Next Article in Journal
Deep Learning-Based Transformer Moisture Diagnostics Using Long Short-Term Memory Networks
Next Article in Special Issue
Electricity Prices in the European Union Region: The Role of Renewable Energy Sources, Key Economic Factors and Market Liberalization
Previous Article in Journal
The Maximum Power Point Tracking (MPPT) of a Partially Shaded PV Array for Optimization Using the Antlion Algorithm
Previous Article in Special Issue
Hospitals’ Energy Efficiency in the Perspective of Saving Resources and Providing Quality Services through Technological Options: A Systematic Literature Review
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Review

Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy: Comprehensive Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Review

by
Muhammad Mushafiq
1,
Muzammil Muhammad Khan Arisar
2,
Hanan Tariq
3 and
Stanislaw Czapp
3,*
1
Faculty of Management and Economics, Gdansk University of Technology, Narutowicza 11/12, 80-233 Gdansk, Poland
2
School of Economics and Management, Beijing University of Posts and Telecommunications, Beijing 100876, China
3
Faculty of Electrical and Control Engineering, Gdansk University of Technology, Narutowicza 11/12, 80-233 Gdansk, Poland
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2023, 16(5), 2381; https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052381
Submission received: 10 February 2023 / Revised: 24 February 2023 / Accepted: 28 February 2023 / Published: 2 March 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Emerging Trends in Energy Economics II)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we analyze the role of economic policy in prompting energy efficiency. This study reviews three aspects, theoretical, empirical, and existing policies to evaluate the relationship of energy efficiency and economic policy. This study furthermore identifies the existing issues from a policy perspective in energy efficiency. Although not all public policies may be justified, it suggests that these types of financial incentives, particularly those based on economic instruments, can play a crucial role in advancing energy efficiency. Additionally, this study identifies existing issues in energy efficiency target achievement and proposes solutions based on the literature review. Finally, it provides possible future research pathways from the aspect of economic policy tools in energy efficiency.

1. Introduction

Reduced energy consumption and emissions of greenhouse gases are the results of increased energy efficiency [1,2]. Additionally, energy efficiency measures can also promote energy equity by improving the accessibility and affordability of energy services for low-income and marginalized communities, leading to positive economic outcomes [3,4]. The growing knowledge of the effects of energy use and greenhouse gas emissions on the environment and human health has elevated the significance of these issues in recent years [2]. Increasing energy efficiency can be accomplished in several ways, for instance, through the adoption of more effective technology, the modification of existing building designs, and individual behavioral shifts. Energy efficiency is crucial since it has been shown to cut costs, decrease emissions of greenhouse gases, and improve environmental conditions [5,6]. Energy efficiency lessens demands for fossil fuels and the emissions that come with them by cutting energy consumption. It also aids in the preservation of finite and more expensive to extract natural resources such as coal, oil, and natural gas [7,8]. Energy efficiency can also lead to lower energy bills; boosting people’s disposable pay in this way can boost the economy and lead to more job opportunities. Public health can also benefit from energy efficiency since it lessens the need for energy infrastructure such as power plants and transmission lines, which in turn reduces air pollution.
Incentives for and impediments to energy-efficient behavior and investment are provided by economic policy, which plays a crucial role in encouraging energy efficiency [9,10]. Energy-efficient technology, building designs, and lifestyles can all be pushed forward with the help of government policy. Tax breaks for energy-efficient products and subsidies for renewable energy sources are two examples of the kinds of economic policies that can be used to discourage the adoption of inefficient technologies [11].
Consumers are encouraged to buy energy-efficient products due to tax credits which reduce the price of these products [12]. Greater output and decreased pricing result from increased demand for energy-efficient goods [13]. The resulting increased demand further drives the price down, creating a self-sustaining cycle. Subsidies for renewable energy sources such as wind, solar, and hydropower are another example of a policy that helps to improve energy efficiency [14]. These subsidies lower the price of renewable energy technology by helping to fund its research, development, and eventual commercialization. By decreasing the reliance on fossil fuels, cutting down on harmful emissions leads to improved energy security [15,16,17].
Policy initiatives aimed at improving energy efficiency may also contribute to a more prosperous economy [18,19]. Production and installation of energy-efficient items are two examples of how energy efficiency regulations can generate employment opportunities [20]. Reducing energy expenses and increasing the allure of a company to potential investors are two ways in which energy efficiency can boost competitiveness [21,22]. Furthermore, energy efficiency policies can inspire innovation by supporting the study and development of cutting-edge energy-saving devices. Economic policy has a significant influence on fostering energy efficiency. Energy consumption and greenhouse gas emissions can be lowered with the support of economic policies that incentivize or discourage actions and investments to promote efficient use of energy. Energy efficiency regulations not only help save resources, but they also have the potential to deliver economic benefits such as reduced energy prices, enhanced competitiveness, and new employment opportunities [23,24,25].
The relationship between a prosperous economy and low energy consumption goes both ways. Energy efficiency is pushed by economic policies, and in turn, energy efficiency can help economic growth and development in a number of ways [26]. Improving energy efficiency has the potential to cut costs, boost competitiveness, and create new jobs. Gains in gross domestic product (GDP), energy intensity, and worker productivity are a few measures of the economic growth that would result from these measures’ implementation as presented in Figure 1.
First, a rise in GDP is just one potential outcome of improved energy efficiency. Bringing down energy prices is one way to make firms more competitive, which in turn can boost investment and economic activity. That can boost the economy and help more people find jobs. Second, improved energy efficiency can lessen energy intensity, or the amount of energy consumed per dollar of GDP. Lower energy costs for firms and people can boost competitiveness and economic activity if energy intensity is reduced. As a result, this may lead to expanded job opportunities and a healthier economy. Third, a boost in energy efficiency can improve productivity in the workplace. The reason for this is because by using energy-efficient technologies and practices, manufacturing efficiency can be increased, hence decreasing the amount of energy needed to create a given quantity of output. As a result, the economy may become more competitive, see decreased prices, and experience a surge in activity.
By providing incentives for energy-efficient behavior and investment, economic policies play a substantial role in increasing energy efficiency. Numerous economic measures, including subsidies, tax incentives, and market-based processes, are widely employed to encourage energy efficiency. With the increased need for energy efficiency, the previous literature reviews have only focused on the tools or economic outcomes of energy efficiency [27,28,29]. Therefore, the novelty of this paper lies with the aspect that it evaluates the literature from the point of view of driving economic factors. The objective and methodological novelties of this paper overlay each other as it explores the theoretical, empirical, and policy research available on the aspects of subsidies, tax incentives, and market-based mechanisms, and the contribution of the study is establishing the state of the art and proposing directions for future research.
Figure 2 further elaborates the contribution of the study and explains path of this study. This study evaluates the existing issues in the energy efficiency implementation in the following section; then, Section 3, Section 4 and Section 5 evaluate the conceptual, empirical, and policy work in the literature of policy instrument subsidies, tax incentives, and market-based mechanisms. Part 6 concludes the article with policy solutions for increasing energy efficiency based on the policy instruments discussed in Section 3, Section 4 and Section 5. Section 7 discusses all possible research avenues on the specific aspects of discussed policy instruments and energy efficiency and new broader research avenues for energy efficiency and economics.

2. Energy Efficiency; State-of-the-Art, Issues, and Case of EU-27 2030

In the realm of energy management, the terms energy efficiency and energy conservation are closely intertwined yet conceptually distinct. Energy efficiency pertains to the optimal utilization of energy to achieve the same level of output while consuming lesser energy [30,31]. This goal can be achieved by implementing improved technologies, refining processes, and enhancing building or product designs. The primary objective of energy efficiency is to decrease energy usage while maintaining the same level of output. On the other hand, energy conservation aims to reduce energy consumption by altering daily habits and behaviors [32,33]. The purpose of energy conservation is to decrease overall energy consumption, which preserves natural resources and reduces carbon emissions.
According to the Paris Climate Agreement, the European Union has committed to increasing energy efficiency by at least 32.5% by the year 2030 [34,35,36,37]. Countries throughout the world joined the Paris Agreement in 2015 to work toward keeping global warming well below 2 degrees Celsius above pre-industrial levels [38,39]. Greenhouse gas emissions from energy consumption are one of the main sources of emissions worldwide; therefore, increasing energy efficiency is viewed as essential to reach these goals. In addition to lowering emissions and saving money, increasing energy efficiency may also strengthen energy security [40,41]. As the energy efficiency sector continues to expand, it may help reduce reliance on fossil fuels, boost business competitiveness, and generate new employment opportunities [42]. However, there are still issues existing in increasing energy efficiency, as elaborated in Table 1, and economic policy plays a vital role in the solution of these issues.
One of the major aims of improving energy efficiency is to reduce energy consumption. Lower energy expenditures, fewer emissions, and better sustainability are the results of switching to a more energy-efficient system or equipment [56]. Examples given in Figure 3 and Figure 4 show the primary and final energy consumption with regards to the target set for 2030, respectively; based on the example, it is evident that the enhancement of energy efficiency constitutes a potent lever to achieve the energy consumption targets that contemporary societies face.
Energy efficiency and consumption reduction are two areas where economic policy makes a significant difference. The government can help businesses and individuals save money and reduce their carbon footprint by enacting policies such as tax credits, subsidies, and market-based mechanisms that support the use of more energy-efficient products and methods. This study examines each of these policy measures in depth in Section 4, Section 5 and Section 6.

3. Statistical Research Trends

Before exploring the policy instruments in the area of energy efficiency, this study explores the existing trends in the literature in regard to energy efficiency and economic policy. We did two searches on Scopus and Web of Science databases to first explain the general trend with search query {“Energy Efficiency” AND “Econom*”} and second for a specific trend {“Energy Efficiency” AND “Economic Policy”}. Web of Science and Scopus databases were accessed on 18 February 2023. The first search rendered 37,695 articles in Scopus and 23,842 articles in Web of Science and the second search resulted in 152 articles in Scopus and 91 articles in Web of Science. This paper presents three key trends: (1) number of articles published annually, (2) top 10 journals based on annual article count publishing related research, and (3) top 10 subject areas based on annual article count published. Exploring research trends allows researchers to gain insightful comprehension about the research landscape, pinpoint knowledge gaps, and prioritize their own research endeavors. Examining variables such as annual article counts, top-rated journals, and subject areas can facilitate a comprehensive understanding of the present state and future direction of research in a specific field [57]. Figure 5 and Figure 6 show the publishing trend in both Scopus and Web of Science for the first and second search, respectively. A trend in general research on economy and energy efficiency started emerging in the mid-1990s and research on economic policy and energy efficiency started to emerge after 2010.
Trends regarding journals based on article count are presented in Table 2 and Table 3. The results show that for the first search, most of the articles according to Web of Science are published by “Energy Policy” with 931 articles indexed in Web of Science, and as per Scopus, it is “Energy” with 1724 articles indexed in Scopus. In Web of Science indexation, the lowest number of articles are published in “Energy Conversion and Management” with 364 articles. Scopus has 441 articles as the lowest number published in “Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews”.
One conclusion is that articles related to energy efficiency and the economy in general are published in journals related to energy and not in interdisciplinary or economy-related journals. The results for the second search are different, as in the second search the top journal publishing research on energy efficiency and economic policy is “Contemporary Economic Policy”, which is a fairly economics-focused journal with six articles indexed in Web of Science.
As per Scopus indexation with 13 articles, “Energy Policy” is top journal. The 10th-ranked journals in Web of Science and Scopus are “Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions” and “Energy and Environment”, respectively. One of the major differences according to publishing research is that in the second search, prestigious journals in economic policy are included in top 10 journals as well, such as “American Economic Journal Economic Policy” and “Oxford Review of Economic Policy”.
Figure 7, Figure 8, Figure 9 and Figure 10 show the top 10 subject areas based on the article count for both the first and second searches in Web of Science and Scopus. For the first search, the top area of research in Web of Science is “Energy Fuels” with 28% of research in this area, and the 10th rank is “Construction Building Technology” with 5% of total research. In Scopus, the top area of research is “Engineering” with 26% of research in this area, and the 10th rank is “Economic, Econometric and Finance” with 3% of total research.
For the second search, the top area of research in Web of Science is “Economics” with 34% of research in this area, and the 10th rank is “Construction Building Technology” with 2% of total research. In Scopus, the top area of research is “Environmental Science” with 25% of research in this area, and the 10th rank is “Earth and Planetary Sciences” with 2% of total research. Confirming the trend from journals, this study found that the second search has a major part, i.e., 13% in “Economics, Econometrics and Finance”.

4. Subsidies

Government subsidies are direct monetary payments made to energy-efficient individuals, organizations, and businesses. The fundamental purpose of subsidies is to decrease the cost of energy-efficient technologies, thus making them more accessible and affordable to consumers [58,59,60]. There are a variety of sorts of subsidies, such as grants, loans, tax benefits, etc. Frequently, subsidies are used to promote the development and implementation of renewable energy sources. Government subsidies may be available to companies that invest in renewable energy technology [61,62,63]. These subsidies can help reduce the cost of renewable energy systems and increase their competitiveness against conventional energy sources.
Subsidies can also be used to promote the adoption of energy-efficient appliances, cars, and structures. Individuals that purchase energy-efficient appliances or automobiles, as well as enterprises that invest in energy-efficient equipment, receive government incentives. These subsidies can assist in reducing the price of energy-efficient products, making them more accessible and affordable for customers. The United States is an example of a government that has offered incentives to consumers and companies purchasing energy-efficient equipment. The federal government provides a number of incentive schemes for energy-efficient behavior and investment. For instance, the Energy Star program offers tax incentives to people and businesses who invest in energy-efficient appliances and cars. Energy Star was established in 1992 and is administered by the United States Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) and the United States Department of Energy (DOE). The program gives tax credits for appliances, air conditioners, and light bulbs that satisfy specified energy-efficiency criteria. The tax credits are intended to reduce the price of energy-efficient goods and promote their widespread adoption [64,65,66].
Subsidies can help develop a market for energy-efficient products and services in addition to decreasing the price of energy-efficient technology. By providing financial incentives for energy-efficient behavior and investment, subsidies can encourage firms to develop and install energy-efficient technology and encourage consumers to adopt them [66,67,68]. Australia’s Renewable Energy Target (RET) program serves as a real-world example of incentives that encourage energy-efficient behavior and investment. The RET is a market-based system that offers businesses and people financial incentives to invest in renewable energy technologies, such as solar panels, wind turbines, and hydropower. Under the RET, firms that create renewable energy are compensated for each unit of renewable energy they generate [69,70,71,72].
Some interesting findings are reached, and some social phenomena are explicated rationally by [73] while exploring the energy efficiency subsidies under market power. Initially, a rise in total subsidies increases the number of subsidized businesses. In addition, fiercer competition increases the number of enterprises requiring subsidies. Thus, the number of supported companies is contingent upon the level of competition in this field. Second, output subsidies result in a larger consumer surplus and a smaller producer surplus than fixed subsidies. Consequently, consumers prefer output subsidies, whereas companies prefer fixed subsidies. Finally, output subsidies have a more positive influence on the environment and subsidize more businesses than fixed subsidies. Thus, the effects of production subsidies on the environment outweigh those of fixed subsidies. The abovementioned work supported production subsidies and demonstrated benefits based on the environmental and consumer surplus effects.
Many researchers have argued for housing and vehicular subsidies for energy efficiency. The paper [74] shows that subsidized properties are associated with higher energy consumption than comparable market-rate properties, and that, among subsidized housing schemes, public housing tends to be the most energy-intensive. Despite the potential for retrofitting multifamily homes and the associated cost, energy, and carbon emission reductions, regulatory restrictions limit investment and consumption decisions for subsidized properties. The authors of the paper [75] in their investigation uncovered strong relationships between the quantity of subsidies received per capita in districts and characteristics indicating territorial stability and social capital. There are considerable disparities in the rate of subsidy receipt between regions that are considered economically disadvantaged and where the danger of energy poverty is greater. While border communities in the eastern United States demonstrate an above-average usage of funding for the insulation of existing homes, persons in larger cities and their suburbs are more likely to use subsidies for a new home. The results imply that subsidies should be redistributed and targeted more precisely in accordance with the program’s stated goals.
As presented in [76], if the subsidy is insufficient, a low-cost firm may manufacture an uncertified product while a high-cost firm produces a certified product. Additionally, the government’s optimal endogenous subsidy scheme operates under three distinct objectives: minimizing total energy consumption, average energy consumption per product, and average energy consumption per unit of GDP. In order to minimize total energy consumption, it is sometimes ideal to induce the low-cost firm to make an uncertified product and the high-cost firm to produce a certified product.
From the perspective of vehicles, the author of [77] suggested that subsidies for electric cars should be reduced or eliminated, with a focus on rapid increases in the fuel efficiency of light-duty vehicles, which will have positive spillover effects on the final energy intensity of electric vehicles and mineral needs following a delayed market scale-up. The author of the paper [78] recommended, instead of subsidizing, mandating the early market uptake of plug-in hybrid electric vehicles (PHEVs) and hybrid electric vehicles (HEVs). Furthermore, it is added that a preferable plan would be to rapidly boost automotive fuel economy requirements to that which can be attained only with HEVs, with moderate support for PHEVs, followed by the support for energy-efficient PHEVs and/or battery electric vehicles (BEVs) if scientific advancements essential for century-scale sustainability are accomplished.
While exploring evidence from China, the authors of [79] discovered that government subsidies had a substantial crowding effect on the R&D intensity of new energy vehicle (NEV) companies. As government subsidies increase, the crowding impact progressively decreases. From the aspect of EU-27, the authors of [80] report that the results are very diverse, depending on the power mix of each nation analyzed, and they indicate that the proposed subsidies can create advantages for consumers in countries that employ the greatest renewable energy sources. Using recent experiences from Estonia, the authors of [81] evaluated the energy renovation subsidy program and found that the distribution of renovation subsidies is linked to geographic socio-economic metrics and that real estate value explains 40% of subsidy distribution differences across geographic areas.
The research of [82] examined how government subsidies for energy efficiency in residential buildings could be best distributed to achieve maximum cost savings. The case study of the Danish municipality of Lyngby-Taarbaek was discussed, revealing systemic bias in heat demand estimations, with the result that older homes were incorrectly assigned a higher heat need than they had. As a result of this bias, 39% of all CO2 emissions are improperly allocated, and 40% of all subsidies are skewed.
It is essential to realize that subsidies might sometimes have significant disadvantages. Subsidies, for instance, might distort market signals, resulting in inefficient resource allocation. Subsidies can also foster reliance on government assistance, which can lead to market instability if government policies are altered. Subsidies are routinely utilized as a policy instrument to improve energy efficiency despite these potential downsides. Subsidies can aid in reducing energy consumption, cutting greenhouse gas emissions, and conserving natural resources by lowering the cost of energy-efficient technology and promoting their adoption.

5. Tax Incentives

Tax incentives are a type of economic policy that is used to encourage energy efficiency by making it cheaper to act and invest in ways that use less energy [83]. Tax incentives work by giving people or businesses who invest in energy-efficient products, technologies, or ways of doing business tax breaks or lower taxes. Tax incentives can come in the form of tax credits, tax deductions, tax exemptions, or other types of tax relief [84,85]. Tax breaks are a common way to encourage people to use less energy because they are easy to set up and can be tailored to specific actions or investments. For example, tax incentives can be used to get people to buy appliances or cars that use less energy, or to get businesses to invest in equipment that uses less energy. Tax breaks may be directed towards encouraging modifications to buildings that can result in significant energy savings and reduced emissions of greenhouse gases [86].
Tax incentives confer a financial advantage to individuals or organizations that alter their energy usage patterns or invest in energy-efficient technologies. This provides an impetus for such entities to undertake sustainable energy practices that can contribute to a reduction in greenhouse gas emissions and environmental conservation. By making these actions and investments cheaper, tax incentives can get more people to use energy-efficient products and practices, which can help cut energy use and greenhouse gas emissions [87,88]. For instance, The Energy Efficient Homes Tax Credit works by giving people who make changes to their homes that save energy a tax credit. The tax credit pays for a portion of the cost of the upgrades, which helps to lower the total cost of the improvements. So, people who use the tax credit are more likely to put money into energy-efficient home improvements, which can help them use less energy and release less greenhouse gases. Another benefit of tax incentives is that they are usually easy to change or adjust to keep up with changes in the energy market or in technology. Tax breaks can be changed to reflect changes in the prices of energy-efficient products or to encourage the use of new technologies that use less energy [89].
In the paper [90], findings imply that incentives to promote the use of energy-efficient appliances may be cost-effective, but whether they are or not depends on the specific nation and the alternatives being considered. In Denmark and Italy, tax credits on boilers appear to be a cost-effective choice, whereas in France and Poland, subsidies on compact fluorescent lamp (CFLi) bulbs are cost-effective in terms of €/ton of carbon dioxide (CO2) abated. Comparing the subsidies to the energy tax choices, the authors discovered that most of the time, the energy tax is more cost-effective than the subsidies.
According to a study of the effectiveness of current and former energy efficiency tax incentives by [91], the 10% energy efficiency tax credits implemented in 1978 were ineffective at generating significant energy savings because they encouraged the same tried-and-true energy efficiency measures that many customers and companies were installing on their own, leading to high costs for “free riders” (consumers and businesses that would have installed the efficiency measures regardless of the tax credits). In addition, the tax incentive was insufficient to encourage new installations.
While exploring the role of tax incentives in encouraging energy efficiency, the research in [92] found that while tax incentives certainly play a part in decision making, other non-tax considerations affect South African enterprises’ decisions to engage in energy efficiency and/or renewable energy projects, according to the findings. These firms did not consider the present tax incentives to be useful or sufficiently motivating for them to alter their environmental practices.
Tax incentives to modernize the energy efficiency of housing in Spain were explored in [93]; their findings showed that a monetary approach to encouraging residential energy efficiency is advantageous. In this regard, it suggests adding an incentive to the personal income tax tied to an increase in the energy efficiency rating of homes. In addition, it proposes changes to the present laws governing tax advantages for the real estate tax and the tax on building, installations, and infrastructure work.
From the perspective of China’s value-added tax reform, the research in [94] indicated that the reform decreases enterprises’ coal intensity by around nine percent. After the reform, coal intensity decreased more for large-scale enterprises, firms in energy-intensive industries, and private firms. This policy reduces energy consumption by encouraging businesses to invest in fixed assets and increase output. Nonetheless, tax benefits are not without restrictions. One difficulty with tax incentives is that they can be difficult to comprehend and implement, especially for small enterprises and individuals unfamiliar with the tax system. In addition, tax incentives may be costly to execute and have a major impact on government finances if they are not carefully targeted [95]. To be efficient and to have the least possible impact on government finances, tax incentives must be properly developed and administered.

6. Market-Based Mechanisms

Market-based methods are economic programs that employ market forces to increase energy efficiency [96,97]. These strategies are designed to generate a market-driven incentive for individuals and organizations to adopt energy-efficient behaviors and invest in energy-efficient technology. Market-based strategies include white certificate emissions trading systems (cap-and-trade schemes), and renewable energy regulations, among others. Emissions trading systems, commonly referred to as cap-and-trade programs, function by placing a limit on the total quantity of greenhouse gas emissions that may be produced in a certain region or industry. Companies that release greenhouse gases are thus obliged to possess emissions permits, with each permit reflecting the authority to emit a particular quantity of greenhouse gases [98,99]. Creating a market for emissions reductions, firms that pollute less than their allowances may sell their unused allowances to enterprises that emit more than their limits [100,101]. This market-driven incentive encourages businesses to cut their emissions and adopt energy-efficient practices and technology, as doing so reduces their emissions and the number of permits they must hold [102,103].
Market-based mechanisms have been proposed as a policy tool to promote energy efficiency, and one such mechanism is the use of white certificates. White certificates are a type of tradable instrument that serve as evidence of energy savings achieved by organizations, and they can be traded on a market that creates a competitive environment that incentivizes organizations to reduce their energy usage and encourage energy efficiency [104,105]. The use of white certificates can create a competitive market that drives down the cost of energy efficiency investments and encourages the development of new energy-saving technologies, thus facilitating the transition towards a sustainable economy [106,107]. This market can help overcome barriers to energy efficiency investment, such as the high upfront cost of energy-saving investments and the difficulty of measuring energy savings accurately. By promoting investment in energy efficiency, white certificates can help reduce energy consumption, greenhouse gas emissions, and promote sustainable development. Overall, white certificates can be an effective policy tool for promoting energy efficiency and contributing to climate change mitigation efforts [108,109,110,111].
The European Union Emissions Trading System (EU ETS) is a cap-and-trade system covering over 11,000 power plants and industrial units in 31 nations. It was established in 2005 and is the largest carbon market in the world. The system imposes a limit on the total amount of greenhouse gas emissions that may be generated by covered facilities and allocates a limited number of permits, each reflecting the right to release a particular quantity of greenhouse gases. The EU ETS has successfully reduced greenhouse gas emissions in the electricity and industrial sectors and offered a market-driven incentive for businesses to adopt energy-efficient practices and technology [112,113,114].
Renewable energy requirements, also known as renewable portfolio standards, are an additional market-based mechanism that encourages energy efficiency. Electricity suppliers are required under renewable energy standards to generate a particular amount of their electricity from renewable energy sources. The EU’s Green Public Procurement (GPP) sets a criteria at 50 percent [115]. These criteria provide a market demand for renewable energy, which stimulates investment in renewable energy technologies and promotes the development and deployment of these technologies [116].
As a policy instrument for increasing energy efficiency, market-based methods provide several benefits. Individuals and corporations are incentivized by the market to adopt energy-efficient habits and invest in energy-efficient technologies. These strategies can be more successful and efficient than command-and-control rules since they rely on market forces to promote energy efficiency [117,118]. Second, market-based procedures are adaptable and simple to modify in response to changes in energy markets and technology [119,120]. For instance, emissions trading systems can be modified to reflect changes in the cost of emissions reductions or to adapt to alterations in the trend of greenhouse gas emissions. Lastly, market-based procedures can be cost-effective because they let people and enterprises select the most cost-effective means of reducing energy use and emissions.
Summarizing the research in market-based processes, these are essential and efficient instruments for increasing energy efficiency. These approaches can be more effective and efficient than classic command-and-control rules by generating a market-driven incentive for energy efficiency and employing market forces to promote energy efficiency. Moreover, market-based procedures are quickly adaptable to changes in energy markets and technology, making them an appropriate policy instrument for encouraging energy efficiency in a fast-changing energy landscape.

7. Conclusions

To ensure long-term prosperity, energy efficiency is essential. To conserve natural resources, lessen reliance on fossil fuels, and boost public health, its primary value is in lowering energy use and greenhouse gas emissions. Promoting energy efficiency through the introduction of economic policies that offer financial incentives to individuals and businesses has been shown to be an effective strategy. Table 4 presents the solution to existing issues in energy-efficiency adoptions based on the literature review.
Subsidies have been found to enhance the market for energy-efficient products and services, as well as stimulate energy-efficient behavior and investment. However, other research has indicated that energy efficiency incentives are not effectively targeted, with the majority of beneficiaries being higher-income homeowners. In addition, there are inequalities in the rate at which different regions get subsidies; low-income communities, which are more vulnerable to energy insecurity and the adverse effects of climate change, receive a smaller share of the total subsidies awarded. Energy subsidies can have the greatest impact if they are tailored to help the most disadvantaged members of society while also providing funding for low-carbon technologies that have broader social and economic advantages.
It has been determined that tax incentives play a substantial role in promoting energy efficiency, decreasing energy consumption, and lowering greenhouse gas emissions. These incentives provide financial benefits to individuals and organizations that invest in energy-efficient products, technology, or practices, therefore increasing their accessibility and desirability. The efficiency of tax incentives varies by country, policy option, and implementation procedure. It has been determined that certain tax incentives, such as the Energy Efficient Homes Tax Credit, are cost-effective and yield significant energy savings. However, the 1978 10% tax credits for energy efficiency were deemed inadequate due to their inability to motivate new installations and their high costs for “free riders”. Some studies have also indicated that non-tax factors, such as personal values and environmental responsibility, have a considerable effect on energy efficiency decisions.
Emissions trading systems, cap-and-trade schemes, and renewable energy regulations are all examples of market-based methods that have been shown to be effective economic programs for encouraging people and businesses to adopt energy-efficient behaviors and invest in energy-efficient technology by harnessing the power of market forces. Successful examples of cap-and-trade systems that have decreased greenhouse gas emissions in the power and industrial sectors include the EU ETS. Regulations mandating that power companies increase their use of renewable energy sources by a specific percentage are known as renewable portfolio standards. Because of their versatility, low cost, and reliance on market forces to promote energy efficiency, market-based solutions have shown to be an efficient policy instrument for doing just that.

Evaluation of Economic Policy

It is essential for governments to evaluate a policy as much as it is to introduce policies. This study discusses two major policy evaluation methods for energy efficiency (1) Evaluation, measurement, and verification (EM&V) and (2) Cost-effectiveness metrics.
Evaluation, measurement, and verification (EM&V) are critical components of any effective economic policy designed to promote energy efficiency and sustainability [121,122]. The main objective of EM&V is to assess the effectiveness of energy efficiency policies by measuring their impact on energy consumption and the environment. The evaluation process involves gathering data and analyzing it to determine the efficacy of energy policies, while measurement and verification involve quantifying the energy savings achieved through the implementation of these policies [123]. This information is then used to improve the policies and ensure that the goals of energy efficiency and sustainability are met [124].
From an economic policy perspective, EM&V is essential to ensure the success of energy efficiency policies. Without effective evaluation, it is impossible to determine the impact of policies or identify areas for improvement. EM&V can provide a systematic approach to assess the effectiveness of energy efficiency policies, including subsidies. This approach involves the collection, analysis, and interpretation of data to evaluate the impact of policies on energy savings and other relevant outcomes. By measuring the energy savings achieved by the technology or practice being incentivized by subsidies, taxation or market-based mechanisms, policymakers can determine if the policy instruments are achieving their intended goals and if they are cost-effective.
Secondly, cost-effectiveness metrics are crucial in assessing the economic viability of various policy options, including those related to energy efficiency [125,126]. Such metrics enable policymakers to measure the efficiency of policies by weighing their costs against their benefits [127,128]. Benefit–cost tests are a specific type of cost-effectiveness metric that aim to compare the net benefits of a policy to its costs while also considering its broader economic, social, and environmental impacts [129]. Policymakers can use benefit–cost tests to identify the most cost-effective policy options that maximize policy efficiency by allocating resources optimally. The use of such metrics can also ensure that policies do not impose undue burdens on businesses or individuals, which can undermine their effectiveness and lead to opposition [130]. Therefore, it is important to employ cost-effectiveness metrics in evaluating the economic impacts of policies such as subsidies, tax incentives, and market-based mechanisms, as they aid policymakers in identifying the most effective and efficient policy options.

8. Future Research Directions

More research is needed to find the best way to direct funding for energy efficiency programs to the people and places that may benefit the most. Future research directions are outlined in two aspects: (1) specific to the economic policy instruments discussed in this paper and (2) other possible areas of research. Incentives might be targeted to low-income neighborhoods or individuals by employing “tagging” or other technologies that identify regions with high rates of energy poverty. Researchers might look into the environmental consequences of various subsidy programs to find the ones that are best at boosting energy efficiency and cutting carbon emissions.
Studies might be undertaken to evaluate the effectiveness of subsidies in lowering energy usage in various settings, such as households, companies, and other public places. Having this data would be helpful for policymakers as they try to figure out how effective subsidies are in increasing energy efficiency. Studies might be done to assess how subsidies affect energy markets and the competitiveness of renewable energy sources. The effect of subsidies on energy costs and the spread of renewable energy sources might be examined as part of this process. The social and economic effects of subsidies, including their dispersion across regions and communities, might be the subject of future research.
Some possible research areas for research on tax initiatives and energy efficiency could be in the following areas: effectiveness of different types of tax incentives, cost-effectiveness of tax incentives, further analysis of the financial benefits of tax incentives for various energy-efficient products and practices across countries. The impact of tax incentives on government finances, the effectiveness of tax incentives in different industries, and companies’ decisions to invest in energy efficiency and/or renewable energy projects can be explored by future research into the non-tax variables, beyond tax incentives, that influence such decisions. Moreover, studies can be conducted to explore how successful tax incentives are for small businesses and individuals who may not be familiar with the tax system and have trouble understanding and using the incentives. Value-added tax reforms may have an influence on energy usage; more research is needed to quantify this effect and establish how the reforms might be improved.
Some potential avenues for future study with regards to market-based mechanisms can be examining how various market-based approaches, such as carbon trading systems, cap-and-trade programs, and renewable energy standards, might best encourage energy efficiency and cut down on greenhouse gas emissions. The feasibility of adapting and improving market-based approaches in light of developments in energy markets and technologies is now being investigated. Examining how market-based approaches to improving energy efficiency stack up against other policy instruments in terms of cost-effectiveness can be useful. How organizations and individuals are affected by market-based approaches, as well as the incentives offered to encourage the adoption of energy-efficient practices and technologies, can be analyzed. Further work can also analyze the cultural, political, and economic aspects that may affect the success of using market-based approaches in various areas and sectors. These avenues for further study have the potential to expand upon the current body of knowledge and furnish policymakers with more solid information upon which to base their judgments about the usage of subsidies as a means of encouraging energy efficiency and lowering carbon emissions.
Generally, the convergence of energy efficiency and economic policy offers promising prospects for novel research initiatives. One potential research direction is the utilization of big data and machine learning methodologies to create more precise and effective assessment techniques for energy efficiency policies. To illustrate, data-driven approaches could be applied to gain deeper insights into the effects of different policy designs and implementation approaches on energy savings and economic ramifications.
Another potential area for research is the establishment of novel financial instruments that incentivize energy efficiency investments. For instance, the deployment of blockchain technology to create a decentralized platform for energy efficiency investments could surmount conventional financing barriers, including high transaction costs and a lack of transparency. Furthermore, future research could investigate the social equity and environmental justice implications of energy efficiency policies. By analyzing the distributional impacts of policies on low-income and marginalized communities, policymakers could gain a better understanding of the potential unintentional consequences of policy interventions and design more effective and equitable policies.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.M., M.M.K.A. and H.T.; methodology, H.T.; software, M.M.; validation, M.M., M.M.K.A., H.T. and S.C.; formal analysis, M.M. and M.M.K.A.; investigation, M.M. and M.M.K.A.; resources, H.T.; data curation, M.M.; writing—original draft preparation, M.M. and M.M.K.A.; writing—review and editing, H.T. and S.C.; visualization, M.M.; supervision, S.C.; project administration, S.C.; revision, M.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

The data are contained within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Uddin, M.; Rahman, A.A. Energy efficiency and low carbon enabler green IT framework for data centers considering green metrics. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2012, 16, 4078–4094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Mushafiq, M.; Prusak, B. Nexus between stock markets, economic strength, R&D and environmental deterioration: New evidence from EU-27 using PNARDL approach. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Petkova-Chobanova, B.; Babayan, T.; Gorovykh, I. Energy efficiency policies and programmes in the Eastern Partnership and Central Asian countries: The role of the Energy Charter PEEREA review process. In Energy Efficiency in Developing Countries; Routledge: London, UK, 2020; pp. 163–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Acuner, E.; Özgür Kayalica, M. A review on household energy consumption behavior: How about migrated consumers? Environ. Econ. 2018, 9, 8–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Worrell, E.; Bernstein, L.; Roy, J.; Price, L.; Harnisch, J. Industrial energy efficiency and climate change mitigation. Energy Effic. 2009, 2, 109–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Mills, E. Building commissioning: A golden opportunity for reducing energy costs and greenhouse gas emissions in the United States. Energy Effic. 2011, 4, 145–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Herring, H. Energy efficiency—A critical view. Energy 2006, 31, 10–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gustavsson, L.; Börjesson, P.; Johansson, B.; Svenningsson, P. Reducing CO2 emissions by substituting biomass for fossil fuels. Energy 1995, 20, 1097–1113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Thollander, P.; Ottosson, M. An energy efficient Swedish pulp and paper industry—Exploring barriers to and driving forces for cost-effective energy efficiency investments. Energy Effic. 2008, 1, 21–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Solà, M.D.M.; de Ayala, A.; Galarraga, I.; Escapa, M. Promoting energy efficiency at household level: A literature review. Energy Effic. 2021, 14, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Hesselink, L.X.W.; Chappin, E.J.L. Adoption of energy efficient technologies by households—Barriers, policies and agent-based modelling studies. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 99, 29–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Cho, Y.; Koo, Y.; Huh, S.Y.; Lee, M. Evaluation of a consumer incentive program for an energy-efficient product in South Korea. Energy Effic. 2015, 8, 745–757. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Herring, H.; Roy, R. Technological innovation, energy efficient design and the rebound effect. Technovation 2007, 27, 194–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Stram, B.N. Key challenges to expanding renewable energy. Energy Policy 2016, 96, 728–734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Kanwal, S.; Mehran, M.T.; Hassan, M.; Anwar, M.; Naqvi, S.R.; Khoja, A.H. An integrated future approach for the energy security of Pakistan: Replacement of fossil fuels with syngas for better environment and socio-economic development. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2022, 156, 111978. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Vivoda, V. Japan’s energy security predicament post-Fukushima. Energy Policy 2012, 46, 135–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Matsumoto, K.; Andriosopoulos, K. Energy security in East Asia under climate mitigation scenarios in the 21st century. Omega 2016, 59, 60–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Peng, H.R.; Tan, X.; Managi, S.; Taghizadeh-Hesary, F. Club convergence in energy efficiency of Belt and Road Initiative countries: The role of China’s outward foreign direct investment. Energy Policy 2022, 168, 113139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Zhao, L.; Chau, K.Y.; Tran, T.K.; Sadiq, M.; Xuyen, N.T.M.; Phan, T.T.H. Enhancing green economic recovery through green bonds financing and energy efficiency investments. Econ. Anal. Policy 2022, 76, 488–501. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. McLaughlin, E.; Choi, J.K.; Kissock, K. Techno-Economic Impact Assessments of Energy Efficiency Improvements in the Industrial Combustion Systems. J. Energy Resour. Technol. Trans. ASME 2022, 144, 082109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Decanio, S.J. The efficiency paradox: Bureaucratic and organizational barriers to profitable energy-saving investments. Energy Policy 1998, 26, 441–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Trianni, A.; Cagno, E.; Farné, S. Barriers, drivers and decision-making process for industrial energy efficiency: A broad study among manufacturing small and medium-sized enterprises. Appl. Energy 2016, 162, 1537–1551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Reuter, M.; Patel, M.K.; Eichhammer, W.; Lapillonne, B.; Pollier, K. A comprehensive indicator set for measuring multiple benefits of energy efficiency. Energy Policy 2020, 139, 111284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Malinauskaite, J.; Jouhara, H.; Ahmad, L.; Milani, M.; Montorsi, L.; Venturelli, M. Energy efficiency in industry: EU and national policies in Italy and the UK. Energy 2019, 172, 255–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Henriques, J.; Catarino, J. Motivating towards energy efficiency in small and medium enterprises. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 139, 42–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Gillingham, K.; Rapson, D.; Wagner, G. The rebound effect and energy efficiency policy. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2016, 10, 68–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Dunlop, T. Mind the gap: A social sciences review of energy efficiency. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2019, 56, 101216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Brockway, P.E.; Sorrell, S.; Semieniuk, G.; Heun, M.K.; Court, V. Energy efficiency and economy-wide rebound effects: A review of the evidence and its implications. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2021, 141, 110781. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Zhou, L.; Li, J.; Li, F.; Meng, Q.; Li, J.; Xu, X. Energy consumption model and energy efficiency of machine tools: A comprehensive literature review. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 112, 3721–3734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Apostolos, F.; Alexios, P.; Georgios, P.; Panagiotis, S.; George, C. Energy Efficiency of Manufacturing Processes: A Critical Review. Procedia. CIRP 2013, 7, 628–633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Patterson, M.G. What is energy efficiency?: Concepts, indicators and methodological issues. Energy Policy 1996, 24, 377–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Staddon, S.C.; Cycil, C.; Goulden, M.; Leygue, C.; Spence, A. Intervening to change behaviour and save energy in the workplace: A systematic review of available evidence. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2016, 17, 30–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. van den Broek, K.L.; Walker, I.; Klöckner, C.A. Drivers of energy saving behaviour: The relative influence of intentional, normative, situational and habitual processes. Energy Policy 2019, 132, 811–819. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Kettner, C.; Kletzan-Slamanig, D. Is there climate policy integration in European Union energy efficiency and renewable energy policies? Yes, no, maybe. Environ. Policy Gov. 2020, 30, 141–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Palmer, E. Introduction: The 2030 Agenda. J. Glob. Ethics 2015, 11, 262–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Oberthür, S.; Szulecki, K.; Claes, D.H. Hard or Soft Governance? The EU’s Climate and Energy Policy Framework for 2030. Polit. Gov. 2019, 7, 17–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  37. Boto-Álvarez, A.; García-Fernández, R. Implementation of the 2030 agenda sustainable development goals in Spain. Sustainability 2020, 12, 2546. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  38. Gao, Y.; Gao, X.; Zhang, X. The 2 °C Global Temperature Target and the Evolution of the Long-Term Goal of Addressing Climate Change—From the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change to the Paris Agreement. Engineering 2017, 3, 272–278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Schleussner, C.F.; Rogelj, J.; Schaeffer, M.; Lissner, T.; Licker, R.; Fischer, E.M.; Knutti, R.; Levermann, A.; Frieler, K.; Hare, W. Science and policy characteristics of the Paris Agreement temperature goal. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2016, 6, 827–835. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Tanaka, K. Review of policies and measures for energy efficiency in industry sector. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 6532–6550. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Wang, Z.; Yao-Ping Peng, M.; Anser, M.K.; Chen, Z. Research on the impact of green finance and renewable energy on energy efficiency: The case study E−7 economies. Renew. Energy 2023, 205, 166–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hepburn, C.; Qi, Y.; Stern, N.; Ward, B.; Xie, C.; Zenghelis, D. Towards carbon neutrality and China’s 14th Five-Year Plan: Clean energy transition, sustainable urban development, and investment priorities. Environ. Sci. Ecotechnology 2021, 8, 100130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  43. Zhang, L.; Huang, F.; Lu, L.; Ni, X.; Iqbal, S. Energy financing for energy retrofit in COVID-19: Recommendations for green bond financing. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 23105–23116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  44. Wu, C.; Yuan, Y.-H.; Yang, C.; Masron, T.A. Impact of Digital Finance on Energy Efficiency in the Context of Green Sustainable Development. Sustainability 2022, 14, 11250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Zhu, T.; Curtis, J.; Clancy, M. Modelling barriers to low-carbon technologies in energy system analysis: The example of renewable heat in Ireland. Appl. Energy 2023, 330, 120314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Poshnath, A.; Rismanchi, B.; Rajabifard, A. Adoption of Renewable Energy Systems in common properties of multi-owned buildings: Introduction of ‘Energy Entitlement’. Energy Policy 2023, 174, 113465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Chen, R.; Fan, R.; Yao, Q.; Qian, R. Evolutionary dynamics of homeowners’ energy-efficiency retrofit decision-making in complex network. J. Environ. Manag. 2023, 326, 116849. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Upham, P.; Kivimaa, P.; Mickwitz, P.; Åstrand, K. Climate policy innovation: A sociotechnical transitions perspective. Env. Polit. 2014, 23, 774–794. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Bang, G. Energy security and climate change concerns: Triggers for energy policy change in the United States? Energy Policy 2010, 38, 1645–1653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Haile, Y.; Min, H. Success factors for renewable energy businesses in emerging economies. Manag. Res. Rev. 2022. ahead of print. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Min, H.; Haile, Y. Examining the Role of Disruptive Innovation in Renewable Energy Businesses from a Cross National Perspective. Energies 2021, 14, 4447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Timilsina, G.R.; Shah, K.U. Filling the gaps: Policy supports and interventions for scaling up renewable energy development in Small Island Developing States. Energy Policy 2016, 98, 653–662. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Wei, T.; Zhou, J.; Zhang, H. Rebound effect of energy intensity reduction on energy consumption. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2019, 144, 233–239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Freire González, J. Empirical evidence of direct rebound effect in Catalonia. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 2309–2314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Freire-González, J. Methods to empirically estimate direct and indirect rebound effect of energy-saving technological changes in households. Ecol. Modell. 2011, 223, 32–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Zakarya, M.; Gillam, L. Energy efficient computing, clusters, grids and clouds: A taxonomy and survey. Sustain. Comput. Informatics Syst. 2017, 14, 13–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Mushafiq, M.; Prusak, B. Does being socially good save firms from bankruptcy? A systematic literature review and bibliometric analysis. Ekon. I Sr. Econ. Environ. 2022, 83, 35–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Jaffe, A.B.; Newell, R.G.; Stavins, R.N. Energy-Efficient Technologies and Climate Change Policies: Issues and Evidence. SSRN Electron. J. 1999. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  59. Martinot, E.; Borg, N. Energy-efficient lighting programs: Experience and lessons from eight countries. Energy Policy 1998, 26, 1071–1081. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Hua, L.; Wang, S. Antecedents of Consumers’ Intention to Purchase Energy-Efficient Appliances: An Empirical Study Based on the Technology Acceptance Model and Theory of Planned Behavior. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2994. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  61. Blum, N.U.; Sryantoro Wakeling, R.; Schmidt, T.S. Rural electrification through village grids—Assessing the cost competitiveness of isolated renewable energy technologies in Indonesia. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2013, 22, 482–496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Frondel, M.; Ritter, N.; Schmidt, C.M.; Vance, C. Economic impacts from the promotion of renewable energy technologies: The German experience. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 4048–4056. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  63. Menanteau, P.; Finon, D.; Lamy, M.L. Prices versus quantities: Choosing policies for promoting the development of renewable energy. Energy Policy 2003, 31, 799–812. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Brown, R.; Webber, C.; Koomey, J.G. Status and future directions of the Energy Star program. Energy 2002, 27, 505–520. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  65. Boyd, G.; Dutrow, E.; Tunnessen, W. The evolution of the ENERGY STAR® energy performance indicator for benchmarking industrial plant manufacturing energy use. J. Clean. Prod. 2008, 16, 709–715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Yeatts, D.E.; Auden, D.; Cooksey, C.; Chen, C.F. A systematic review of strategies for overcoming the barriers to energy-efficient technologies in buildings. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2017, 32, 76–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Thiruchelvam, M.; Kumar, S.; Visvanathan, C. Policy options to promote energy efficient and environmentally sound technologies in small- and medium-scale industries. Energy Policy 2003, 31, 977–987. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Stieß, I.; Dunkelberg, E. Objectives, barriers and occasions for energy efficient refurbishment by private homeowners. J. Clean. Prod. 2013, 48, 250–259. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Buckman, G.; Diesendorf, M. Design limitations in Australian renewable electricity policies. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3365–3376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  70. Nelson, T.; Nelson, J.; Ariyaratnam, J.; Camroux, S. An analysis of Australia’s large scale renewable energy target: Restoring market confidence. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 386–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  71. Martin, N.J.; Rice, J.L. Developing renewable energy supply in Queensland, Australia: A study of the barriers, targets, policies and actions. Renew. Energy 2012, 44, 119–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Valentine, S. Braking wind in Australia: A critical evaluation of the renewable energy target. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 3668–3675. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Nie, P.Y.; Wang, C.; Yang, Y.C. Comparison of energy efficiency subsidies under market power. Energy Policy 2017, 110, 144–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Reina, V.J.; Kontokosta, C. Low hanging fruit? Regulations and energy efficiency in subsidized multifamily housing. Energy Policy 2017, 106, 505–513. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  75. Frantál, B.; Dvořák, P. Reducing energy poverty in deprived regions or supporting new developments in metropolitan suburbs? Regional differences in the use of subsidies for home energy efficiency renovations. Energy Policy 2022, 171, 113250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Huang, W.; Zhou, W.; Chen, J.; Chen, X. The government’s optimal subsidy scheme under Manufacturers’ competition of price and product energy efficiency. Omega 2019, 84, 70–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Harvey, L.D.D. Rethinking electric vehicle subsidies, rediscovering energy efficiency. Energy Policy 2020, 146, 111760. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  78. Harvey, L.D.D. Cost and energy performance of advanced light duty vehicles: Implications for standards and subsidies. Energy Policy 2018, 114, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Jiang, C.; Zhang, Y.; Bu, M.; Liu, W. The Effectiveness of Government Subsidies on Manufacturing Innovation: Evidence from the New Energy Vehicle Industry in China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1692. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  80. De Santis, M.; Silvestri, L.; Forcina, A. Promoting electric vehicle demand in Europe: Design of innovative electricity consumption simulator and subsidy strategies based on well-to-wheel analysis. Energy Convers. Manag. 2022, 270, 116279. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  81. Lihtmaa, L.; Hess, D.B.; Leetmaa, K. Intersection of the global climate agenda with regional development: Unequal distribution of energy efficiency-based renovation subsidies for apartment buildings. Energy Policy 2018, 119, 327–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  82. Siddique, M.B.; Bergaentzlé, C.; Gunkel, P.A. Fine-tuning energy efficiency subsidies allocation for maximum savings in residential buildings. Energy 2022, 258, 124810. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Surrey, S.S. Tax Incentives as a Device for Implementing Government Policy: A Comparison with Direct Government Expenditures. Harv. Law Rev. 1970, 83, 705. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Briant, A.; Lafourcade, M.; Schmutz, B. Can Tax Breaks Beat Geography? Lessons from the French Enterprise Zone Experience. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 2015, 7, 88–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  85. Batchelder, L.L.; Goldberg, F.T., Jr.; Orszag, P.R. Efficiency and Tax Incentives: The Case for Refundable Tax Credits on JSTOR. Stanf. Law Rev. 2006, 59, 23–76. [Google Scholar]
  86. Brown, M.A.; Southworth, F. Mitigating climate change through green buildings and smart growth. Environ. Plan. A 2008, 40, 653–675. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  87. Kaygusuz, K. Energy for sustainable development: A case of developing countries. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2012, 16, 1116–1126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  88. Stevens, C. Linking sustainable consumption and production: The government role. Nat. Resour. Forum 2010, 34, 16–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Alexander, M.M.; Sulkowski, A.J.; Wiggins, W.P. Sustainability & Tax Policy Fixing A Patchwork of Policies with a Coherent Federal FrameworK on JSTOR. Va. Environ. Law J. 2016, 35, 1–58. [Google Scholar]
  90. Markandya, A.; Ortiz, R.A.; Mudgal, S.; Tinetti, B. Analysis of tax incentives for energy-efficient durables in the EU. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 5662–5674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Nadel, S. Energy Efficiency Tax Incentives in the Context of Tax Reform; American Council for an Energy-Efficient Economy: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  92. Dippenaar, M. The role of tax incentives in encouraging energy efficiency in the largest listed South African businesses. S. Afr. J. Econ. Manag. Sci. 2018, 21, a1723. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  93. Villca-Pozo, M.; Gonzales-Bustos, J.P. Tax incentives to modernize the energy efficiency of the housing in Spain. Energy Policy 2019, 128, 530–538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Zhou, Q.; Li, T.; Gong, L. The effect of tax incentives on energy intensity: Evidence from China’s VAT reform. Energy Econ. 2022, 108, 105887. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Bhandary, R.R.; Gallagher, K.S.; Zhang, F. Climate finance policy in practice: A review of the evidence. Clim. Policy 2021, 21, 529–545. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Portney, P.R.; Stavins, R.N. Public Policies for Environmental Protection; Routledge: England, UK, 2010; pp. 1–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Almeida, E.L.F. De Energy efficiency and the limits of market forces: The example of the electric motor market in France. Energy Policy 1998, 26, 643–653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Pranindita, N.; Sagala, S.; Samosir, A.; Anhorn, J.; Van Laere, A.K.; Zacepins, A.; Sainz, A.; Rutz, D.; Rosslee, D.; Kirchmeyr, F.; et al. Biogas Market in Indonesia: The Roles of Carbon Trading. In Proceedings of the 2021 3rd International Sustainability and Resilience Conference: Climate Change, Sakheer, Bahrain, 15–16 November 2021; Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers Inc.: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2021; pp. 199–204. [Google Scholar]
  99. Hashim, H.; Zubir, M.A.; Kamyab, H.; Zahran, M.F.I. Decarbonisation of the Industrial Sector Through Greenhouse Gas Mitigation, Offset, and Emission Trading Schemes. Chem. Eng. Trans. 2022, 97, 511–516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. Chesney, M.; Taschini, L. The Endogenous Price Dynamics of Emission Allowances and an Application to CO 2 Option Pricing. Appl. Math. Financ. 2012, 19, 447–475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Zhao, X.; Shang, Y.; Ma, X.; Xia, P.; Shahzad, U. Does Carbon Trading Lead to Green Technology Innovation: Recent Evidence From Chinese Companies in Resource-Based Industries. IEEE Trans. Eng. Manag. 2022, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Voland, N.; Saad, M.M.; Eicker, U. Public Policy and Incentives for Socially Responsible New Business Models in Market-Driven Real Estate to Build Green Projects. Sustainability 2022, 14, 7071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  103. Gou, Z.; Lau, S.S.Y.; Prasad, D. Market readiness and policy implications for green buildings: Case study from hong kong. J. Green Build. 2013, 8, 162–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Zajkowski, K. Settlement of reactive power compensation in the light of white certificates. In Proceedings of the E3S Web of Conferences 19, UNSP 01037, Polanica Zdroj, Poland, 13–15 September 2017. [Google Scholar]
  105. Zajkowski, K. Determination of the Environmental Impact of Reactive Power Compensation in the Power GrID. Nonconv. Technol. Rev. 2016, 20, 54–61. [Google Scholar]
  106. Lo, K. A critical review of China’s rapidly developing renewable energy and energy efficiency policies. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 29, 508–516. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  107. Mundaca, L. Markets for energy efficiency: Exploring the implications of an EU-wide ‘Tradable White Certificate’ scheme. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 3016–3043. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Peñasco, C.; Anadón, L.D.; Verdolini, E. Systematic review of the outcomes and trade-offs of ten types of decarbonization policy instruments. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2021, 11, 257–265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Giraudet, L.G.; Bodineau, L.; Finon, D. The costs and benefits of white certificates schemes. Energy Effic. 2012, 5, 179–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  110. Langniss, O.; Praetorius, B. How much market do market-based instruments create? An analysis for the case of “white” certificates. Energy Policy 2006, 34, 200–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  111. Parmentola, A.; Petrillo, A.; Tutore, I.; De Felice, F. Is blockchain able to enhance environmental sustainability? A systematic review and research agenda from the perspective of Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). Bus. Strateg. Environ. 2022, 31, 194–217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  112. Perino, G.; Willner, M.; Quemin, S.; Pahle, M. The European Union Emissions Trading System Market Stability Reserve: Does It Stabilize or Destabilize the Market? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2022, 16, 338–345. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Nguyen, M.A.T.; Yu, M.M.; Lirn, T.C. Airlines’ eco-productivity changes and the European Union Emissions Trading System. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2022, 102, 103100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Fageda, X.; Teixidó, J.J. Pricing carbon in the aviation sector: Evidence from the European emissions trading system. J. Environ. Econ. Manage. 2022, 111, 102591. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. EC Renewable Energy Directive. Available online: https://energy.ec.europa.eu/topics/renewable-energy/renewable-energy-directive-targets-and-rules/renewable-energy-directive_en (accessed on 5 February 2023).
  116. Zeng, L.; Du, W.; Zhang, W.; Zhao, L.; Wang, Z. An inter-provincial cooperation model under Renewable Portfolio Standard policy. Energy 2023, 269, 126771. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  117. Guo, R.; Yuan, Y. Different types of environmental regulations and heterogeneous influence on energy efficiency in the industrial sector: Evidence from Chinese provincial data. Energy Policy 2020, 145, 111747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  118. Ngo, T.Q. How do environmental regulations affect carbon emission and energy efficiency patterns? A provincial-level analysis of Chinese energy-intensive industries. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 3446–3462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  119. Wang, F.; Xu, H.; Xu, T.; Li, K.; Shafie-khah, M.; Catalão, J.P.S. The values of market-based demand response on improving power system reliability under extreme circumstances. Appl. Energy 2017, 193, 220–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  120. Papadaskalopoulos, D.; Strbac, G. Decentralized participation of flexible demand in electricity markets—Part I: Market mechanism. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 3658–3666. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  121. Haley, B.; Gaede, J.; Winfield, M.; Love, P. From utility demand side management to low-carbon transitions: Opportunities and challenges for energy efficiency governance in a new era. Energy Res. Soc. Sci. 2020, 59, 101312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  122. Vine, E.; Hall, N.; Keating, K.M.; Kushler, M.; Prahl, R. Emerging issues in the evaluation of energy-efficiency programs: The US experience. Energy Effic. 2012, 5, 5–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  123. Schiller Consulting, I.; Schiller, S.R.; Goldman, C.A.; Galawish, E. National Energy Efficiency Evaluation, Measurement and Verification (EM&V) Standard: Scoping Study of Issues and Implementation Requirements; Lawrence Berkeley National Lab: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  124. Meyers, S.; Kromer, S. Measurement and verification strategies for energy savings certificates: Meeting the challenges of an uncertain world. Energy Effic. 2008, 1, 313–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  125. Belaïd, F.; Ranjbar, Z.; Massié, C. Exploring the cost-effectiveness of energy efficiency implementation measures in the residential sector. Energy Policy 2021, 150, 112122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  126. Fagan, J.E.; Reuter, M.A.; Langford, K.J. Dynamic performance metrics to assess sustainability and cost effectiveness of integrated urban water systems. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2010, 54, 719–736. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  127. Dodoo, A.; Gustavsson, L.; Tettey, U.Y.A. Final energy savings and cost-effectiveness of deep energy renovation of a multi-storey residential building. Energy 2017, 135, 563–576. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  128. Streicher, K.N.; Mennel, S.; Chambers, J.; Parra, D.; Patel, M.K. Cost-effectiveness of large-scale deep energy retrofit packages for residential buildings under different economic assessment approaches. Energy Build. 2020, 215, 109870. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  129. Arimura, T.H.; Li, S.; Newell, R.G.; Palmer, K. Cost-Effectiveness of Electricity Energy Efficiency Programs. Energy J. 2012, 33, 63–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  130. Pinkerton, S.D.; Johnson-Masotti, A.P.; Derse, A.; Layde, P.M. Ethical issues in cost-effectiveness analysis. Eval. Program Plann. 2002, 25, 71–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Theoretical framework of energy efficiency and economy. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 1. Theoretical framework of energy efficiency and economy. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g001
Figure 2. Framework of the study. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 2. Framework of the study. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g002
Figure 3. European Union’s primary energy consumption with regard to 2030 goals. Source: Own elaboration based on public data available at EuroStat. The data were accessed on 4 February 2022 from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/main/data/database.
Figure 3. European Union’s primary energy consumption with regard to 2030 goals. Source: Own elaboration based on public data available at EuroStat. The data were accessed on 4 February 2022 from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/main/data/database.
Energies 16 02381 g003
Figure 4. European Union’s final energy consumption with regard to 2030 goals. Source: Own elaboration based on public data available at EuroStat. The data were accessed on 4 February 2022 from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/main/data/database.
Figure 4. European Union’s final energy consumption with regard to 2030 goals. Source: Own elaboration based on public data available at EuroStat. The data were accessed on 4 February 2022 from https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/main/data/database.
Energies 16 02381 g004
Figure 5. Number of articles published annually using first query. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 5. Number of articles published annually using first query. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g005
Figure 6. Number of articles published annually using second query. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 6. Number of articles published annually using second query. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g006
Figure 7. Top 10 subject areas in Web of Science based on articles published annually using first query. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 7. Top 10 subject areas in Web of Science based on articles published annually using first query. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g007
Figure 8. Top 10 subject areas in Scopus based on articles published annually using first query. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 8. Top 10 subject areas in Scopus based on articles published annually using first query. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g008
Figure 9. Top 10 subject areas in Web of Science based on articles published annually using second query. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 9. Top 10 subject areas in Web of Science based on articles published annually using second query. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g009
Figure 10. Top 10 subject areas in Scopus based on articles published annually using second query. Source: Own elaboration.
Figure 10. Top 10 subject areas in Scopus based on articles published annually using second query. Source: Own elaboration.
Energies 16 02381 g010
Table 1. Issues in energy efficiency.
Table 1. Issues in energy efficiency.
IssuesDetails
Lack of financingEnergy-saving measures often require a lot of financing up front, which businesses, governments, and households may not have easy access to. This can make it more challenging for individuals to use energy-saving technologies and methods, and it could mean missed chances to save energy and cut down on pollution [43,44].
Barriers to the adoption of energy efficiency technologiesAdoption of energy-efficient solutions is hampered by factors such as a lack of knowledge about available technology, restricted access to necessary resources, and reluctance to change. For instance, individuals can be unaware of the options for increasing energy efficiency or the value of doing so. Additionally, there may be inadequate incentives for organizations and individuals to adopt energy-efficient technology [45,46,47].
Resistance to policy and regulatory measuresThere is opposition to policies and rules that are meant to make energy use more efficient, such as building codes, minimum energy performance standards, and requirements for energy labels. Policies that mandate the use of energy-efficient technology, for instance, may be met with resistance from businesses and individuals who view such mandates as an unnecessary burden or an unnecessary expense. Policies that prohibit the use of particular energy-intensive technologies or impose penalties for noncompliance may also meet opposition [48,49].
Limited technical capacitySome governments lack the necessary technical competence to fully adopt energy efficiency measures, and this is particularly true for developing nations. Some of these barriers include a scarcity of readily available data and knowledge about energy efficiency, as well as a shortage of trained people capable of designing, installing, and maintaining such technology. In addition, research and development funding for energy efficiency may be inadequate, slowing the introduction of cutting-edge efficiency measures [50,51,52].
Rebound EffectThe phenomenon of the rebound effect is multifaceted and poses a significant challenge to the achievement of energy efficiency improvements and reduced energy consumption. The rebound effect can be defined as the situation in which energy savings achieved through efficiency improvements are offset by an increase in energy consumption. The rebound effect manifests in two primary forms: direct and indirect [53]. Direct rebound occurs when the efficiency gains in using a particular technology translate into lower costs, which, in turn, incentivizes users to increase their consumption of the technology, thereby offsetting some or all of the energy savings [54]. In contrast, indirect rebound arises when the efficiency improvements lead to reductions in the cost of goods and services, and consumers, as a result, increase their spending, thereby offsetting the gains from energy efficiency improvements by increasing energy consumption [55].
Source: Own elaboration based on the literature.
Table 2. Top 10 Journals in Web of Science and Scopus for first query.
Table 2. Top 10 Journals in Web of Science and Scopus for first query.
Journals in WoSArticlesJournals in ScopusArticles
Energy Policy931Energy1724
Journal Of Cleaner Production860Energy Policy1232
Energy799Applied Energy1134
Energies775Energies831
Applied Energy550Journal Of Cleaner Production772
Sustainability550Sustainability575
Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews450Renewable Energy478
Energy and Buildings430Energy Conversion and Management468
Energy Economics388Energy And Buildings462
Energy Conversion and Management364Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews441
Source: Own elaboration based on data from Web of Science and Scopus.
Table 3. Top 10 Journals in Web of Science and Scopus for second query.
Table 3. Top 10 Journals in Web of Science and Scopus for second query.
Journals in WoSArticlesJournals in ScopusArticles
Contemporary Economic Policy6Energy Policy13
Energy Policy5Applied Energy6
American Economic Journal Economic Policy3Climate Policy4
Energy3Energy4
Oxford Review of Economic Policy3Energies3
Asian Economic Policy Review2Energy Economics3
Ecological Economics2Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions3
Energy Economics2International Journal of Energy Economics and Policy3
Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions2Renewable Energy3
Equilibrium Quarterly Journal of Economics and Economic Policy2Energy and Environment2
Source: Own elaboration based on data from Web of Science and Scopus.
Table 4. Solution of the problems faced in implementation of efficient energy consumption through economic policy.
Table 4. Solution of the problems faced in implementation of efficient energy consumption through economic policy.
IssuesSubsidiesTax IncentivesMarket-Based Mechanisms
Lack of financingIn order to combat the shortage of funding and make energy-efficient solutions more widely available and affordable, subsidies can provide direct financial assistance for their implementation.Offering tax credits or deductions for investments in energy efficiency is one way that government programs may help bring down the price of energy-saving technology and practices. This has the potential to increase the demand for and adoption of energy-efficient solutions.Market-based methods, such as cap-and-trade systems or carbon taxes, can place a price on carbon emissions, providing a financial incentive for firms and individuals to adopt energy-efficient technology and practices. As the price of carbon emissions rises, this might spur investment in efficient energy technologies.
Barriers to the adoption of energy efficiency technologiesBy providing financial support for promotion, dissemination of information, installation and demonstration of these technologies, research and development, and the creation of stakeholder networks, subsidies can address the lack of awareness and access to information about energy-efficient technologies. Increased public knowledge and the lower purchase prices made possible by tax incentives are two ways in which these kinds of technology might be made more widely available.By providing a financial incentive for companies and individuals to adopt energy-efficient technology, market-based processes can aid in spreading energy efficiency knowledge. This can reduce the barriers to adopting energy-efficient solutions and help people adjust to the new normal.
Resistance to policy and regulatory measuresSubsidies provide monetary assistance for the adoption of energy-efficient technology and practices, which can help overcome resistance to policy and regulatory initiatives. With this backing, energy-efficient solutions may be made more easily accessible and inexpensive, which in turn can boost adoption and lessen resistance to change. By making energy-efficient solutions more appealing and accessible and by lowering their cost, tax incentives can help diminish opposition to policy and regulatory actions.In order to lessen opposition to policy and regulatory measures, market-based mechanisms might offer a financial incentive for firms and individuals to adopt energy-efficient technology and practices.
Limited technical capacityProviding financing for energy efficiency research and development, as well as the training and development of trained professionals, is one way in which subsidies may help solve a shortage of technical competence.Tax breaks can help alleviate a lack of technical expertise by stimulating investment in energy efficiency research and development and making professions in energy efficiency more appealing.By providing a financial incentive for investment in energy efficiency R&D and the training of trained individuals, market-based methods can help alleviate the shortage of technical talent. To achieve this, market signals such as carbon pricing, emissions trading systems, and performance-based incentives are used to encourage people and companies to adopt more energy-efficient technologies and practices.
Rebound EffectIf the rebound effect proves to be considerable, it may be necessary to reevaluate the efficacy of subsidies for energy efficiency measures. In some instances, it may be necessary to curtail or terminate subsidies to prevent the rebound effect from nullifying potential energy savings. Nevertheless, it is crucial to consider the broader economic and social consequences of such a decision. Subsidies may be indispensable in promoting the adoption of energy-efficient technologies, particularly in low-income and disadvantaged communities, where the initial expenses associated with such technologies may represent a barrier to adoption.Tax incentives can serve as an effective tool to discourage excessive energy consumption, and one way of achieving this is by implementing taxes on energy consumption. This mechanism motivates individuals and businesses to curb their energy usage to avoid paying higher taxes. As a result, such a measure encourages more efficient energy use, as individuals and businesses may be inclined to seek out more energy-efficient technologies or modify their energy consumption behavior.Market-based mechanisms, including emissions trading or carbon taxes, can be employed as effective means of reducing the rebound effect. These mechanisms help internalize the negative externalities associated with energy use and incentivize energy-efficient behavior by raising the cost of energy consumption. This increased cost can motivate individuals and businesses to seek ways to reduce their energy consumption, thereby promoting more efficient energy use.
Source: Own elaboration based on literature.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Mushafiq, M.; Arisar, M.M.K.; Tariq, H.; Czapp, S. Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy: Comprehensive Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Review. Energies 2023, 16, 2381. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052381

AMA Style

Mushafiq M, Arisar MMK, Tariq H, Czapp S. Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy: Comprehensive Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Review. Energies. 2023; 16(5):2381. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052381

Chicago/Turabian Style

Mushafiq, Muhammad, Muzammil Muhammad Khan Arisar, Hanan Tariq, and Stanislaw Czapp. 2023. "Energy Efficiency and Economic Policy: Comprehensive Theoretical, Empirical, and Policy Review" Energies 16, no. 5: 2381. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052381

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop