Next Article in Journal
Local Perception of Drivers of Land-Use and Land-Cover Change Dynamics across Dedza District, Central Malawi Region
Next Article in Special Issue
Effective Segmentation of Organic Food Consumers in Vietnam Using Food-Related Lifestyles
Previous Article in Journal
Assessing the Influence of Adverse Weather on Traffic Flow Characteristics Using a Driving Simulator and VISSIM
Previous Article in Special Issue
Environmental Consciousness and Green Customer Behavior: The Moderating Roles of Incentive Mechanisms
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Does Public Infrastructure Breed Consumption Downgrade and Overcapacity in China? A DSGE Approach on Macroeconomic Effects

1
School of Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, 111 Wuchuan Road, Shanghai 200433, China
2
School of Economics, Huazhong University of Science and Technology, 1037 Luoyu Road, Wuhan 430074, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2019, 11(3), 831; https://doi.org/10.3390/su11030831
Submission received: 30 December 2018 / Revised: 21 January 2019 / Accepted: 1 February 2019 / Published: 5 February 2019
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sustainability in Asian Emerging Markets)

Abstract

:
As the most influential emerging and developing country in Asia, China has attached great importance to the construction of infrastructural facilities, laying stress on its pivotal role in sustainable growth. Recently, however, a pessimistic mood about the term “consumption downgrade” continues to emerge, ascribing the dip in people’s disposable income to real estate bubbles stemming from too much government infrastructure spending. This paper collects empirical evidence, develops a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) framework, regards Productive Government Expenditure (PGE) as a critical endogenous variable, and investigates thoroughly its overall effects on key indicators concerning economic growth and sustainable development. Results show that household consumption indeed responds directly and negatively confronting a sudden increase of public infrastructure investment in China, yet aggregate output is instead boosted. On top of that, productive capacity does not present a supposed reduction, but a promotion under the PGE shock. These findings indicate that so-called “consumption downgrade” delivers the wrong message of weak productivity; capacity utilization is in essence improved by vigorous government support for infrastructure construction, which ultimately benefits continuously-stable social sustainability in the long term.

1. Introduction

In light of the unprecedented rapidity and size of economic growth, China has long been praised for top priority in public investment on infrastructure, aiming at promoting social welfare through a series of positive measures like the China Railway High-speed (CRH), Three Gorges Dam, Fiber-To-The-Home (FTTH), and so on. However, in the shadow of expensive housing prices hovering at an incredible level and gradually escalating trade war, the latter half of year 2018 in China was featured by a hotly-debated concept: “consumption downgrade”. Deeply worrying about the potential adverse influence upon their normal life, some pessimistic consumers express excessive anxiety and impute their decreased purchasing power to aggressive expansion of public infrastructure investment, for the reason that these projects bear a long return period and crowd out their counterparts, which directly satisfies the current needs of ordinary citizens. Consumers around China complain about the sky-high housing prices and heavy household debt, which successfully aroused the attention of the government. No matter how excellent the economic performance is, it is hard to deny that a widespread belief in a dismal business outlook impairs market expectation, as well as government executive ability. Hence, it is important to consolidate sustainability by letting government attach importance to household consumption and welfare, in addition to the chief goal of achieving economic growth.
What is worse, the situation faced by the central bank and monetary policy is also tough and grim. Although the People’s Bank of China (PBoC) successfully accomplished the purpose of curbing excessive credit expansion in M2and bank loans, the shadow banking system has sprung up rapidly, and the loans in it have taken up 20.25% by the first quarter of 2018, according to the data released by the Center for Quantitative Economic Research (CQER), Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. These quasi-bank financial institutions growing up in the shadows are by no means subjected to regulations compared with their traditional counterparts and act as the perfect places concealing credit and liquidity risks. A salient feature of shadow banking is high leverage, which is accompanied by asset price bubbles especially exposed in the turbulent housing market in China recently. As is pointed out by [1], the prosperously-developed shadow banking sector contributes to a noticeably rising debt-to-GDP ratio. Since many transactions conducted by these non-bank institutions are invisible to regulators and inexperienced investors, the monetary authority’s hand is actually tied, and its once effective conventional contractionary interest rate policies no longer work well as before. Just as the wide criticisms on the large-scale fiscal stimulus after the 2008 global financial crisis, public infrastructure investment and all other well-intended policies might run counter to the government’s desire: The liberalized Chinese financial system cultivates incentives for hiding default risks, which leads the financial assistance to flow into high-stake trade markets rather than into the real economy [2].
At another level, as is strongly appealed and advocated by scholars and politicians, public infrastructure investment indeed plays a pivotal role in improving people’s living standards, realizing free education, and providing affordable healthcare. This infrastructure-based development path contributes to a harmonious civil order and rational consumption behavior associated with sustainable growth in the long term, especially in emerging and developing countries.
Quite a few criticisms towards vigorous government support on fundamental facilities and systems concentrate on its side effects through corruption and inefficiency during the execution process. The work in [3] proposed a conceptual model for benchmarking the sustainability of local governments. Another vein is the tendency of accumulating surplus capacity and bringing down capital utilization rate, which generates a waste of resources and not environmental production behaviors. If the Ministry of Finance incessantly grants appropriation for capital construction, the government-supported enterprises will continually operate, even if their commodity supply has already exceeded the market demand. When the downstream building companies do not need so much steel or the subway lines in city’s outskirts rarely carry passengers, the steel mills and subway systems run idle, bearing tremendous operational costs. Even worse, state-owned banks are prone to finance government business enterprises, which are backed by public credibility. As a result, numerous private enterprises with high efficiency find it hard to get funded and have to start empty-handed, leading to a further deterioration of the market environment.
Therefore, critical questions arise here: Does the aggressively-expanded government infrastructure spending unintentionally breed the by-product of consumption degradation? Does the actively-proposed investment in manufacturing industry create the problem of overcapacity or not? Should we blame the well-intentioned Productive Government Expenditure (PGE) accumulation for the disorganization, redundancy, and inefficiency among certain state-owned enterprises? What are the exact macroeconomic effects of these infrastructure projects all across the nation?
To address these issues, this paper focuses on the particular institutional arrangements in China and carries out a systematic and meticulous study. We first characterize stylized facts in China and apply a Vector-Autoregression (VAR) model to discuss the effect on household consumption and aggregate output in response to a positive PGE shock. The VAR model indicates that PGE crowds out household consumption. Then, we incorporate public infrastructure investment and capacity utilization in a Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model. The dynamic analysis shows that a conscious policy decision of actively-promoting public investment crowds out household consumption and generates the superficial appearance of the so-called “consumption downgrade”, which resonates well with the empirical evidence. However, such a policy in essence enhances secular growth invisibly by alternative fiscal support. The situation of industry overcapacity is alleviated by the increased capital utilization and rapidly-diminished goods in stock.
Regarding the methodologies, the Vector-Autoregression (VAR) model is an econometric method of applying time series, through which we can identify the dynamic effect of Productive Government Expenditure (PGE) on other economic variables, such as consumption, output, and so on. For the theoretical part, the Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model is a useful and prominent tool for policy makers (e.g., central banks and local governments), to analyze the aggregate economic behavior and predict the outcomes of policy intervention. More importantly, a calibrated DSGE model simulates the effects of fiscal and monetary policies and, thus in this way, confirms the impulse response analysis in vector autoregression accordingly.
This paper contributes to existing studies in the following aspects. First, to the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper attempting to comprehensively elucidate the underlying causes and exact mechanism of the hotly-debated, yet still ambiguous notion of “consumption downgrade”. It is of crucial importance in both theory and practice to expound this new concept for the sake of guiding the direction of public opinion, stabilizing market sentiment, as well as fulfilling the ultimate objective of improving people’s livelihood. As a second contribution, this study establishes a formal and explicit framework in which principal indicators including consumption, output and capacity utilization are examined in a theoretical framework with respect to PGE. As is later manifested in Section 2.3, even though so much literature had referred to industry overcapacity produced by PGE before, no deterministic conclusions have been drawn. More importantly, this paper is instructive for posterior scholars who are curious and keen to draw on the experience of the “China miracle” and helps them delve into the desirable policy instruments applicable to developing economies that share the same traits as China. By fitting their typical characteristics into an extended Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model, we extend the applicability of this model to institutional design aiming at facilitating healthy, harmonious, and sustained development.
The impact of productive government expenditure on household consumption mainly depends on two opposite effects in our model. On the one hand, in the Real Business Cycle (RBC) model, an increase in productive government expenditure changes household’s lifetime budget constraint, therefore reducing the present value of household’s lifetime wealth. The negative wealth effect pulls down current consumption and increases labor supply, which finally crowds out private consumption. On the other hand, in view of the transmission path of production, the increase in productive government expenditure raises aggregate output and total income of residents, thus leading to a positive wealth effect. In the traditional Keynesian theory, the expansion of fiscal policy will promote total output and consumption. In our general equilibrium model, however, the effect of fiscal expansion on consumption is due to the dominant wealth variation. Furthermore, the magnitude of the effect on consumption also depends on other indirect price effects, such as the wage effect and the interest rate effect.
The rest of our work is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews existing literature concerning the comprehensive influence of government infrastructure investment. Section 3 displays the macro characteristics in China and presents preliminary empirical results. Section 4 builds up a theoretical general equilibrium model, characterizing agents behaviors and solving the deterministic steady state. Section 5 calibrates the theoretical model with credible parameters in line with the stylized facts in China, adds an exogenous Productive Government Expenditure (PGE) shock, and evaluates impulse responses in the simulated framework. In this section, sensitivity analysis is further conducted as an extension of the benchmark model in the face of uncertainty in calibrated parameters. Section 6 concludes, provides policy implications, and puts forward limitations and corresponding future research.

2. Literature Review

In the common pursuit of alleviating poverty, rationally utilizing non-renewable resources and maintaining prolonged society stability, experts in all kinds of fields assiduously carry out the exploration of public infrastructure. On account of the inherent properties (great expense and ultra-long return period) of infrastructure construction projects, it is a matter of obligation for government to take regulatory actions to prevent natural monopolies and potential risks in public capital formation [4]. Accounting for the absolute share in infrastructure funding sources, government expenditure accordingly becomes the major research emphasis of social scientists. Just as [5] underlines in its executive summary, collaborative efforts are in urgent need for assessing the actual impacts and efficiency of infrastructure investment.

2.1. Public Infrastructure Investment: Growth and Development

As early as three decades ago, [6] had already addressed an elaborate review of the empirical evidence for how public infrastructure investment influences a broad range of economic activity on the national and regional level. Aside from expediting technology progress and accumulating productive factor inputs, government infrastructure at the same time attracts the notice of households and firms, in this way accelerating regional growth to a higher degree. Soon after, a seminal theoretical research by [7] first systematically examined this issue and came to the conclusion that real GDP growth presents a negative relationship with government-consumption-to-GDP share and a positive (albeit insignificant) correlation with public-investment-to-GDP share. Then, two years later in the detection of [8], this positive coefficient became significant. Contemporarily in the 1980s and early 1990s, the wide use of general equilibrium models [9,10,11,12] established solid theoretical ground for the extensive macro effects of public infrastructure input. In order to explore the long-run effects of government expenditure on economic growth, the work in [13] built a standard endogenous model including public capital and taxation, applied it to a convincing dataset including 23 countries, and supported the proposed growth benefits from public investment. Some new evidence in advanced economies by [14] manifested that expanded government investment increases both temporary and permanent output, encourages private capital formation, and most importantly, lowers the unemployment rate. Apart from all these exquisite studies, a series of National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) programs with regard to productivity and growth conducted investigations from all conceivable angles, grabbing deserved concern all over the world: The work in [15] applied a quantity of dual cost function models to Swedish data from 1960–1988 and showed that public infrastructure capital rationalizes cost-savings in private business enterprises and manufacturing process, efficiently reducing costs. Yet, this result was disproven by [16], in which the accumulation in public capital actually produced no quantitatively-significant effects on private productivity, putting forward the term “productivity puzzle”. In view of the difficulties in evaluating the infrastructure impact on firms’ productive performance, the work in [17] incorporated decisions into the existing production theory model and found that state infrastructure indeed stimulates economic growth by directly benefiting manufacturing sectors, but it also creates indirect scale effects and brings about additional social costs. Comparing the growth experience of Africa with that of East Asia, the work in [18] highlighted the importance of efficiently implementing infrastructure construction: The more directly public investment enters the production function, which implies these inputs are effectively utilized, the more excellent growth performance the economy will exhibit. More typically, with an eye toward the transportation infrastructure projects, the work in [19] examined the extensive railroad network of colonial India, predicted a general equilibrium trade model, and put forward credible arguments that a sophisticated railroad network lowers trade cost, facilitates inter-regional trade, elevates real income, and in the end, sufficiently promotes harmonious and sustainable development.

2.2. Public Infrastructure Investment: Household Consumption

In addition to generally analyzing the macro effects of PGE on macro growth and development, a number of studies specifically paid close attention to its contribution to household consumption and domestic living.
As an early work laying stress on the dynamic effect of public investment by means of a two-sector Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model, the work in [20] placed micro foundations supporting that a flexible transportation system and advanced municipal facilities motivate private sectors to promote productivity and achieve welfare improving. His quantitative analysis on seven Latin American countries implied an optimal level of infrastructure for welfare gains’ maximization. Using two distinct large samples from the World Bank and from the “Statistical Atlas of Latin America”, the work in [21] came up with the conclusion that domestic well-being derives benefits from infrastructure, but also admitted the adverse effects of expensive costs from administrative intervention and inefficiency from corruption. Proposing a spatial equilibrium model embedding infrastructure, the work in [22] presented empirical evidence emphasizing the significance of government productive investments to redistribute inter-regional economic activity, while at the same time reminding that the real effect is largely influenced by political investment decision. Later on, in a comprehensive empirical investigation, the work in [23] applied the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) dynamic methods and showed that income inequality is significantly reduced by the promotion of infrastructure quantity and quality. What is more, this ameliorating effect is more evident in developing countries. In a full and thorough investigation into multiple channels of government infrastructure affecting the real economy, the work in [24] gave credit to the profound influence of public infrastructure on people’s long-term happiness by enhancing employment and labor productivity, guiding private capital to flow efficiently into profitable businesses, as well as reinforcing the medical and educational system. More recently, the work in [25] inspected the effects on income inequality of heavy infrastructure investment and found compelling evidence that a sufficient supply of construction facilities benefits distributive equity. Yet, this research also raises doubt, claiming that the unclear internal accelerating mechanism, especially the comprehensive influence on households, demands further exploration. Likewise, concentrating on inequality from the perspective of agent heterogeneity, the work in [26] considered idiosyncratic productivity shocks and suggested whether government spending on public capital aggravates household wealth and depends on the relative magnitude of externalities and factor substitutability.
Thus far, the clear effects of PGE on household consumption are inconclusive, not to mention the decoding of the novel concept “consumption downgrade”.

2.3. Public Infrastructure Investment: Overcapacity

Except for the debatable influence on consumers, a more salient issue under the spot light is the relationship of excess capacity and over-investment.
Early in the beginning of this century, scholars perceived the common trouble of serious overcapacity in Asian markets and linked it with inappropriate government infrastructure stimulus: The work in [27] attributed the East Asian crisis of 1997 to excess fiscal spending, which misleads individual and institutional investors to overspend in a bogus boom and creates nothing but redundant capacity. According to [28], an inevitable drawback of state ownership is that government has an incentive to generate excess capacity in order to offset operational inefficiency.
In view of the sizable investment in fast-developing China, the overcapacity problem causes deep anxiety. In the renewable energy industry, the work in [29] pointed out the non-negligible misjudgment involved in policy implementation and supervision, calling for a comprehensive approval mechanism so as to target precisely promising renewable energy projects in urgent need of financial assistance, especially those of a medium or small size. Deeply concerned about the persistent investment enthusiasm on coal power, the work in [30] constructed the power planning model and found that the current coal power projects are exposed to a striking level of investment waste, generating colossal excess capacity of over 200 gigawatts. Looking at the regional economic growth in China, the work in [31] used a Vector Error Correction Model (VECM) and found a mixed contribution of government infrastructure. Allowing for the marked regional disparity, less developed areas were incapable of absorbing huge volumes of capacity, most frequently referred to as the network effect, put forward by [32], in which paving one road is productive, while paving more creates confusion on the contrary. For this reason, the government is supposed to chew over policy details to guarantee that the pace of infrastructure development is not beyond the ultimate bearing capacity in certain areas.
Not all scholars are so pessimistic. Exclusively focusing on the effect of investment incentives, the work in [33] targeted four major infrastructure sectors in China, suggesting that the worry about overcapacity brought by too much infrastructure investment was actually unfounded. Given the solid and sound economic growth in China, any potential overcapacity is a necessary sacrifice for the associated sectoral development and can be eventually converted to a strong impetus for the country’s sustainable progress. A similar conclusion was reached in a quasi-experiment in western China by [34], who applied a price-difference approach and confirmed that the increased shipping capacity of transportation makes for an appreciable social return to public investment. From the angle of industrial agglomeration, the work in [35] utilized Chinese data from 285 cities during 2004–2013 and presented dynamic spatial econometric results that infrastructure improvement and sharing along with industrial agglomeration distinctly increase energy allocation and scale efficiency, reduce the costs for transaction and transportation, and furthermore stimulate business transformation and upgrade capacity and technology.
Again, no clear-cut evidence exists manifesting the positive relationship between government infrastructure investment and the excess productive capacity.

3. Empirical Evidence

3.1. Stylized Facts

As a matter of fact, the current economic climate in China seems not so dismal as certain gloomy predictions. Figure 1 provides a visual overview of market sentiment for consumers and producers. First, the main body (stacked areas) of this chart displays three indices, which measure economic outlook of households, their degree of optimism about overall economic personal finance, and how products/services supplied by manufacturers meet consumer expectations, respectively. None of these indicators in the consumer market reflect a sentiment downturn, at least in the past five years. As a matter of fact, we can observe a distinct steady upward trend since the middle of year 2016, under a series of supportive news including the Chinese official currency (Renminbi) added to the Special Drawing Rights (SDR) Basket, implementation of supply-side reforms, reconstruction of central-controlled enterprises, etc. Second, in the market for domestic manufacturers, the purple dashed line shows that the Purchasing Managers’ Indices (PMI) keep pace with the consumer indices, presenting a stable and bullish mood among business decision makers, purchasing managers, and market analysts.
Apart from the market sentiments, we add some extra information closely linked to the long-term stability of the aggregate economy. The blue solid line in Figure 1 further gives insight into how efficient the production sectors operate in China. As a standard business metric and a key macro indicator for productive capacity, the utilization rate captures the ratio of actually realized economic productivity to its potential level. The industrial capacity utilization rate in China reached its peak at the beginning of 2018, steadily rising after the wave trough in mid-2016, at least over the last five years.
Overall, the broad outline of economic status for some time past cannot help to confirm the existence of shrinking consumption power for households. The business activities slowed down in 2015, which is very reasonable since the spreading of the concept of the “new normal” laid less stress on full-speed growth and paid more attention to profound structural reform. Nevertheless, over the last two years, China soon returned back to a sound growth momentum.
Since the above picture is still a sketchy overview, the displayed general prosperity in China’s economy may have some shortage of credibility. Therefore, descriptive details are called for in Table 1 to reveal the time series characteristics of the concerned variables during the period of 1995Q1∼2017Q4 in China. All the quarterly time series we use were extracted from the integrated dataset in [36] based on the raw data from China’s National Bureau of Statistics (NBS), Ministry of Finance, and the People’s Bank of China (PBoC). “PGE share” is the ratio of gross fixed capital formation of government to total government spending. “Consumption” and “output” are household consumption level and Gross Domestic Product (GDP) by expenditure. “Investment” is gross capital formation. “Inflation” is the quarterly percentage change in the Consumer Price Index (CPI). Nominal variables are deflated by their respective price deflators, detrended, and take the logarithmic form.
Some salient features deserve to be mentioned in Table 1, reflecting distinct Chinese characteristics.
From the perspective of volatilities, consumption is more volatile (1.64 times) than output, which is a stylized fact in developing countries. Investment fluctuates much more (five times) than output, whereas the magnitudes of fluctuations in output and inflation are nearly equal.
First of all, one plausible explanation for more volatile consumption is the fast-expanding Chinese “Moonlight Clan” in recent years, who consume all their disposable incomes before the next month they get paid. In addition, raised concerns about the sustainability of unprecedented high growth rates have an impact on consumer sentiments and render households more sensitive to market turbulence. It is worth noting that the correlation between consumption and PGE share is negative and statistically significant. A higher proportion of productive government expenditure promotes production and increases aggregate output. However, as a tradeoff, more taxation will be imposed to keep government budget balanced, and in turn pull down the household’s disposable income. As a result, the negative correlation coefficient implies that the effect on the reduction in consumption is dominant, showing the crowd out effect of PGE on consumption.
The chief variable in evidence, the proportion of productive government expenditure in total government spending, shows intense volatility, 1.76-times that of the fluctuation of the business cycle. This result resembles the observations of the frequent application of fiscal policy in China. Aiming at stimulating economic growth, multiple investments in infrastructure and development (e.g., Beijing-based Asian Infrastructure Investment Bank (AIIB), globally-watched Belt and Road Initiative (BRI) initiative, etc.) all contribute to the sharp wave of government expenditure. Although the increase in PGE share stimulates the production, consumption is diminished by the negative income effect, which in turn pulls down the aggregate output. The increase in productive expenditure partially offsets the expansionary effect of the reduction in consumption. As a result, the correlation coefficient between PGE share and output is negative, but not statistically significant.
As a visual supplementary of the characteristic macroeconomic environment in Table 1, the time series chart in Figure 2 intuitively exhibits the evolution trend of public infrastructure investment with respect to the business cycle. The inverse behavior of PGE and private consumption can be observed easily, while output shows a more vague and smooth development through the last five years in China.

3.2. Public Infrastructure Shock

According to the descriptive statistical analysis in Section 3.1, a more aggressive investment into public infrastructure construction goes along with a conspicuously lower consumption level and uncertain economic development. Nevertheless, the very shallow correlation analysis seems not able to provide persuasive evidence for ascribing “consumption downgrade” and even bad economic performance to these active initiatives.
To settle this problem, we take a step further and develop a standard Vector-Autoregression (VAR) model, in order to explore the exact causal relationship between public infrastructure investment and economic condition. The dynamic impacts of an unexpected increase in PGE are reported in Figure 3, in which the full sample is again 1995Q1∼2017Q4.
The results of the VAR model are lucid. When the economy is hit by a positive PGE shock, household consumption receives an apparent crowd-out impact and continues to drop under the aggressive expansion of public productive investment for a long time. The logic is intuitive: vigorous movements in construction programs signify clear policy orientation and lead individuals to form a natural expectation to earn appreciable profit by cutting down expenses and putting money into real estate and emerging companies.
The dynamic evolution of aggregate output is, once again, not explicit enough, in view of the fairly thick confidence interval denoted by the grey areas in Figure 3b. At the very start, economic productivity gets an immediate promotion and lasts for some periods. This expansionary impact is interpretable and satisfies the strong desire for pursuing aggressive growth and development. In accordance with the national priority of boosting economic growth above the annual GDP target, the Chinese government has established complete and systemic strategic development plans to throw into heavy industries and long-term construction for productive purposes.
As a whole, the VAR evidence demonstrates a dual role of a temporary PGE shock: it restrains private consumption of the current age, as well as accelerates potential GDP growth.
Even so, a couple of pending issues are still up in the air because of the lacking data: Does this investment-driven economy bring forth the hidden peril of excess capacity in the industrial sector? Extensively praised for the remarkable “China miracle” of seemingly sustained eminent growth, what on Earth is the general public benefit from the well-intended public spending on manufacturing industries? A comprehensive general equilibrium model is called for systematically exploring the overall macroeconomic effects of the active policy on public infrastructure, especially the effects on overcapacity, which is closely bound up with long-term social and economic development and the living standard of domestic residents, which unfortunately failed to be explained by the empirical analysis before.

4. Model

4.1. Entrepreneurs

On the supply side, we have two production sectors of intermediate and final firms. Final goods are sold in perfect competition markets, and intermediaries live in an imperfect market where goods’ differentiation endows intermediate firms with a certain degree of price markup, as well as monopolistic profit.

4.1.1. Final Firms

Assume there is a continuum of measure one of homogeneous intermediate entrepreneurs j [ 0 , 1 ] in monopolistic competition markets. Final firms elaborate intermediate goods and aggregate them in the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) production function initiated by [37]:
Y t = 0 1 Y t ( j ) ψ ψ 1 d j ψ 1 ψ
where ψ > 1 is the constant elasticity of substitution. Final entrepreneurs maximize profits according to the amounts of intermediate goods Y t ( j ) :
max P t Y t 0 1 P t ( j ) Y t ( j ) d j
The first order condition gives their demand for intermediate goods:
Y t ( j ) = Y t ( P t P t ( j ) ) ψ
Substituting (2) into (1), we obtain the price of final goods:
P t = 0 1 P t ( j ) 1 ψ d j 1 1 ψ

4.1.2. Intermediate Firms

In a monopolistic competitive market, intermediate firms set P t ( j ) to gain excess profit given the demand function (2). To introduce price stickiness, we apply the staggered price setting in [38] and let only a proportion ( 1 ρ ) of intermediaries change price at each period. They choose optimal price level P t ( j ) freely, whereas the rest ρ of them bear nominal rigidity and set price one period ahead: P t ( j ) = P t 1 ( j ) .
What is worth noting here is the setting of the production function for intermediate goods. With the aim of maintaining a sound development, the government grants a variety of supporting expenditures such as infrastructure investment, research funding, and productive transfer payments for unemployment benefit or retirement pension. This spending promotes enforcing property rights, optimizing resource allocation, and in this manner, increasing the marginal product of capital input [13]. Therefore, we take into account the practical effect of productive GE to each firm g p , t ( j ) in actual production processes, incorporating it and the rate of capital utilization z t in the intermediate production function:
Y t ( j ) = a t [ z t k t ( j ) ] θ n t ( j ) 1 θ g p , t ( j ) α
where 0 < θ < 1 and 0 < α < 1 . k t ( j ) and n t ( j ) respectively denote the capital stock and labor. In accordance with the general setting that the depreciation rate is a convex, increasing function of the utilization rate. we follow [39,40] and let the depreciation satisfy:
δ t ( z t ) = 1 ϕ z t ϕ
where ϕ > 1 implies the elasticity of depreciation. The autoregression with lag order one, AR(1) process a t , introduces an exogenous stochastic technology shock to the model with dynamics: ln a t = ρ a ln a t 1 + ϵ t a , ϵ t a i . i . d . N ( 0 , σ a 2 ) . Let A t = a t z t θ g p , t ( j ) α , and rearranging (4), we obtain:
Y t ( j ) = A t k t ( j ) θ n t ( j ) 1 θ
Since the labor market and asset market are perfect competitive, every intermediate firm j accepts the given wage and capital return, minimizing costs based on optimal inputs of production factors:
( 1 θ ) r t θ w t = n t ( j ) k t ( j )
where w t and r t represent the real wage and rate of return to capital of intermediate firms.
Intermediate firm j, which is able to reset price, maximizes its expected profit as:
max E t i = 0 ( β ρ ) i [ P t + i ( j ) Y t + i ( j ) P t + i r t + i k t + i ( j ) P t + i w t + i n t + i ( j ) ]
by choosing P t + i ( j ) subject to the technological constraint:
Y t + i P t + i P t + i ( j ) ψ = A t k t ( j ) θ n t ( j ) 1 θ
Therefore, the optimal price setting P t ( j ) for intermediate firm j is as follows:
P t ( j ) = ψ ψ 1 E t i = 0 [ ( β ρ ) i P t + i Y t + i ( j ) m c t + i ] E t i = 0 ( β ρ ) i Y t + i ( j )
where m c t + i = 1 A t + i r t + i θ θ 1 θ w t + i θ 1 is the marginal cost.
Integrating P t ( j ) into (3), we derive the final price:
P t = ρ P t 1 1 ψ + ( 1 ρ ) P t ( j ) 1 ψ

4.2. Households

Corresponding to the above infinite-horizon production economy, on the consumption side, households are identical in a continuum of one unit measure. They maximize lifetime expected utility given the labor wage and capital return:
E 0 t = 0 β t l n ( c t i + g c , t i ) η ( n t i ) 1 + γ 1 + γ
where 0 < β < 1 is the discount factor, γ > 0 , and η > 0 . c t i and n t i signify the consumption and labor supply of household i [ 0 , 1 ] at time t. g c , t i represents the consumptive goods and services provided by the government, such as monthly subsidies for medical and social insurance. We set aside the unequal weight of private consumption and consumptive government spending in the household utility function and regard them as perfect substitutes. Detailed investigation can be found in [41].
At period t, household i gains wage earning w t n t i and capital return r t k t i , acquires monopoly profit ξ i by holding shares in intermediate firms, and simultaneously pays the lump-sum tax τ t i > 0 . Therefore, household i is subject to the budget constraint at time t:
c t i + k t + 1 i = w t n t i + r t k t i + ( 1 δ t ) k t + ξ t i τ t i
All the variables in (13) are real ones.
Likewise, first order conditions give the Euler equation for consumption and labor supply as follows:
β E t c t i + g c , t i c t + 1 i + g c , t + 1 i ( r t + 1 + 1 δ t + 1 ) = 1
η ( n t i ) γ = w t c t i + g c , t i

4.3. Government

In regard to the decision making in the public sector, we simplify government income by aggregating lump-sum taxes imposed on all households as T t = 0 1 τ t i d i and abstract from tax distortions and public debt. The fiscal revenue is applied to two types of Government Expenditures (GE): productive government expenditure G p , t = 0 1 g p , t ( j ) d j and consumptive government expenditure G c , t = 0 1 g c , t ( i ) d i , with a certain proportion μ > 0 of G p , t = μ G t and G c , t = ( 1 μ ) G t . Hence, the government faces its budget constraint:
G t = T t
For the benefit of comprehensive and permanent development of future generations, PGE G p , t improves people’s livelihood through government services, public transportation, and social security system. It also accumulates physical capital stock and benefits productivity through investment and infrastructure. To explore the dynamic effect of the policy shift to attach high importance to go in for large-scale construction, we add an unanticipated exogenous shock on PGE following an A R ( 1 ) process:
l n G p , t = ρ g l n G p , t 1 + ( 1 ρ g ) l n G p + ϵ t g , ϵ t g i . i . d . N ( 0 , σ g 2 )
where G p is the steady-state value of G p , t . In parallel, the central bank provides auxiliary measures and implements monetary policy following a standard inflation-targeting Taylor rule adopted by [42], where nominal interest rate R t responds to policy inertia R t 1 , inflation π t , output gap Y t Y , and the intertemporal feedback from the change in output gap Y t Y / Y t 1 Y correspondingly.
ln R t R = ρ R ln R t 1 R + ( 1 ρ R ) ρ π π t + ρ Y ln Y t Y + ρ Y 1 ln Y t Y ln Y t 1 Y + ln ζ t
where letters without the time subscript denote the steady-state values and π t = P t P t 1 is the inflation rate. Finally, ζ t represents a standard interest rate shock, which is determined by the following equation:
l n ζ t = ρ ζ l n ζ t 1 + ϵ t ζ , ϵ t ζ i . i . d . N ( 0 , σ ζ 2 )

4.4. Equilibrium

In equilibrium, goods markets’ clearing requires the resource constraint to be satisfied:
C t + I t + G t = w t N t + r t K t + Ξ t Y t
with the aggregate capital motion equation:
K t + 1 = ( 1 δ t ) K t + I t
Naturally, the first term of (21) is intuitively deemed to be inventory, which is a perfect proxy for the overcapacity level in the production process.
The aggregations of individual variables yield aggregate consumption C t = 0 1 C t i d i , capital stock K t = 0 1 k t i d i , labor N t = 0 1 n t i d i , and monopoly profit Ξ t = 0 1 ξ t i d i .
In addition, the efficient utilization holds:
θ a t ( z t K t ) θ 1 N t 1 θ G p , t α = z t ϕ 1

4.5. Steady State

In this section, we present the deterministic steady state, in which a variable without a time subscript denotes its steady-state value as before.
Given the value of discount factor β , the elasticity of substitution in production ψ , inflation rate π , and depreciation rate δ , the price motion Equation (11) derives monopoly markup x = ψ ψ 1 1 β ρ 1 β ρ π , and the Euler Equation (14) gives the rate of return to capital r = 1 β 1 + δ . Combining (5) with the values x and r, we obtain the depreciation elasticity ϕ = x r δ and capital utilization rate z = ( ϕ δ ) 1 ϕ .
Simplifying the equilibrium efficient utilization (22), we find the capital-output ratio K Y = x r θ . With I = δ K , the investment-output ratio γ I I Y = θ ϕ is determined. Resource constraint (20) yields GE-output ratio γ G = 1 γ C γ I , given the consumption-output ratio γ C from the dataset of [36].
In the production process, incorporating the steady-state condition P t = P t 1 = P and intermediate goods demand (2) into optimal pricing yields the equilibrium output:
Y = [ ( θ z x r ) θ ( μ γ G ) α N 1 θ ] 1 1 α θ
Finally, since the level of weekly working hours is fixed in a certain society, its conditional demand function determines real wage w = ( 1 θ ) ( 1 1 ψ ) Y N .
In this way, labor preference in utility η = w N γ C + G p , aggregate investment I = γ I Y , productive GE G p = ( 1 γ I ) Y w η N γ , consumptive GE G c = 1 μ μ G p , household consumption C = Y I G , and the monopoly profit of Ξ = Y ψ are all pinned down.

5. Results

On the basis of this constructed model, we can finally evaluate concretely the systematic and structured influence of long-term infrastructure projects over the entire dynamic economy, especially on excess productive capacity.

5.1. Calibration

In order to investigate the internal transmission channel of PGE to household consumption, economic output, and remnant inventory, we calibrate our model parameters in Table 2 according to the conventional new Keynesian DSGE model, while keeping up with the actual characteristics of China’s economy.
The time-discounting factor is set at β = 0.991 , which helps to determine the steady-state rate of return to capital r = 0.03 with the rate of quarterly depreciation δ = 0.025 . On the production side, the share of capital input is calibrated at a general level of θ = 0.3 . The monopoly markup in steady state ψ ψ 1 = 1.1 follows [43]. For labor supply, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution γ = 0.25 is consistent with [44], which enables us to pin down the relative preference for consuming goods or leisure at η = 3.62 . The Calvo contract non-resetting parameter for price stickiness is ρ = 0.75 . A typical eight-hour workday is applied to the labor market, which implies the steady-state average individual’s hours N = 1 / 3 .
In line with the empirical evidence presented in Section 3, we used the same dataset over the period 1995Q1∼2017Q4 and obtained the consumption-output ratio γ C = 0.38 , the proportion of productive expenses in government budget expenditure τ = 0.26 , and the steady-state value of quarterly CPI inflation π = 0.52 % . The rest of the steady-state values for solving the steady-state equilibrium can be calculated using the expressions in Section 4.5.
In the second part of Table 2, as for the key parameter denoting the elasticity of PGE in the intermediate production function, we set the benchmark level as α = 0.11 , following [45]. With regard to the policy instruments of the central government, we followed [42] and let the Taylor rule coefficients be ρ R = 0.75 , ρ π = 1.5 , ρ Y = 0.125 , and ρ Y 1 = 0.125 .
Finally, for exogenous shocks, the persistency of technology, PGE, and interest rate shocks are respectively ρ a = 0.9 , ρ g = 0.6 (benchmark level), and ρ ζ = 0.5 , generally following the existing literature about monetary policy in China. The standard deviation of shocks is: σ a = σ ζ = σ g = 0.1 .

5.2. Model Dynamics

This section conducts impulse response analysis for the overall dynamic effects of an increased input on infrastructure development.
Figure 4 draws a big picture of economic impacts in the face of a standard PGE, which is quite indicative if we go through it row by row.
The first row in Figure 4 gives an overall macro dynamics under the expansionary PGE shock. First, household consumption suffers a conspicuous and immediate drop, which lasts for some periods. In the similar pattern shown by the VAR model in Section 3.2 and explained previously, a large scale of public support in manufacturing processes crowds out individual consumption, as well as private investment for speculative purposes. This suppressed tendency, however, by no means lasts long. The second impulse response swiftly jumps back before the fifth period, which implies rapid recovery in investor sentiment. Corresponding to that, output displays an optimistic outlook, and productivity improves. The variable of “inventory” here deserves serious discussion. Contrary to the speculations that government-backed manufacturing and construction are subject to the defects of redundancies and inefficiencies, excess capacity is actually well eliminated. The situation of industry overcapacity is turned around, displayed by the rapidly-diminished goods in stock.
The effects of primary factor inputs in production are presented in the second row. Corresponding to the alleviation of excess capacity, capital stock declines in the same trajectory as overcapacity, with its rate of return going up conversely (since capital stock in the conventional DSGE model is always a state variable lagging one period by default, the rate of return to capital gets a momentary drop when the shock comes). In the labor market, the transient drop of real wage is acceptable if we consider the career moves when intensive public infrastructure creates a large number of new vacancies, which elevates job mobility. After new employees are in position, their real wages are in effect quickly promoted, just like the closely-resembled trajectory of the impulse response of working hours.
The dynamic evolutions in the third row are rather sensible likewise. Inventory depletion by virtue of large-scale installations and constructions efficiently improves capital utilization rate, as well as speeds up the velocity of depreciation. The impact response of monopoly markup is thought-provoking. Repeatedly emphasized by sociologists, politicians, and economists, the heavy government investment in the productive process breeds a defect of exacerbated monopoly in state-owned enterprises. Thereby, price markup is immediately elevated when the shock hits. Yet, this condition is not sustained: after the installation and configuration of productive resources are accomplished, enhanced efficiency soon brings about a lower level of monopoly in intermediate goods’ production and a benign market environment.
In the last row, from the aspect of price movements, inflation drops at the very beginning due to the auxiliary contractionary monetary policy of raising market interest rates (as is revealed in the impulse response of interest rate in Column 1), yet soon springs back in a favorable investment climate, in concert with the second subgraph in the first row. Finally, provided that the government maintains the balance between productive and consumptive expenditure in its fiscal budget, every type of GE receives a standard positive impact from the exogenous PGE shock.
Overall, our numerical simulation results take a deep dive into the comprehensive macroeconomic effects of strengthened public infrastructure. Not only do they make a logical extension on stylized facts in Section 3.1 and empirical evidence from the VAR model in Section 3.2, but they also confirm that the new Keynesian DSGE model behaves well and develops a fine theoretical framework for investigating the macroeconomic effects in China. This thorough investigation on the general equilibrium system indicates that a conscious policy decision of actively promoting public investment especially in infrastructure for the purpose of stimulating economic growth seems to crowd out private consumption and generate the superficial appearance of the so-called “consumption downgrade” symbolized by the slowdown in retail sales, yet in essence enhances secular growth invisibly by alternative fiscal support. As a matter of fact, focusing sorely on the fast-moving consumer goods markets and claiming “consumption downgrade” are wholly implausible. If we consider consumers’ pursuit of high-quality lifestyle, as well as efficiently improved rates of capital return and utilization, a positive PGE shock virtually brings about the “economy upgrade”.

5.3. Sensitivity Analysis

As is manifested in Section 5.2, despite creating the unfavorable situation in the consumer market instantly, a positive PGE shock implicitly brings about beneficial effects on sustained productivity progress and superior de-stocking performance. Strictly speaking, these results are in the first place based on our calibrated parameter of α = 0.11 and ρ g = 0.6 drawn from the estimation of [45]. Going a step further, what if the output elasticity of productive government spending α changes (which means g p , t ( j ) carries a stronger/weaker weight in production function (4)) or the policy persistence of public infrastructure investment ρ g changes (longer/shorter duration for which the policy remains in force): will the remarkable policy achievements on output and overcapacity fail to accomplish their goals? Which direction will the economic activities evolve towards? What then are the interactions of every macro indicator? To address these questions, we conduct the following sensitivity analyses as an extension of our benchmark model, trying to probe in what way could parallel emerging countries strive for the successful outcomes China has achieved. Table 3 summarizes the results of the three types of sensitivity analyzes, and Section 5.3.1, Section 5.3.2 and Section 5.3.3 demonstrate the details.

5.3.1. Output Elasticity of PGE

Figure 5 exhibits the macroeconomic characteristics with the change of PGE weight. We extract the most representative indicators (consumption, output, investment, and inventory) from Figure 4, since all dynamic trajectories of the rest of the variables can be categorized into impulse responses of these four.
The first three key macroeconomic indicators reflect the broad economic climate. It is conceivable that output and investment are boosted when α increases, and even household consumption presents a subtle recovery. The dynamic movements of existing inventory, nevertheless, reveals crucial information. Under the current PGE weight in production function calibrated for China, we have observed an evident depletion in inventory representing greater efficiency in capital utilization and conversion. As α goes higher, although it still achieves a lower level of inventory accumulation, in the longer term of economic development, potential overproduction eventually comes to the surface, raising the issue of excess productive capacity.

5.3.2. Persistency of PGE

The results displayed in Figure 6 are more straightforward. As expected, the rise of ρ g prolongs the duration and extends the scope of policy impacts brought forth by persistent PGE shock. In addition, a more persistent policy support generates a deep and profound influence upon the capital accumulation process, in which production resources are more quickly used in the firstten periods, yet easily stacked in later periods.

5.3.3. Supplementary Measures of the People’s Bank of China

Another meaningful issue worth exploring is the not yet completed market-oriented interest rate reform. With the wake of the developing financial system and liberalizing interest rate, the PBoC has become fully conscious of the instability and weaker power of money velocity and decided to conduct the gradual transition to price-based monetary policy. In the past, China was used to maximizing its limited resources through a centralized structure. Then, in the progressively market-oriented Chinese market, when the PBoC lays more emphasis on the interest rate tool and makes it react to the economy climate more flexibly, is the above macroeconomic effects of a positive PGE shock of great difference?
Here, Figure 7 reports the macroeconomic impacts when the monetary authority changes official interest rates slightly/strongly in response to the economic situation. Analogous to the alteration in Section 5.3.2, albeit at a moderate scale, the general economic atmosphere receives a bigger impact when the degree of marketization increases and the PBoC lets interest rates respond more freely. A more sensitive monetary policy rule (higher ρ Y ) generates a more frictionless business environment, paving the way for a sustained and potent investment for production. It should not be neglected that a less flexible interest rate rule generates the consequences of considerable overcapacity on the production side, which calls for a more free and frictionless business environment, for the sake of maximizing resource utilization and raising efficiency.
To sum up, the sensitivity analyses of the facet of PGE’s productive weight, shock persistency, and monetary policy rule give much information: our preliminary result that generous public infrastructure input in China inhibits consumption and expedites productivity remains robust under the change of the above three conditions. The perpetual business development benefits from the active initiatives of government. The intricate impact on internal productive capacity is divergent given different parameter values. A healthy and not a backlash inventory depletion requires lower weight in production function α , shorter policy duration ρ g , and a more market-driven interest rate rule ρ Y .

6. Conclusions and Policy Implications

Despite firmly retaining its position as the top contributor to world GDP growth, unfortunately China has not achieved its goal of “prosperity-for-all” thus far, in the presence of the major obstacle of enormous population and marked wealth disparity. With an eye toward reducing poverty and building an advanced and affluent society, China has been dedicated to promoting public facilities and services with great effort.
The merits of mature and reliable public infrastructure are too numerous to enumerate: For instance, a modern and smart transportation system reduces auto use and alleviates a great deal of air pollution. The world’s largest hydroelectric dam helps China to meet its energy demand without depleting non-renewable resources. Successful clean water and sanitization projects effectively extend the average life expectancy of the entire society and raise the overall level of residents’ health. In other words, from a developing perspective, public infrastructure is indeed of vital significance to emerging countries, creating appreciable positive externalities especially for those that hold tremendous production potential.
The outstanding policy performance, of course, has a dual character. We should never take convenience and premium services for granted, and thoroughly pondering the profound and far-reaching influence of government infrastructure investment deserves to be carried out.
In this paper, we first characterize China’s stylized facts for the past two decades utilizing the latest time series data of the Chinese macro economy, collect empirical evidence, and build a standard VAR model so as to explore the impact of a positive PGE shock on household consumption and aggregate output. From the VAR model, we come up with the primary results that PGE crowds out private consumption and benefits economic productivity. For the purpose of thoroughly investigating the internal mechanism of how government infrastructure expenditure affects household consumption, economic productivity, and general capacity utilization in a dynamic interactive system, we develop a new Keynesian DSGE model and incorporate public infrastructure investment as a kind of PGE into the production function of intermediate firms. Model equilibrium gives the deterministic steady state, in which values are assigned to corresponding calibrated parameters. Subsequent numerical results enable us to evaluate the applicability of the simulated model, with which we explore further analysis on the profound influence from the heavy investment in the facilities and services fundamental for domestic economic operation.

6.1. Policy Implications

Based on the above-mentioned results, we draw corresponding policy implications of strengthening infrastructure construction.
First and foremost, the generally supposed “consumption downgrade” is by no means a groundless conjecture. Not only does the empirical evidence (either the simple correlation analysis or standard VAR model) show that much emphasis on public infrastructure reduces household consumption, but our carefully-designed theoretical framework demonstrates that a manufacturing-oriented policy shift indeed produces an inhibitory effect on residential expenditure. As a vital weather vane of market demand and social production, this indicator ought to be taken seriously by the government and especially its authorized spokesman. Given its direct and indirect influence on domestic sentiments of consumers, investors, as well as entrepreneurs through the macroeconomic mechanism, the relevant authority is obliged to truthfully and publicly announce the inevitable outcome of slumped consumption level and more essentially clarify the necessity and desirability of its specific policy design: the unexposed policy outcome of long-term benefited productivity and economic growth is a proven fact, not to mention the effectively utilized productive capacity in China’s case. Only in this way could the administrative accountability system operate with a long-term effective mechanism.
Our second implication is a logical extension of the underlined argument in the first implication and is also the direction of endeavor for the government exerting efforts to apply PGE policy extensively, efficiently, and successfully. As is manifested by the extended sensitive analysis on benchmark impulse response results, booming industrial and infrastructure development has disparate impacts on inventory in the economy, allowing for the movement of PGE weight in the production function, shock persistency, or monetary policy rule. When we turn our eyes toward the details of the manufacturing process, a worrying development during industry upgrading is the excess capacity of productive factor input. Large-scale installation and construction accumulate a huge amount of capital stock, with the underlying propensity to lead to a waste of resources, environmental deterioration, and an ecologically-unsustainable economy. A sensible government shall always accurately assess the characteristics of its own economy, prudently conceive of corresponding plans, and keep an appropriate balance between economic development and excess productive capacity. For example, the administrative institution might need to control the PGE policy to be prompt and potent, but not sluggish or sloppy. Besides, an auxiliary support of an unrestricted and flexible market environment is worth trying. Our paper points out the crucial requisite for how promoting public infrastructure in effect expedites the production process and depletes inventories in quantity. The tricky issue of excess capacity could be well addressed by this active policy initiative, under the detailed conditions in our research results above.
Building upon the former two arguments, our research helps decision makers endow PGE action a greater appearance of legitimacy. When households finally apprehend that their ultimate well-being is not impaired, but improved and, more importantly, they need not weigh and consider tradeoff between instant and future living conditions, the sensational “consumption downgrade” will be correctly deciphered. As a matter of fact, the cooled enthusiasm of fast-moving consumer goods is an implicit sign for the general pursuit of a high-quality lifestyle, reflected by the consumer preferences of spending more on culture accumulation, entertainment activities, sports, and travel. Dispelling the public misunderstanding of “consumption downgrade” is of vital significance to improve administrative efficiency, prevent panic spread, stabilize market sentiment, and advance a steady economic development.

6.2. Limitations and Future Research

Admittedly, there are of course certain limitations in this work. First, the shortage of applicable data in the VAR model is an inevitable deficiency of current work. Therefore, it would be very ideal if future empirical research could make up for it and carry out a perfect and flawless econometric analysis. For an applicable dataset with more information about government activities, we can estimate the dynamic effect of Productive Government Expenditure (PGE) and the magnitude of the crowd out effect on household consumption based on the structural VAR model and time-varying structural VAR model. Second, the policy specification of our present model is still confined to a simplified monetary rule, since this paper mainly emphasizes the discussion about the fiscal policy effect of Productive Government Expenditure (PGE). A pretty interesting research direction is to adopt a modified Taylor rule following [46] in a more elaborate way. For China’s special institutional background, a monetary rule taking into consideration both the nominal interest rate and money supply will enhance the persuasive power of the theoretical framework, under the premise of an effective and feasible model solution.
Last, but not least, from the concern about more flexible, but fragile financial markets in China thanks to the bulky shadow banking system, it is quite crucial to add the internal transmission mechanism from nominal interest rates to asset price bubbles to future work. Currently, the present model still deems market interest rates to be simply set by the central bank, which is succinct and fits the facts. Nevertheless, if we elaborate an integral and essential sector of financial intermediaries in our generalized equilibrium model, the whole narration may be organized more comprehensively and be more well-grounded.

Author Contributions

Y.L. developed the study concept, contributed to the theoretical part, and wrote the paper. Q.Y. conducted the empirical analyzes, revised the theoretical model, and wrote the paper.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest. The funders had no role in the design of the study; in the collection, analyzes, or interpretation of data; in the writing of the manuscript; nor in the decision to publish the results.

References

  1. Yang, Q.; Lang, Y.; Xu, C. Is the High Interest Rate Combined with Intense Deleveraging Campaign Desirable? A Collateral Mechanism under Stringent Credit Constraints. Sustainability 2018, 10, 4803. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Chen, K.; Ren, J.; Zha, T. The Nexus of Monetary Policy and Shadow Banking in China. Am. Econ. Rev. 2018, 108, 3891–3936. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. da Cruz, N.F.; Marques, R.C. Scorecards for Sustainable Local Governments. Cities 2014, 39, 165–170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Ari, I.; Koc, M. Sustainable Financing for Sustainable Development: Understanding the Interrelations between Public Investment and Sovereign Debt. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Fay, M.; Toman, M.; Benitez, D.; Csordas, S. Infrastructure and Sustainable Development. In Postcrisis Growth and Development; Fardoust, S., Kim, Y., Sepúlveda, C.P., Eds.; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2010; pp. 329–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Eberts, R.W. Public Infrastructure and Regional Economic Development. Econ. Rev. 1990, 26, 15–27. [Google Scholar]
  7. Barro, R.J. Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries. Q. J. Econ. 1991, 106, 407–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Easterly, W.; Rebelo, S. Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth. J. Monet. Econ. 1993, 32, 417–458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Barro, R.J. Government Spending in a Simple Model of Endogeneous Growth. J. Political Econ. 1990, 98, S103–S125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Christiano, L.J.; Eichenbaum, M. Current Real-Business-Cycle Theories and Aggregate Labor-Market Fluctuations. Am. Econ. Rev. 1992, 82, 430–450. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Baxter, M.; King, R.G. Fiscal Policy in General Equilibrium. Am. Econ. Rev. 1993, 83, 315–334. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Glomm, G.; Ravikumar, B. Public Investment in Infrastructure in a Simple Growth Model. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 1994, 18, 1173–1187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Cashin, P. Government Spending, Taxes, and Economic Growth. Staff Pap. 1995, 42, 237–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Abiad, A.; Furceri, D.; Topalova, P. The Macroeconomic Effects of Public Investment: Evidence from Advanced Economies. J. Macroecon. 2016, 50, 224–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Berndt, E.R.; Hansson, B. Measuring the Contribution of Public Infrastructure Capital in Sweden; Working Paper 3842; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Holtz-Eakin, D. Public-Sector Capital and the Productivity Puzzle; Working Paper 4122; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Morrison, C.J.; Schwartz, A.E. State Infrastructure and Productive Performance; Working Paper 3981; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Hulten, C.R. Infrastructure Capital and Economic Growth: How Well You Use It May Be More Important Than How Much You Have; Working Paper 5847; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Donaldson, D. Railroads of the Raj: Estimating the Impact of Transportation Infrastructure; Working Paper 16487; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Rioja, F.K. Productiveness and Welfare Implications of Public Infrastructure: A Dynamic Two-Sector General Equilibrium Analysis. J. Dev. Econ. 1999, 58, 387–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Sanchez-Robles, B. Infrastructure Investment and Growth: Some Empirical Evidence. Contemp. Econ. Policy 1998, 16, 98–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Haughwout, A.F. Public Infrastructure Investments, Productivity and Welfare in Fixed Geographic Areas. J. Public Econ. 2002, 83, 405–428. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Calderón, C.; Chong, A. Volume and Quality of Infrastructure and the Distribution of Income: An Empirical Investigation. Rev. Income Wealth 2004, 50, 87–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Agenor, P.R.; Moreno-Dodson, B. Public Infrastructure and Growth: New Channels and Policy Implications; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Calderón, C.; Servén, L. Infrastructure, Growth, and Inequality: An Overview; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Turnovsky, S.J. Economic Growth and Inequality: The Role of Public Investment. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 2015, 61, 204–221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Erturk, K.A. Overcapacity and the East Asian Crisis. J. Post Keynes. Econ. 2001, 24, 253–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Esfahani, H.S.; Ram’írez, M.T. Institutions, Infrastructure, and Economic Growth. J. Dev. Econ. 2003, 70, 443–477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Ming, Z.; Liu, X.; Li, Y.; Peng, L. Review of Renewable Energy Investment and Financing in China: Status, Mode, Issues and Countermeasures. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 31, 23–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Yuan, J.; Li, P.; Wang, Y.; Liu, Q.; Shen, X.; Zhang, K.; Dong, L. Coal Power Overcapacity and Investment Bubble in China during 2015–2020. Energy Policy 2016, 97, 136–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Shi, Y.; Guo, S.; Sun, P. The Role of Infrastructure in China’s Regional Economic Growth. J. Asian Econ. 2017, 49, 26–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Fernald, J.G. Roads to Prosperity? Assessing the Link between Public Capital and Productivity. Am. Econ. Rev. 1999, 89, 619–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Bai, C.E.; Qian, Y. Infrastructure Development in China: The Cases of Electricity, Highways, and Railways. J. Comp. Econ. 2010, 38, 34–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Li, Z.; Chen, Y. Estimating the Social Return to Transport Infrastructure: A Price-Difference Approach Applied to a Quasi-Experiment. J. Comp. Econ. 2013, 41, 669–683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Liu, J.; Cheng, Z.; Zhang, H. Does Industrial Agglomeration Promote the Increase of Energy Efficiency in China? J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 164, 30–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Chang, C.; Chen, K.; Waggoner, D.F.; Zha, T. Trends and Cycles in China’s Macroeconomy. NBER Macroecon. Annu. 2016, 30, 1–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Dixit, A.K.; Stiglitz, J.E. Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity. Am. Econ. Rev. 1977, 67, 297–308. [Google Scholar]
  38. Calvo, G.A. Staggered Prices in a Utility-maximizing Framework. J. Monet. Econ. 1983, 12, 383–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. King, R.G.; Rebelo, S.T. Resuscitating Real Business Cycles. In Handbook of Macroeconomics; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1999; Volume 1, pp. 927–1007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Greenwood, J.; Hercowitz, Z.; Huffman, G.W. Investment, Capacity Utilization, and the Real Business Cycle. Am. Econ. Rev. 1988, 78, 402–417. [Google Scholar]
  41. Bouakez, H.; Rebei, N. Why Does Private Consumption Rise After a Government Spending Shock? Can. J. Econ./Revue Canadienne Déconomique 2007, 40, 954–979. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Smets, F.; Wouters, R. Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach. Am. Econ. Rev. 2007, 97, 586–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Liu, Z.; Ma, H. Trade Liberalization, Market Structure, and Firm Markup: Evidence from China; Working Paper; American Economic Association: Pittsburgh, PA, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  44. Mankiw, N.G.; Reis, R. Pervasive Stickiness. Am. Econ. Rev. 2006, 96, 164–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Guo, C.; Hu, Y.; Li, Y. Fiscal Expansion, Vertical Structure of Industries and Capacity Utilization Rate in China. Manag. World 2016, 10, 13–33. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  46. Li, B.; Liu, Q. On the Choice of Monetary Policy Rules for China: A Bayesian DSGE Approach. China Econ. Rev. 2017, 44, 166–185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The economic climate in China (2013M3∼2018M9). Note: 1. Green/yellow/orange areas respectively stand for the market sentiment indicators of consumers’ expectation/confidence/satisfaction. 2. The dashed purple line depicts Purchasing Managers’ Indices (PMI). 3. The solid blue line depicts industrial capacity utilization rates. Data sources: CEInetStatistics Database—macro monthly database; National Bureau of Statistics of China; www.tradingeconomics.com; IHSMarkit.
Figure 1. The economic climate in China (2013M3∼2018M9). Note: 1. Green/yellow/orange areas respectively stand for the market sentiment indicators of consumers’ expectation/confidence/satisfaction. 2. The dashed purple line depicts Purchasing Managers’ Indices (PMI). 3. The solid blue line depicts industrial capacity utilization rates. Data sources: CEInetStatistics Database—macro monthly database; National Bureau of Statistics of China; www.tradingeconomics.com; IHSMarkit.
Sustainability 11 00831 g001
Figure 2. Cyclical pattern of PGE. Data source: Center for Quantitative Economic Research (CQER), Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Figure 2. Cyclical pattern of PGE. Data source: Center for Quantitative Economic Research (CQER), Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Sustainability 11 00831 g002
Figure 3. Dynamic responses to a standard PGE shock. Confidence interval: 95%. Data source: Center for Quantitative Economic Research (CQER), Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Figure 3. Dynamic responses to a standard PGE shock. Confidence interval: 95%. Data source: Center for Quantitative Economic Research (CQER), Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Sustainability 11 00831 g003
Figure 4. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (benchmark).
Figure 4. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (benchmark).
Sustainability 11 00831 g004
Figure 5. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (change in output elasticity of PGE). Blue/black/green/yellow/purple lines denote α = 0.01 / 0.11 / 0.21 / 0.31 / 0.41 .
Figure 5. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (change in output elasticity of PGE). Blue/black/green/yellow/purple lines denote α = 0.01 / 0.11 / 0.21 / 0.31 / 0.41 .
Sustainability 11 00831 g005
Figure 6. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (change in shock persistency). Blue/green/black/ yellow/purple lines denote ρ g = 0.4 / 0.5 / 0.6 / 0.7 / 0.8 .
Figure 6. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (change in shock persistency). Blue/green/black/ yellow/purple lines denote ρ g = 0.4 / 0.5 / 0.6 / 0.7 / 0.8 .
Sustainability 11 00831 g006
Figure 7. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (change in monetary policy). Blue/green/black/ yellow/purple lines denote ρ Y = 0.025 / 0.075 / 0.125 / 0.175 / 0.225 .
Figure 7. Impulse responses to a positive PGE shock (change in monetary policy). Blue/green/black/ yellow/purple lines denote ρ Y = 0.025 / 0.075 / 0.125 / 0.175 / 0.225 .
Sustainability 11 00831 g007
Table 1. Time series statistics (1995Q1∼2017Q4). PGE, Productive Government Expenditure.
Table 1. Time series statistics (1995Q1∼2017Q4). PGE, Productive Government Expenditure.
VariablesVolatility
(Sd.Error)
Volatility
(w.r.t. Output)
Correlation Coefficients
(w.r.t. PGE Share)
Correlation Significance
(p-Value)
PGE Share0.01481.75931/
Consumption0.01381.6399−0.6103 ***0.0000
Output0.00841−0.16700.1116
Investment0.04265.06260.4878 ***0.0000
Inflation0.00840.9975−0.01650.8762
* p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01. Data source: Center for Quantitative Economic Research (CQER), Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.
Table 2. Model parameters.
Table 2. Model parameters.
ParameterDescriptionValue
Households
β Discount factor0.991
δ Depreciation rate0.025
θ Capital share0.3
γ Inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply0.25
η Leisure preference3.62
ρ Calvo price stickiness0.75
ψ Elasticity of substitution11
NSteady-state working hours1/3
Government policy
α PGE parameter (benchmark)0.11
ρ R Smooth coefficient in Taylor rule0.75
ρ π Inflation coefficient in Taylor rule1.5
ρ Y Output gap coefficient in Taylor rule0.125
ρ Y 1 Feedback coefficient in Taylor rule0.125
Shocks
ρ a Technology shock persistence0.9
ρ g PGE shock persistence (benchmark)0.6
ρ ζ Interest rate shock persistence0.5
σ a Technology shock volatility0.1
σ g PGE shock volatility0.1
σ ζ Interest rate shock volatility0.1
Table 3. Sensitivity analysis summary.
Table 3. Sensitivity analysis summary.
ConsumptionOutputInvestmentInventory
Larger PGE weight
in production
( α ↑)
subtle recovery ↑promoted ↑promoted ↑prolonged overcapacity ↑
More persistent
PGE shock
( ρ g →)
prolonged →,
subtle boosted ↑
prolonged →,
promoted ↑
prolonged →,
promoted ↑
depletion instantly ↓,
prolonged overcapacity ↑
Stronger monetary
policy control
( ρ Y ↑)
less boosted ↓less promoted ↓less promoted ↓less overcapacity
in long-term ↓

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Lang, Y.; Yang, Q. Does Public Infrastructure Breed Consumption Downgrade and Overcapacity in China? A DSGE Approach on Macroeconomic Effects. Sustainability 2019, 11, 831. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11030831

AMA Style

Lang Y, Yang Q. Does Public Infrastructure Breed Consumption Downgrade and Overcapacity in China? A DSGE Approach on Macroeconomic Effects. Sustainability. 2019; 11(3):831. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11030831

Chicago/Turabian Style

Lang, Youze, and Qiuyi Yang. 2019. "Does Public Infrastructure Breed Consumption Downgrade and Overcapacity in China? A DSGE Approach on Macroeconomic Effects" Sustainability 11, no. 3: 831. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11030831

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop