Next Article in Journal
An Empirical Study on the Mechanism of Dynamic Capacity Formation in the Supply Chain
Previous Article in Journal
Environmental Justice Pedagogies and Self-Efficacy for Climate Action
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Assessing the Economic Viability of Agricultural Holdings with the Inclusion of Opportunity Costs

by
Zuzana Hloušková
1,*,
Michaela Lekešová
1,
Anna Prajerová
1 and
Tomáš Doucha
2
1
Liaison Agency FADN CZ, Institute of Agricultural Economics and Information, 120 00 Prague, Czech Republic
2
Research Section, Institute of Agricultural Economics and Information, 120 00 Prague, Czech Republic
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2022, 14(22), 15087; https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215087
Submission received: 12 October 2022 / Revised: 4 November 2022 / Accepted: 9 November 2022 / Published: 14 November 2022
(This article belongs to the Section Sustainable Agriculture)

Abstract

:
A key area of sustainable agriculture is the economic sustainability of agricultural holdings. Agricultural holdings should achieve such an income that they are able to cover all of their costs. As part of this study, an indicator of entrepreneurial income and an indicator of economic profit were proposed. Economic profit, in contrast to entrepreneurial income, considers the costs of lost opportunities, so-called opportunity costs. For this purpose, three indicators of the opportunity costs of production factors of labor, land, and capital were defined and calculated. To assess economic profit between different groups of holdings, an economic viability index is established, which identifies a holding as sustainable or at risk. This indicator is composed of the entrepreneurial income indicator and the difference between entrepreneurial income and economic profit. Based on FADN data of a five-year time series, it was confirmed that extensive holdings specializing in grazing livestock are among the most economically endangered subjects. The highest proportion of sustainable holdings was found in holdings specializing in milk production. From the size point of view, small holdings are most endangered, which was confirmed for all production focuses. In contrast, more large and very large holdings were included in the group of viable holdings.

1. Introduction

The Common Agricultural Policy currently addresses many long-term issues, but it also has to deal with new issues. It can be simply stated that, from a long-term perspective, the CAP (Common Agriculture Policy) in the EU is aimed at supporting the income of farms to reach a balanced productive agriculture. The relatively new focus of a green Europe aims at the mutual reciprocity of many diverse aspects with an emphasis on the environment. However, the economic sustainability of agricultural enterprises cannot be neglected in the picture of new policy goals. The research is focused on the issue of the dual farm structure, which is characterized by the different nature of two groups of agricultural enterprises and occurs especially in countries that have undergone the transformation of agriculture. The dual farm structure in agriculture is relatively unusual among EU states, for which the generally applied EU methodology is not sufficient. For this reason, we proceeded with the proposal of a methodology that will allow an objective assessment of the economic situation of farms in this non-standard environment. The aim of this paper is to provide knowledge for the evaluation of farms in an environment with a significant dual farm structure, such as in the Czech Republic.
Data from a Farm Accountancy Data Network (FADN) sample survey are used in EU countries to assess the economic situation of agricultural holdings. Establishment of a FADN survey and its administration according to harmonized rules is one of the conditions for joining the EU. In the Czech Republic, these data from the FADN survey have been available since 2004. The advantages of using FADN data are considerable. The database contains information on both the structure of the holding and its production, costs, financial situation, received subsidies, and economic results. The survey is carried out regularly every year when the same comparable indicators are available. Harmonized methodology ensures comparability between individual EU states. A wide spectrum of classification enables results to be found for different types of holdings. Tracking data at the company level serve to support a microeconomic view of the economic management of agricultural entities. Last but not least, representativeness of the obtained data for the region, production focus, and economic size according to the unified typology of agricultural holdings in the EU is methodologically ensured. Unfortunately, in addition to a wide list of advantages, certain limits can also be discussed in the use of data from the FADN database, which are mainly caused by changes in society, economic developments, as well as shifts in the needs of agricultural and environmental policy. These are, for example, changes in methodological guidelines over time, which can cause difficulties when evaluating results in a time series, or a narrowly specified list of monitored and published indicators that adapts to the above-mentioned changes over time. This article is focused on the final indicators of the economic management of agricultural holdings, as defined by FADN standard results [1]. FADN standard results are a set of indicators that are calculated according to uniform formulas and are commonly used in EU member states and the European Commission.
In connection with the preparation of the new CAP in the EU, the question of which kinds of farms may be threatened by the effects of the agricultural policy has raised again. In the EU environment, employing FADN impact indicators for evaluating income does not allow for a unified view of farms due to their dual structure in some countries. One of these countries, where the dual structure of farms is very pronounced, is the Czech Republic.
The dual structure of farms can be described by the high difference between the two groups of enterprises. In the Czech Republic, one of the groups is a group of large enterprises, which contains a smaller number of farms, but produces most of the agricultural production. Large companies are legal entities and are in a better position to obtain bank loans. The second group is smaller-sized businesses. These are mostly family farms with a predominance of unpaid labor and owned land. These differences do not allow identification of the real threat to farms from changes in the impact of agricultural policies.
Standard results contain several indicators that are considered indicators of the economic result of agricultural holdings. These are gross farm income (total output minus intermediate consumption plus balance current subsidies and taxes), farm net value added (gross farm income minus depreciation), and farm net income (farm net value added minus total external factors plus balance subsidies and taxes on investments). Total external factors include wages paid, rent paid, and interest paid. The final indicator does not take into account the costs of unpaid labor, the owned land, and the equity capital, which are available to agricultural holdings. In practice, the valuation of own factors is approached as the valuation of lost opportunity costs, also known as opportunity costs. Opportunity costs are an important component for assessing the long-term viability of a holding. Czech agriculture has an extreme and, among EU countries, unique dual structure; on the one hand, large holdings, which mainly use paid employees, rent land, and use external capital intensively, and, on the other hand, smaller entities (often family farms), which use mostly unpaid family workers, manage their own land, and use external capital on a smaller scale. In view of this fact, the question arises as to whether the indicator farm net income, which should represent the final profit of business activity, is the most suitable indicator for comparing economic results among all agricultural entities in the Czech Republic.
The authors are searching for a way to compile an indicator, here called the economic viability index, that would solve the shortcomings of the current impact indicators. The intention is to enable the assessment of policy impacts from a production sector perspective as a farm size perspective without the necessity to separate family farms and legal entities. This means objectively assessing the threats to both groups of businesses.
The novelty of the research comes from the design of a method that enables the evaluation of economic viability between economic subjects with a different approach to business. It brings the comparability of results into an environment with a dual character of business and thus enables a more accurate setting of agricultural policy measures.
Within this study, an economic viability index was designed, and opportunity costs of labor, land and capital were calculated for various farming specializations and economic size classes. The economic viability index identifies the farm as sustainable or endangered. Moreover, since the data are based on the FADN methodology, the method can also be applied to other EU countries. The findings are very important as they enrich the knowledge of the farms’ economic viability and they allow them to target agricultural policies to the appropriate group of farmers.
Within this study, we discuss the possibility of using opportunity costs for the evaluation of the economic viability of agricultural holdings in the Czech Republic, the design of indicators of opportunity costs, and subsequent final economic indicators using the FADN database, including the assessment of the results found.

1.1. Sustainability and Viability

The FADN is used in the European Union to assess the economic (income) level of agricultural holdings, to plan strategic measures of the Common Agricultural Policy, and also to retrospectively evaluate previously adopted political measures. The aim is to ensure functional agriculture, i.e., food production, biodiversity, clean environment, permanent qualitative soil potential and improvement, the settlement of a functioning countryside and, last but not least, the viability of agricultural holdings, which have an impact on all the areas mentioned. The aim of the CAP, together with national (state) aid and other measures, is therefore permanent sustainability based on production, economic, environmental, and social areas. In his recent study, Darnhofer [2] considers the prospective possibility of changing the CAP and the approach of holdings to the benefit of sustainability and resilience. Indicators of the economic sustainability of agricultural holdings include among others information on profitability, productivity and viability [3]. Viability in relation to economic sustainability in agriculture was analyzed by O’Donoghue et al. [4] using supplemented data to the FADN survey; comparing eight states, they identified the highest proportion of economically sustainable holdings in Germany, and the lowest in Poland. The authors concluded that there are several definitions in the literature that explain the concept of economic viability. However, the emphasis is on the farmer making a living. In some studies, there is also a requirement for returns from on-farm investment. Views differ on whether to consider viability as a farm household welfare measure or an opportunity cost measure.
To determine the viability of agricultural holdings in this study, indicators constructed on the basis of the accounting results and the value of evaluated opportunity costs are used.
The EU pilot study [4] compared the viability of eight EU member states based on FADN data. The broad model of viability, identifying sustainable and vulnerable farms, was constructed as:
F F I C O C H W F > T W ,
where FFI is family farm income, COC is cost of own capital, HWF is hours worked on the farm, and TW is threshold wages.
One of the most recently published outputs was prepared by Hlavsa et al. [5], who proposed the farm economic viability (FEV) indicator. This indicator considers only opportunity costs of labor and capital and is calculated based on the following formula:
F E V = F N V A R P ( I P + O C C ) W + O C L ,
where FNVA stands for farm net value added, RP is rent paid, IP is interest paid, OCC is opportunity costs of capital (including land), W is wages, and OCL stands for opportunity costs of labor.
An agricultural holding is economically viable if the FEV value is greater than one. If it is lower than or equal to one, then a holding is considered unviable from the point of view of its further development.
The European Commission 2018 [6] classified agricultural holdings from the FADN survey between 2004 and 2013 according to their farm net income compared to opportunity costs and depreciation. Four classes were compiled from the results: (1) income > opportunity costs; (2) income is still positive; (3) delayed depreciation; and (4) financial distress. The largest share of holdings classified in class 3 and 4 was in 2009. Conversely, the largest share of the sustainable group of holdings (class 1 and 2) was found in 2007.
To assess the viability of agricultural holdings, an estimate of the costs of lost opportunities is used [3,4,7]. It stands for lost activities in which the holdings could put their own production factors if they did not run the farm business activity. The advantage of this approach lies in the possibility of comparing the economic results of holdings using mainly external resources with holdings that use their own resources. In addition, the different structure and degree of use of own production factors in different types of agricultural holdings requires the inclusion of opportunity costs for a more objective assessment of economic profit. Opportunity costs of own production factors are equivalent to external factors which, unlike own factors, are already considered in the final management indicator (farm net income).

1.2. Opportunity Costs

The costs of lost opportunities, so-called opportunity costs, are estimated for production factors in agriculture, which include unpaid labor, land owned, and equity capital. Opportunity costs are not part of the FADN business data database. Another component for the overall determination of the economic viability of holdings is off-farm income, which is important for assessing the situation of smaller holdings [8,9]. The FADN system does not contain this information and cannot be ascertained in any way other than direct investigation; therefore, it is often not included in the viability assessment. These data were supplemented, for example, in the FLINT project [4].
The opportunity costs of unpaid labor express the income that the entrepreneur would receive if he/she were to terminate his/her entrepreneurial activity and work as an employee. For small-scale sole proprietorships, this item contains a large volume of opportunity costs. The different authors lean towards different approaches for determining wage costs that are used to value unpaid labor. Here, one can consider both the employment relationship in agriculture [4] and outside agriculture [10,11] or the workplace in the same region [6,12] or not. Wage costs value the amount of unpaid labor, which in the FADN system is monitored by the indicator of the input of unpaid labor (FWU). For this purpose, the European Commission 2021 [13] applies the calculation of the average hourly regional wage of paid workers in agricultural holdings in the FADN database and the number of hours worked by unpaid labor. In the case of a small number of farms in a region, the national average value is taken into account.
The opportunity costs of equity capital are higher than the cost of external capital because of the higher risk involved in investing one’s own funds in a business versus the risk of a creditor. Furthermore, an entrepreneur using equity capital loses the possibility of reducing income tax by deducting cost interest. This is also why it is appropriate to consider the valuation of the cost of equity capital when assessing the economic situation of holdings. An alternative cost for using equity capital can be, for example, depositing capital in a savings account, or income from investing in securities or real estate. Among the methods used for equity capital valuation are, for example, the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), the arbitrage pricing model, and the dividend growth model. These models were built mainly for large corporate firms; they cannot be used to adequately value the cost of land owned, and therefore are not suitable for agricultural holdings. However, even for determining the viability of agricultural holdings, some authors [4,5,14,15,16] do not value land owned and use the value of the total property owned. In contrast, other studies [13,17] use an equity capital valuation approach after deducting the value of agricultural land. This approach makes it possible to determine the opportunity cost for the production factor of land separately. The opportunity costs of equity capital can be derived using a certain percentage of the equity capital value in the form of an interest rate. Its amount can be determined, for example, in the form of Eurostat’s ten-year government bond yields [16], the long-term interest rate of government bonds for convergence purposes of the European Central Bank [4], or the long-term interest rate for own property from the Global Insight database [13].
In addition, some authors consider a risk premium for depositing capital in a risky environment [18,19], which can be determined in several ways. The value of the risk premium for doing business in a given country is published by Damodaran [20] under an indicator called total equity risk premium. A different approach is applied by agri benchmark (a network of agricultural economists, producers, specialists and advisors in key sectors of the agricultural chain, agribenchmark.org (accessed on 10 September 2022)), which uses a uniform value of 3% for property valuation due to the comparability of results between individual European countries.
The opportunity costs of land owned represent the returns from its alternative use. If the farmers did not carry out their economic activity, then they could rent their land or sell it. Soil differs from other production factors in its non-reproducibility and immobility. Land is permanent, it is not consumed, and thus it is not depreciated as an asset. Approaches to determine the opportunity costs of land also differ. Some authors value land within equity capital [16] and do not specifically single it out. The valuation of land owned, i.e., the alternative income of renting it, can be completed using the average rent rate in a given region or holding [11]. Authors considering the sale of land as an alternative for its pricing use the average market price of agricultural land in the region or in the holding [6,13,17]. In its methodology, agri benchmark uses the equivalent of rent in the value for which the farmer would like to enter into a new lease agreement.

2. Materials and Methods

The case study is located to the Czech Republic. There are 62,151 registered farmers, of which 82% are family farms, and 18% are legal entities. Agriculture covers approximately half (53%) of the country’s total area and contributes 2% to the national gross domestic product. There are 4.2 million hectares of agricultural land in the Czech Republic, of which 3 million hectares is arable land. In 2021, the main crop production was cereals (1,334,000 ha), oilseeds (442,000 ha), sugar beet (61,000 ha), legumes (43,000 ha), and others. In livestock, the Czech Republic focuses on production of meat, milk, and eggs. The total number of reared beef cattle is 1.4 million, pigs are 1.5 million, and poultry is 23.8 million. All technologies used in agriculture are comparable to neighboring EU countries. The importance of organic farming is rising (constituting more than 19% of beef cattle and more than 15% of land in 2019).
The FADN database in the Czech Republic [21] was used for this paper. The data set was used for the five-year time series from 2016 to 2020 as the economic viability should be analyzed as a multiannual average [14].
Agricultural holdings were classified according to the typology of agricultural holdings in the EU into the group of holdings specializing in field crops, grazing livestock, milk, and mixed. Furthermore, holdings were classified according to economic size into small (EUR 8000–50,000 of standard output (SO)), medium (EUR 50,000–500,000 of SO), large (EUR 500,000–1,000,000 of SO), and very large (more than EUR 1,000,000 of SO).
The proposed method takes into account opportunity costs of own labor, opportunity costs of land owned, and positive values of opportunity costs of equity capital after deducting the value of owned agricultural land.
On the basis of a literature search, an indicator of the opportunity costs of land (OpC) was determined, which is calculated by multiplying the land owned in hectares and the amount of rent in the given region determined from the FADN database. In this way, the current situation on the agricultural land market is taken into account. This study also works with the opportunity cost of labor indicator (OpCLB), which is determined by multiplying the input of unpaid labor by the farm average wage in the region. Both values are obtained from the FADN CZ database. The last own factor considered is the opportunity cost of capital (OpCA), where the value of the final state of land owned is subtracted from the equity. This difference is then multiplied by the interest rate. To estimate the cost of equity capital, according to the agri benchmark methodology, a uniform 3% interest rate for long-term government bonds is used, which takes into account the risk premium.
Total opportunity costs are the sum of the above individual components according to the following equation:
T O p C = O p C L B + O p C L + O p C A ,
where TOpC is total opportunity cost, OpCLB is opportunity cost of labor, CpCL is opportunity cost of land, and OpCA is opportunity cost of assets.
As the final economic indicator, FADN standard results determine the farm net income, which includes investment subsidies. To determine entrepreneurial income, it is necessary to subtract investment subsidies from farm net income. Entrepreneurial income using basic FADN indicators is calculated according to the following equation:
E I = T O I C + B C S T E C D ,
where EI is entrepreneurial income, TO is total output, IC is intermediate consumption, BCST is balance current subsidies and taxes, EC is external costs, and D is depreciation.
In general, accounting profit represents income minus costs; if we subtract the opportunity costs of the entrepreneur’s own production factors from this indicator, we obtain economic profit. Using the indicators of the FADN system, economic profit can subsequently be achieved by applying the following equation:
E P = T O I C + B C S T E C D T O p C ,
where EP is economic profit, TO is total output, IC is intermediate consumption, BCST is balance current subsidies and taxes, EC is external costs, and D is depreciation and TOpC is total opportunity costs.
The following simple but complex equation is subsequently defined for the calculation of the economic viability index of agricultural holdings:
E V I = E I E I E P ,
where EVI is economic viability index, EI is entrepreneurial income, and EP is economic profit.
An economic viability index threshold of 1 has been defined. Farms with an economic viability index equal to 1 make neither a profit nor a loss. Farms whose economic viability index is higher than 1 are likely to be viable in the long term. The higher the index result, the better off the farm is, as it achieves a higher economic profit. Farms with an economic viability index less than 1 generate a loss if we consider opportunity costs. The lower the number, the higher the threat and the risk of leaving the business and the farms viability is likely to be endangered. With a negative result, farms operate at a clear loss even without deducting opportunity costs.
A value of the economic viability index higher than 1 indicates a long-term viable agricultural holding. In contrast, a result that is equal to 1 or lower means that the viability of the holding is endangered, because it does not have the means for further development, or it must be compensated by a lower standard of living on farms, respectively.
The Mann-Whitney U test was used to determine whether there are statistically significant differences between two independent groups for a single continuous variable with nonparametric distribution. The test was performed for the economic viability index to be compared between groups of farms classified according to type of farming and economic size. The Mann–Whitney U test has many suitable uses, and it should be considered when using ranked data, data that deviate from acceptable distribution patterns, or for when there are noticeable differences in the number of subjects in the two comparative groups [22].
The data were processed in the TIBCO Statistica program.

3. Results

From the data presented, significant differences are evident both between the type of farming and between farms with different economic sizes within individual specializations. Holdings in mixed production and milk production have the highest workload. Usually, large and very large farms employ paid workers, whereas small and medium farms have a larger share of their own labor. Larger holdings have more available external capital, which accounts for almost 40% of total assets for livestock holdings. As the size of the holding increases, the share of land owned and the share of permanent grassland decreases. The effect of size is also evident in the shares of opportunity costs, which is highest for small and medium farms. In contrast, for large and very large farms, the influence of opportunity costs is minimal. The lowest farm net value added per annual work unit (AWU) is found in grazing livestock holdings with a focus on meat production, while the highest farm net value added per AWU is also achieved by grazing livestock holdings, specializing in milk production.
The presented results demonstrate the diversity of Czech agriculture and confirm the need for further research (e.g., how to improve the sustainability of Czech small- and medium-sized farms with a higher share of their own resources). An overview of average values of selected indicators and their comparison between groups of holdings of individual types of farming and economic size is shown in Table 1.
It is clear that the farm type has an influence on the farm’s economic viability in the conditions of the Czech Republic. In general, the lowest economic viability index is for grazing livestock farms. The highest viability was found at milk farms.
The lowest level for the economic viability index is found in small-sized holdings for all production focuses. Small field crops and small mixed farms are most endangered. In contrast, large crops and large mixed farms, which achieve the highest economic viability, can be assessed as economically viable. Very large farms achieve the highest economic viability index in the production focus of milk and grazing livestock.
It was found that the largest margin of economic viability between the lower and upper quartile occurs in large and very large farms with a focus on field crops and mixed farming. Conversely, small mixed and milk farms show the lowest variability of this indicator. The results of the distribution of the economic viability index are presented in Table 2. An interesting finding was detected in the lower quartile for very large field crops farms, large milk farms, and large mixed farms. These groups of farms have a negative index in the lowest quartile, although the median value reaches rather high values. The economic results of farms in these groups are negative even without subtraction of the opportunity costs.
Hlavsa et al. [5] performed a similar analysis, taking into account differences in the production focus of agricultural holdings. Their output confirms the established results of viability; using the FEV indicator (Equation (1)), the least resilient holdings in the livestock grazing group were found, followed by holdings of mixed production. In contrast, different results were found for sustainable (viable) holdings, where the FEV indicator was the highest for field production holdings; however, using the economic viability index calculated here, the highest value was found for the group of holdings specializing in milk production.
In order to divide the holdings according to economic viability, the holdings were classified into two classes of economic viability: (1) the class that contains endangered holdings, whose economic viability index is equal to or less than 1; and (2) the class of viable holdings, whose economic viability index is greater than 1. During the examined five-year period, the same proportion of viable holdings (49.9%) and endangered holdings (50.0%) was found.
The largest share of viable holdings (61%) can be found in milk production. The same share, but of endangered holdings, can be found in the livestock grazing specialization. Field production holdings in the viable group are in the most favorable position, with an average value of 3.04 of the economic viability index. In the endangered group, holdings with mixed production are in the least favorable position, with the economic viability index of −0.44 (Table 3). The reason can be found in the highest representation of small farms, whose negative index of economic viability lowers the average of the entire group.
In a more detailed analysis according to economic size, the largest share of viable holdings was found in the group of large field crops farms. This group is closely followed by large grazing livestock farms and very large milk farms. The highest share of endangered holdings was detected in groups with small holdings of all production focuses (79% of farms and more). The group of small mixed farms shows almost 88% of endangered farms (Table 3).
Testing was performed for a statistically significant difference in the distribution of the economic viability index between groups of holdings of different production orientations and sizes, both for the entire set and for the distribution according to the class of economic viability for the group of endangered and viable holdings.
Hlavsa et al. [5] also found a statistically significant difference in some production orientations, based on testing the analysis of variance between groups of holdings in areas with natural constraints (ANC). In our case, where the economic viability index reflects the opportunity costs of all three production factors, a statistically significant difference in distribution was found between almost all the tested pairs. The hypothesis of the same distribution was only confirmed in five pairs. This is the mean value of the economic viability index for endangered field crops and mixed farms, and field crops and milk farms. For the group of viable farms, three pairs with a statistically similar distribution were found, namely field crops and mixed farms, field crops and milk, and milk and mixed farms (Table 4).
From the economic point of view, the results confirm that economic viability varies between different farming groups. Grazing livestock stands out compared to other groups. This is because there are mostly small farms in this group. They are mainly extensive cattle breeding farms in foothills and mountain locations, which must be maintained despite the lower economic performance due to the lower productivity. According to the results found, as is discussed in the next section, it is confirmed that this is the most endangered group of businesses.
When assessing the difference in the mean value (median) of the economic viability index from the perspective of farm size, a large influence of this aspect was found. Only between the groups of endangered small and medium farms was the null hypothesis of the same distribution accepted. Testing other pairs confirmed a statistically significant difference in the distribution between holdings of different sizes (Table 5). These results prove the impact of the dual farm structure. Large farms are likely to be the most sustainable. This finding is in line with the new strategic plan of the Czech agricultural policy focusing on the small farm support.

4. Discussion

In general, farm economy and incomes are usually measured in the EU by the so-called indicator A (farm net value added per AWU), but also by the entrepreneurial income. Any interpretations of the mentioned indicators across different farm categories are influenced in the Czech conditions by the extreme dual farm structure. The Czech dual farm structure is characterized by the existence of a relatively low number of very large farms with a very low share of unpaid labor and own land, and at the same time with many small and medium enterprises (SMEs) as family farms in the majority of cases, with just a contrary prevailing share of unpaid labor and own land. To objectively assess the real economic situation of farms under the mentioned dual farm structure is a problem that is not so important in EU countries with a relatively homogeneous (non-dual) farm structure. The inclusion of opportunity costs in the complex assessment of the real economic situation of farms is therefore very important in the Czech Republic. This kind of assessment has also been used in the preparation of the Czech strategic plan for the CAP 2023+ and has been reflected, e.g., in a very high level (23%) of the so-called redistribution of direct payments to the benefit of smaller farms, the highest level in EU countries. The 23% redistribution in the Czech policy means that this share of the basic income support system (BISS–the main part of direct payments in the CAP) is used for an additional payment per ha for the first 150 ha of each farm, regardless of its size.
From the results found, in accordance with the conclusions of other studies [12,23,24,25], it can be stated that the least developable and economically viable holdings are oriented on extensive production, as are, for example, livestock grazing holdings in the Czech Republic. One of the reasons why farmers focused on grazing livestock do not leave agriculture is the fact that they are in remote areas where there is not a large availability of other livelihood opportunities. The continuation of their agricultural activities is important for the preservation of the rural settlement and its further development.
A study of the technical efficiency of milk farms in EU countries states in its conclusions that holdings classified in a narrowly specialized milk production are less efficient and can achieve an increase in efficiency by diversifying activities [25]. This article, however, using the economic viability indicator, points out that holdings of mixed production are endangered to a greater extent, although the largest share of milk produced in the Czech Republic comes from mixed holdings. In addition, the type of production focus also has an impact on the development of costs (e.g., rent) due to changes in individual CAP measures [26,27].
Based on a set of European agricultural holdings, Baležentis et al. [28] confirmed that their economic profit increases with their size. This follows on from the finding that higher resilience is achieved by larger holdings, and, in contrast, small holdings are endangered from the point of view of economic viability in the conditions of the Czech Republic. A similar suggestion was also proposed by Coppola et al. [29] who analyzed the economic viability of farms in Italy. Moreover, Biagini et al. [30] concluded that the benefits from the large-scale farm structure can also be applied to the efficiency of income gained from CAP measures.
A high share of endangered enterprises is in the group of the smallest enterprises. There is a high risk of leaving agriculture for these businesses. This leads to the question of why these businesses do not abandon agriculture, and why they do not take advantage of other livelihood opportunities. One of the reasons can be the off-farm income of farms. Off-farm income can cover a significant share of the total income of family farms. However, the FADN system does not currently track this income. The differences between the size, production orientation, and natural conditions of agricultural holdings are particularly significant in Czech agriculture. One of the key areas of sustainability in agriculture is the economic sustainability of agricultural holdings. For its assessment, an indicator called the economic viability index was established. According to the index, agricultural holdings were classified into two groups: viable and endangered. This indicator includes estimates of opportunity costs of all three production factors—labor, land, and capital. Based on the data of the five-year time series, it was confirmed that among the most economically endangered subjects are extensive holdings specializing in livestock grazing. The highest proportion of sustainable holdings was found in holdings focused on milk production. From the size point of view, small holdings are most endangered, which was confirmed for all production orientations. In contrast, more large and very large holdings were included in the group of viable holdings. This finding confirms the need to support the viability and resilience of smaller, extensive farms. These are farms focused on grazing livestock. These farms are located in remote areas that need to be maintained in a sustainable way. Agriculture is important to preserve employment and social interaction so that the countryside is not abandoned. A relevant type of this kind of support is redistribution. This methodology was applied as one of the impact assessment factors for its determination. The redistribution is also aimed at small farms, to which it contributes a relatively large share of direct payments on the first 150 hectares. From the point of view of EU policy, the high value of this support in the Czech Republic is unique, in that it also emphasizes the need to support small farms. To continue this research, there could be deeper examination of the group of endangered holdings, of all size groups, with a focus on identifying the causes of their non-viability. These findings could help to identify effective CAP tools to increase the resilience of the vulnerable farms identified in this study.
At the same time, the proposed indicator could be used for modelling the impact of future agricultural policies, for their optimization, and for evaluation of current tools. Any dual structure provokes e.g., questions about the efficiency of flat policy measures. The extreme dual structure of Czech farms thus stimulates further research following the need to respect this structure in shaping agricultural policy instruments, to look for the improvement in the economic viability of smaller farms and for a higher internal (national) convergence in this area among different farm categories. Another important politically sensitive question arises from the presented findings: how strong is the resilience of small Czech farms in particular, and what stimulates them to survive and to continue in business? This, however, is a question mainly for sociologists.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Z.H. and M.L.; formal analysis, Z.H. and M.L.; investigation, Z.H. and A.P.; methodology, M.L. and T.D.; project administration, A.P.; validation, Z.H., M.L. and A.P.; writing—original draft, Z.H., M.L. and A.P.; writing—review and editing, Z.H., M.L., A.P. and T.D. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This study was supported by the Ministry of Agriculture of the Czech Republic, institutional support MZE-RO0922 (1281/2022).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data presented in this study are available on request from the corresponding author. The data are not publicly available due to privacy restrictions (GDPR).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. European Commission. DG AGRI. Definitions of Variables used in FADN Standard Results, RI/CC 1750; European Commission: Brusseles, Belgium; Luxembourg, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  2. Darnhofer, I. Farm resilience in the face of the unexpected: Lessons from the COVID-19 pandemic. Agric. Hum. Values 2020, 37, 605–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Lynch, J.; Donnellan, T.; Finn, J.A.; Dillon, E.; Ryan, M. Potential development of Irish agricultural sustainability indicators for current and future policy evaluation needs. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 230, 434–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  4. O’Donoghue, C.; Devisme, S.; Ryan, M.; Conneely, R.; Gillespie, P.; Vrolijk, H. Farm economic sustainability in the European Union: A pilot study. Stud. Agric. Econ. 2016, 118, 163–171, ISSN 2063-0476. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Hlavsa, T.; Spicka, J.; Stolbova, M.; Hlouskova, Z. Statistical analysis of economic viability of farms operating in Czech areas facing natural constraints. Agric. Econ. 2020, 66, 193–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. European Commission. DG Agri. Agricultural and Farm Income. DG Agriculture and Rural Development; European Commission: Brusseles, Belgium; Luxembourg, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  7. Spicka, J.; Hlavsa, T.; Soukupova, K.; Stolbova, M. Approaches to estimation the farm-level economic viability and sustainability in agriculture: A literature review. Agric. Econ. 2019, 65, 289–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Dabkienė, V. Off-farm role in stabilizing disposable farm income: A Lithuanian case study. Agric. Econ. 2020, 66, 325–334. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Vrolijk, H.C.J.; Poppe, K.J. Impact of off-farm income and paid taxes on the composition and volatility of incomes and wealth of dairy farmers in The Netherlands. In Proceedings of the 171th EAAE Seminar Measuring and Evaluating Farm Income and Well-Being of Farm Families in Europe—Towards a Shared and Broader Approach for Analysis and Policy Design? Taenikon, Switzerland, 5–6 September 2019; pp. 1–14. [Google Scholar]
  10. Bosch, A.; Blandón, G. The influence of size on cost behaviour associated with tactical and operational flexibility. Estud. Econ. 2011, 38, 419–455, ISSN 0304-2758. [Google Scholar]
  11. Ciaian, P.; Kancs, A.; Espinosa, M. The Impact of the 2013 CAP Reform on the Decoupled Payments’ Capitalisation into Land Values. J. Agric. Econ. 2018, 69, 306–337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Davidova, S.; Gorton, M.; Ratinger, T.; Zawalinska, K.; Iraizoz, B. Farm productivity and profitability: A comparative analysis of selected new and existing EU member states. Comp. Econ. Stud. 2005, 47, 652–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. European Commission. DG AGRI. EU Dairy Farms Report Based on 2018 FADN Data; European Commission: Brusseles, Belgium; Luxembourg, 2021. [Google Scholar]
  14. Špička, J.; Dereník, P. How opportunity costs change the view on the viability of farms? Empirical evidence from the EU. Agric. Econ. 2021, 67, 41–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Nurmet, M.; Omel, R. Economic Viability by Farm Size of Estonian Family Farms. Probl. Agric. Econ. 2020, 362, 14–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Vrolijk, H.C.J.; De Bont, C.; Blokland, P.; Soboh, R. Farm Viability in the European Union: Assessment of the Impact of Changes in Farm Payments; LEI Wageningen: Hague, The Netherlands, 2010; ISBN 978-90-8615-399-2. [Google Scholar]
  17. Wąs, A.; Sulewski, P.; Majewski, E. Methodical and practical aspects of the parity income in the Polish agriculture. Probl. Agric. Econ. 2019, 2, 3–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Alekneviciene, V.; Stareviciute, B.; Alekneviciute, E. Evaluation of the efficiency of European Union farms: A risk-adjusted return approach. Agric. Econ. 2018, 64, 241–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Hennessy, T.; Shrestha, S.; Farrell, M. Quantifying the viability of farming in Ireland: Can decoupling address the regional imbalances? Ir. Geogr. 2008, 41, 29–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Damodaran, A. Country Risk: Determinants, Measures and Implications—The 2021 Edition; New York University: New York, NY, USA, 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. FADN. Database Farm Accountancy Data Network Czech Republic, Liaison Agency FADN CZ, Institute of Agricultural Economics and Information; FADN: Prague, Czech Republic, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  22. MacFarland, T.; Yates, J. Mann–Whitney U Test. In Introduction to Nonparametric Statistics for the Biological Sciences Using R; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Miljatović, A.; Vukoje, V. Assessment of Economic Viability of Small-Scale Farms in Serbia. Contemp. Agric. 2022, 71, 65–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Savickiene, J.; Mickeikiene, A.; Jurgelaitiene, L. Assessment of Economic Viability in Agriculture. Strategic Approaches in Economy, Governance and Business; Zbuchea, A., Pînzaru, F., Eds.; Tritonic: Bucharest, Romania, 2016; pp. 101–118. ISBN 978-606-749-180-7. [Google Scholar]
  25. Náglová, Z.; Rudinskaya, T. Factors Influencing Technical Efficiency in the EU Dairy Farms. Agriculture 2021, 11, 1114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Klaiber, H.A.; Salhofer, K.; Thompson, S.R. Capitalisation of the SPS into Agricultural Land Rental Prices under Harmonisation of Payments. J. Agric. Econ. 2017, 68, 710–726. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Gocht, A.; Britz, W.; Ciaian, P.; Paloma, S.G. Farm Type Effects of an EU-wide Direct Payment Harmonisation. J. Agric. Econ. 2013, 64, 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Baležentis, T.; Galnaitytė, A.; Kriščiukaitienė, I.; Namiotko, V.; Novickytė, L.; Streimikiene, D.; Melnikiene, R. Decomposing Dynamics in the Farm Profitability: An Application of Index Decomposition Analysis to Lithuanian FADN Sample. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2861. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Coppola, A.; Scardera, A.; Amato, M.; Verneau, F. Income Levels and Farm Economic Viability in Italian Farms: An Analysis of FADN Data. Sustainability 2020, 12, 4898. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Biagini, L.; Antonioli, F.; Severini, S. The Role of the Common Agricultural Policy in Enhancing Farm Income: A Dynamic Panel Analysis Accounting for Farm Size in Italy. J. Agric. Econ. 2020, 71, 652–675. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Average values of selected indicators for the period 2016–2020.
Table 1. Average values of selected indicators for the period 2016–2020.
Type of FarmingField CropsMilk
Economic SizeSmallMediumLargeVery LargeSmallMediumLargeVery Large
Number of observations24112043134072827165241
Annual work unit/100 ha 5.652.211.572.288.284.283.243.78
Livestock unit/ha forage crops0.260.610.210.381.091.130.991.10
Share of unpaid labor (%)94.6370.4211.922.43100.0068.584.410.00
Total liabilities per total assets (%)5.6916.9027.2729.183.4417.2936.2938.67
Share of rented land (%)47.0563.2580.1978.4437.4454.8183.5683.78
Share of permanent grassland (%)9.146.164.684.2056.8154.0652.6933.70
Total output per ha (CZK)33,05629,77534,54146,60143,12447,67340,81555,137
Total intermediate consumption per ha (CZK)22,22519,78423,30233,84629,89931,20731,33942,304
Total subsidies excl. on investments per ha (CZK)836478818526982311,30713,73714,09217,997
Farm net value added per AWU (CZK)12,25912,93215,63817,67419,14123,61218,60323,784
Total subsidies excl. on investments per total output (%)33.2330.3127.2626.2728.7135.2538.1234.99
Total opportunity costs per ha (CZK)17,80072501985203831,61112,75721722219
Total costs per total costs plus opportunity costs (%)61.1680.2094.3195.6952.0976.6995.4796.92
Type of FarmingGrazing LivestockMixed
Economic SizeSmallMediumLargeVery LargeSmallMediumLargeVery Large
Number of observations63249836102224391771002
Annual work unit/100 ha 3.892.071.632.477.453.192.172.92
Livestock unit/ha forage crops0.550.580.690.821.100.870.891.20
Share of unpaid labor (%)96.6652.701.370.9199.0980.894.600.11
Total liabilities per total assets (%)9.0820.0327.9643.085.5016.6731.5538.27
Share of rented land (%)51.7163.4376.7182.8033.5261.1682.2181.90
Share of permanent grassland (%)89.0786.2373.0339.8740.0829.7032.4317.09
Total output per ha (CZK)16,28914,91818,06034,59436,57231,79330,73451,373
Total intermediate consumption per ha (CZK)16,45214,41117,60125,72322,99722,50724,03839,130
Total subsidies excl. on investments per ha (CZK)14,31015,16514,84712,337959310,67610,89313,324
Farm net value added per AWU (CZK)857911,84811,78616,68416,08714,33413,85119,621
Total subsidies excl. on investments per total output (%)135.58145.80104.7636.8051.3449.6245.9228.69
Total opportunity costs per ha (CZK)15,33161331642147330,12811,53219731972
Total costs per total costs plus opportunity costs (%)60.5278.8094.5896.6253.6173.8195.1096.78
ha—utilized agricultural area, AWU—annual work unit, and source—FADN CZ (2022).
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the economic viability index.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the economic viability index.
GroupsMeanMedianLower QuartileUpper QuartileStd.Dev.Coef.Var.
Field crops1.421.140.302.462.84199.81
Small0.420.430.120.761.03246.42
Medium1.241.150.472.152.03163.88
Large2.702.540.414.614.54168.24
Very large1.571.51−0.083.343.51223.01
Milk1.601.410.512.622.22138.84
Small0.570.500.240.830.5290.77
Medium1.561.390.742.381.94124.07
Large1.630.91−0.202.912.93180.27
Very large1.751.650.442.882.38136.30
Grazing livestock1.020.730.251.511.78174.98
Small0.590.450.140.860.81136.90
Medium1.491.320.572.232.41162.15
Large1.691.580.412.401.95115.15
Very large2.101.781.213.601.6679.09
Mixed1.200.980.162.162.67223.26
Small0.470.410.160.700.53114.55
Medium1.020.970.281.581.74169.92
Large1.511.22−0.272.833.30219.13
Very large1.381.390.082.673.10224.87
Source—FADN CZ (2022).
Table 3. Representation of enterprises by economic viability class.
Table 3. Representation of enterprises by economic viability class.
GroupsEconomic Viability IndexShare of Observations (%)
EndangeredViableEndangeredViable
Field crops−0.423.0446.853.2
Small0.221.5284.615.4
Medium−0.122.3845.754.3
Large−2.004.6229.170.9
Very large−1.323.6141.358.7
Milk−0.192.7338.861.2
Small0.38NS82.117.9
Medium0.032.4035.464.6
Large−0.483.9352.347.7
Very large−0.492.9034.066.0
Grazing livestock0.162.3761.338.7
Small0.311.6979.720.3
Medium−0.182.6440.859.2
Large−0.042.5633.366.7
Very largeNSNSNSNS
Mixed−0.442.8650.449.6
Small0.321.5087.812.2
Medium0.052.0651.548.5
Large−0.903.5445.854.2
Very large−0.953.1042.557.5
NS—not shown for low number of observations, source—FADN CZ (2022).
Table 4. Analysis of statistically significant differences in the distribution of the economic viability index between groups of agricultural enterprises with different production orientations.
Table 4. Analysis of statistically significant differences in the distribution of the economic viability index between groups of agricultural enterprises with different production orientations.
Compared Groups
A–B
Rank Sum ARank Sum BUZp-ValueNb. of
Observation A
Nb. of
Observation B
Sig.
All
Mixed-field crops3,565,2074,456,8081,871,487−3.2990.00118402165*
Grazing livestock-field crops1,774,5663,808,2451,082,490−7.1550.00011762165*
Milk-field crops886,0822,951,753607,0582.7520.0066052165*
Mixed-grazing livestock2,860,6661,688,970996,8943.6450.00018401176*
Mixed-milk2,174,734815,501481,014−5.0180.0001840605*
Grazing livestock-milk960,845626,026268,769−8.4610.0001176605*
Endangered farms
Mixed-field crops876,9721,007,739445,916−1.9550.0519281013
Grazing livestock-field crops676,524827,721314,1304.9680.0007211013*
Milk-field crops151,150628,226114,6350.8820.3782351013
Mixed-grazing livestock696,320664,105265,264−7.2230.000928721*
Mixed-milk530,346146,52099,290−2.1200.034928235*
Grazing livestock-milk353,965103,48175,7512.4390.015721235*
Viable farms
Mixed-field crops918,0431,213,037501,715−1.7550.0799121152
Grazing livestock-field crops309,072982,956205,332−6.7710.0004551152*
Milk-field crops273,172885,831204,537−1.1670.2433701152
Mixed-grazing livestock660,458274,570170,8305.3290.000912455*
Mixed-milk583,732238,671167,404−0.2190.827912370
Grazing livestock-milk171,900168,82568,160−4.7040.000455370*
Mann-Whitney U Test (w/continuity correction) marked tests are significant at * p < 0.05, source–FADN CZ (2022).
Table 5. Analysis of statistically significant differences in the distribution of the economic viability index between different sized groups of agricultural holdings.
Table 5. Analysis of statistically significant differences in the distribution of the economic viability index between different sized groups of agricultural holdings.
Compared Groups
A–B
Rank Sum ARank Sum BUZp-ValueNb. of
Observation A
Nb. of
Observation B
Sig.
All
Very large–small2,631,2051,242,731611,60515.4110.00016601123*
Very large–medium3,507,8084,784,8201,874,7423.4510.00116602412*
Very large–large1,819,894714,732441,264−3.6310.0001660591*
Small–medium1,416,1024,833,778784,976−20.1530.00011232412*
Small–large837,312632,443206,186−12.9020.0001123591*
Medium–large3,509,2771,001,229599,199−6.0110.0002412591*
Endangered farms
Very large–small416,699870,511186,518−13.9020.000678926*
Very large–medium471,5301,065,851241,349−11.9240.0006781075*
Very large–large 310,82691,03067,1592.0280.043678218*
Small–medium923,2361,079,765494,035−0.2860.7759261075
Small–large 582,23772,70348,83211.8710.000926218*
Medium–large 745,81790,75466,88310.0040.0001075218*
Viable farms
Very large–small639,37856,23236,72913.7560.000982197*
Very large–medium1,314,8321,375,208480,75511.0290.0009821337*
Very large–large629,196289,494146,543−5.6890.000982373*
Small–medium98,6691,078,67679,166−9.0500.0001971337*
Small–large29,707133,02810,204−14.1910.000197373*
Medium–large1,034,719428,186140,266−12.9360.0001337373*
Mann-Whitney U Test (w/continuity correction) marked tests are significant at * p < 0.05, source–FADN CZ (2022).
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Hloušková, Z.; Lekešová, M.; Prajerová, A.; Doucha, T. Assessing the Economic Viability of Agricultural Holdings with the Inclusion of Opportunity Costs. Sustainability 2022, 14, 15087. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215087

AMA Style

Hloušková Z, Lekešová M, Prajerová A, Doucha T. Assessing the Economic Viability of Agricultural Holdings with the Inclusion of Opportunity Costs. Sustainability. 2022; 14(22):15087. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215087

Chicago/Turabian Style

Hloušková, Zuzana, Michaela Lekešová, Anna Prajerová, and Tomáš Doucha. 2022. "Assessing the Economic Viability of Agricultural Holdings with the Inclusion of Opportunity Costs" Sustainability 14, no. 22: 15087. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142215087

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop