What Determines the Shadow Economy? An Extreme Bounds Analysis
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
3. Data
4. Methodology and Model Specification
5. Results and Discussion
6. Policy Recommendations
7. Limitations of the Study
8. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Causal Variable | Theoretical Reasoning | References |
---|---|---|
Tax and social security contribution burdens (Personal income tax, Indirect taxes). | Over-taxation distorts labour-leisure choices, which can lead to a rise in the supply of labour in the unofficial economy. For every dollar difference in labour costs, there is an equal motive to minimize the tax spread and operate in the shadow economy. The total tax burden and social security are key determinants of the existence of the shadow economy, and together they form a tax wedge to enhance the shadow economy. | Thomas (1992), Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a,b), Giles (1999), Tanzi (1999), Schneider (2005), Dell’Anno (2007), Dell’Anno, Gomez-Antonio and Alanon Pardo (2007), Buehn and Schneider (2013). |
Quality of Institutions (Bureaucracy Quality, Corruption, Democratic Accountability, Law and Order, Government Stability, Investment Profile, Socioeconomic Conditions) | The quality of formal institutions contributes to the growth of the informal sector. It is far more important for the government to be able to apply the taxation system and regulations arbitrarily defined than for the taxes and regulations themselves to be high enough for people to work off the books. A bureaucracy with corrupt officials tends to increase unofficial activity, whereas securing property rights and contract enforceability increases the benefits of formality. Effective policies levy some taxation, mostly on competitive government services. Indeed, higher supply of public services promotes the formal sector. If government systems can be enhanced and fiscal policies made more in line with the average voter’s wishes, the informal sector will expand as a consequence of political institutions’ failure to support an efficient market economy. | Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobatón (1998a,b), Friedman, Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobaton (2000), Dreher and Schneider (2010), Dreher, Kotsogiannis and Macorriston (2009), Schneider (2010), Buehn and Schneider (2013), Teobaldelli (2011), Teobaldelli and Schneider (2012), Amendola and Dell’Anno (2010), Losby et al., (2002), Schneider and Williams (2013). |
External Conflict and Internal Conflict | Individuals and businesses will be driven to the shadow economy if citizens are uneasy and uncertain and believe that the country’s legal system has failed, undermining the official economy. Diplomatic pressures, trade restrictions, sanctions, civil war, and terrorism all limit the functioning of markets, increasing the incentives for people to engage in illegal activities. This results in widespread corruption, and since the government is unable to safeguard the populace via the legal system, the temptation for individuals to work in the informal sector increases. | Torgler and Schneider (2007), Sörensen, J.S., (2006). |
Development of the Official Economy | A further critical component in the creation of the shadow economy is the expansion of the formal economy. The bigger the joblessness rate (GDP growth), the higher the motivation to engage in shadow economy activity. | Schneider and Williams (2013), Feld and Schneider (2010). |
Self-Employment | The bigger the self-employment rate, the more shadow economy activities are possible. | Schneider and Williams (2013), Feld and Schneider (2010). |
Unemployment | The likelihood of working in the shadow economy increases with the level of unemployment. | Schneider and Williams (2013), Williams and Schneider (2016), Dell’Anno et al., (2007). |
Liquid Liabilities | An increase in the per capita income due to easier access to the financial and credit markets reduces the size of the shadow economy. | Gharleghi and Jahanshahi (2020). |
Share of the Labour Force | The lower the official labour force participation rate, the higher the shadow economy. | Schneider and Williams (2013), Feld and Schneider (2010). |
GDP Per Capita (Economic Growth) | A greater shadow economy is correlated with a shift of economic activity away from the formal economy, implying a slowing of economic growth. | Medina, Jonelis, and Cangul (2017). |
Regulations (Monetary Freedom, Business Freedom, Financial Freedom, Investment Freedom, Trade Freedom, Property Rights) | Regulations, such as those governing the labour market or trade barriers, also serve to limit individual freedom of choice in the official economy, thus providing the incentive to work in the shadow economy. There is a clear association between nations with stronger regulatory standards and a greater proportion of the shadow economy as a proportion of (GDP). Enforcement, not the entire scope of regulation—which is often not enforced—is the primary element determining the cost imposed on enterprises and people, inducing them to participate in the shadow economy. | Johnson, Kaufmann, and Shleifer (1997), Johnson, Kaufmann, and Zoido-Lobatón (1998b), Friedman, Johnson, Kaufmann, and ZoidoLobatón (2000), Kucera and Roncolato (2008), Schneider (2011), Hassan and Schneider (2016). |
Education | A higher level of educational participation reduces shadow economic activities. Education decreasing the size of the shadow economy through increasing income and opportunity cost. | Gërxhani and Werfhorst (2013), Hanousek and Palda (2004), Buehn, and Farzanegan, (2013), Berrittella (2015). |
ICT variables | The shadow economy shrinks as a result of information and communication technologies (ICTs). With the help of ICTs, the shadow economy could be reduced because more people would be employed and educated, and by reducing the number of burdensome bureaucratic processes. | Garcia-Murillo and Velez Ospina (2014), Remeikienė et al., (2021), Elgin, (2013). |
Poverty | The shadow economy could be fuelled by a greater demand for goods and services from low-income households. Poverty-stricken people may be able to purchase goods and services at lower prices in the shadow economy, thereby promoting the spread of shadow production. In addition, the prevalence of poverty may lead low-income people to look for work in the underground. To put it another way, the informal economy is a way for people who are struggling to make ends meet. Welfare recipients may choose informal jobs since working in the official sector entails a large implicit tax. In this situation, poverty drives individuals into the shadow economy. | Amuedo-Dorantes (2004), Canelas, (2015), Devicienti, Groisman and Poggi (2010), Kim (2005), Schneider and Enste (2013). |
Military in Politics | The nations that have Military in Politics, increased the Military spending. As a result, countries that spend more on their armed forces have lower shadow economies. In terms of controlling the underground sector’s size, military build-ups could have a positive impact. This could be because such spending is more centrally managed or because there are not as many middlemen involved (compared to nonmilitary spending). | Goel and Saunoris (2014) |
Inflation, the Consumer Prices Index | It turns out that as long as wages are sticky and inflation is rising steadily, price increases could lead to more people participating in the shadow economy. In the “official economy”, citizens in developing nations have numerous options to earn decent incomes and “extra money” (Schneider et al., 2010, p. 446). When demand for goods and services is reduced during a recession, inflation is reduced, which in turn encourages more people into the shadow economy to make up for lower-income and shrinking official job opportunities. | Dell’Anno and Davidescu (2018), Schneider et al., (2010). |
Religion in Politics | The extent of informal transactions is influenced by religious affiliation. In countries with a higher percentage of religious citizens, religious norms simplify informal transactions and provide an alternative to legal contract enforcement laws. There are significant linkages between the major church and the state in nations with limited informal economic activity, such as via religious law. When religion and the state are mutually beneficial, religion acts as “supernatural police” to safeguard the state’s interests. | Schneider, Linsbauer, and Heinemann (2015), Achim et al., (2019). |
Time Required to Start a Business | Entrepreneurs enter the shadow economy primarily to alleviate bureaucratic burdens, and one of these factors assessing the costs and time necessary to establish a company looks to be a logical instrument for expanding the shadow economy. | Dreher and Schneider (2010), Friedman et al., (2000). |
General Government Final Consumption Expenditure | Final consumption expenditures of the general government include things like unemployment compensation benefits and supplements, family allowances (such as food stamps), accident injury and sick pay (including survivor’s aids), pensions (including old-age, disability, and survivor’s aids), and reimbursements for healthcare expenses (such as the stipulation of a particular healthcare service). As a result, employee remuneration will rise, and the shadow economy will shrink as a result of the increase in wages. | Gasparėnienė, Remeikienė, and Heikkila (2016). |
Government Spending | Companies have more incentive to operate in shadow economies when government spending as a percentage of GDP is higher. In other words, both resource allocation distortions and (potential) higher levels of corruption serve as economic justifications to work in the shadow economies. | Dell’Anno (2007), Dell’Anno and Davidescu (2018), Schneider (2011). |
Population | As the population grows, the formal sector is under more pressure to employ large numbers of human resources, which raises the unemployment rate and opens the door to the possibility of the shadow economy’s absorption of large numbers of human resources. | Joshi et al., (1975), Schneider and Enste (2013). |
Code | Symbol | Variable Name/Units | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|---|---|
SHADOW | Y1 | Shadow Economy (% of GDP) | It is constituted of economic activities that evade expenses and are excluded from the right and advantages included in statutes and administrative norms governing ownership agreements, commercial licenses, contractual arrangements, tors, financial credit, and welfare systems, among others. | Medina, L. and Schneider, M.F., 2018. Shadow economies around the world: what did we learn over the last 20 years? International Monetary Fund. |
EXCONF | X1 | External Conflict (index 0–4) | It is a risk analysis of the existing government’s vulnerability to foreign action, which may take the form of peaceful external influence (diplomatic pressures, withdrawal of assistance, economic barriers, border disputes, and sanctions) or violent external forces (cross-border conflicts to all-out war). Each subcomponent of the risk assessment is assigned a maximum of four points and a minimum of zero points on a four-point scale. Four points equals very low risk; zero points equals very high risk. Subcomponents include foreign pressures, war, and cross-border conflict. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
BUREAU | X2 | Bureaucracy Quality | The quality of the bureaucracy acts as a shock absorber, in which it is reducing policy revisions when governments change. Thus, countries with strong bureaucracies that can govern without major policy changes or service interruptions receive high marks. In low-risk countries, the bureaucracy is usually independent of political pressure and has a well-established recruitment and training system. Changes in government are traumatic for policy formulation and day-to-day administrative functions in countries lacking a strong bureaucracy. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
CORRUP | X3 | Corruption (index 0–6) | This is a political corruption evaluation. Corruption is a danger to foreign capital for numerous reasons: it disrupts the financial and economic atmosphere; it decreases corporate and government efficiency by enabling individuals to obtain power by favour rather than talent; and it adds inherent political turmoil. The risk rating assigned is six points with a minimum of zero. 6 points = Very Low Risk, 0 points = Very High Risk. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
DEMAC | X4 | Democratic Accountability (index 0–6) | This metric indicates how receptive the government is to its constituents. For example, in a democratic society, a less responsive government is more likely to fall peacefully, but in a nondemocratic society, it may fall violently. The risk rating assigned is six points with a minimum of zero. In general, democracies have the most risk points (lowest risk), while autocracies have the least risk points (highest risk). | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
ETHNIC | X5 | Ethnic Tensions (index 0–6) | This component assesses racial, nationality, or language tensions within a country. The risk rating assigned is six points with a minimum of zero. Countries with high racial and nationality tensions receive lower ratings due to intolerance and unwillingness to compromise. Countries with low tensions are given higher ratings. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
GOVSTAB | X6 | Government Stability (index 0–4) | It assesses the government’s capacity to deliver and maintain power. Each sub-component of the risk assessment is assigned a maximum of four points and a minimum of zero.4 points = Very Low Risk, 0 points = Very High Risk. There is unity in government, legislative strength, and popular support. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
LAW | X7 | Law and order (index 0–3) | It is scored as a single component with two parts. The risk rating assigned is six points with a minimum of zero. The “Law” element assesses the legal system’s strength and impartiality, while the “Order” element assesses public observance of the law. A nation’s court system may be rated three stars, yet its crime rate may be ranked one star if the law is habitually disregarded without effective enforcement (For instance, massive unlawful strike activity). | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
SOCIOECO | X8 | Socioeconomic Conditions (index 0–4) | It measures the socioeconomic pressures that may limit government action or fuel social discontent. There are three components that make up the risk rating, each with a maximum of four points and a minimum of zero. 4 points = Very Low Risk, 0 points = Very High Risk, which include subcomponents: consumer confidence, poverty, and unemployment. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
RORIG | X9 | Property Rights (index 0–100) | The property rights component assesses individuals’ ability to accumulate private property. It assesses how well a country’s laws protect private property rights and how well its government enforces them. Additionally, it considers the risk of seizure, the independence of the court, and the capacity of people and enterprises to implement. The score is calculated on a scale of 0 to 100, with higher values indicating stronger protection of property rights. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
INVPRO | X10 | Investment Profile (index 0–4) | This component assesses factors affecting investment risk that are not covered by political, economic, or financial risk components. There are three components that make up the risk rating, each with a maximum of four points and a minimum of zero. 4 points = Very Low Risk, 0 points = Very High Risk. Contract Viability/Expropriation; Profit Repatriation; Payment Delays. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
INCONF | X11 | Internal Conflict (index 0–4) | It assesses the level of political turmoil in the nation and its influence on governance. Most highly rated countries have no armed or civil opposition and no arbitrary violence, direct or indirect, against their own people. A country in a civil war gets the lowest rating. There are three components that make up the risk rating, each with a maximum of four points and a minimum of zero. 4 points = Very Low Risk, 0 points = Very High Risk. Terrorism/Political Violence; Civil Disorder. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
RELIGION | X12 | Religion in Politics (index 0–6) | Index of religion in government that results from a single religious group’s dominance of society and/or governance—or a thirst for power—in such a fashion that civil law is replaced by religious law, other religions are excluded from political systems, and religious freedom and expressions of religious identity are suppressed. The dangers vary from unskilled individuals imposing ineffective policies to civil disobedience or civil conflict. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
MILRPOL | X13 | Military in Politics (index 0–6) | The military’s influence in politics is represented through an index. The national guard is not chosen, and hence its participation, even at a peripheral level, undermines democratic responsibility. Military engagement may be prompted by an external or internal danger, may be a sign of underlying troubles, or may constitute a full-scale military takeover of the country. Over the long run, a military-dominated administration would almost likely deteriorate the effectiveness of government operations, become corrupt, and create an unpleasant environment for foreign firms. | The International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) |
GFCF | X14 | Gross Fixed Capital Formation (% of GDP) | Gross domestic fixed investment as a percentage of GDP. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
GOVCONS | X15 | General Government Final Consumption Expenditure (% of GDP) | It encompasses all current government acquisitions of products and services, whether large and small (including compensation of employees). It also comprises the vast majority of national defence and security spending, with the exception of military and government capital spending, which are excluded. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
INFLCP | X16 | Inflation, Consumer Prices (annual %) | It quantifies the proportional change in the cost of a set basket of goods and services to the typical consumer over a certain period of time. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
INTERNET | X17 | Individuals Using the Internet (% of the Population) | Individuals who have used the internet in the previous three months are considered internet users. The Internet may be accessed via a variety of devices, including computers, mobile phones, PDAs, gaming consoles, and digital televisions. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
LIQUID | X18 | Liquid Liabilities (% of GDP) | They consist of the sum of time and savings deposits, foreign currency transferable deposits, certificates of deposit, and securities repurchase agreements (M2), transferable deposits and electronic currency (M1),) currency and central bank deposits (M0) as well as visitor checks, foreign currency time deposits, commercial paper, and resident-held mutual funds or market funds. | Global Financial Development (GFDD)|Data Catalog (worldbank.org) https://datacatalog.worldbank.org/dataset/global-financial-development |
GDPPCG | X19 | GDP Per Capita Growth (%) | GDP growth rate per capita in fixed national currency. The aggregates are calculated in constant 2010 United States dollars. GDP per capita is calculated as follows: GDP at purchase prices is the sum of all resident producers’ gross value-added plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the product value. It excludes depreciation of manufactured assets and depletion and degradation of natural resources. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
OPENNESS | X20 | Trade (% of GDP) | It is the total value of imports and exports of services and goods as a percentage of the GDP. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
SCHPRI | X21 | School Enrollment, Primary (% gross) | Primary school teaches students the fundamentals of reading, writing, and arithmetic, as well as the fundamentals of natural science, geography, history, art, music, and social science. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
SCHSEC | X22 | School Enrollment, Secondary (% gross) | Secondary school strives to create the basis for continuous education and learning by providing more subject- or skill-focused training with the aid of more trained instructors. It concludes the supply of basic education that started with elementary education. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
SCHTER | X23 | School Enrolment, Tertiary (% gross) | Higher education, either leading to an advanced research credential or not, often needs satisfactory completion of secondary school as a minimum entry requirement. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
SELFEMP | X24 | Self-Employed, total (% of total employment) (modelled ILO estimate) | Self-employed workers are those who work for themselves, with one or a few partners, or in a cooperative. Jobs whose pay is directly linked to the profits made from the goods and services produced. Employers, own-account workers, producers’ cooperative members, and contributing family workers are all self-employed. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
TELEPHONE | X25 | Fixed Telephone Subscriptions (Per 100 People) | The term “fixed telephone subscriptions” represents the total number of permanent wireless local loop (WLL) memberships, operational analogue landlines, fixed public payphones, voice-over-IP (VoIP) memberships, and ISDN voice channel equivalents. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
UNEMP | X26 | Unemployment, total (% of the total Labour Force) (Modelled ILO Estimate) | It represents the proportion of the workforce that is unemployed yet available for and actively looking for work. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
POVERTY | X27 | Population Living Below National Poverty Line (% Population) | It is the percentage of people who live below the country’s poverty threshold. Nationwide calculations are based on sample survey subpopulations estimates. Each nation has its own definition of poverty. | Euromonitor International |
GOVSPEN | X28 | Government Spending | This component looks at government spending as a percentage of GDP. The total is made up of government spending on consumption and transfers. The ideal level varies by country, depending on factors like culture, geography, and development. Because the methodology assumes no government spending, underdeveloped countries with limited government capacity may receive inflated scores. In most cases, general government expenditure data includes federal, state, and local governments. In the absence of general government spending data, central government expenditure data are used. | Euromonitor International |
TAXBUR | X29 | Tax Burden (index 0–100) | It is a metric for the government’s tax burden. It consists of both direct taxes (highest marginal rates on individual and business income) and cumulative taxes (all forms of direct and indirect taxation at all levels of government). As a consequence, the fiscal freedom element contains three measurement: the highest marginal tax rates on individual and corporate income, as well as the overall tax burden as a share of GDP. Each of these quantitative factors contributes one-third to the fiscal freedom component. Fiscal freedom scores reflect the diminishing revenue returns associated with extremely high tax rates. The data for each factor is normalized to 100 points. | Euromonitor International |
POPUL | X30 | Population, total | It is calculated according to the de facto definition of population, which includes all inhabitants irrespective of age or citizenship. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
BUSFREE | X31 | Business Freedom (index 0–100) | Business freedom measures the effectiveness of government regulation of business. It is calculated using a variety of measures of the difficulties associated with beginning, running, and ending a firm. The business freedom score for each nation varies from 0 to 100, with 100 being the most free. | Euromonitor International |
TIMEBUS | X32 | Time Required to Start a Business (days) | It refers to the time in days required to complete all the formalities for starting a firm lawfully. | World Bank Development Indicators (WDI) |
MONFREE | X33 | Monetary Freedom (index 0–100) | It integrates a price stability metric with an evaluation of price regulations. Market activity is distorted by both inflation and price regulations. Without microeconomic interference, price stability is the optimum situation for the free economy. | Euromonitor International |
TRADFFREE | X34 | Trade Freedom (index 0–100) | It represents the absence of tariff and nontariff barriers to goods and services imports and exports. The trade-weighted average tariff rate and nontariff barriers comprise the trade freedom score (NTBs). The Trade freedom scale where 20 points mean extensively used NTBs and 0 points are given when NTBs are not used to limit international trade. | Euromonitor International |
INVFREE | X35 | Investment Freedom (index 0–100) | There would be no restrictions on the movement of investment money in an economically free nation. Individuals and corporations would have the freedom to shift resources into and out of certain activities on a domestic and international level. The score runs from 0 to 100; the ideal nation would have a score of 100 on the Index of Economic Freedom’s investment freedom component. | Euromonitor International |
FINFREE | X36 | Financial Freedom (index 0–100) | It is defined as freedom from government control and interference in banking. Banking, insurance, and capital markets state ownership reduces competition and service. Finance, capital markets, government influence on credit allocation, and openness to foreign competition are all factors measured by the Index. To assess an economy’s overall financial freedom, these five areas are used. A country’s financial freedom is rated from 0 to 100, with 0 representing total government interference. | Euromonitor International |
References
- Schneider, F.; Enste, D.H. Shadow economies: Size, causes, and consequences. J. Econ. Lit. 2000, 38, 77–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Williams, C.C.; Schneider, F. Measuring the Global Shadow Economy: The Prevalence of Informal Work and Labour; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Medina, L.; Schneider, M.F. Shadow Economies around the World: What Did We Learn over the Last 20 Years; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Hirschman, A.O. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1970; Volume 25. [Google Scholar]
- Olson, M. Stagflation and the political economy of the decline in productivity. Am. Econ. Rev. 1982, 72, 143–148. [Google Scholar]
- Hoinaru, R.; Buda, D.; Borlea, S.N.; Văidean, V.L.; Achim, M.V. The impact of corruption and shadow economy on the economic and sustainable development. Do they “sand the wheels” or “grease the wheels”? Sustainability 2020, 12, 481. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Elgin, C.; Erturk, F. Informal economies around the world: Measures, determinants and consequences. Eurasian Econ. Rev. 2019, 9, 221–237. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Elgin, C.; Erturk, F. Is informality a barrier to convergence? Econ. Bull. 2016, 36, 2556–2568. [Google Scholar]
- Caurkubule, Ž.; Rubanovskis, A. Shadow economy as an obstacle to sustainable economic development. J. Secur. Sustain. Issues 2014, 4, 175–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dixon, H. Controversy: On the use of the ‘hidden economy’estimates. Econ. J. 1999, 109, 335–337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tanzi, V. Uses and abuses of estimates of the underground economy. Econ. J. 1999, 109, F338–F347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Giles, D.E.A. Measuring the hidden economy: Implications for econometric modelling. Econ. J. 1999, 109, F370–F380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Feld, L.P.; Schneider, F. Survey on the shadow economy and undeclared earnings in OECD countries. Ger. Econ. Rev. 2010, 11, 109–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Leamer, E.E. Sensitivity analyses would help. Am. Econ. Rev. 1985, 75, 308–313. [Google Scholar]
- Sala-i-Martin, X. I Just Ran Four Million Regressions; National Bureau of Economic Research Cambridge: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Gilbert, C.L. Professor Hendry’s Econometric Methodology; Modelling Economic Series; Earlier Publised in Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1986; Volume 48, pp. 283–307. [Google Scholar]
- Schneider, F. Size and development of the shadow economy of 31 European and 5 other OECD countries from 2003 to 2014: Different developments? J. Self-Gov. Manag. Econ. 2015, 3, 7–29. [Google Scholar]
- Hassan, M.; Schneider, F. Size and development of the shadow economies of 157 countries worldwide: Updated and new measures from 1999 to 2013. Available SSRN 2861026 2016, 4, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feige, E.L. Reflections on the meaning and measurement of unobserved economies: What do we really know about the ‘shadow economy’. J. Tax Adm. 2016, 2, 5–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Macias, J.B.; Cazzavillan, G. Modeling the informal economy in Mexico. a structural equation approach. J. Dev. Areas 2010, 4, 345–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Schneider, F.; Buehn, A.; Montenegro, C.E. New estimates for the shadow economies all over the world. Int. Econ. J. 2010, 24, 443–461. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vo, D.H.; Ly, T.H. Measuring the shadow economy in the ASEAN nations: The MIMIC approach. Int. J. Econ. Financ. 2014, 6, 139–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hassan, M.; Schneider, F. Modelling the Egyptian shadow economy: A MIMIC model and a currency demand approach. J. Econ. Political Econ. 2016, 3, 309–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schneider, F.; Linsbauer, K.; Heinemann, F. Religion and the shadow economy. Kyklos 2015, 68, 111–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Medina, L.; Schneider, F. Shedding Light on the Shadow Economy: A Global Database and the Interaction with the Official One. In Munich Society for the Promotion of Economic Research—CESifo; CESifo: Munich, Germany, 2019; Volume SSRN 3502028. [Google Scholar]
- Mauro, P. Corruption and growth. Q. J. Econ. 1995, 110, 681–712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alfoul, M.N.A. Effects of ICT Investment and Usage on Economic Growth in MENA Countries: Does Governance Matter? Ph.D. Thesis, Swinburne University of Technology, Hawthorn, VIC, Australia, 2022. [Google Scholar]
- Dreher, A.; Schneider, F. Corruption and the shadow economy: An empirical analysis. Public Choice 2010, 144, 215–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gharleghi, B.; Jahanshahi, A.A. The shadow economy and sustainable development: The role of financial development. J. Public Aff. 2020, 20, e2099. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Torgler, B.; Schneider, F. The impact of tax morale and institutional quality on the shadow economy. J. Econ. Psychol. 2009, 30, 228–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Canh, N.P.; Kim, S.; Thanh, S.D. Entrepreneurship and natural resource rent-seeking: The roles of institutional quality. Econ. Bull. 2020, 40, 1159–1177. [Google Scholar]
- Canh, P.N.; Dinh Thanh, S. Exports and the shadow economy: Non-linear effects. J. Int. Trade Econ. Dev. 2020, 29, 865–890. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Friedman, E.; Johnson, S.; Kaufmann, D.; Zoido-Lobaton, P. Dodging the grabbing hand: The determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. J. Public Econ. 2000, 76, 459–493. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Johnson, S.; Kaufmann, D.; Shleifer, A. The Unofficial Economy in Transition, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall; Brookings Institution: Washington, DC, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Nguyen, B.; Canh, N.P.; Thanh, S.D. Institutions, human capital and entrepreneurship density. J. Knowl. Econ. 2021, 12, 1270–1293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Su, D.T.; Nguyen, P.C.; Christophe, S. Impact of foreign direct investment, trade openness and economic institutions on growth in emerging countries: The case of Vietnam. J. Int. Stud. 2019, 12, 243–264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dreher, A.; Kotsogiannis, C.; McCorriston, S. How do institutions affect corruption and the shadow economy? Int. Tax Public Financ. 2009, 16, 773–796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kaufmann, D.; Kraay, A.; Mastruzzi, M. Governance matters III: Governance indicators for 1996, 1998, 2000, and 2002. World Bank Econ. Rev. 2004, 18, 253–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Canh, N.P.; Binh, N.T.; Thanh, S.D.; Schinckus, C. Determinants of foreign direct investment inflows: The role of economic policy uncertainty. Int. Econ. 2020, 161, 159–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Canh, N.P.; Thanh, S.D. Financial development and the shadow economy: A multi-dimensional analysis. Econ. Anal. Policy 2020, 67, 37–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thanh, S.D.; Canh, N.P. Local governance: Impacts of fiscal decentralization on government size and spending composition in Vietnam. Asian Econ. J. 2019, 33, 311–340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R.W. Legal determinants of external finance. J. Financ. 1997, 52, 1131–1150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Porta, R.L.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; Shleifer, A.; Vishny, R.W. Law and finance. J. Political Econ. 1998, 106, 1113–1155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hoffman, R.C.; Munemo, J.; Watson, S. International franchise expansion: The role of institutions and transaction costs. J. Int. Manag. 2016, 22, 101–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Busse, M.; Hefeker, C. Political risk, institutions and foreign direct investment. Eur. J. Political Econ. 2007, 23, 397–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hallerberg, M.; Wolff, G.B. Fiscal institutions, fiscal policy and sovereign risk premia in EMU. Public Choice 2008, 136, 379–396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Canh, N.P. The effectiveness of fiscal policy: Contributions from institutions and external debts. J. Asian Bus. Econ. Stud. 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Park, J. Corruption, soundness of the banking sector, and economic growth: A cross-country study. J. Int. Money Financ. 2012, 31, 907–929. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nguyen, C.P.; Su, T.D.; Nguyen, T.V.H. Institutional quality and economic growth: The case of emerging economies. Theor. Econ. Lett. 2018, 8, 1943. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nguyen, C.P.; Nguyen, T.V.H.; Schinckus, C. Institutions, economic openness and stock return co-movements: An empirical investigation in emerging markets. Financ. Res. Lett. 2019, 28, 137–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nguyen, C.P.; Schinckus, C.; Su, T.D.; Chong, F. Institutions, inward foreign direct investment, trade openness and credit level in emerging market economies. Rev. Dev. Financ. 2018, 8, 75–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Moosa, I.A.; Khatatbeh, I.N. Robust and fragile determinants of the infection and case fatality rates of COVID-19: International cross-sectional evidence. Appl. Econ. 2021, 53, 1225–1234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Leamer, E.E. Let’s take the con out of econometrics. Am. Econ. Rev. 1983, 73, 31–43. [Google Scholar]
- Young, C.; Holsteen, K. Model uncertainty and robustness: A computational framework for multimodel analysis. Sociol. Methods Res. 2017, 46, 3–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Khatatbeh, I. The Macroeconomic Consequences of Financialisation. Ph.D. Thesis, RMIT University, Melbourne, VIC, Australia, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Khatatbeh, I.N.; Moosa, I.A. Financialization and income inequality: An extreme bounds analysis. J. Int. Trade Econ. Dev. 2021, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levine, R.; Renelt, D. A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. Am. Econ. Rev. 1992, 82, 942–963. [Google Scholar]
- Sturm, J.-E.; De Haan, J. Determinants of long-term growth: New results applying robust estimation and extreme bounds analysis. Empir. Econ. 2005, 30, 597–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Torgler, B.; Schneider, F. Shadow Economy, Tax Morale, Governance and Institutional Quality: A Panel Analysis; CREMA Working Paper Series 2007-02; Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts (CREMA): Zürich, Switzerland, 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Teobaldelli, D.; Schneider, F. Beyond the Veil of Ignorance: The Influence of Direct Democracy on the Shadow Economy; Working Paper No. MO3749; Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute for Economic Research, University of Munich CESifo: Munich, Germany, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Amendola, A.; Dell’Anno, R. Institutions and human development in the Latin America shadow economy. Estud. Derecho Gob. 2010, 3, 9–25. [Google Scholar]
- Batrancea, L.; Nichita, A.; Batrancea, I.; Gaban, L. The strenght of the relationship between shadow economy and corruption: Evidence from a worldwide country-sample. Soc. Indic. Res. 2018, 138, 1119–1143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berdiev, A.N.; Saunoris, J.W.; Schneider, F. Give me liberty, or I will produce underground: Effects of economic freedom on the shadow economy. South. Econ. J. 2018, 85, 537–562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Remeikienė, R.; Gasparėnienė, L.; Bayar, Y.; Ginevičius, R.; Ragaišytė, I.M. ICT development and shadow economy: Empirical evidence from the EU transition economies. Econ. Res.-Ekon. Istraživanja 2021, 5, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Elgin, C. Internet usage and the shadow economy: Evidence from panel data. Econ. Syst. 2013, 37, 111–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Abu Alfoul, M.; Mishal, Z.A.; Schneider, F.; Magableh, K.; Alabdulraheem, A.R. The hidden economy in Jordan: A MIMIC approach. Cogent Econ. Financ. 2022, 10, 2031434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dell’Anno, R.; Davidescu, A.A. Estimating shadow economy in Tanzania: An analysis with the MIMIC approach. J. Econ. Stud. 2018, 45, 100–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goel, R.K.; Nelson, M.A. Shining a light on the shadows: Identifying robust determinants of the shadow economy. Econ. Model. 2016, 58, 351–364. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berdiev, A.N.; Saunoris, J.W.; Schneider, F. Poverty and the shadow economy: The role of governmental institutions. World Econ. 2020, 43, 921–947. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Owolabi, A.O.; Berdiev, A.N.; Saunoris, J.W. Is the shadow economy procyclical or countercyclical over the business cycle? International evidence. Q. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2022, 84, 257–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- OECD. Shining Light on the Shadow Economy: Opportunities and Threats; OECD Paris: Paris, France, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Esaku, S. Does income inequality increase the shadow economy? Empirical evidence from Uganda. Dev. Stud. Res. 2021, 8, 147–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schneider, F.; Buehn, A. Shadow Economies in Highly Developed OECD Countries: What Are the Driving Forces? Discussion Paper No. 6891; Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA): Bonn, Germany, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Restrepo-Echavarria, P. Measuring underground economy can be done, but it is difficult. Reg. Econ. 2015, 1, 10–11. [Google Scholar]
- Schneider, F.; Buehn, A. Estimating the Size of the Shadow Economy: Methods, Problems and Open Questions; CESifo Working Paper No. 4448 (November); CESifo: Munich, Germany, 2013. [Google Scholar]
Variable | CDF(0) | Sign | |
---|---|---|---|
LAW | −3.29 | 99.0% | − |
INCONF | −2.12 | 98.8% | − |
BUREAU | −3.56 | 98.7% | − |
INFLCP | 0.02 | 98.5% | + |
MONFREE | −0.19 | 98.1% | − |
TIMEBUS | 0.03 | 98.1% | + |
POVERTY | 0.16 | 97.8% | − |
CORRUP | −2.95 | 97.7% | − |
INTERNET | −0.19 | 97.0% | − |
PRORIG | −0.15 | 96.8% | − |
Variable | 1991–1999 | 2000–2008 | 2009–2017 |
---|---|---|---|
INFLCP | 99.4% | 98.9% | 90.1% |
TIMEBUS | 98.6% | 97.5% | 96.4% |
POVERTY | 99.5% | 99.9% | 96.9% |
PRORIG | 96.6% | 99.7% | 99.9% |
BUSFREE | 98.8% | 99.2% | 95.3% |
MONFREE | 99.8% | 97.8% | |
GOVSTAB | 96.7% | ||
INCONF | 90.1% | ||
CORRUP | 96.5% | ||
RELIGION | 97.9% | 93.0% | 96.3% |
DEMAC | 99.0% | 96.0% | 91.8% |
TELEPHONE | 99.6% | 96.5% | |
INTERNET | 100.0% | 100.0% | 96.2% |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Abu Alfoul, M.N.; Khatatbeh, I.N.; Jamaani, F. What Determines the Shadow Economy? An Extreme Bounds Analysis. Sustainability 2022, 14, 5761. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14105761
Abu Alfoul MN, Khatatbeh IN, Jamaani F. What Determines the Shadow Economy? An Extreme Bounds Analysis. Sustainability. 2022; 14(10):5761. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14105761
Chicago/Turabian StyleAbu Alfoul, Mohammed Nayel, Ibrahim Naser Khatatbeh, and Fouad Jamaani. 2022. "What Determines the Shadow Economy? An Extreme Bounds Analysis" Sustainability 14, no. 10: 5761. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14105761