Next Article in Journal
A Comparison of the Loading Direction for Bending Strength with Different Wood Measurement Surfaces Using Near-Infrared Spectroscopy
Previous Article in Journal
Natural Weathering of Bio-Based Façade Materials
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Estate-Level Economics of Carbon Storage and Sequestration

by
Petri P. Kärenlampi
1,2
1
Lehtoi Research, 81235 Lehtoi, Finland
2
School of Forestry, University of Eastern Finland, 80100 Joensuu, Finland
Forests 2020, 11(6), 643; https://doi.org/10.3390/f11060643
Submission received: 20 April 2020 / Revised: 25 May 2020 / Accepted: 30 May 2020 / Published: 5 June 2020
(This article belongs to the Section Forest Economics, Policy, and Social Science)

Abstract

:
The expense of carbon sequestration in terms of capital return deficiency is investigated at estate level, in the case of a fertile boreal estate dominated by spruce forest. Thinnings from below result as a high expense of increased rotation age, thinnings from above as a small expense. The expense of increased timber stock is greater than any proportional carbon rent based on present carbon prices. Application of nonproportional carbon rent is proposed.

1. Introduction

Boreal forests constitute a potentially significant carbon sink. A particular benefit of boreal regions is significant carbon storage in the soil. It has been approximated that the amount of soil carbon may exceed the carbon storage in living biomass [1,2,3,4]. However, living biomass produces the litter resulting in soil carbon accumulation. The rate of carbon storage depends on the rate of biomass production on the site. Biomass production rate, in turn, is related to the amount of living biomass [2,5,6,7].
In the occurrence of clearcutting and soil preparation, the net release of carbon from the soil to the atmosphere begins [8,9,10,11]. Correspondingly, maintenance of canopy cover possibly is essential in carbon sequestration.
Human activity related to the sequestration and release of carbon in the atmosphere forms a complex system of industries and disciplines [12,13,14,15,16]. Instead of trying to propose some kind of holistic, interdisciplinary optimum, we here discuss microeconomics of carbon sequestration in forestry, focusing on the estate level.
Within the business of forestry, a straightforward policy might appear as a carbon trade system, possibly administered by public agents [17]. An unbiased carbon trade, however, would incorporate a high initial expense [18]. Fortunately, it has been recently shown that a carbon rental system is equivalent to the carbon trade system, without much of an initial expense [18].
In general, the amount of productive biomass is not constant within any forest estate. The canopy cover is also not constant, but rather subject to change over time. A natural reason for the variation in time is that any estate has some variety of stand ages and stand biomass densities. The development of the state of any particular estate can be designed in terms of some sort of dynamic programming [19].
From the viewpoint of generic instructions, or policy actions, it might be beneficial to reduce the variety of initial estate states by adopting some kind of unifying boundary conditions. A tempting candidate is the normal forest principle [20]. This principle simply refers to postulating that stand ages are evenly distributed and stand characteristics are uniquely determined by stand age. Such a postulation, even if often departing from reality, simplifies many treatments significantly, producing idealized systems that are stationary in time.
Within the normal forest principle, quantities such as rotation age and average stand trunk volume per area unit become well defined, not only for a single stand but also on the estate level. Correspondingly, microeconomic discussion regarding such quantities becomes simplified. One can even state that the normal forest principle allows for determination of microeconomically optimal rotation age, as well as an expected value of stand volume.
Microeconomically optimal rotation age and expected value of stand volume are not necessarily optimal from the viewpoint of national economics, nor from the viewpoint of carbon sequestration. It has been recently shown that microeconomics often favors solutions with relatively low capitalization [19,21,22]. Low capitalization has adverse effects on volumetric growth rate, as well as litter accumulation rate [21,23].
In this paper, our primary interest is the microeconomics of carbon sequestration. We intend to clarify the economic consequences of increment of biomass density, as well as the extension of semiclosed canopy cover, on a real estate level. In terms of rotation forestry, the latter corresponds to extension of rotation age.
First, experimental materials are presented, as well as related computational methods. Then, microeconomic methods, as well as carbon rent formulae are introduced. Third, results are reported, separately for systems with thinnings from above and below. Finally, the outcome is discussed, and a functional carbon sequestration subsidy system is proposed.

2. Materials and Methods

2.1. Empirical Observations

Eleven circular plots of area 314 square meters were taken from typical spots of 11 spruce-dominated forest stands in November 2018 at Vihtari, Eastern Finland. Seven of the stands had experienced only young stand cleaning, whereas four of the stands were previously thinned commercially. Breast-height diameters were recorded, as well as tree species, and a quality class was visually determined for any measured tree.
On measured plots on sites without any previous commercial thinning, the basal area of tree trunks at breast height varied from 32 to 48 m2/ha, and stem count from 1655 to 2451 per hectare. On measured plots on stands previously thinned commercially, the basal area varied from 29 to 49 m2/ha, and the stem count from 891 to 955 per hectare. Further details of the experimental stands are reported in earlier papers [21].
The particular estate is characterized by measurements from the 11 sample plots. However, such a sample does not necessarily represent the entire estate accurately. More importantly, the sampling does not conform to the normal forest principle, with assumptions of constant age distribution and stand characteristics uniquely determined by stand age. In this study, we utilize the normal forest principle in terms of establishing a “normal stand” on the basis of the observations and then approximating the development of this “normal stand” as a function of stand age.
The normal stand is established on the bases of two never-thinned sample plots of medium site fertility and younger range of stand age, among the empirical observations. The two sample plots were combined into one experimental plot of area 628 square meters. Within the representative sample plot, the basal area of acceptable-quality trees was 35.3 m2/ha, and corresponding stem count 1401 per hectare. The age of the normal stand was 35 years, and dominating tree height 15 m. Measurement results used in the formulation of the normal stand are shown in the Supplementary Materials.

2.2. Growth Model

For prognostication of further development of the normal stand, some kind of growth model is needed. The growth model of Bollandsås et al. [21,22,24] is adopted, discussing not only growth but also mortality and recruitment. Trees are discussed in diameter classes of 50 mm, and each class is represented by its central tree. Growth is computationally implemented in terms of the probability of a tree to transfer to the next diameter class [21,22,24].
With breast-height diameters being measured for any sample plot, and diameter growth being approximated by the above-mentioned growth model, some kind of technique is needed for determining stem volumes. For any diameter class, the volumetric amount of two assortments, pulpwood and sawlogs, is clarified according to an appendix given by of Rämö and Tahvonen [25,26]. In order to discuss financial issues, value growth needs to be addressed, instead of only volumetric growth. The monetary value of the assortment volumes is taken as national stumpage prices from years 2000 to 2011, as given by Rämö and Tahvonen [25]. Bare land value of 600 Euros/ha is used, corresponding to local circumstances at the time of writing.
Description of stand development until the time of observation in 2018 requires another kind of approach. According to approximation by local professionals, the 2017 annual volume growth rate was 16 m3/ha. Using this growth rate, as well as the 2018 commercial volume estimate 256 m3/ha in an exponential growth function resulted as a stand volume history with a small but finite initial volume.
Possibly the simplest way to approximate financial history is to determine an internal rate of operative return for the period from stand establishment to 2018. In other words, we require
V ( τ 3 ) e s τ 3 R ( τ 1 ) e s τ 1 C ( τ 2 ) e s τ 2 = 0
where R is regeneration expense at regeneration time τ 1 , C is young stand cleaning expense at cleaning time τ 2 , and V is stumpage value of trees at observation time τ 3 . In this study, the observation time τ 3 corresponds to November 2018, regeneration time is clarified according to known stand age, and young stand cleaning is assumed to have occurred ten years after regeneration. It is assumed that prices and expenses do not evolve in real terms, and thus presently valid expenses can be used in Equation (1). The regeneration expense is taken as 1250 Eur/ha, and young stand cleaning 625 Eur/ha.
It is worth noting that the operative internal rate of return s in Equation (1) does not correspond to capital return rate in the entire activity, as the latter depends on nonoperative capitalization such as bare land value.

2.3. Financial Considerations

In order to determine a momentary capital return rate, we need to discuss the amount of financial resources occupied [21,23,27]. This is done in terms of a financial potential function, defined in terms of capitalization per unit area K. The momentary capital return rate becomes
r ( t ) = d κ K ( t ) d t
where κ in the numerator considers value growth, operative expenses, interests and amortizations, but neglects investments and withdrawals. In other words, it is the change of capitalization on an economic profit/loss basis. K in the denominator gives capitalization on a balance sheet basis, being directly affected by any investment or withdrawal. It is worth noting that timber sales do not enter the numerator of Equation (2): selling trees at market price levels does not change the amount of wealth, it only converts wealth from trees into the form of cash. However, harvesting naturally changes capitalization appearing in the denominator of Equation (2). Harvesting also likely changes the change rate of capitalization occurring after the harvest.
Equation (2) gives a momentary capital return rate, not necessarily sufficient for management considerations. By definition, the expected value capitalization per unit area is
K = p ( K ) K d K
where p ( K ) is the probability density function of capitalization K. By change of variables we get
K = 0 τ p ( K ) K d K d a d a = 0 τ p ( a ) K ( a ) d a
where a is stand age (or time elapsed since latest regeneration harvesting), and τ is rotation age. The expected value of the change rate of capitalization is
d κ d t = 0 τ p ( a ) d κ ( a ) d t d a
Correspondingly, the expected momentary rate of relative capital return is
r ( t ) = d κ d t K = 0 τ p ( a ) d κ ( a , t ) d t d a 0 τ p ( a ) K ( a , t ) d a = 0 τ p ( a ) K ( a , t ) r ( a , t ) d a 0 τ p ( a ) K ( a , t ) d a
We find from Equation (6) that the expected value of capital return rate within an estate generally evolves in time as the probability density of stand ages evolves. However, Equation (6) can be simplified to be independent of time by adopting the normal forest principle, where stand age probability density is constant [20]. Besides, constancy of the expected value of capital return rate in time requires that prices and expenses do not evolve in real terms. Then, the expected value of the capital return rate becomes
r = 0 τ d κ ( a ) d t d a 0 τ K ( a ) d a = 0 τ K ( a ) r ( a ) d a 0 τ K ( a ) d a
It has been recently shown that Equation (7) corresponds to the ratio of the partition functions of the change rate of capitalization and capitalization itself [28]. It also has been recently shown that the maximization of the net present value of future revenues may result in financially devastating consequences [29]. Momentary capital return rate as given in Equation (2) was introduced in 1860 [27]; an expected value was mentioned in 1967 [30,31], however applications have been introduced only recently [21,22,28,29].
High capital return rates are gained by an improvement harvesting including diameter-limit cutting to the transition diameter between pulpwood and sawlogs [21]. It is possible to retain a state of high capital return for decades, implementing further diameter-limit cuttings frequently, provided there is an abundant supply of pulpwood-size stems of an at least semi-shade-tolerant tree species [21]. In this investigation, however, the focus is in procedures inducing an increment of biomass density on the one hand, and extension of semiclosed canopy cover on the other hand. The former can simply be achieved by applying cutting diameter limits greater than the transition diameter between pulpwood and sawlogs.
In the context of the improvement harvesting, 20% of the stemcount of good-quality trees was removed in all diameter classes due to the establishment of striproads.
The stumpage value is determined in terms of roadside price, deduced by harvesting expense. We here use the roadside prices recently applied by Parkatti et al. [32], 34.04 Eur/m3 for spruce pulpwood, and 58.44 Eur/m3 for sawlogs. We further use the same harvest-expense function as Parkatti et al. [32], stated to be based on a productivity study of Nurminen et al. [33], however with one correction. Model parameter C5 value is taken as 2, instead of 1. With this correction, the expense function corresponds to present local circumstances, including the transfer expense of machinery. In addition to the expense function, we include a fixed harvesting entry expense per hectare. Justification of the latter is that some sites require at least partial pre-harvest cleaning. The entry expense is approximated as 200 Eur/ha. Again, is assumed that prices and expenses do not evolve in time. In other words, the capital return rate is discussed in real terms.
The growth model operates in five-year time steps [21,22,24], as discussed above. Consequently, an eventual harvesting entry may take place every five years. According to recent investigations, it often is favorable to harvest every five years [21]. However, the fixed harvesting entry cost of 200 Eur/ha restricts low-yield harvesting entries. Numerical investigations indicated that it is not reasonable to harvest if the yield would be less than 20–30 m2/ha. Such an entry limit is in concert with practices applied in the area. It is worth noting that the maximization of capital return rate within any five-year period does not lead to the maximization of the expected value of capital return rate. The reason is that provided the capital return rate is greater than the accumulated expected value, increased capitalization increases the expected value according to Equation (7).
In addition to high thinnings intended to maximize capital return rate [21,22,28,29], the consequences of following semi-official silvicultural guidance commonly applied in the area [34] are discussed. Thinnings are predominantly applied from below, and any rotation is terminated in clearcutting. Clearcutting expenses are lower than thinning harvesting costs, according to Parkatti et al. [32], stated to be based on a productivity study of Nurminen et al. [33]. In addition, a 15% clearcutting premium for the roadside price of sawlogs is applied, in accordance with local tradition.
Application of Equation (7) results as an expected value of capital return rate for any treatment schedule investigated. Treatment schedules not corresponding to the most economical one induce some amount of capital return rate deficiency, in terms of percentage per annum. Such deficiency is related either to the amount of timber stock deviating from the optimal timber stock, or the rotation age deviating from the optimal rotation age, or both. In the former case, the deficiency often is due to an excess standing volume, which allows for expressing the deficiency per excess volume unit.

2.4. Carbon Rent Considerations

The last issue in this section of methods regards carbon trade and carbon renting. It is worth noting that carbon prices or rents do not enter the analysis described above in any way. Carbon prices and rents are discussed in order to enable a comparison of the capital return deficiency per excess volume with any hypothetical carbon rent.
It has been recently shown that policies based on carbon rent are equivalent to policies based on carbon sequestration subsidies and taxies [18]. Unbiased carbon sequestration trade would require a huge initial investment; correspondingly mostly carbon rent procedures are practically feasible [18]. We will here present a brief derivation of the equivalency of the two principles of subsidies, however adopting boundary conditions possibly less restrictive than those of Lintunen et al. [18].
Let us establish a carbon sequestration subsidy system at a particular time τ1. Within a time range up to time τ2 the total carbon trade compensation is
p τ 1 C τ 1 + τ 1 τ 2 d ( p C ) d t d t = p τ 1 C τ 1 + τ 1 τ 2 [ p d C d t + C d p d t ] d t
where p t is carbon price at time t, and C t is carbon inventory at time t. On the other hand, the revenue from carbon rentals is
τ 1 τ 2 u C d t
where u is the rent rate per carbon unit. Now, in order to establish equivalency between the carbon storage trade and rent, Equations (8) and (9) must become equal. Equality naturally should apply in any possible circumstance. One of the circumstances is that the time change rate of prices, as well as inventories, is zero. In such a case, the latter term of Equation (8) vanishes. Consequently, long-term flow of carbon rents should equal a one-time initial storage purchase payment. If the duration of the rent payments extends towards infinity, the only possibility is that the present value of rent payments forms a contracting series. One possibility of such contracting series is
u τ 1 C τ 1 0 e q t d t = p τ 1 C τ 1
where q is a discount rate. The corresponding solution for the carbon rent rate is
u t = q p t
One can readily show that Equation (11) applies not only to a steady-state of Equations (8) and (9), but also to any incremental carbon price and inventory.

3. Results

3.1. Thinnings from Above

Thin markings in Figure 1 show the capital return rate according to Equation (2) for any five-year period after the improvement harvesting for three different cutting limit diameters. The lower is the cutting limit diameter, the higher is the capital return rate. Nonsmoothness of the curves is due to irregular harvesting: skipping harvesting at the end of any five-year period increases capital return rate due to missing harvesting entry expense. The absence of harvesting, however, reduces the capital return rate during the following five-year period due to greater capitalization.
Thick markings in Figure 1 show the expected value of capital return rate accumulated according to Equation (7). These curves appear rather flat: the expected value of capital return rate is not sensitive to rotation age, at least not after 70 years. We find that increasing the cutting limit diameter decreases the expected value of the capital return rate by 10% to 30%.
It is worth noting that in all the Figures below, the leftmost data point within any curve corresponds to quantities appearing during the first five-year period after observationss in November 2018.
Thin markings in Figure 2 show standing commercial trunk volume per hectare during any five-year period after the improvement harvesting. Differences are rather significant: diameter-limit cutting to the transition diameter between pulpwood and sawlogs reduces the stand volume rapidly, whereas a 100 mm larger cutting limit retains a high stand volume. The same goes for expected (average) values integrated over the stand age.
Figure 3 shows capitalization in Euros per hectare, thin markings for any five-year period, and thick markings for any accumulated expected value. The capitalization in Figure 3 shows many of the features as stand volume in Figure 2 does, however with one significant difference: expected values of capitalization are higher, in relation capitalizations within any five-year period. The reason for this difference is that regeneration expenses induce a significant initial capitalization on any stand, whereas initial stand volume is small. Amortization of regeneration and young stand cleaning expenses is done at the end of any rotation. It is worth noting that according to Equations (2) and (7), the change rate of capitalization can be produced by multiplying the data from Figure 1 and Figure 3.
Figure 4 shows that the net growth rates vary significantly depending on the cutting diameter limit. Diameter limit cutting to the transition diameter between pulpwood and sawlogs, resulting in a high capital return rate as shown in Figure 1, results as a small stand volume (Figure 2) and correspondingly a low volumetric growth rate (Figure 4). The growth rate also declines rapidly along with decreasing stand volume (Figure 2 and Figure 4). However, the volumetric growth rate in Figure 4 is less sensitive to cutting limit diameter than the stand volume in Figure 2 and capitalization in Figure 3.
Figure 1 showed that the greatest expected value of capital return rate is gained with a diameter limit cutting to the transition diameter between pulpwood and sawlogs. We also found that the capital return rate is not very sensitive to rotation age, but the maximum is reached at rotation age of 75 years. Greater cutting limit diameters induce capital return rate deficiency according to Figure 1. The deficiency also depends on rotation age. The deficiency is replotted in Figure 5. It is found that increment of standing volume by greater cutting diameter limit (Figure 2) induces a capital return rate deficiency that often is in excess of a percent unit (Figure 5). Doubling the expected value of stand volume would correspond to a roughly 25% reduction in the capital return rate (Figure 1, Figure 2, and Figure 5).
The capital return rate deficiency in terms of percentages (Figure 5) can be converted to Euros per hectare and year by multiplying by the capitalization appearing in Figure 3. The result is shown in Figure 6. It is found that the deficiency may be more than one hundred Euros per hectare and year. Doubling the standing volume (Figure 2) would induce a capital return deficiency in the order of 100 Euros per hectare and year (Figure 2 and Figure 6).
From the viewpoint of any carbon rent policy, or any other carbon sequestration policy, it is of interest to find that the capital return rate deficiency is due to any excess stand volume. First, the excess commercial stand volume in cubic meters per hectare is plotted in Figure 7. This plot actually is a more detailed analysis of the data appearing in Figure 2. The expected value of stand volume (Figure 2) corresponding to the maximum value of the expected capital return rate (Figure 1) is 80 m3/(ha*a). Figure 7 reveals that the excess stand volume achievable may be more than that.
The annual capital return rate deficiency per excess stand volume is shown in Figure 8. Figure 8 simply is the deficiency per hectare shown in Figure 6 divided by the excess volume per hectare shown in Figure 7. It is found that cutting diameter limit of 300 mm results as a deficiency in the order of 1.5 Eur/(excess m3*a). In the case of the lower cutting diameter limit of 250 mm, the deficiency depends strongly on rotation age. Figure displays also negative deficiencies. These are due to negative excess volumes, which are however not relevant from the viewpoint of carbon sequestration.

3.2. Thinnings from Below

The second set of treatment procedures correspond to thinnings from below. The treatments are implemented according to semiofficial silvicultural instructions applicable in the area [34]. Thinning entries are triggered by a given basal area of trees per hectare, and another value of the basal area is required after thinning. The limiting basal areas depend on the dominant height of trees. The first thinning from below, combined with quality thinning, as well as opening striproads, was conducted to basal area 21 m2/ha. The second thinning was implemented when the basal area exceeded 32 m2/ha, and it was conducted to basal area 25 m2/ha. The latter basal area limits were used for all further thinnings.
Figure 9 shows the capital return rate for the normal stand if thinned from below, thin markings for any five-year period, and thick markings for accumulated expected values. During the first five-year period the capital return rate is greater than the expected value; in later periods the expected value is greater, with one exception. A thinning at stand age 100 years is considered the last thinning feasible for the stand. According to local tradition there is a 15% premium in the price of sawlogs from clearcuttings. The high value of capital return rate is due to this price increment, along with lower harvesting expense in clearcutting. However the momentary peak has a small contribution to the expected value, which indicates a clearcutting possibly should occur at a rather young age. One must recognize that the last thinning, triggering the clearcutting price premium, as well as clearcutting harvesting expenses, would occur earlier with younger rotation ages. In the case of only one thinning, the capital return rate would be greater than shown in Figure 9, expected value at best 5.1% per annum at 40 years rotation age.
Figure 10 shows the development of stand volume per hectare; five-year average with thin markings, accumulated expected value with thick markings. The effect of thinnings is very clearly visible in the five-year average volume, unlike the expected value, and unlike the capital return rate in Figure 9.
Figure 11 shows the development of capitalization per hectare; five-year average with thin markings, accumulated expected value with thick markings. Again, there are similarities between Figure 10 and Figure 11. However, the capitalization in Figure 11 is less sensitive to thinning from below than the stand volume in Figure 10. There is a similar difference as between Figure 2 and Figure 3: expected values of capitalization are higher, in relation capitalizations within any five-year period, due to capitalization induced by regeneration expenses. It is also worth noting that there is hardly any net growth after the age of 105 years in Figure 10, whereas capitalization increases to 110 years in Figure 11.
Figure 12 shows the net growth per hectare, five-year average with thin markings, accumulated expected value with thick markings. After the first thinning from below, the growth rate is greater than after improvement harvesting to the transition limit of pulpwood and sawlogs, but smaller than after gentle thinnings from above (cf. Figure 4). In Figure 12, the expected value of net annual growth reaches a weak maximum at the age of 50 years.
The expected capital return rate deficiency increases with rotation age (Figure 13). It appears in Figure 13 that there would be a short-term decrement at the age of 100 years. Again, with younger rotation ages, the last thinning resulting as the clearcutting premium in sawlog prices and reduction in harvesting expenses would occur earlier. In comparison to Figure 5, the capital return rate deficiency is only slightly higher below the rotation age of 50 years, but then increases in a roughly proportional manner to stand age.
The capital return rate deficiency in terms of Euros per hectare and year also increases monotonically, considering the variable timing of the last thinning inducing the transition to clearcutting sawlog prices and harvesting expenses (Figure 14). In comparison to Figure 6, the capital return rate deficiency again is only slightly higher below the stand age of 50 years, but then strongly increases.
The expected excess commercial volume, in comparison to that providing the greatest capital return rate in Figure 1, is shown as a function of rotation age in Figure 15. Unlike in the case of thinnings from above (Figure 6), it increases monotonically.
The annual capital return rate deficiency per excess stand volume is shown in Figure 16. At rotation ages up to 50 years, the deficiency appears to decrease. That situation, however, would change if clearcutting price premium, as well as clearcutting harvesting expenses, would be applied right after the first thinning. Along with increasing rotation age, the capital return deficiency per excess volume increases. In comparison to Figure 8, the deficiencies are higher with thinnings from below, particularly with high rotation age.

4. Discussion

Issues related to increment of biomass density on the one hand, and extension of semiclosed canopy cover on the other hand, have been discussed at the estate level, with application to fertile boreal spruce estates.
Extending rotations induces a large capital return rate deficiency if thinnings from below are applied (Figure 9 and Figure 16). With thinnings from above, the capital return rate is insensitive to rotation age (Figure 1). However, intensive thinning from above tends to reduce the amount of living biomass, and correspondingly capital return rate deficiency per standing cubic meter may depend on rotation age (Figure 8).
Manipulation of biomass density is possible even if the rotation age is not manipulated. The possibilities for this are particularly pronounced if thinnings are done from above (Figure 2). It is possible to double the density of living biomass, in comparison to the financially optimal treatment schedule (Figure 2), and consequently, growth rate is increased (Figure 4). However, another consequence is the deficiency in the capital return rate (Figure 1 and Figure 5).
It is possible to allocate the capital return rate deficiency to the excess value of commercial stand volume. With prices applicable at the time of writing, the deficiency per excess volume is in the order of 1.5 Euros per excess standing cubicmeter, if the biomass density is doubled (Figure 8). With smaller excess volume, the specific deficiency is less (Figure 2 and Figure 8).
An applicable carbon rent can be derived from carbon storage market price according to Equation (11). At the time of writing, the market price of carbon dioxide emissions is in the order of 25 Euros per ton. This inserted to Equation (11) together with a 3% discount rate, often applied in Forestry [35,36,37], results as an annual carbon rent of 0.75 Euros per ton of carbon dioxide.
In coarse terms, a cubicmeter of commercial trunk volume in boreal forest stores a ton of carbon dioxide (in living biomass, litter, and soil) [1,2,4,7,38,39]. Correspondingly, considering the prices valid at the time of writing, one might reasonably expect a carbon rent of 0.75 Euros per standing cubicmeter. In comparison to Figure 8, that is not enough. The deficiency of capital return rate per standing cubicmeter is greater than an appropriate rent. The situation will naturally change if the market price of carbon dioxide emissions changes.
It has recently been shown that a carbon sequestration trade policy is equivalent to a carbon rent policy [18]. The same treatment, abbreviated and with somewhat less restrictive boundary conditions, is given in Equations (8) to (11) of this paper. There are reasons why any carbon sequestration trade compensation must be proportional to the carbon storage on the estate level [18]. If it would not be, agents with large carbon inventories initially would suffer heavy and unjustified release taxes. Applying the Equivalency of Equation (10) would thus indicate that also the carbon rent arrangement would be proportional to the total carbon inventory.
As mentioned above, the carbon rent derived from the present carbon dioxide market price (Equation (11)) is not enough to compensate for the capital return deficiency due to increased biomass density. However, there is no particular reason why the carbon rent should be proportional (unlike the carbon trade). If the carbon rent is made nonproportional, the marginal rent may reasonably exceed the capital return rate deficiency.
All the quantitative results in this paper are estate-specific. It is of interest to consider how they would change if the properties of the estate would change. Changing soil fertility, as well as changing temperature sum, would change the values of all time derivatives. Correspondingly, capital return rates, as well as annual capital return deficiencies would change. Greater fertility would result in greater change rates with respect to time and vice versa. Effect of adopting other dominating tree species but Norway spruce on the estate is somewhat more difficult to estimate.
It has recently been proposed that on a national level, sites of low fertility and regions of cool climate are most suitable for carbon sequestration, while regions with high production capacity are best suitable for wood raw material supply [17]. Consequently one might think that carbon rent derived from present emission prices not being enough to compensate for capital return deficiency on a fertile spruce estate would not necessarily be very detrimental. However, maximizing capital return rate results as low capitalization, and correspondingly as reduced growth (Figure 1, Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4), which in turn reduces timber supply. Any carbon sequestration subsidy would increase capitalization, growth, and timber supply.
Many of the quantitative results in this paper depend on the market prices of roundwood assortments, bare land, silvicultural and harvesting expenses, carbon emission, as well as the discount rate applied in Equations (10) and (11). Considering eventual changes in the latter two is straightforward in terms of Equations (10) and (11). Changes in the former quantities contribute in a trivial manner if they are proportional. In the case of significant nonproportional changes in prices, most of the Figures of this paper will have to be redrawn.
The growth model applied in this study discusses stem sizes in 50 mm intervals [24]. The main transition of assortments from pulpwood to sawlogs happens in the diameter class from 200 to 250 mm [25,26]. Correspondingly, computations implemented in this paper assume cutting limit diameters 200, 250, and 300 mm. It is not self-evident that the cutting diameter limit best corresponding to the assortment transition is 200 mm. Considering eventual defects in trees, as well as some degree of asymmetry in geometry, a representative diameter limit for utilizing the transition may be greater than 200 mm; 220 mm is used by some practitioners. If the latter cutting diameter limit would be used, nondimensionless quantities, along with their time derivatives, would be subject to change.
The capital return rate in Figure 1 and Figure 9 is a dimensionless quantity, not affected by size-scaling. A fourth pair of curves could be drawn in Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4. The capital return rate deficiency in Figure 5 and Figure 11 is the time derivative of a dimensionless quantity. Figure 6 and Figure 11 might be only slightly affected, provided assortment estimation in [25,26] holds. The excess values stand volume in Figure 7 and Figure 13 would be reduced, as the base of comparison (in terms of financially optimal stand volume) would be greater. The capital return rate deficiency per excess volume in Figure 8 and Figure 16 would be greater, as the excess volume would be reduced.
It might be of interest to try to relate the present results with previous approaches with a focus to large-scale systems. Some investigations claim benefits of intensive forestry with significant harvesting, considering the displacement of nonforest products with forest products [12,13]. Other investigators claim displacement factors are not large enough, and consequently minimized harvesting, resulting as large carbon stocks in forests, should be favored [15,16]. The present results happen to be in concert with both views. Maximization of capital return rate results in small carbon inventory, as well as a smallish rate of wood production. Carbon stocking, as well as growth rate, can be increased at the expense of capital return deficiency (Figure 2, Figure 4, and Figure 5).

5. Conclusions

Extending rotations induces a large capital return rate deficiency if thinnings from below are applied. With thinnings from above, the capital return rate is insensitive to rotation age.
Manipulation of biomass density is possible even if the rotation age is not manipulated. Maximization of capital return rate results in small carbon inventory, as well as a smallish rate of wood production. Carbon stocking, as well as growth rate, can be increased at the expense of a capital return rate deficiency.
It is possible to allocate the capital return rate deficiency to the excess value of commercial stand volume. However, the deficiency of capital return rate per standing cubicmeter is greater than any appropriate proportional rent, based on present carbon prices. The situation will naturally change if the market price of carbon dioxide emissions changes.
As any proportional the carbon rent derived from the present carbon dioxide market price is not enough to compensate for the capital return rate deficiency, a nonproportional carbon rent is proposed.

Supplementary Materials

The following are available online at https://www.mdpi.com/1999-4907/11/6/643/s1.

Funding

This research was partially funded by Niemi Foundation.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Adams, A.; Harrison, R.; Sletten, R.; Strahm, B.; Turnblom, E.; Jensen, C. Nitrogen-fertilization impacts on carbon sequestration and flux in managed coastal Douglas-fir stands of the Pacific Northwest. For. Ecol. Manag. 2005, 220, 313–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Lal, R. Forest soils and carbon sequestration. For. Ecol. Manag. 2005, 220, 242–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Liskia, J.; Lehtonen, A.; Palosuo, T.; Peltoniemi, M.; Eggersa, T.; Muukkonen, P.; Mäkipää, R. Carbon accumulation in Finland’s forests 1922-2004-an estimate obtained by combination of forest inventory data with modelling of biomass, litter and soil. Ann. For. Sci. 2006, 63, 687–697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Peltoniemi, M.; Mäkipää, R.; Liski, J.; Tamminen, P. Changes in soil carbon with stand age—an evaluation of a modelling method with empirical data. Glob. Chang. Biol. 2004, 10, 2078–2091. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Campioli, M.; Vicca, S.; Luyssaert, S.; Bilcke, J.; Ceschia, E.; Iii, F.S.C.; Ciais, P.; Fernández-Martínez, M.; Malhi, Y.; Obersteiner, M.; et al. Biomass production efficiency controlled by management in temperate and boreal ecosystems. Nat. Geosci. 2015, 8, 843–846. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Powers, M.; Kolka, R.; Palik, B.J.; McDonald, R.; Jurgensen, M. Long-term management impacts on carbon storage in Lake States forests. For. Ecol. Manag. 2011, 262, 424–431. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Thornley, J.H.M.; Cannell, M.G.R. Managing forests for wood yield and carbon storage: A theoretical study. Tree Physiol. 2000, 20, 477–484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Karhu, K.; Wall, A.; Vanhala, P.; Liski, J.; Esala, M.; Karhu, K. Effects of afforestation and deforestation on boreal soil carbon stocks—Comparison of measured C stocks with Yasso07 model results. Geoderma 2011, 164, 33–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Liski, J.; Palosuo, T.; Peltoniemi, M.; Sievänen, R. Carbon and decomposition model Yasso for forest soils. Ecol. Model. 2005, 189, 168–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Rantakari, M.; Lehtonen, A.; Linkosalo, T.; Tuomi, M.; Tamminen, P.; Heikkinen, J.; Liski, J.; Mäkipää, R.; Ilvesniemi, H.; Sievänen, R. The Yasso07 soil carbon model–Testing against repeated soil carbon inventory. For. Ecol. Manag. 2012, 286, 137–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Tupek, B.; Launiainen, S.; Peltoniemi, M.; Sievänen, R.; Perttunen, J.; Kulmala, L.; Penttilä, T.; Lindroos, A.; Hashimoto, S.; Lehtonen, A. Evaluating CENTURY and Yasso soil carbon models for CO2 emissions and organic carbon stocks of boreal forest soil with Bayesian multi-model inference. Eur. J. Soil Sci. 2019, 70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Gustavsson, L.; Haus, S.; Lundblad, M.; Lundström, A.; Ortiz, C.A.; Sathre, R.; Truong, N.; Wikberg, P.-E. Climate change effects of forestry and substitution of carbon-intensive materials and fossil fuels. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 67, 612–624. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Van Kooten, G.C.; Bogle, T.N.; De Vries, F.P. Forest Carbon Offsets Revisited: Shedding Light on Darkwoods. For. Sci. 2015, 61, 370–380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Van Kooten, G.C.; Johnston, C.M.T. The Economics of Forest Carbon Offsets. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2016, 8, 227–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Pukkala, T. Carbon forestry is surprising. For. Ecosyst. 2018, 5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Seppälä, J.; Heinonen, T.; Pukkala, T.; Kilpeläinen, A.; Mattila, T.; Myllyviita, T.; Asikainen, A.; Peltola, H. Effect of increased wood harvesting and utilization on required greenhouse gas displacement factors of wood-based products and fuels. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 247, 580–587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  17. Pukkala, T. At what carbon price forest cutting should stop. J. For. Res. 2020, 31, 713–727. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Lintunen, J.; Laturi, J.; Uusivuori, J. How should a forest carbon rent policy be implemented? For. Policy Econ. 2016, 69, 31–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Kilkki, P.; Väisänen, U. Determination of the optimum cutting policy for the forest stand by means of dynamic programming. Acta For. Fenn. 1969, 102, 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Leslie, A.J. A Review of the Concept of the Normal Forest. Aust. For. 1966, 30, 139–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Kärenlampi, P.P. Harvesting Design by Capital Return. Forests 2019, 10, 283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Kärenlampi, P.P. The effect of capitalization on financial return in periodic growth. Heliyon 2019, 5, e02728. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  23. Kärenlampi, P.P. Stationary Forestry with Human Interference. Sustainabiliy 2018, 10, 3662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Bollandsås, O.M.; Buongiorno, J.; Gobakken, T. Predicting the growth of stands of trees of mixed species and size: A matrix model for Norway. Scand. J. For. Res. 2008, 23, 167–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Rämö, J.; Tahvonen, O. Economics of harvesting boreal uneven-aged mixed-species forests. Can. J. For. Res. 2015, 45, 1102–1112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Heinonen, J. Koealojen puu-ja puustotunnusten laskentaohjelma KPL. In Käyttöohje (Software for Computing Tree and Stand Characteristics for Sample Plots. User’s Manual); Research Reports; Finnish Forest Research Institute: Vantaa, Finland, 1994. (In Finnish) [Google Scholar]
  27. Pressler, M.R. Aus der Holzzuwachlehre (zweiter Artikel). Allgemeine Forst und Jagd Zeitung 1860, 36, 173–191, Translated by W. Löwenstein and J.R. Wirkner as “For the comprehension of net revenue silviculture and the management objectives derived thereof”. J. Forest Econ. 1995, 1, 45–87. [Google Scholar]
  28. Kärenlampi, P.P. State-space approach to capital return in nonlinear growth processes. Agric. Finance Rev. 2019, 79, 508–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Kärenlampi, P.P. Wealth accumulation in rotation forestry–Failure of the net present value optimization? PLoS ONE 2019, 14, e0222918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Speidel, G. Forstliche Betreibswirtschaftslehre, 2nd ed.; Verlag Paul Parey: Hamburg, Germany, 1967; 226p. (In German) [Google Scholar]
  31. Speidel, G. Planung in Forstbetrieb, 2nd ed.; Verlag Paul Parey: Hamburg, Germany, 1972; 270p. (In German) [Google Scholar]
  32. Parkatti, V.-P.; Assmuth, A.; Rämö, J.; Tahvonen, O. Economics of boreal conifer species in continuous cover and rotation forestry. For. Policy Econ. 2019, 100, 55–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Nurminen, T.; Korpunen, H.; Uusitalo, J. Time consuming analysis of the mechanized cut-to-length harvesting system. Silva Fenn. 2006, 40, 335–363. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Äijälä, O.; Koistinen, A.; Sved, J.; Vanhatalo, K.; Väisänen, P. (Eds.) Metsänhoidon Suositukset. Tapion Julkaisuja. 2019. Available online: https://www.metsanhoitosuositukset.fi/wp-content/uploads/2019/06/Metsanhoidon_suositukset_Tapio_2019.pdf (accessed on 15 May 2020).
  35. Pukkala, T. Plenterwald, Dauerwald, or clearcut? For. Policy Econ. 2016, 62, 125–134. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Pyy, J.; Ahtikoski, A.; Laitinen, E.; Siipilehto, J. Introducing a Non-Stationary Matrix Model for Stand-Level Optimization, an Even-Aged Pine (Pinus sylvestris L.) Stand in Finland. Forests 2017, 8, 163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Sinha, A.; Rämö, J.; Malo, P.; Kallio, M.; Tahvonen, O. Optimal management of naturally regenerating uneven-aged forests. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 256, 886–900. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Petersson, H.; Holm, S.; Ståhl, G.; Alger, D.; Fridman, J.; Lehtonen, A.; Lundström, A.; Mäkipää, R. Individual tree biomass equations or biomass expansion factors for assessment of carbon stock changes in living biomass–A comparative study. For. Ecol. Manag. 2012, 270, 78–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Schepashenko, D.; Shvidenko, A.; Usoltsev, V.; Lakyda, P.; Luo, Y.; Vasylyshyn, R.; Lakyda, I.; Myklush, Y.; See, L.; McCallum, I.; et al. A dataset of forest biomass structure for Eurasia. Sci. Data 2017, 4, 170070. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Annual capital return rate (thin markings) and expected value accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 1. Annual capital return rate (thin markings) and expected value accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g001
Figure 2. Commercial stem volume per hectare (thin markings) and expected value accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 2. Commercial stem volume per hectare (thin markings) and expected value accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g002
Figure 3. Capitalization per hectare (thin markings) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 3. Capitalization per hectare (thin markings) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g003
Figure 4. Net growth rate per year and hectare (thin markings) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 4. Net growth rate per year and hectare (thin markings) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick markings) for three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g004
Figure 5. Capital return rate deficiency in percentage/year, for different rotation ages and three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 5. Capital return rate deficiency in percentage/year, for different rotation ages and three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g005
Figure 6. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per hectare and year, for different rotation ages and three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 6. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per hectare and year, for different rotation ages and three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g006
Figure 7. Excess commercial stem volume per hectare, in comparison to the treatment schedule corresponding to the greatest expected value of capital return rate. The three curves correspond to three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 7. Excess commercial stem volume per hectare, in comparison to the treatment schedule corresponding to the greatest expected value of capital return rate. The three curves correspond to three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g007
Figure 8. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per excess commercial volume and year, for different rotation ages and three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Figure 8. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per excess commercial volume and year, for different rotation ages and three different cutting diameter limits (200 mm, 250 mm, and 300 mm).
Forests 11 00643 g008
Figure 9. Capital return rate per year (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Figure 9. Capital return rate per year (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Forests 11 00643 g009
Figure 10. Commercial volume per hectare (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Figure 10. Commercial volume per hectare (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Forests 11 00643 g010
Figure 11. Capitalization per hectare (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Figure 11. Capitalization per hectare (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Forests 11 00643 g011
Figure 12. Net growth rate per year and hectare (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Figure 12. Net growth rate per year and hectare (thin drawing) and expected values accumulated over stand age (thick drawing), with thinnings from below.
Forests 11 00643 g012
Figure 13. Capital return rate deficiency in percentage per year, with thinnings from below.
Figure 13. Capital return rate deficiency in percentage per year, with thinnings from below.
Forests 11 00643 g013
Figure 14. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per hectare and year, with thinnings from below.
Figure 14. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per hectare and year, with thinnings from below.
Forests 11 00643 g014
Figure 15. Excess commercial volume per hectare with thinnings from below, in comparison to the treatment schedule corresponding the greatest expected value of capital return rate.
Figure 15. Excess commercial volume per hectare with thinnings from below, in comparison to the treatment schedule corresponding the greatest expected value of capital return rate.
Forests 11 00643 g015
Figure 16. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per excess commercial volume and year with thinnings from below, in comparison to the treatment schedule corresponding to the greatest expected value of capital return rate.
Figure 16. Capital return rate deficiency in Euros per excess commercial volume and year with thinnings from below, in comparison to the treatment schedule corresponding to the greatest expected value of capital return rate.
Forests 11 00643 g016

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kärenlampi, P.P. Estate-Level Economics of Carbon Storage and Sequestration. Forests 2020, 11, 643. https://doi.org/10.3390/f11060643

AMA Style

Kärenlampi PP. Estate-Level Economics of Carbon Storage and Sequestration. Forests. 2020; 11(6):643. https://doi.org/10.3390/f11060643

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kärenlampi, Petri P. 2020. "Estate-Level Economics of Carbon Storage and Sequestration" Forests 11, no. 6: 643. https://doi.org/10.3390/f11060643

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop