Next Article in Journal
Application of Multi-Species Differential Evolution Algorithm in Sustainable Microgrid Model
Previous Article in Journal
Investigating Private Sectors’ Behavioral Intention to Participate in PPP Projects: An Empirical Examination Based on the Theory of Planned Behavior
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Politics of Agribusiness and the Business of Sustainability
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Using Insights from Prospect Theory to Enhance Sustainable Decision Making by Agribusinesses in Argentina

by
Jimena Gonzalez-Ramirez
1,*,
Poonam Arora
1 and
Guillermo Podesta
2
1
O’Malley School of Business, Manhattan College, Riverdale, NY 10471, USA
2
Rosenstiel School of Marine and Atmospheric Science, University of Miami, Miami, FL 33149, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2018, 10(8), 2693; https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082693
Submission received: 30 June 2018 / Revised: 20 July 2018 / Accepted: 23 July 2018 / Published: 1 August 2018
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sustainable Agribusiness and Agri-food Prospects)

Abstract

:
Farm production often involves family-owned agribusinesses where decisions are made by households or individuals, not corporate managers. As these decisions have important economic, environmental, and social implications, decision-making processes must be understood to foster sustainable agricultural production. Decision experiments, involving lotteries, targeting farmers in the Argentine Pampas were used to estimate prospect theory (PT) parameters. Results suggest that decisions under risk are better represented by prospect theory than by expected utility (EU) theory: Decision makers treat gains and losses differently and use subjective probabilities of outcomes; they are quite loss averse and are more likely to overweigh probabilities of infrequent events, such as large droughts or floods. Statistical testing revealed heterogeneity in the risk tied to land tenure (land owners vs. renters) and agribusiness roles (farmers vs. technical advisors). Perceptions of risk, probability, and outcomes played a large role in the sustainability of production. Due to a strong desire to avoid losses, decision makers have a greater short term focus: Immediate economic outcomes are more salient, and environmental and social investments are framed as costs rather than long-term gains. This research can help design policies, programs, and tools that assist agribusinesses in managing better contradictions across the triple bottom line to ensure greater sustainability.

1. Introduction

Agribusinesses can play a critical role as food providers, rather than just act as profit maximizers, particularly in Argentina where these entities are typically small to medium sized organizations that are household- or family-owned, often with social ties within the local community. The decision processes of these agribusinesses involve important and unavoidable tradeoffs between different sustainability dimensions [1]. On the one hand, decision-makers seek to maximize profits and to ensure their immediate survival by preventing a loss. On the other hand, their very existence is linked to maintaining the long-term productivity of the land and employees, who have the knowledge and experience to help maximize output from each farm plot [1]. Therefore, agribusinesses need to balance the three pillars of sustainability: Profit, people, and the planet.
Food production, however, occurs in a context of increasing climate variability in which extreme weather events, like droughts, floods, and heat/cold waves, are expected to become more frequent, intense, or of a longer duration [2,3,4,5,6]. In the U.S., farmers have noticed an increase in extreme weather [7], and a similar intensification of extremes is emerging in the observed climate records across many parts of the world [8,9]. As agribusinesses face more frequent and extreme weather events due to climate change, achieving sustainability will become even more challenging. Balance across the three pillars will require that farmers adapt to climate change by changing their behavior and optimizing tradeoffs among and within the three pillars to meet market demand for specific commodities and products, while also ensuring their own long-term survival. It will also require that agricultural policies, programs, and decision tools consider how and why agribusinesses make management decisions and tradeoffs across the three pillars [1].

1.1. The Argentine Pampas

In this article, we study agribusiness decisions under risk in the Argentine Pampas, one of the most fertile agricultural regions of the world [10]. Specifically, we seek to understand how the risk preferences of agribusiness decision makers influence production choices. Argentina is a major contributor to global food security: It already produces amounts of grain that are sufficient to feed at least 200 million people, five times its current population, and has substantial potential to increase production even more [11]. Argentina is the leading world exporter of soybean oil and meal, and the third largest exporter of soybeans as beans.
Climate fluctuations, technological innovations, and global and local economic and social contexts have influenced agriculture in the Pampas over the last few decades [12]. The growing global demand for grains, local changes in the Argentine economy, and simplification of agronomical management [13] has enhanced the relative profitability of agriculture in Argentina. As a result, cropping related activities conducted by agribusinesses dominate, displacing pastures and native grasslands [14,15]. A most striking pattern has been the increasing dominance of soybeans. Despite the large income provided by soybean exports (≈1/3 of the value of all Argentine exports in 2016 involved soy oil, meal, or beans), there are growing concerns about the sustainability of “soybean monoculture” [16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24].
High land prices in the Pampas, together with the virtual inexistence of credit, have made growth via the purchase of land economically prohibitive. Instead, agribusinesses increase the size of their operations by renting additional land, a mechanism that involves much more affordable capital outlays. Owners of smaller extensions that are economically unviable [25] increasingly rent out their land to agribusinesses that both own and rent land, or to new firms entering the sector [26]. Consequently, land tenure patterns have changed rapidly: Recent estimates find approximately 60% of the land currently farmed by agribusinesses in the Pampas is rented [27]. Estimates place the size of the annual land rental market in the Pampas at over US$4 billion [28]. Typical leases for the land are annual and are, thus, characterized by frequent turnover. These short-term (annual) lease contracts induce maximization of short-term profits and discourage multiannual investments to preserve soil quality [29,30,31].
Argentine agriculture is not a subsidized sector: Agribusinesses take on the risks inherent in commodity markets; their economic incentive is the potential profit based on the actual crop price [32]. This risk manifests more strongly on land that is rented, as the rental payment is an upfront cost [28]. Additionally, the shift to export crops has introduced greater unpredictability due to environmental and social consequences from recent structural changes. Unlike pastures, which are multi-year investments present on the land year-round, agricultural crops are annual choices that may remain for any length of time between four to eight months. When land is fallow, it collects water through rainfall, but does not lose nearly as much through evapotranspiration that occurs when plants are in the ground. Thus, in many parts of the Pampas, the depth of the water table has shifted upwards by an estimated two meters over the course of the last twenty years [33], increasing the probability of inundation from severe rainfall. Floods and droughts have varying social and economic implications. Floods cause greater disruption of social life and capital, while droughts lead to greater economic hardship.
Similarly, social relationships have also been altered by the recent structural changes, raising issues of local learning, social capital, and cohesion [34]. Agribusiness decision makers who own the land may view the costs associated with maintaining long-term productivity of the land, building social capital, and encouraging local participation as low-risk investments, whereas those renting the land may be less willing to invest in such longer-term investments. Environmental and social goals are, therefore, not only inexorably intertwined with economic goals in the decision processes and are essential to the long-term sustainability of agribusiness in the region, but also vary based on the role of the decision maker (owner vs. renter). Policy makers need to consider farmers’ risk preferences and any heterogeneity between renters and owners when designing farm policies that address environmentally unsustainable practices and that promote other practices where environmental and social impacts are also considered.

1.2. Literature Review: Prospect Theory and Role Influences

Sustainable agriculture depends on agribusiness decisions that are frequently made under conditions of uncertainty and incomplete information, and are influenced by decision makers’ differences in risk preferences and perceptions. Land use and agricultural management decisions involve risks connected to global market prices, climate events, such as rainfall or droughts, outbreaks of pests and diseases, and the introduction of new technologies. Most efforts to study risk attitudes among farmers in the developing world have been based on neoclassical economics and have relied on expected utility (EU) theory [35], which assumes that risk preferences are consistent between domains and across time, and are adequately captured by the concavity of the utility function. However, Kahneman and Tversky [36] show that risk preferences are better explained by prospect theory (PT), which accounts for the differences in risk preferences in the domain of gains versus losses, as well as the strong preference for certainty by decision makers.
The utility function is based on objective probabilities in EU theory, while PT allows for the influence of subjective probabilities, where individuals can place different decision weights on different probabilities. As extreme weather events become more frequent and acute, understanding subjective probabilities and their weighting becomes more relevant to modelling farmers’ decisions [37]. PT also includes a reference point, in which the value function has a kink that separates gains and losses. This reference point is dynamic and subjective. Thus, major limitations of EU theory are the lack of consideration of any reference dependence and of probability weighting.
PT states that decisions under uncertainty are made to either ensure gains or avoid losses that, psychologically speaking, loom larger than gains. In PT, risk preferences are characterized by the curvature of the value function and by two additional parameters: Nonlinear weighting of probabilities (or certainty preference) and loss aversion [36]. Specific functions and values used to estimate these parameters are shown in the Results section. Taken together, these three parameters provide a descriptive rather than normative model of decision making. At a first look, PT suggests that options that result in gains (i.e., outcomes above the reference point) will be preferred, even if they lead to negative longer-term environmental or social externalities. However, PT also provides a possible technique to reverse such choices by reframing them—when the negative externalities are presented as certain losses, the option that generates them is less likely to be preferred. Moreover, PT implies that farmers may take big risks to escape losses.
While PT has motivated economists, psychologists, and policy makers to better capture/represent risk preferences to understand behavior and to, subsequently, design more effective policies, field studies eliciting risk measures have primarily characterized risk preferences by one parameter: The curvature of the utility function (See [38] for a review of studies in developing countries). The curvature determines whether the individual is risk averse, risk neutral, or risk seeking. Some articles have gone beyond the curvature to elicit PT parameter values for the curvature of the value function, loss aversion, and probability weighting [37,39,40,41]. Researchers have estimated correlations between different variables and risk preference parameters [39,42,43,44]. For example, Tanaka, Camerer and Nguyen (2010) [39] estimated PT parameters and found that (a) people living in low income villages were more loss averse and (b) no statistical differences for risk aversion or probability weighting were detected. Moreover, Liu (2013) estimated risk preference parameters for PT among cotton farmers in China, and found that risk and loss aversion affected farmers’ decisions to adopt a new cotton technology [45].
General differences based on land tenure (between renter and owners) have been well-studied [46,47,48]. In Iowa, Varble et al. (2016) found significant differences between land tenure and the willingness to adopt different conservation practices [49]. In Argentina, Arora and colleagues [28] explored differences between renters and owners on agribusiness goals. They found that, possibly due to underlying psychological differences in the connection with the land, ownership was positively correlated with a long-term environmental focus, whereas land rental was positively correlated with a short-term profitability focus. The deeper connection from actual land ownership changed how losses and gains were framed, suggesting that heterogeneity in the PT variables based on land tenure is likely.
Heterogeneity in risk preferences and the framing of decisions has also been documented based on the role of the decision maker. Whether the decision maker is the producer working the land—and, thus, someone likely to be psychologically connected to the outcome—or a technical advisor who may have a broader perspective and greater psychological distance from the decision [50], can influence risk preferences and choices. Boyles and colleagues [51] found that having distance from the decision (i.e., an advisory role) resulted in a longer-term and global frame leading to a greater willingness to incur smaller short-term losses for a larger longer-term gain. This is true even when advisors were making decisions for themselves, i.e., their own gains and losses were determined by their choices.
Clearly, risk preferences and goal motivations vary depending on land tenure and the role of the decision maker in the agribusiness. What is less understood is the relationship between land tenure and decision making roles on risk preferences and consequent choices. Thus, understanding the underlying PT parameters as they vary by the tenure and role of decision maker in the agribusiness, and how they differ from EU expectations is important if we are to develop policies and decision tools that support decision making for sustainable agriculture.

1.3. Research Hypotheses

The research reported here seeks to answer two main questions: (1) Are Argentine agribusiness decisions under risk consistent with EU theory or, instead, are they better represented by PT, displaying loss aversion and different probability weightings? and (2) is there heterogeneity in preferences (risk aversion, loss aversion, and probability weighting) that can be tied to land tenure and agribusiness role?
Specifically, for the first question, we will test whether EU theory assumptions regarding probability weighting (being linear) and loss aversion (no differences in how gains and losses are perceived) hold true. Given documented findings in the literature that support PT as a descriptive theory of decision making, our alternative hypotheses to counter EU theory assumptions are that agribusiness decision makers do not weigh probabilities linearly, and that they perceive gains and losses differently.
In the second question, we seek to examine the impact of land tenure (renters vs. owners) on PT parameters. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first paper to study risk preference differences between land renters and owners through analyses of PT parameters. Since heterogeneity in risk perspectives and choices may also be tied to psychological and emotional distance from a decision, we explore how agribusiness producers who are farmers, and, therefore, food suppliers, may differ in their PT parameters from those who provide advisory services to those who are farmers/owners.
We examine these questions and test our hypotheses via a lab-in-the-field experiment containing three paper-based exercises with decision makers from agribusinesses in the Pampas. Our hypotheses diverge from traditional assumptions of rationality and utility maximization inherent in EU theory to account for the heuristics and biases that have been well documented in human decision making [52]. We test the validity of “Homo economicus”, a rational maximizer of self-interest [53], as a decision maker in a real world setting to create better descriptive models of agribusiness decision making.
Research on agricultural production, farm management, and policies have traditionally been based on assumptions of rationality and EU theory [54]. In this research, by testing the underlying assumptions, we question the true impact of “sustainability-oriented” policies and programs: Can tax incentives to encourage investments in long-term climate change mitigation and adaptation really work if the decision maker views the choice as a short-term certain loss rather than as a long-term gain? Perhaps a better understanding of actual risk preferences and the influence of role and land tenure on risk preferences could result in policies, programs, and tools that are more likely to frame the mitigation and adaptation choices as the more palatable options. The following sections discuss our methodology, experimental materials, results, and the resulting theoretical and policy implications. It bears noting that though grounded in behavioral economics, our methods, analysis, and interpretations borrow from psychology and management as sustainable decision making by agribusinesses requires such an interdisciplinary approach.

2. Materials and Methods

2.1. Experimental Design and Games

PT describes decisions under risk by three parameters, including the curvature of the value function, loss aversion, and probability weighting. This experiment was designed following functional forms for utility, probability weighting, and the value of the prospect as described by [55]. The underlying value function is a piece-wise function for gains and losses for the outcome, x :
U ( x ) = { x σ   f o r   x > 0 λ ( x ) σ   f o r   x < 0
where σ describes the curvature of the value function and λ describes the degree of loss aversion. This value function has a kink at zero, where U(x) = 0. If σ   < 1 , the value function is concave in the gain domain, and convex in the loss domain. If λ > 1 , an individual is loss averse and weighs losses λ -times more than gains of the same magnitude, which is reflected in a steeper curvature of the value function in the loss domain. The probability weighting function is:
w ( p ) = p α ( p α + ( 1 p ) α ) 1 α
where p is the objective probability of an event. PT considers that individuals make decisions based on subjective probabilities, weighing objective probabilities. If α < 1 ( α > 1 ), the individual overweighs (underweighs) small probabilities and underweighs (overweighs) large probabilities. If α = 1 , w ( p ) becomes linear, it matches EU theory. Faced with a prospect that pays, x , with a probability, p , or pays, y , with a probability, 1 p , the value of the prospect (A or B, see below) is defined as:
V ( p r o s p e c t ) = w ( p ) U ( x ) + ( 1 w ( p ) ) U ( y )
When α = 1 and λ = 1 , the above equations collapse to match EU theory. However, for all other values, EU theory falls short. An individual faced with two prospects, A and B , containing different lotteries, chooses option B as long as V ( B ) V ( A ) .

2.2. Procedures and Participants

Experimental data was collected from 341 AACREA (Asociación Argentina de Consorcios Regionales de Experimentación Agrícola) members in the Pampas, which provides a representative sample of active farmers and/or advisors who are highly influential in the region [56]. Each participant is connected to the decision-making process in an agribusiness. Most participants are the primary decision makers in the agribusiness, though a small minority provide advice. For the remainder of the article, we use the term farmer and agribusiness decision maker interchangeably. AACREA members farm in areas with relatively homogeneous ecological and production characteristics and tend to have an education that is above average [56]. At the time the experiments were conducted, AACREA had about 1600 members. Paper-based exercises were distributed to all members (organized into groups of 8–10 agribusinesses from a region and who have similar production systems) by AACREA technical advisors (the professionals who coordinate group interactions and information exchanges, and who introduce technical or management innovations to group members).
Each farmer completed a series of paper-based exercises eliciting PT parameters, as well as some demographic questions. The experimental games are summarized in Figure 1, Figure 2 and Figure 3. Exercise forms were collected by the groups’ advisors and sent to AACREA Headquarters for coding and quality control.
In each game, a participant was presented with two prospects, A and B , and with specific probabilities for each prospect, which were depicted by black and white balls, as illustrated by Figure 1, Figure 2 and Figure 3. For each game, the participant was asked to choose the value of Z that would make him/her choose Option B instead of Option A, or switch from Option A to Option B. The probabilities vary across, but not within, the three games. Games 1 and 2 are about gains, while Game 3’s prospects include both positive and negative payments. Given the choice of Z for each game, values of α , σ , and λ are assigned based on predetermined tables such that they satisfy the condition that V ( B ) V ( A ) for each game following Equations (1)–(3).

3. Results

3.1. PT vs. EU

After assigning a value for α , σ , and λ to each participant, we computed summary statistics, which are depicted in Table 1:
Table 1 shows that the average farmer has a concave (convex) value function in the gain (loss) domain. Moreover, the average farmer overweighs small probabilities and underweighs large probabilities as the average α is below one. Lastly, we observe that the average farmer is loss averse, putting two and a half times more weight on losses than gains, on average.
To place our findings in context, we compared our results with other studies. For comparison, Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen (2010) estimated average values for (σ, α, λ) as (0.59, 0.74, 2.63) and (0.63, 0.74, 2.63) among southern and northern Vietnamese villages, respectively [39]. Liu (2008) estimated average values of (0.48, 0.69, 3.47) for (σ, α, λ) [45]. Moreover, Bocquéh, Jacquet, and Reynaud (2013) found average values of (0.51, 0.65, 3.76) for (σ, α, λ) among French farmers [37]. Therefore, the average parameter values in our sample are in line with previous studies.
To study our first research question, we tested whether the α and λ parameters from the experimental results were equal to those assumed by EU theory. Moreover, we tested for risk neutrality versus risk aversion. We performed one-sample t-tests to test the following pairs of null and alternative hypotheses: (1) H 0 :   σ = 1 versus H a : σ < 1 ; (2) H 0 :   α = 1 versus H a : α < 1 ; and (3) H 0 :   λ = 1 versus H a : λ > 1 . The first pair of hypotheses tested for risk neutrality with an alternative hypothesis of risk aversion if we assumed that risk preferences were only captured by the curvature of the utility function, as in EU theory. The second and third pairs tested whether EU theory holds, meaning that the probability weighting was linear and that there are no differences between gains and losses (i.e., no loss aversion). We reject the null hypothesis for each pair, with p-values below 0.0001 for the three t-tests. We conclude that agribusiness decision makers are risk averse and that our results are statistically different from EU theory.
We also performed Wilcoxon signed-rank tests for the same pairs of hypotheses to confirm our results using a non-parametric statistical hypothesis test. We confirm our results, as we reject the null hypothesis for each pair, with p-values below 0.0001. Our hypothesis testing implies that Argentine agribusiness preferences are better captured by PT than EU theory, as decision makers appear to be loss averse and as they overweigh small probabilities and underweigh large probabilities. Furthermore, we observed that the average farmer has a diminishing value function in the gain domain and an increasing value function in the loss domain. We also report the median values to further show that they are not close to the EU theory or risk neutrality assumptions, and conclude that Argentine agribusiness behavior is better captured by PT. Agribusiness decision makers are, on average, risk averse, loss averse, and overweigh small probabilities and underweigh large probabilities.

3.2. Heterogeneity

3.2.1. Land Tenure

One of the contributions of our article is to study the heterogeneity in risk preferences between renters and owners, and between producers and advisors to understand any heterogeneity that may influence the way agribusinesses adapt to climate change and attain sustainability in their crucial function as food suppliers. We began by identifying decision makers by land tenure: Owners only, renters only, and those who are both owners and renters (owners + renters), as shown in Table 2.
Table 2 excludes participants who are only advisors, i.e., they only provide advice, but do not themselves own and/or rent land, for a total of 317 decision makers. For the current analysis, we focused on this subsample, as these are the primary decision-makers. Table 2 shows that most agribusinesses own and rent land at the same time, thus, the decision makers make choices on different plots of land. To explore differences between the three groups, we created three box plots for each PT value, as illustrated by Figure 4:
Panel (a) shows similar boxes for owners only and for those who are owners and renters at the same time. The box plot for renters only stands out as the most different in that panel, with higher quartiles. Moreover, the median is closer to one for renters, meaning that renters are closer to EU theory assumptions. At first glance, owners only and owners + renters appear to overweigh more small probabilities than renters only. Moreover, owners only and owners + renters seem to underweigh more large probabilities than renters only.
Switching to the curvature of the value function, we observed that the three box plots are very similar in Panel (b) from Figure 4. The first three quartiles are below one for every type, showing that most farmers have a concave (convex) value function in the gain (loss) domain. Lastly, Panel (c) shows differences between the three boxes, with owners and renters with the highest median and third quartile, and renters with the lowest quartiles overall. We observed that farmers who are both owners and renters appear to be more loss averse. Comparing owners only to renters only, we noticed more loss aversion among owners than renters. While we know that the connection to the land manifests differently for owners and renters [28], tenants start the cropping cycle in the loss domain, as having paid out the rent, they incur high upfront costs. Thus, renters should be more willing to do what needs to be done to overcome the initial loss [28], which is confirmed by the lower degree of loss aversion.
To complement the visual analysis, we conducted three Welch two-sample t-tests to compare the average between renters only versus owners and owners + renters: (1) H 0 :   α r e n t e r = α o w n e r versus H a : α r e n t e r α o w n e r ; (2) H 0 :   σ r e n t e r = σ o w n e r versus H a :   σ r e n t e r σ o w n e r   ; and H 0 :   λ r e n t e r = λ o w n e r versus H a : λ r e n t e r λ o w n e r . The subscript for owners includes both owners and owners + renters. We confirmed our visual analysis. For the first pair, we reject the null hypothesis and find that the average among renters, α r e n t e r =   0.77 , is statistically significantly higher than the average among owners, α o w n e r = 0.66 , with a p-value = 0.017. Hence, renters overweigh (underweigh) less small (large) probabilities relative to owners. For the second pair, we fail to reject the null hypothesis, and find that the average among renters, σ r e n t e r = 0.61 , is not statistically different than the average among owners, σ o w n e r = 0.62 . For our third test, we reject the null hypothesis, as the average among renters, λ r e n t e r = 2.01 , is statistically different from the average among owners,   λ o w n e r = 2.61 , with a p-value = 0.16. Hence, renters only are less loss averse than owners, as they weigh losses twice as gains, while owners weigh losses 2.6 times more than gains.

3.2.2. Producers Versus Advisors

We also seek to understand differences between producers and advisors, with the latter as those who advise producers. Here, we include technical advisors who do not own and/or rent land, as well as advisors who own and/or rent land. The paper-based exercises included a question that asked participants to identify themselves as producers or advisors. Table 3 summarizes the distribution among both occupations.
We note that our sample consists mostly of producers. While we only observe 35 advisors, we want to understand their behavior as they play a crucial role advising agribusinesses about new technologies, adaptation strategies, and conservation practices to attain sustainability. As with land tenure, we first explored any difference visually, as shown in the box plots in Figure 5.
Panel (a) shows that technical advisors are closer to EU theory as the median is closer to 1. On the other hand, producers appear to overweigh more small probabilities relative to technical advisors. They also underweigh more large probabilities relative to advisors. Hence, the contrast between the gain and loss domains is more pronounced for producers relative to advisors. We conjecture that producers tend to care more about low probability events, such as droughts or floods, relative to advisors, who know different farms and learn about new technologies and farming strategies. For the curvature of the value function, producers appear to have a steeper value function relative to advisors. Lastly, Panel (c) shows that producers are more loss averse than advisors. Since producers primarily work the land, they may feel more connection to their farm compared with advisors who see numerous farms. The quartiles for advisors are closer to each other, but we observe a few outliers at the top of the distribution. We observe that producers have a much steeper value function in the loss domain relative to advisors. These parameters suggest that producers are willing to take bigger risks to overcome losses relative to advisors.
Following the same methodology as in Section 3.2.1, we performed three Welch two sample t-tests to compare the averages between producers and advisors: (1) H 0 :   α p r o d u c e r = α a d v i s o r versus H a : α p r o d u c e r α a d v i s o r ; (2) H 0 :   σ p r o d u c e r = σ a d v i s o r versus H a :   σ p r o d u c e r σ a d v i s o r   ; and H 0 :   λ p r o d u c e r = λ a d v i s o r versus H a : λ p r o d u c e r λ a d v i s o r . For the first test, we found that the average among producers, α p r o d u c e r = 0.66 , is not statistically different than the average among advisors, α a d v i s o r = 0.74 , with a p-value = 0.132. While producers have a smaller probability weighting, we cannot reject the null of equal means between both groups. For the second test, we also fail to reject the null hypothesis. We find that the average among producers, σ p r o d u c e r = 0.61 , is not statistically different than the average among advisors, σ a d v i s o r = 0.68 , with a p-value = 0.173. On the other hand, for the third test, we reject the null hypothesis and conclude that the average among producers, λ p r o d u c e r = 2.54 , is statistically different than the average among technical advisors, λ a d v i s o r = 2.05 , with a p-value = 0.049. We conclude that producers are more loss averse than advisors, since producers weigh losses 2.5 times more than gains while advisors weigh losses twice as much as gains. As advisors are less loss averse, their advice will reflect this difference, and it will be interesting to see if producers are open to a recommendation that may make them uncomfortable due to their stronger loss aversion.
In summary, our analysis allows us to better understand agribusiness decision makers and to identify differences in human behavior based on land tenure and agribusiness role. In this Results section, we find that renters only overweigh small probabilities less than owners only and owners + renters. Similarly, renters only underweigh large probabilities less than owners and owners + renters. Furthermore, we find that renters are less loss averse than owners and owners + renters. We find similar differences between advisors and producers, with producers being more loss averse than advisors.

4. Discussion

Our results illustrate that agribusiness decision makers are better represented by PT parameters than EU theory—they treat gains and losses differently and use subjective probabilities of outcomes: They are quite loss averse and are more likely to overweigh small probabilities. Some of these divergences from EU theory are further nuanced based on the role of the decision maker (producer vs. advisor) and land tenure (owner vs. renter), as summarized in Table 4. In all cases, however, the agribusiness decision makers we studied do not act like Homo economicus, providing evidence for all our hypotheses.
Our results are in line with studies on risk preferences that estimate the three PT parameters. Tanaka, Camerer, and Nguyen (2010) found that individuals are loss averse and overweigh (underweigh) small (large) probabilities in Vietnamese villages [39]. Liu (2010) and Bocquéh, Jacquet, and Reynaud (2013) found similar results among cotton farmers in China [45] and among French farmers [37], respectively. However, Chinese cotton farmers and French farmers are more loss averse than Argentine farmers or Vietnamese individuals, placing more weight on losses than gains. Our article contributes to the literature by studying risk preferences in a market-oriented country that is a major contributor to the global food supply and that lacks agricultural subsidies and agricultural insurance. Given these conditions, farmers face losses differently than farmers in countries with subsidies and insurance for farmers. Hence, understanding their risk preferences becomes extremely relevant for any farm policies or programs. To the best of our knowledge, no other articles have studied heterogeneity in risk preferences based on land tenure and agribusiness role, which prevents us from comparing our specific results to other studies. Therefore, our article also contributes to the literature by connecting risk preferences with land tenure and agribusiness roles.
Our paper-based exercises were context independent, and, as such, the deviations from EU theory can be thought of as baseline levels. There is evidence in the literature that context can change how decisions are spontaneously framed [57] and outcomes are evaluated [58]. Thus, it is important to consider how the high levels of observed loss aversion may manifest in choices when there is greater unpredictability in the context. Numerous agribusiness decisions occur under conditions of high uncertainty caused by unpredictability in decision drivers, like the commodity prices of soybean and wheat, and increases in extreme weather events due to climate change. Here, a loss averse, risk averse farmer who is more likely to overweigh the small probability of a drought may choose options that ensure a short-term gain while ignoring the drought’s costlier longer-term environmental and social consequences.
One such example prevalent in the Pampas is the decision to grow (or not grow) cover crops to manage the depth of shallow groundwater. Cover crops are not intended to be harvested. Instead they are planted to enhance soil properties, prevent erosion, and increase water consumption by increasing the time there is a crop in the ground, thus, lowering water table depth (WTD) and decreasing flooding risks [59]. However, cover crops are not as prevalent as researchers/observers think that they should be, especially given the documented increase in WTD due to the switch from mixed pasture/crops to continuous agriculture [33]. This is, in part, due to the perception that droughts are more disruptive, leading to greater losses [1]. As a result, the small probability of a drought is overweighed in the decision process, and the loss averse decision maker—wishing to avoid droughts at all costs—chooses not to plant cover crops. Inadvertently, the agribusiness takes on an additional risk of flooding. Sustainable agriculture would require the decision maker to attempt to manage the groundwater level to avoid droughts and floods by considering both phenomena appropriately. Knowing that farmers are less likely to plant cover crops due to their risk preferences, policy makers can design behavioral nudges to make the potential losses from high WTDs and floods more salient. The goal of the nudges would be to balance the contrast between flood and loss perceptions.
The heterogeneity between owners and renters similarly influences decision making and sustainable agriculture. Land rents are typically due and paid upfront. Thus, renters begin a cropping cycle in the domain of losses, which makes them likely to be more risk seeking. Soybean is the lower cost, higher profit crop, and, as such, is frequently cultivated by renters without rotation. This trend towards monoculture is further exacerbated by the minimal use of fertilizer (an expensive input in Argentina) by renters. There is a greater willingness to take on the risks of monoculture and lack of replacement of nutrients to ensure the initial loss is covered by renters. An interesting caveat is that although land leases are typically one-year, when there is a multi-year lease, renters will use fertilizer during all but the last year of the lease to minimize the potential total loss [28]. The monoculture trend has not substantially impacted yields yet due to technical innovations, masking the negative impact in the form of gradual soil nutrient depletion.
Similar differences in loss aversion between producers and advisors suggest that producers tend to be more averse to losses, showing a sharper contrast between their gain and loss behavior. As advisors are exposed to different farm plots, technologies, and management practices as they interact with multiple agribusinesses, they may feel less connection toward the land. Advisors frequently introduce new technologies and practices to agribusinesses, and their decision-making processes play a critical role in promoting sustainability and climate change adaptation. As with the example of cover crops, an advisor will be more willing to recommend this practice than producers, who may not be as willing to adopt this practice. If producers trust and follow their advisors, these recommendations are more likely to be implemented by producers even if they may make them uneasy due to stronger overall risk aversion.
One limitation of this research is that it does not assess the reference point—a central issue in PT. It is the reference point that determines whether a decision is in the domain of gains or of losses. Without this understanding of how decision makers distinguish between gains and losses, it is difficult to construct policies, programs, or tools that can assist in making more sustainable management and adaptation decisions under risk. The reference point is a dynamic quantity that is adjusted and constructed based on the context of the decision [60]. For example, agribusinesses often adjust their reference point based on previous year performance, as well as expectations of future rainfall or commodity prices [61]. The reference point may also be impacted by social influence, where comparisons with relevant peers can result in adjustments. These comparisons need not be economic—they can be environmental (quality of my land) and social (status in the community, contribution to local social capital). Thus, understanding how reference points are constructed and dynamically adjusted is important to the creation of policies, programs, and tools that support sustainable agriculture.
Using PT to capture risk preferences to better understand how decisions are made under conditions of risk is essential to the overall sustainability of agribusinesses and the agricultural system. To attain sustainability in the face of more extreme weather events and considering loss aversion, agricultural agencies and policy makers can design nudges that make the environmental loss more salient. As owners and producers appear to be more loss averse and as owners tend to contrast more gains and losses, they should be more influenced by the aforementioned nudges and be willing to change their behavior. By understanding differences in risk preferences, environmental campaigns and programs can be better targeted to attain sustainability.
Agribusinesses in Argentina should be fundamentally triple bottom line (profit, planet, people) achievers—to ensure their survival, they must ensure profitability while maintaining the environmental quality of their land for agricultural activities, and building social capital to ensure local knowledge is not lost. Though many act to do so, others fall short, in part due to most agribusiness decisions being made under conditions of risk and incomplete information. Perceptions of risk, probability, and outcomes play a large role in such decisions where concrete data is missing. PT parameters better capture these perceptions and tendencies, and suggest that, due to a strong desire to avoid losses, decision makers have a greater short term focus. As a result, immediate economic outcomes are more salient, and environmental and social investments are framed as costs rather than long-terms gains. These parameters illustrate that certain assumptions are made by decision makers that may inherently contradict each other, preventing higher levels of agribusiness sustainability. This research provides some insights that can be used to design policies, programs, and tools that assist agribusinesses in better managing the contractions across the triple bottom line to ensure greater sustainability.

Author Contributions

The three authors contributed to the conceptualization of the paper. P.A. led the introduction, background, current research and hypotheses with input from J.G.-R. and G.P. Within Materials and Methods, J.G.-R. led the Experimental Design and Games subsection that describes the methodology and models, with feedback from P.A. and G.P. Moreover, G.P. led the subsection on Procedures and Participants and helped collect and check the field data. The data analysis and data visualization were performed by J.G.-R. The Results section was led by J.G.-R. with input from P.A. and G.P. The three authors discussed the results, their interpretations, and their implications that are summarized in the Discussion led by P.A. with input by J.G.-R. and G.P. The three authors participated in the writing, review, and editing process. Lastly, the funding acquisition was done by G.P. and P.A.

Funding

This research was funded by NSF Grant # SES-0345840 to the Center for Environmental Decisions (CRED), Columbia University, and by NSF Grant # CNH-1211613 to the second and third authors.

Acknowledgments

We thank Elke Weber (formerly at Columbia University), who designed the exercises to elicit PT parameters. We also thank the members, technical advisors and staff of AACREA, who willingly participated in the decision exercises and helped us to collect and check the data.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Arora, P.; Peterson, N.; Bert, F.E.; Podestá, G.P. Managing the Triple Bottom Line for Sustainability: A Case Study of Argentine Agribusinesses. Sustain. Sci. Pract. Policy 2016, 12, 63–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Carril, A.F.; Cavalcanti, I.F.A.; Menéndez, C.G.; Sörensson, A.; López-Franca, N.; Rivera, J.A.; Robledo, F.; Zaninelli, P.G.; Ambrizzi, T.; Penalba, O.C.; et al. Extreme events in the La Plata basin: A retrospective analysis of what we have learned during CLARIS-LPB project. Clim. Res. 2016, 68, 95–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Cavalcanti, I.F.A.; Carril, A.F.; Penalba, O.C.; Grimm, A.M.; Menéndez, C.G.; Sanchez, E.; Cherchi, A.; Sörensson, A.; Robledo, F.; Rivera, J.; et al. Precipitation extremes over La Plata Basin—Review and new results from observations and climate simulations. J. Hydrol. 2015, 523, 211–230. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). Managing the Risks of Extreme Events and Disasters to Advance Climate Change Adaptation. A Special Report of Working Groups I and II of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change; Field, C.B., Barros, V., Stocker, T.F., Dahe, Q., Eds.; IPCC: Cambridge, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  5. Veldkamp, T.I.E.; Wada, Y.; de Moel, H.; Kummu, M.; Eisner, S.; Aerts, J.C.J.H.; Ward, P.J. Changing mechanism of global water scarcity events: Impacts of socioeconomic changes and inter-annual hydro-climatic variability. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2015, 32, 18–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Peterson, T.C.; Heim, R.R.; Hirsch, R.; Kaiser, D.P.; Brooks, H.; Diffenbaugh, N.S.; Dole, R.M.; Giovannettone, J.P.; Guirguis, K.; Karl, T.R.; et al. Monitoring and Understanding Changes in Heat Waves, Cold Waves, Floods, and Droughts in the United States: State of Knowledge. Bull. Am. Meteorol. Soc. 2013, 94, 821–834. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Chatrchyan, A.M.; Erlebacher, R.C.; Chaopricha, N.T.; Chan, J.; Tobin, D.; Allred, S.B. United States agricultural stakeholder views and decisions on climate change. Wiley Interdiscip. Rev. Clim. Chang. 2017, 8, e469. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Fischer, E.M.; Knutti, R. Observed heavy precipitation increase confirms theory and early models. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2016, 6, 986–991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. The U.S. Global Change Research Program (USGCRP). Climate Science Special Report: Fourth National Climate Assessment, Volume I; Wuebbles, D.J., Fahey, D.W., Hibbard, K.A., Dokken, B.C., Stewart, B.C., Maycock, T.K., Eds.; U.S. Global Change Research Program: Washington, DC, USA, 2017; p. 470.
  10. Calvino, P.; Monzon, J. Farming Systems of Argentina: Yield Constraints and Risk Management, Crop Physiology: Applications for Genetic Improvement and Agronomy; Elsevier Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  11. Merlos, F.A.; Monzon, J.P.; Mercau, J.L.; Taboada, M.; Andrade, F.H.; Hall, A.J.; Jobbagy, E.; Cassman, K.G.; Grassini, P. Potential for crop production increase in Argentina through closure of existing yield gaps. Field Crops Res. 2015, 184, 145–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Bert, F.E.; Podestá, G.P.; Rovere, S.L.; Menéndez, Á.N.; North, M.; Tatara, E.; Laciana, C.E.; Weber, E.; Toranzo, F.R. An agent based model to simulate structural and land use changes in agricultural systems of the Argentine pampas. Ecol. Model. 2011, 222, 3486–3499. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Qaim, M.; Traxler, G. Roundup Ready soybeans in Argentina: Farm level and aggregate welfare effects. Agric. Econ. 2005, 32, 73–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Magrin, G.O.; Travasso, M.I.; Rodríguez, G.R. Changes in Climate and Crop Production during the 20th Century in Argentina. Clim. Chang. 2005, 72, 229–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Pengue, W. Transgenic Crops in Argentina: The Ecological and Social Debt. Bull. Sci. Technol. Soc. 2005, 25, 314–322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Delvenne, P.; Vasen, F.; Vara, A.M. The “soy-ization” of Argentina: The dynamics of the “globalized” privatization regime in a peripheral context. Technol. Soc. 2013, 35, 153–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Arancibia, F. Challenging the bioeconomy: The dynamics of collective action in Argentina. Technol. Soc. 2013, 35, 79–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Salembier, C.; Elverdin, J.H.; Meynard, J.-M. Tracking on-farm innovations to unearth alternatives to the dominant soybean based system in the Argentinean Pampa. In Agronomy Sustainable Development; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2016; Volume 36. [Google Scholar]
  19. Urcola, H.A.; de Sartre, X.A.; Veiga, I., Jr.; Elverdin, J.; Albaladejo, C. Land tenancy, soybean, actors and transformations in the pampas: A district balance. J. Rural Stud. 2015, 39, 32–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Cerdeira, A.L.; Gazziero, D.L.P.; Duke, S.O.; Matallo, M.B. Agricultural Impacts of Glyphosate-Resistant Soybean Cultivation in South America. J. Agric. Food Chem. 2011, 59, 5799–5807. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  21. Filomeno, F.A. State capacity and intellectual property regimes: Lessons from South American soybean agriculture. Technol. Soc. 2013, 35, 139–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Leguizamón, A. Modifying Argentina: GM soy and socio-environmental change. Geoforum 2014, 53, 149–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Choumert, J.; Phélinas, P. Is GM Soybean Cultivation in Argentina Sustainable? CERDI Études et Documents; Bonjean, A., Ed.; Centre d’Études et de Recherches sur le Developpement International: Clermont Ferrand, France, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  24. García-López, G.A.; Arizpe, N. Participatory processes in the soy conflicts in Paraguay and Argentina. Ecol. Econ. 2010, 70, 196–206. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Bert, F.E.; Podestá, G.P.; Rovere, S.L.; North, M.; Menéndez, A.; Laciana, C.E.; Macal, C.M.; Weber, E.U.; Sydelko, P. Agent-Based Modelling of a Rental Market for Agricultural Land in the Argentine Pampas. In Proceedings of the 2010 International Congress on Environmental Modelling and Software, “Modelling for Environment’s Sake”, Ottawa, ON, Canada, 5–8 July 2010; Swayne, D.A., Yang, W., Voinov, A.A., Rizzoli, A., Filatova, T., Eds.; International Environmental Modelling and Software Society (iEMSs): Ottawa, ON, Canada, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  26. Gallacher, M. The Changing Structure of Production: Argentine Agriculture 1988–2002; Documento de Trabajo, Universidad del CEMA: Buenos Aires, Argentina, 2009; p. 24. [Google Scholar]
  27. Reboratti, C.E. Un mar de soja: La nueva agricultura en Argentina y sus consecuencias. Revista de Geografía Norte Grande 2010, 45, 63–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Arora, P.; Bert, F.; Podestá, G.; Krantz, D.H. Ownership effect in the wild: Influence of land ownership on agribusiness goals and decisions in the Argentine Pampas. J. Behav. Exp. Econ. 2015, 58, 162–170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Caviglia, O.P.; Andrade, F.H. Sustainable intensification of agriculture in the Argentine Pampas: Capture and use efficiency of environmental resources. Am. J. Plant Sci. Biotechnol. 2010, 3, 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  30. Choumert, J.; Phélinas, P. Determinants of agricultural land values in Argentina. Ecol. Econ. 2015, 110, 134–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Choumert, J.; Phélinas, P. Farmland Rental Values in GM Soybean Areas of Argentina: Do Contractual Arrangements Matter? Études et Documents; CERDI—Centre d’Etudes et de Recherches sur le Developpement International: Clermont-Ferrand, France, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  32. Senesi, S.I.; Palau, H.; Chaddad, F.R.; Daziano, M. The evolution of farming networks in a fragile institutional environment: The case of Argentina. J. Chain Netw. Sci. 2013, 13, 71–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Aragón, R.; Jobbágy, E.G.; Viglizzo, E.F. Surface and groundwater dynamics in the sedimentary plains of the Western Pampas (Argentina). Ecohydrology 2010, 4, 433–447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Murphy, K. The social pillar of sustainable development: A literature review and framework for policy analysis. Sustain. Sci. Pract. Policy 2012, 8, 15–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Hurley, T.M. A Review of Agricultural Production Risk in the Developing World; Harvest Choice: 2010. Available online: http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/record/188476?ln=en (accessed on 26 July 2018).
  36. Kahneman, D.; Tversky, A. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 1979, 47, 278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Bocquého, G.; Jacquet, F.; Reynaud, A. Expected utility or prospect theory maximisers? Assessing farmers’ risk behaviour from field-experiment data. Eur. Rev. Agric. Econ. 2013, 41, 135–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Cardenas, J.C.; Carpenter, J. Behavioural Development Economics: Lessons from Field Labs in the Developing World. J. Dev. Stud. 2008, 44, 311–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Tanaka, T.C.; Colin, F.; Nguyen, Q. Risk and Time Preferences: Linking Experimental and Household Survey Data from Vietnam. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 557–571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Camerer, C.F. Prospect Theory in the Wild: Evidence from the Field. In Choices, Values and Frames; Kahneman, D.T.A., Ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2000; pp. 288–300. [Google Scholar]
  41. Nguyen, Q.L.; Leung, P. Do Fishermen Have Different Attitudes Toward Risk? An Application of Prospect Theory to the Study of Vietnamese Fishermen. J. Agric. Resour. Econ. 2009, 34, 518–538. [Google Scholar]
  42. Wik, M.K.; Tewodros, A.; Bergland, O.; Holden, S.T. On the measurments of risk aversion from experimental data. Appl. Econ. 2004, 36, 2443–2451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Rosenzweig, M.R.B.; Hans, P. Wealth, Weather Risk and the Composition and Profitability of Agricultural Investments. Econ. J. 1993, 103, 56–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Yesuf, M. Risk, Time, and Land Management under Market Imperfections: Applications to Ethiopia; Goteborg University: Goteborg, Sweden, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  45. Liu, E.M. Time to Change What to Sow: Risk Preferences and Technology Adoption Decisions of Cotton Farmers in China. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2013, 95, 1386–1403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ryan, R.L.; Erickson, D.L.; De Young, R. Farmers’ motivations for adopting conservation practices along riparian zones in a midwestern watershed. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2003, 46, 19–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Fraser, E. Land tenure and agricultural management: Soil conservation on rented and owned fields in southwest British Columbia. Agric. Hum. Values 2004, 21, 73–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Tosakana, N.S.P.; Van Tassell, L.W.; Wulfhorst, J.D.; Boll, J.; Mahler, R.; Brooks, E.S.; Kane, S. Determinants of the adoption of conservation practices by farmers in the Northwest Wheat and Range Region. J. Soil Water Conserv. 2010, 65, 404–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Varble, S.; Secchi, S.; Druschke, C.G. An Examination of Growing Trends in Land Tenure and Conservation Practice Adoption: Results from a Farmer Survey in Iowa. Environ. Manag. 2016, 57, 318–330. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  50. Trope, Y.; Liberman, N. Construal-Level Theory of Psychological Distance. Psychol. Rev. 2010, 117, 440–463. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  51. Boyles, J.; Hanges, P.; Arora, P. Towards an Understanding of the Impact of Role-Congruence in Advisor Choices in Social Dilemmas. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the International Association for Conflict Management, Clearview, FL, USA, 28 June–1 July 2015. [Google Scholar]
  52. Kahneman, D.; Tversky, A. Choices, values, and frames. Am. Psychol. 1984, 39, 341. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Yamagishi, T.; Li, Y.; Takagishi, H.; Matsumoto, Y.; Kiyonari, T. In Search of Homo Economicus. Psychol. Sci. 2014, 25, 1699–1711. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  54. Chavas, J.P.; Chambers, R.G.; Pope, R.D. Production economics and farm management: A century of contributions. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2010, 92, 356–375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Wakker, P.P. Prospect Theory for Risk and Ambiguity; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  56. Orlove, B.; Taddei, R.; Podestá, G.; Broad, K. Environmental Citizenship in Latin America: Climate, Intermediate Organizations, and Political Subjects. Latin Am. Res. Rev. 2011, 46, 115–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Liberman, V.; Samuels, S.M.; Ross, L. The name of the game: Predictive power of reputations versus situational labels in determining prisoner’s dilemma game moves. Personal. Soc. Psychol. Bull. 2004, 30, 1175–1185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  58. Arora, P.; Peterson, N.D.; Krantz, D.H.; Hardisty, D.J.; Reddy, K.S. To cooperate or not to cooperate: Using new methodologies and frameworks to understand how affiliation influences cooperation in the present and future. J. Econ. Psychol. 2012, 33, 842–853. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Kaye, J.P.; Quemada, M. Using cover crops to mitigate and adapt to climate change. A review. In Agronomy for Sustainable Development; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2017; Volume 37. [Google Scholar]
  60. Slovic, P. The construction of preference. Am. Psychol. 1995, 50, 364–371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Bert, F.E.; Rovere, S.L.; Macal, C.M.; North, M.J.; Podestá, G.P. Lessons from a comprehensive validation of an agent based-model: The experience of the Pampas Model of Argentinean agricultural systems. Ecol. Model. 2014, 273, 284–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. This figure summarizes Exercise 1, which was presented to participants. Each participant was asked to choose a value of Z at which Option A is no longer preferred to Option B. Possible values for Z are: 1360, 1120, 1240, 1300, 1440, 1540, 1660, 1800, 2000, 2200 and 2600.
Figure 1. This figure summarizes Exercise 1, which was presented to participants. Each participant was asked to choose a value of Z at which Option A is no longer preferred to Option B. Possible values for Z are: 1360, 1120, 1240, 1300, 1440, 1540, 1660, 1800, 2000, 2200 and 2600.
Sustainability 10 02693 g001
Figure 2. This figure summarizes Exercise 2, which was presented to participants, and follows the same procedure as Exercise 1. Possible values for Z are: 1080, 1120, 1160, 1240, 1300, 1360, 1440, 1540, 1660, 1800, 2000, 2200 and 2600.
Figure 2. This figure summarizes Exercise 2, which was presented to participants, and follows the same procedure as Exercise 1. Possible values for Z are: 1080, 1120, 1160, 1240, 1300, 1360, 1440, 1540, 1660, 1800, 2000, 2200 and 2600.
Sustainability 10 02693 g002
Figure 3. This figure summarizes the Exercise 3, which was presented to participants, and follows the same procedure as Exercise 1. Possible values for Z are: 1050, 1100, 1200, 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700, 1800, 1900, 2000, 2100, 2500, 3000, 3500 and 4500.
Figure 3. This figure summarizes the Exercise 3, which was presented to participants, and follows the same procedure as Exercise 1. Possible values for Z are: 1050, 1100, 1200, 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700, 1800, 1900, 2000, 2100, 2500, 3000, 3500 and 4500.
Sustainability 10 02693 g003
Figure 4. Box plots comparing the distribution of PT parameter values between, from left to right within each panel, owners, owners & renters, and renters: (a) PT parameter α ; (b) PT parameter σ ; and (c) PT parameter λ .
Figure 4. Box plots comparing the distribution of PT parameter values between, from left to right within each panel, owners, owners & renters, and renters: (a) PT parameter α ; (b) PT parameter σ ; and (c) PT parameter λ .
Sustainability 10 02693 g004
Figure 5. Box plots comparing the distribution of PT parameter values between, from left to right within each panel, producers and advisors: (a) PT parameter α ; (b) PT parameter σ ; and (c) PT parameter λ .
Figure 5. Box plots comparing the distribution of PT parameter values between, from left to right within each panel, producers and advisors: (a) PT parameter α ; (b) PT parameter σ ; and (c) PT parameter λ .
Sustainability 10 02693 g005
Table 1. Summary Statistics of Prospect Theory (PT) Parameters.
Table 1. Summary Statistics of Prospect Theory (PT) Parameters.
ParameterMinMedianMeanMax
σ 0.10.60.61.3
α 0.10.60.71.4
λ 0.22.22.57.1
Table 2. Distribution of Owners and Renters.
Table 2. Distribution of Owners and Renters.
Owner OnlyOwner + RenterRenter Only
11716040
Table 3. Distribution of Producers versus Advisors.
Table 3. Distribution of Producers versus Advisors.
ProducersAdvisors
30635
Table 4. Summary of Results.
Table 4. Summary of Results.
HypothesisResults
Expected Utility Theory versus Prospect TheoryProspect theory better captures risk preferences among Argentine agribusiness decision makers, who are found to be loss averse and who overweigh (underweigh) small (large) probabilities.
Heterogeneity in Risk Preferences based on land tenure and agribusiness roleOwners only and Owners + Renters (Producers) are more loss averse than renters only (advisors).
Owners only and Owners + Renters overweigh (underweigh) more small (large) probabilities than renters only.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Gonzalez-Ramirez, J.; Arora, P.; Podesta, G. Using Insights from Prospect Theory to Enhance Sustainable Decision Making by Agribusinesses in Argentina. Sustainability 2018, 10, 2693. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082693

AMA Style

Gonzalez-Ramirez J, Arora P, Podesta G. Using Insights from Prospect Theory to Enhance Sustainable Decision Making by Agribusinesses in Argentina. Sustainability. 2018; 10(8):2693. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082693

Chicago/Turabian Style

Gonzalez-Ramirez, Jimena, Poonam Arora, and Guillermo Podesta. 2018. "Using Insights from Prospect Theory to Enhance Sustainable Decision Making by Agribusinesses in Argentina" Sustainability 10, no. 8: 2693. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082693

APA Style

Gonzalez-Ramirez, J., Arora, P., & Podesta, G. (2018). Using Insights from Prospect Theory to Enhance Sustainable Decision Making by Agribusinesses in Argentina. Sustainability, 10(8), 2693. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10082693

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop