0.0010.0010.0010.0010.9000.0010.0170.9000.001
EuropeSouth America0.46430.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.5880.849
The Middle EastNorth America0.0010.0880.0010.0010.9000.0010.0290.5760.001
The Middle EastSouth America0.9000.0020.9000.9000.0570.9000.9000.9000.61
North AmericaSouth America0.0010.0010.0010.0010.9000.0010.0270.7360.001
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 9. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparisons for import duty rate indicators at different levels of the country group factor by world region according to the Tukey test.
Table 9. Results of pairwise a posteriori comparisons for import duty rate indicators at different levels of the country group factor by world region according to the Tukey test.
Region 1Region 2tariff_
lines
total_rate_ltotal_rate_mfnagr_rate_lnon_agr_rate_lnon_agr_
rate_mfn
AfricaAsia0.0010.0010.0010.0110.0130.001
AfricaThe CIS0.0010.0010.0030.0020.0070.002
AfricaEurope0.0010.0010.0010.0010.0010.001
AfricaThe Middle East0.0010.0490.0010.1710.7200.001
AfricaNorth America0.0210.1020.0070.1810.4480.002
AfricaSouth America0.0010.2880.0310.8130.9000.029
AsiaThe CIS0.5530.4520.9000.4490.6170.900
AsiaEurope0.0530.0070.0590.1580.0090.012
AsiaThe Middle East0.7520.9000.8690.9000.9000.900
AsiaNorth America0.8260.9000.7950.9000.9000.747
AsiaSouth America0.3410.4010.3060.3710.0030.074
The CISEurope0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.745
The CISThe Middle East0.9000.6640.9000.6830.4270.900
The CISNorth America0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.900
The CISSouth America0.9000.0330.3940.0300.0020.329
EuropeThe Middle East0.9000.2370.9000.7000.0300.784
EuropeNorth America0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.900
EuropeSouth America0.9000.0010.0010.0010.0010.001
The Middle EastNorth America0.9000.9000.9000.9000.9000.900
The Middle EastSouth America0.9000.7240.0950.6740.4960.071
North AmericaSouth America0.9000.5510.2460.4850.3010.112
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 10. Results of analysis of variance for selected indicators, 2020.
Table 10. Results of analysis of variance for selected indicators, 2020.
IndicatorANOVA for Country GroupsANOVA for
Regions
Number of regional trade agreements++
Global volumes of goods imports++
Global volumes of exports of goods++
Total number of trade disputes++
Total number of nontariff measures++
The number of bound tariff lines++
The average bound rate of duty in general++
The average rate of MFN duty in general++
Average bound duty rate (Agricultural goods)++
Average rate of MFN duty (Agricultural goods)--
Average bound duty rate (Nonagricultural goods)++
Average MFN duty rate (Nonagricultural goods)++
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own research.
Table 11. The value of the inflation coefficient of the VIF in the array of independent variables—indicators of foreign trade activity.
Table 11. The value of the inflation coefficient of the VIF in the array of independent variables—indicators of foreign trade activity.
Variable VIF Value
RTAs8.3977.5786.742
Disputes_total9.8699.7369.272
tariff_lines11.97711.8488.880
total_rate_l 32.23832.088-
total_rate_mfn 17,425.782--
agr_rate_l21.27421.2695.931
agr_rate_mfn 1225.9857.1535.944
non_agr_rate_l9.6149.5795.227
non_agr_rate_mfn 10,278.5008.1826.707
SPS11.46711.35710.924
TBT 10.61710.61710.502
ADP4.6294.6274.625
CV2.4752.4752.475
SG1.8851.8531.853
SSG1.7921.7861.751
QR2.4292.3442.325
TRQ 3.7683.7253.591
XS2.0512.0382.038
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Table 12. VIF value for the final set of independent variables to be used in the econometric analysis.
Table 12. VIF value for the final set of independent variables to be used in the econometric analysis.
VariableVIF ValueVariableVIF Value
1.RTAs6.7429.TBT 10.502
2.Disputes_total9.27210.ADP4.625
3.tariff_lines8.88011.CV2.475
4.agr_rate_l5.93112.SG1.853
5.agr_rate_mfn5.94413.SSG1.751
6.non_agr_rate_l5.22714.QR2.325
7.non_agr_rate_mfn6.70715.TRQ3.591
8.SPS 10.92416.XS2.038
Source: compiled by the author on the basis of his own calculations.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Tananaiko, T.; Yatsenko, O.; Osypova, O.; Nitsenko, V.; Balezentis, T.; Streimikiene, D. Economic Rationale for Manifestations of Asymmetry in the Global Trading System. Sustainability 2023, 15, 5316. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065316

AMA Style

Tananaiko T, Yatsenko O, Osypova O, Nitsenko V, Balezentis T, Streimikiene D. Economic Rationale for Manifestations of Asymmetry in the Global Trading System. Sustainability. 2023; 15(6):5316. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065316

Chicago/Turabian Style

Tananaiko, Tetiana, Olha Yatsenko, Olha Osypova, Vitalii Nitsenko, Tomas Balezentis, and Dalia Streimikiene. 2023. "Economic Rationale for Manifestations of Asymmetry in the Global Trading System" Sustainability 15, no. 6: 5316. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15065316

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop