Next Article in Journal
Thermogram Based Indirect Thermographic Temperature Measurement of Reactive Power Compensation Capacitors
Previous Article in Journal
Production of Substitute Natural Gas Integrated with Allam Cycle for Power Generation
Previous Article in Special Issue
Capacity Mechanisms in Europe and the US: A Comparative Analysis and a Real-Life Application for Greece
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Distribution System Management Model Based on the Cooperative Concept of Unifying the Multi-Owned Networks

by
Pornthep Chiraprawattrakun
and
Nopbhorn Leeprechanon
*
Department of Electrical and Computer Engineering, Faculty of Engineering, Thammasat University, Klong Luang, Pathum Thani 12120, Thailand
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2023, 16(5), 2163; https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052163
Submission received: 22 January 2023 / Revised: 10 February 2023 / Accepted: 13 February 2023 / Published: 23 February 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Electricity Market Reform and Deregulation)

Abstract

:
The growth of microgrids to fulfil electricity demand could lead to arguments or conflicts between the private microgrid system owners and the existing national distribution authority, especially in overlapping sales areas. The core issue identified in this paper is a distribution system management model based on the cooperative concept of unifying the multi-owned networks as a single system to ensure the natural monopoly function. This model can avoid complex wheeling charges across multi-owned grids within overlapping sales areas, in which all network users pay at the expense of the merged system charge. This paper proposes the model and shows numerical examples using a suitable distribution network pricing model to recover existing costs and plan for future system expansion. The proposed model and charging algorithm were tested on a modified IEEE 13 bus to examine their impacts. The result demonstrates that the model resolves the issues with the overlapping sales area and creates a fair scenario for the network users regarding the usage charges. Thailand is chosen as the primary reference area, as it is a country with an actual sample case for the argument.

1. Introduction

Though varying from country to country, the emergence of microgrids and distributed energy resources (DERs) worldwide has led to the development of local power markets. In most developing countries, DERs are widely known as small power producers (SPPs). The SPP programme was introduced in 1992 based on elements of the small power programme extracted from the Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act (PURPA 1978) of the United States [1]. When the SPPs are allowed to sell their excess generated capacity directly to consumers, in many cases, they decide to build their distribution systems to expand their customer bases at the retail level and eventually become a utility or a microgrid. There is a possibility that their sales areas will overlap, as mentioned in [2]. The microgrids with overlapping areas can be illustrated as shown in Figure 1.
This area could cause arguments with respect to competition and redundancy investment. For instance, as reported in [3,4], in Thailand, the argument arises from the overlapping areas between SPP networks and the existing state-owned distribution systems—especially in industrial estate areas where the networks are disconnected. It is more likely that similar issues will arise in countries with similar power sector structures to Thailand, such as Cambodia [5] and the Philippines [6]. Therefore, this requires a study of how to manage the microgrids and the state-owned distribution systems in the area to keep them on a level playing field and prevent redundancy investments.
For reasons of economic efficiency, in a power market, the separate multi-owned networks should be interconnected to become “a single physical multi-owned system” under natural monopoly conditions. Traditionally, this can compensate for other network usages by employing the power wheeling model. This analogy has been practically applied in the wholesale international electricity markets in Europe and North America. However, the wheeling model may not always facilitate fair competition. For example, one utility can be treated or charged for service differently from another generator or utility—especially from a system operator in its own network [7]. Moreover, some complexities in the wheeling charge calculations can arise in many cases, e.g., the cumulative charges based on the number of networks used, electricity loss compensation, and the generation company’s (GenCo’s) responsibility to its customers in each network.
Therefore, Ruff [7] suggests stopping wheeling across the multi-owned transmission system and proposes a combined single transmission operator to manage the use of the system as a natural monopoly. This suggestion is similar to the concept of the national transmission authority proposed in [8]. Although the concepts in [7,8] are for the transmission network, the same scheme can be applied to the distribution system. The combined single transmission operator can refer to a combined single distribution operator in a single physical multi-owned distribution system where a part of the network is owned by a distribution company (DisCo) or SPP. To coordinate all DERs in a single distribution system, Ashok et al. [9] and Mousavi et al. [10] introduced a distribution system operator (DSO) framework to handle this activity. However, they still did not consider the case for multi-owned distribution systems. Thus, there is a need to find an appropriate management model for solving the problem of multi-owned distribution systems in order to reduce the complexity of pricing across the system.
The assumption of the management model is to combine the network owners’ assets into a single distribution system. The single distribution operator will rely heavily on the cooperation of the network owners. This paper, therefore, proposes the concept of “the cooperatives” (co-ops). A cooperative is an association of persons united voluntarily to meet their common economic needs [11]. It operates based on three underlying essential principles, i.e., user ownership (the people who use a cooperative own it), user control (a democratic structure), and user benefits (fair and equitable benefit sharing) [12]. Some studies on successful cooperatives, such as [13,14], confirm that they can encourage engagement amongst their members.
One of the distinctive points of co-ops, especially for distribution systems, is the democratic structure that ensures the equitable voting rights of its members, as opposed to a company model where the voting rights depend on the number of shares. Therefore, the network owners can ensure that their ownership persists after integrating their assets into the single system. However, a fair asset assessment to determine the number of shares is still an essential prerequisite before joining a co-op due to the profit-sharing requirements.
From the studies on benefits and motivation for both cooperatives themselves and their members, as mentioned in [15,16], it is evident that the cooperative concept perfectly fits the needs of the proposed model. Therefore, this paper presents a distribution cooperative (DisCo-op) responsible for managing the integrated distribution system cooperatively. The proposed model is discussed in Section 3.
When the separated multi-owned distribution system becomes a combined single system, every network user must be subject to the same pricing methodology in order to ensure fairness and transparency.
Traditionally, a national electricity tariff—known as a uniform tariff (UT)—issued by state-run utilities is used as a benchmark for network usage pricing. Unfortunately, this is often inefficient [17], and the regulated firms tend to be overcapitalised [18]. For example, the embedded demand charge in the national electricity uniform tariff [19] consists of energy costs, transmission and distribution (T and D) systems, and a service charge [20,21]. However, it is calculated based on the postage stamp method to recover the cost of the entire national T and D system, which is the subsidy cost of the asset outside a local area. Therefore, a UT is not suitable for the combined single multi-owned system’s usage charge because the demand charge or distribution charge cannot guarantee the cost recovery of the local system.
At present, there are many pricing methodologies to determine the network usage charge, such as the traditional approaches reported in [22] and several pricing approaches developed for deregulated environments in [23]. The study of Thitapars et al. [4] is an example of applying one of these traditional wheeling charge methods to solve the issues in Thailand. Most of the approaches have focused on cost allocation and regulatory provisions for natural monopoly networks. However, some methods still levy unfair cross-subsidisation charges—for example, the postage stamp and contract path methods, because they are designed based on a service-based concept rather than the actual use of the network. Therefore, it is worth applying the studies on power flow tracing and sensitivity analysis [24,25,26,27] to measure the actual usage. Yang et al. [28] proposed an approach for allocating transmission costs based on optimal power flow (OPF) for the spot market. Li et al. [29] applied sensitivity analysis for transmission loss pricing; although their study focused only on the price for transmission loss, it showed that a reasonable charge should involve the power flow tracing approach. The methods based on power tracing (e.g., in [24,25,26,27]) are fair and transparent ways to recover the actual network usage cost, but they still need to be clarified with respect to the new investment costs—particularly in terms of when and where to reinforce the network.
There are several studies concerning the methodology used to determine a system usage charge. One of the concepts is the distribution use-of-system (DUoS) charge. A similar principle to the DUoS charge design has been reported in [30,31]. According to these studies, the charges should be economically efficient, transparent, and able to recover capital, operational, and administrative costs. Both Yang et al. [32] and Mancera et al. [33] introduced the allocation for operation and maintenance—or transmission costs—of existing networks for both used and unused capacities. Jenkins et al. [34] introduced a DUoS charge for future network reinforcement and a calculation method based on the time of use and the location of users. With this approach, a network user is charged for future investments only when breaching defined critical flows. There are two suggested scenarios to obtain critical flows, i.e., the peak period (maximum demand but minimum generation) and the off-peak period (minimum demand but maximum generation). Time-of-use pricing [35] is an approach based on the elasticity of demand. It aims to signal customers to flatten the load profile, enabling investment decisions to be postponed until the right time. These concepts can be extended to network reinforcement decisions.
With the current trend, rather than focusing on the network usage cost, studies now try to focus on finding optimal energy prices or a trading paradigm between prosumers and customers instead. For example, Li et al. [2] introduced an approach based on the Stackelberg game model to find an optimal energy price, focusing on the overlapping sales areas of microgrids. Likewise, the peer-to-peer trading studies [36,37,38,39,40] and the Nash mechanism for distribution marginal pricing described in [41] all aim for similar purposes. As mentioned earlier, with the increasing number of microgrids—particularly when they overlap—a redundancy of distribution systems could unnecessarily increase the network’s cost. Consequently, the electricity price will be higher than it should be, even though it is optimal for prosumers and customers. As long as both prosumers and customers use a distribution network, the network usage cost is unavoidable.
When focusing on the single distributor, it is now a single, physical, multi-owned distribution network. However, as long as the network owners maintain reciprocal charging for network access, the arguments will remain, especially in the overlapping areas. Moreover, the transactions will be more complicated. Therefore, there is a need to find a more straightforward pricing methodology for the use of multi-owned distribution systems. The method must be competitive for GenCos and satisfy the network owners fairly and equitably.
Based on the gaps in the aforementioned studies, the contribution of this paper to the literature is to resolve the following two major problems:
(i)
The argument between network owners in overlapping sales areas where there is a redundancy of investment in the distribution system due to the violation of the existing monopoly in power distribution.
(ii)
The difficulty in formulating a fair and non-discriminatory tariff for consumers across the distribution network when multiple grid owners are willing to physically combine their grids into a single multi-owned system.
The overview of the literature studies is summarised in Table 1.
The remainder of this paper is organised as follows: First, Section 2 formulates the problem to introduce a managerial model to help solve the issue of multi-owned distribution systems based on a cooperative concept called “Distribution Cooperative” (DisCo-op) to resolve the first major problem. Then, this model is discussed in detail in Section 3. To resolve the second major problem, Section 4 elaborates on and describes the use of system charges under the proposed DisCo-op model. The approach applies the principles of the concepts described in [24,34] and the qualified literature mentioned earlier. The purpose is to show how a DisCo-op collects revenue from its members to ensure system cost recovery and sufficient investment costs for future network expansion. There is no need to offer a new pricing technique for the unified system. Instead, the practical implementation based on the available pricing scheme has been investigated and only focuses on distribution and usage charges. The numerical example in Section 5 confirms that the proposed DisCo-op model can be implemented without wheeling transactions across network users. Section 6 illustrates the comparison between the DisCo-op model and the traditional wheeling model. Finally, some concluding remarks are given in Section 7.

2. Problem Formulation

As described above, distribution systems are no longer solely owned by major utilities or state-owned utilities. Instead, in developing countries, most parts of the national distribution systems (NDSs) are owned and operated by national distribution authorities (NDAs). The remaining parts of the systems, called private distribution systems (PDSs), are owned by the SPPs.

2.1. Unbundled Distribution System Management

Figure 2 illustrates the initial state of the distribution system management model after the private grid owners have joined the playing field. Every NDS and PDS has its own DSO internally, which acts independently. Without an electrical connection, there is a breach of the natural monopoly concept, causing economic inefficiency, and customers also lose the ability to choose their own suppliers.
Therefore, it is necessary to integrate the NDS and all PDSs to become a single, physical, multi-owned system, as shown in Figure 3. At this stage, a local power market is formed. Each grid owner can allow others to use its network. However, this requires wheeling charges to compensate the network owners for third-party access transactions.
Regarding the aforementioned difficulty of wheeling charges, a sample scenario is illustrated in Figure 4. Microgrids 1 and 2 are supposed to charge Microgrid 3 for wheeling through their distribution system to deliver the electricity to Customer 1. However, the actual transactions are: (1) Microgrid 1 charges Microgrid 2 and (2) Microgrid 2 charges Microgrid 3. Each charge rate could differ depending on the wheeling charge policy of each microgrid and its network cost. Furthermore, the more microgrids and customers there are, the higher the complexity of the transactions and calculations will be. Thus, the final cost is difficult to understand, especially for end customers.
Therefore, to resolve these issues, this paper aims to return the multi-owned distribution system to a combined single-ownership system—in other words, a virtual natural monopoly, as suggested in [7,8,9,10]. To establish this single owner, firstly, it requires a centralised business unit to act as a juristic person representing the system asset’s shareholders. Secondly, a centralised autonomous operator is required to coordinate the operation of each mini-DSO of the NDS and the PDSs.

2.2. Distribution System Management Model with Cooperative Concept

As mentioned in Section 1, the cooperative concept perfectly fits the needs of the proposed model. The juristic person should be an entity that operates under cooperative principles. Every grid owner who shares their assets with the cooperative can be treated as a member. Every member will be under the same regulations, have equal voting rights and be entitled to a dividend based on the proportion of their shared assets. This entity is called a “Distribution Cooperative” (DisCo-op).
For the operation unit, the definition is the same as the independent distribution system operator (iDSO). The iDSO will manage all information in integrated systems, monitor network conditions, and record the usage of each network user under a new acceptable grid code. The iDSO is not owned by any GenCo; thus, it can be assumed that there will be no conflict of interest amongst the grid owners who also own power generators. Once unfair advantages are removed, the market will be on a level playing field, minimising barriers to entry and paving the way for new players.
The proposed model for the DisCo-op and the iDSO is illustrated in Figure 5.

3. Distribution Cooperative (DisCo-Op) Model

3.1. Core Principles of Distribution Cooperatives

As outlined in [11], there are seven principles of cooperatives, as follows:
  • Voluntary and open membership;
  • Democratic member control;
  • Member economic participation;
  • Autonomy and independence;
  • Education, training, and information;
  • Cooperation among cooperatives;
  • Concern for the community.
The cooperative’s organisation is open to every member who is willing to accept the responsibilities of membership without discrimination; it is an independent and self-driven organisation run by its members in a democratic manner to make decisions and educate or help one another. Every member contributes to the organisation’s business and receives profits in return in the form of dividends based on the proportion of their contribution. In addition, the organisation can also aim for sustainable community development through its policies. These principles are blended and adapted to make up the fundamentals of the proposed distribution system management model.

3.2. Functions of Distribution Cooperatives

Once the NDAs and the SPPs agree to share their network and form a cooperative body (DisCo-op), the functions of the DisCo-op are as illustrated in Figure 6 and can be described as follows:

3.2.1. Ownership Function

This function is based on the fundamental cooperative concept. As shown in Figure 6a, a DisCo-op is made up of cooperative members who share their assets for mutual utilisation and mutual benefit. A central office or board of directors, which the members elect, oversees the cooperative business as a juristic person on behalf of the members by appointing managers and staff. Every member is subject to consensus regulations, under which the iDSO regulates the operational function and the DisCo-op regulates the ownership function. All earnings from shared assets are disbursed for expenses such as network operation and maintenance (O and M), administration, insurance, and miscellaneous costs. Then, the remaining capital is reserved for expansion and planning (E&P) investment as a long-term planning fund. Lastly, the net profit is distributed as a dividend. The proportion of the dividend depends on the proportion of the member’s shared assets.

3.2.2. Operational Function

As shown in Figure 6b, the operational functions are divided as follows:
The DisCo-op is an entity that takes responsibility as a market facilitator. The DisCo-op can provide services not only for the members, but also for other GenCos, e.g., the DERs and the prosumers. The DisCo-op can be treated as a natural monopoly to facilitate the optimal use of distribution networks.
The E and P and O and M functions perform actions for reinforcement of the integrated network.
The iDSO is an independent entity that performs control actions for the security and reliability of the entire integrated network by working closely and in coordination with the mini-DSOs.
Even though details of how an iDSO coordinates DERs are yet to be considered in this paper, it is worth adopting the framework described in [10] and passing only its functionality of market settlement to the DisCo-op.
Therefore, a DisCo-op, with underlying support from the iDSO, can be considered as a cooperation of the NDS and the PDS owners whose primary business is providing services on the integrated distribution system; it would be a jointly owned and democratically controlled enterprise that aims to meet the owners’ common economic, social, and cultural needs in a win–win strategy. With the single distribution system, the DisCo-op member can continue their business as usual without the need for confusing wheeling transactions. Moreover, its unified expansion and planning can reduce the chance of overlapping network construction in the future.

3.3. Recovery Return Concept

A DisCo-op is an organisation that must do business and distribute profit to its members. This section illustrates the big picture of the recovery return concept, which is discussed in more detail in Section 4.
With respect to the electricity trading depicted in Figure 6b, Equations (1) and (2) illustrates the operational functions as follows:
U T = M W h + T + D + S e r v i c e + T a x
D i D L i 0
A customer will still pay a uniform tariff (UT) to the utilities, i.e., NDAs or SPPs, depending on the service area. Usually, from Equation (1), the UT consists of an energy charge (MWh), transmission usage charge (T), distribution usage charge (D)—also known as a “peak demand charge”—service charges (S), and tax. The NDA passes the charges for MWh and T to GenCos/IPPs, because the NDA itself is only the distribution owner and does not have a generator. For the part of distribution networks that are now taken care of by the DisCo-op, a new distribution usage charge for the local system (DL) is calculated and charged to every network user i. The cost component of DL typically consists of operation and maintenance (O&M), expenses of the DisCo-op and iDSO, and a reserve for expansion and planning (E&P) or future network reinforcement. From the customer’s point of view, there are no changes because the DL is already bundled in the UT as a part of D. In addition, with Equation (2), the D is always greater than or equal to the total DL, because the UT rate is calculated from the whole distribution system under the NDA in the country—not just from the local system. The utilities can deduct the DL from each customer’s UT payment and then pass it on to the DisCo-op. On the other hand, from the perspective of the utilities that also own a network, rather than paying the O&M and E&P to reinforce their network, they can switch to paying only the DL to the DisCo-op instead. The utilities that have no network can still charge for the UT from the customers, but they no longer need to pay for wheeling to the network owners. They can switch to paying the DL to the DisCo-op.

3.4. Cooperative Members

Regarding the principles of cooperatives described in [11] and the “user benefit, user owner, and user control” concepts discussed in [12], the distribution owners—i.e., the NDAs and the PDS owners—are automatically entitled to be members of the DisCo-op. However, not every network user can be a cooperative member. The eligible cooperative members must do the same business and supply their products for mutual benefit, e.g., distribution systems.
The shareholding percentage of the owners is based on a benchmark cost of their network in the integrated system. This percentage is essential in distributing the profits back to the members as dividends at the end of the period, as shown in Equations (3) and (4).
S u r p l u s = i D L i E & P O & M + N R I
D i v i d e n d i = S u r p l u s × S h a r e s i
It should be noted that the shareholding percentage is used only for profit-sharing and withdrawal of membership prerequisites. The voting rights are equitable amongst the cooperative members regardless of shares.
Table 2 illustrates the concept of UT payment and dividends as described in Equations (1)–(4). This assumes a 10,000 GBP net return from investment (NRI), and the NDA and the SPPs hold 47.10% and 52.90% of the shares, respectively. D in the UT is assumed to be 76 GBP per kWh per year. It is noted that the total D in UT is higher than the total DL. However, the DL rate for an individual user is not necessarily lower than the UT, depending on the cost and usage of each user.

3.5. Boundaries of the Proposed Solution

In some countries, the NDS and the NDA are required by law for social equity, including rural electrification. Therefore, the proposed model can be applied only in specific areas, such as industrial estates, where a part of the NDS can be integrated with the PDS or the area has no NDS.
In addition, the NDA may have authority by law to either stimulate the distribution system or obtain rebates from the system even though it has already become a cooperative member. Therefore, the NDA might not be able to become a cooperative member unless accepted by every member. In Section 4, an approach that can support both cases is proposed, regardless of whether or not the NDA is a member of the cooperative.
The cooperative is an autonomous organisation through which the network is operated and managed by the members, such as a holding company. Nevertheless, the cooperation between members would not be sustainable without regulations upon which every member consensually agrees. Moreover, the cooperative should still be under-regulated by a national authority organisation so that the development of the network progresses in the same direction as national regulations and the national development plan. The cooperative’s regulations are essential and require a thoughtful design because the cooperative’s identity and members’ engagement should persist after applying the regulations. The authors assume that every member agrees on the fundamental cooperative regulations and agrees to accept the NDA as a member of the cooperative. Any additional regulations are yet to be considered in this study.

4. Distribution Use of Sharing System (DUoSS) Charges

In Section 3, the operational function of the DisCo-op and recovery return concept has been discussed. This functionality can be illustrated in Figure 6b. In this section, the recovery return concept is expanded to ensure that the DisCo-op can do distribution system business and return net investment gains to the members.
Focusing on the distribution usage charge for the local system (DL) for DisCo-op, it must be practical for every network user and able to resolve the second problem mentioned in Section 1. In this case, the NDAs can be considered network users but hold different functionality from the SPPs and the customers. The NDAs, by law, can either be charged for network patronage or receive a rebate from the system. The rebate can be for any purpose, but there are two main reasons. The first is to compensate for support from the main grid if the electricity in the local network has a shortage or exceeds demand. Secondly, because of the exclusion of the distribution usage component in the national UT, the NDA might set up a scheme to compensate the social equity factor in the national UT from the local system with an appropriate rate instead. These charges or rebates are also considered as a requirement for the network access charge.

4.1. Distribution Use-of-Sharing-System (DUoSS)

There are three significant features to consider for the network access charge: Firstly, it should support network growth. Secondly, it should continuously maintain network reliability and recover all operating costs. Both should be calculated based on each user’s contribution to a sharing system. Finally, it should compromise with the NDA in terms of its role and responsibilities. Therefore, this paper applies the concept of DUoS to come up with a novel distribution usage charge for the multi-owned distribution system, called the distribution use-of-sharing-system (DUoSS) charge, which can be expressed as follows:
DUoSS = t ( F I n v C t + O M C t )
The future network reinforcement cost ( F I n v C t ) is the construction cost for new lines to enhance the distribution network’s capability and the efficiency of period t. This cost can be expressed as the rate per the maximum capability of the network after enhancement, in GBP/kW. Therefore, this rate is estimated based on the future value (FV) of the construction cost. In an integrated network, the cost of each circuit could differ depending on its original book cost. It is assumed that a benchmark rate is already available for each circuit, and does not focus on an approach to determine the rate in this study. A user could be charged for DUoSS according to the accumulation of the benchmark cost on each circuit used for power flow. In other words, DUoSS charges will depend on the number of circuits or the line distance.
The O&M cost ( O M C t ) is calculated from the recurring costs in network operations during period t, i.e., wages, administration, network maintenance, and other miscellaneous costs (for example, see [3]). Typically, the recurring period in the calculation is annual and, thus, the cost is known as the equivalent annual cost (EAC). Nevertheless, in the proposed approach, the calculation can be performed for any period. Therefore, the term equivalent periodic cost (EPC) is used instead. Normally, the EAC can be determined by applying an annuity calculation method. However, when transforming into EPC, it should still guarantee that all of the O&M costs are recovered for that period. It should be noted that approaches to determining the EAC or EPC are not investigated in this study.
Using Equation (5), the DUoSS charge can be cumulatively calculated as a number for the defined calculation period t, and then the network users can be billed only once. The details of the calculation algorithm for each period are explained in Section 4.4.

4.2. Future Network Reinforcement Cost (FinvC)

Based on Jenkin et al.’s approach in [34], it is a general objective to recover the future network reinforcement cost. This paper magnifies this approach into DUoSS to consider the role and responsibility of the NDA, which is not a network user. This means that every party in the local network is now able to participate in the network reinforcement. The participation of each network user and the NDA can be defined as follows:
F I n v C a d j u s t e d = F I n v C + E q
F I n v C = F I n v C p + F I n v C c + F I n v C a
F I n v C p =   ( P G i , p o f f p e a k × Y i R W i , p )
F I n v C c =   ( P D i , c p e a k × Y i R W i , c )
F I n v C a =   ( R W i , p + R W i , c )
R W i , p = P G i , p p e a k × Y i
R W c = P D i , c o f f p e a k × Y i
Y i = n = 1 i {   y n ; f n d   f n c f + f n g   y n ; f n g   f n c f + f n d     0 ;   otherwise
E q = k E q k
E q k = A c t u a l   C o s t   F I n v C A c t u a l   C o s t × F I n v C k
A c t u a l   C o s t = n ( f n a × Y a n )
Y a n = {   y n ;   f n a   f n c f 0 ;   otherwise
In Equation (6), the future network reinforcement cost (FInvC) consists of the cumulative cost from each network user, as expressed in Equation (7), and an equaliser presented in Equations (14) and (15) to justify the slight difference between the calculation and the actual cost.
The cost of each user can be expressed as shown in Equations (8)–(10). Typically, the future investment cost is from the future growth of the network within a certain period—the cumulative benchmark future network reinforcement rate of each used circuit, followed by deductions for rewards or penalties. The cost for the SPPs and the customers is expressed in Equations (8) and (9), respectively. During the off-peak period, the network usage rating depends on the connected generators. Therefore, the SPPs are the network users and are responsible for the cost in this period. On the other hand, during the peak period, the network usage rating depends on the demand. Therefore, the customers are the network users and are responsible for the cost in this period.
Equation (10) can be used to calculate the cost for the NDA. Unlike the SPPs and the customers, the NDA is typically a distribution system service provider, not a network user. Therefore, it is not responsible for the network usage rating. However, as mentioned earlier, in the event that the NDA has the authority to stimulate or ask for some rebates from the system, the NDA can contribute to the distribution system by offering rewards and penalties. The reward and penalty scheme aims to reduce the network usage rating, as expressed in Equations (11) and (12). Rewards are for generators in the peak periods and loads in the off-peak periods, while penalties are the opposite. Equations (11) and (12) will become a reward or penalty depending on the benchmark future network reinforcement rate.
The benchmark future network reinforcement rate at circuit i (Yi), as expressed in Equation (13), is cumulative because the generators and loads can involve multiple networks or circuits. Therefore, the rate reflects the usage on every affected network. The decision to increase or reduce the rate of the charge will depend on the defined critical flow.
The critical flows can be defined based on the safety limit of a line’s capacity. For example, if a line has a maximum capacity of 100 MW, the safety limit capacity could be 80%, i.e., 80 MW. The Y i rate increases only on the lines where the usage equals or exceeds the critical flows based on this assumption. No future network reinforcement cost is calculated if the usage is lower than the critical flows. In other words, there is no need for further investment if the usage is lower than the line’s safety capacity. The new investments can be deferred until required.
In [34], the future network reinforcement cost was calculated in two periods, i.e., peak and off-peak periods. However, the calculation can be performed for any period using the proposed method. The period can be daily or hourly, depending on the requirement or policy. The Y i rate must be transformed into a daily or hourly rate as well. For example, if the requirement is every 12 h, at noon and midnight, the Y i rate for these calculations should be transformed into a half-day rate.
This approach starts from system configurations, i.e., benchmarking rate ( y n ) and critical flows. At a time for each defined period, a power flow analysis is carried out to identify the power flows in each line. Next, this information is used to calculate all Y i rates using Equation (13).
It should be noted that, usually, the obtained charge and the actual cost calculated from actual flows and the Y a n rate of a circuit—as expressed in Equations (16) and (17), respectively—are the same. However, they could be slightly different due to precise calculation or technical constraints. The equaliser in Equations (14) and (15) is for justification. The expressions not only provide leverage and maintain cost recovery, but also improve the productive efficiency of the tariff. Nevertheless, the proportion of each user’s responsibility will be the same.

4.3. Network Operation and Maintenance Cost (OMC)

From the perspective of network operation and maintenance, the cost for each user is defined as follows:
O M C = O M C a + O M C p + O M C c
O M C p = n ( W n o m × F n × f n , p )
O M C c = n ( W n o m × F n × f n , c )
O M C a = 1 × { ( O M C p + O M C c ) × ϕ r 1 + ϕ r ;   ϕ r 0 n E P C n o m × ϕ r ;   ϕ r < 0
F n = { f n c a p k f n , k ;   k f n , k 0 0 ;   k f n , k = 0
W n o m = E P C n o m × 1 + ϕ r f n c a p ; f n c a p 0 0 ; f n c a p = 0
E P C n o m = E P C n × ϕ U T I L I S E
| ϕ r |   1
ϕ U T I L I S E 0
The O&M costs should be charged to each network user according to their usage, as expressed in Equation (18). This paper uses Bialek’s approach [24], which is based on Kirchhoff’s current law and the proportional sharing principle, to trace and identify the power flow that each user has used in the network. Equations (19) and (20) can be used to calculate the charge amount for the SPPs and the customers, respectively. The obtained charge amount depends on the charge rate, sharing factor, and the amount of power flows used by each user in each line.
As mentioned earlier, the NDA is usually just a distribution service provider, not a network user. Therefore, the network users are only the SPPs and the customers of both the NDA and the SPPs. However, the NDA can still participate in the integrated distribution system through a regulatory policy factor ( ϕ r ). Accordingly, Equation (21) provides the O&M cost for the NDA while also considering the regulatory factor. This factor is discussed in the latter part of this section.
The sharing factor (F) is a special term introduced in DUoSS to indicate the line usage rating, as expressed in Equation (22). When the value of F is close to unity, it indicates that the line usage is approaching the safety capacity. If the factor often hits the safety limit, it indicates the need for a new network reinforcement investment.
The charge rate ( W n o m ) calculated by Equation (23) is the ratio between a line’s O&M cost ( E P C   n o m ) and its capacity ( f c a p n ), expressed in GBP/kW. Each line has an individual rate. Every power flow through the line will be charged at the line rate.
When focusing only on the charge rate factor ( W n o m × F n ), an inverse correlation is observed between this factor and the total usage of line n. The charge rate will decrease when the line usage rating increases, and vice versa. Therefore, this factor can be used to encourage the network users to use the network more efficiently.
The line’s O and M cost ( E P C   n o m ) can be determined using Equations (24) and (26). The utilisation factor ( ϕ U T I L I S E ) is another factor introduced in DUoSS to indicate that the DisCo-op either subsidises or increases the cost of the network. When the DisCo-op sets the factor to be greater than unity, a premium cost will be added to the network. Normally, this is used to improve the network’s reliability as a premium service provided by the DisCo-op. In addition, the factor can also be set to less than unity to subsidise the total cost of the network. Sometimes, the network may not be fully utilised, and the DisCo-op may decide to subsidise the cost of the unused capacity. The factor setup depends on the DisCo-op’s policy.
The regulatory factor ( ϕ r ), as expressed in Equations (21) and (25), is introduced in DUoSS to indicate the participation of the NDA in the distribution system. A positive ϕ r indicates an extra charge to be added to the O&M costs. This extra amount will be returned to the NDA for any purpose. When ϕ r is negative, the NDA will subsidise some of the network’s O&M costs incurred by the SPPs and the customers. This can be an explicit subsidisation to stimulate or patronise the integrated distribution system area, or for marketing purposes. The positivity or negativity of this factor depends on the regulatory policy of the NDA.
The power flow tracing methods proposed in [24,25,26,27] can be used to determine the electricity that flows through the network for each load and generator. When the flows of each user are determined, the charges that are based on the flows will be fair and reflect actual network usage. For simplicity, the DC load flows can be used as a tool to illustrate the power flows in the network. A detailed power flow analysis is unnecessary because the ratio of network users is not significantly different. This concept can be applied to both transmission and distribution without changing the system configurations.
Even though the O&M cost can be independently calculated for any period, it is recommended to calculate it for the same period as the future investment cost calculation.

4.4. DUoSS Calculation Algorithm

The calculation process of the DUoSS charge for each user is illustrated in Figure 7. The process starts with the information prepared for the system profile, such as each line’s capacity and cost. Then, the period for which to perform the DUoSS calculation is defined. Finally, the cost is calculated for the defined period to determine the EPC and Yi for each circuit or line.
Once this information is promptly prepared, the calculation is performed periodically. The DUoSS charges obtained from each periodic calculation are accumulated for each billing cycle, after which the charges are reset and restarted.

4.5. Profit Sharing

The application of the cooperative concept to the operation of the proposed model is illustrated in Figure 8. One well-known feature of a cooperative is the “patronage dividends”, which are those distributions of profits paid by the cooperative to their owners [42]. Patronage dividends are paid based on a portion of the business’s profit. Fundamentally, the actual dividend for each DisCo-op member is based on (1) how much they shared the system’s assets and (2) how much they used the cooperative’s services or product purchasing. As shown in Figure 8, although the main objectives of the proposed model must be network growth and sustainability, the cooperative can manage the surplus from both expenses and the network reinforcement to make more profit as long as the primary purpose remains. Eventually, all profits will be returned to the members based on shareholding and DUoSS payment proportions.
Regarding the principles of the cooperative, the second and third cooperative principles are “Member Democratic Control” and “Member Economic Participation”, respectively, which describe how members invest in the cooperative and benefit from its surplus, as well as the requirement of an equitable sharing process to distribute the surplus [43]. The profit-sharing or cooperative patronage dividend can be expressed as follows:
D i v i , t d = S u r p l u s t d × C o n t r i b i , t d
S u r p l u s t d = N R I t d E x p e n s e t d E & P t d
Contri m , t d = Invest m , t d + Spending m , t d i ( Invest m , t d + Spending m , t d
I n v e s t m , t d = S h a r e s m , t d + j ( F I n c C m , j R W m , j )
S p e n d i n g m , t d = m { O M C m , j ;   O M C m , j 0 0 ;   O M C m , j < 0
The algorithm used to determine the dividend is illustrated in Figure 9. In Equation (27), the dividend for a member is calculated based on the surplus that the cooperative makes and the member’s contribution. During a period td, the surplus, as expressed in Equation (28), is the profit after deducting all expenses from the net return on investments. The contribution, as expressed in Equation (29), is based on each member’s investment and total spending. The investment, as expressed in Equation (30), represents the shares and all future investment charges paid by each member until the end of the period. The shares can be purchased based on the total benchmark cost of the network that each member contributes to the local distribution system. The DisCo-op will evaluate the benchmark cost and register it as shares at the first opportunity after becoming a member. In Equation (31), the total spending is the payment for O and M from each member. It should be noted that the contribution is calculated only from positive payments in order to prevent negative contributions. Therefore, all negative amounts from rewards are excluded.

4.6. When the NDA Is Unavailable

In areas where the NDA is unavailable, the same approach can still be applied. The DisCo-op can choose to play the role of the NDA if required; it can provide a reward or charge a penalty to the SPPs or customers and set the regulatory factor itself.

5. DUoSS: Numerical Example

5.1. Simulation on an Integrated Test System

To illustrate the calculation based on a test system that can represent the actual system, the IEEE 13 bus test feeder [44] was chosen to represent a local power market area. The system depicted in Figure 10 is an integrated distribution system assumed to consist of the NDS and the PDS area. The simulation was performed in two sample periods, i.e., peak and off-peak periods, similar to the previous example.
The equivalent periodic cost (EPC) in the test system is assumed to be 990.00 GBP per half-day, as calculated from the equivalent monthly cost (EMC) of 62,400.00 GBP. The Y i , EPC, and line capacity for each circuit in the test system, along with the regulatory factor and the defined period of calculation, are presented in Table 3.
Table 4 also shows that customers have to pay a DUoSS charge of GBP 60.60 for network usage that exceeds the line capacity during peak periods, while the SPP does not need to pay due to its contribution during the peak period. Under the same approach, the SPP has to pay 400.00 GBP for excess generation during the off-peak period when breaching the critical flows of lines AA-AB and AB-N. At the same time, the customers are rewarded with 10.60 GBP for their contributions during this period.
The DisCo-op can consider investing this money to reinforce the lines where safety capacity is often breached. Meanwhile, there is no charge for lines with usage below the safety limit, which means that the line capacity is sufficient for current usage and no reinforcement is required.
Table 5 shows the calculation of O and M cost based on the approach in Equations (18)–(26), where the utilisation factor ( ϕ U T I L I S E ) and the regulatory factor ( ϕ r ) are set to unity (100%) and 0.05 (5%), respectively. It can be observed that, because of the unused lines, the total DUoSS charge for O and M collected from the user per period is only GBP 890.00, while the EPC is 990.00 GBP. This is an indicator of overinvestment. The DisCo-op is responsible for the cost of the unused lines.
Table 6 illustrates a summary of the responsibilities of each user in the integrated network. Every network user, including the SPP and the NDA, is responsible for the DUoSS charges. The customer charges are mainly derived from their actual electricity usage. The SPP charges come from the unused excess power generation. The charge for the NDA is a reward to the users who help reduce the network usage rating and the regulatory factors. Lastly, the cost of the unused parts of the network, along with any overinvestments, is the responsibility of DisCo-op.
The simulation was performed for one day only. Thus, the DUoSS charge was 2430.00 GBP (or 2230.00 GBP excluding the unused lines), as shown in Table 5. Therefore, if the same pattern in the simulation is repeated every day for a month (30 days), the accumulated charges would be 66,900.00 GBP.
After all DUoSS charges are collected from the users, the DisCo-op will make a regulatory payment to the NDA. However, if the regulatory factor is a negative value, the NDA will be billed for the DUoSS charges instead.
When considering the traditional wheeling approach, the NDA and the SPP will reciprocally charge one another for only the customer usage at Nodes D and Y. Table 7 shows wheeling charges for every user. During the off-peak period, the NDA network will use the entire power flow from the SPP network. Therefore, the NDA network usage rate will increase by 0.3090 GBP/kW as the wheeling rate from the SPP increases. On the other hand, during the peak period, the SPP network will use some of the power flows from the NDA network. In this case, it is about 0.27 MW. Therefore, the cost of SPP is increased by 0.0214 GBP/kW as a proportion of the NDA charge rate. This is even more complicated when more customers are on other networks, as illustrated in Figure 4.
This simulation demonstrates that DUoSS—a straightforward approach—can be used to determine the charges regardless of the network area. This not only eliminates the additional wheeling transactions but also ensures that the usage charges are based on the same approach for every user.
Based on the algorithm presented in Figure 9, Table 8 shows the dividend calculation against the contribution of each network user, which is accumulated into a total dividend for each cooperative member. It is assumed that the surplus made by the cooperative is 10,000.00 GBP and that the SPP and NDA hold the shares of the cooperative initiated from the value of the NDS and the PDS in the integrated system. In this simulation, the EPC is assumed to represent the shares instead of the actual initiated value of the NDS and the PDS, so that the contribution to the dividend will be observable. As shown in Table 7, the NDA receives a dividend of 4709.62 GBP, while the SPP receives a dividend of 5290.38 GBP. Both dividends are based on the investment and spending of each network user. Hence, the dividend is distributed fairly and equitably and complies with the patronage dividend concept.

5.2. Simulation of the PEA’s Distribution System: Amata City Industrial Estate

Figure 11 depicts a part of the existing distribution system at the Amata City Industrial Estate under Thailand’s Provincial Electricity Authority (PEA); it illustrates many possibilities to tie SPP distribution lines to the PEA network from the PEA’s point of view. One of the best possibilities is to use a substation at a high-voltage (HV) level.
Based on the report from the PEA in [3] on the wheeling charge rate for the SPPs, Figure 12 and Table 9 illustrate the summary of the actual data from the Amata City Industrial Estate in August 2018. The input data in the PEA report indicate that the network is always in a normal condition, without any signals for network reinforcement. The defined maximum capacity (DMC) of the PEA for the Amata City Industrial Estate is 410.40 MW. The defined load for customers is 277.00 MW, although the total actual usage of the system is only 66.26 MW. This simulation assumes that all customers in the AKA01 section (the red section in Figure 11) belong to the SPP. This means that the SPP will inject only 9.68 MW into the system, leaving 344.14 MW (i.e., 84% of the network capacity) unused.
In [3], two new methodologies were proposed for the PEA that can be applied to any industrial estate area instead of using the national rate: the postage stamp method and a method proposed by Thammasat University (the TU cost-based method). These methods proposed the wheeling rate for the Amata City Industrial Estate at 58.76 THB/kW/month and 61.69 THB/kW/month, respectively. In [19], the distribution usage uniform tariff (D) of the PEA was defined at 132.93 THB/kW/month.
Table 10 illustrates the comparison between the DUoSS charge and other wheeling charge methods in the PEA report for the Amata City Industrial Estate. The table shows that, due to ineffective network utilisation, none of the methods in the PEA report can recover the costs of the distribution system in the Amata City Industrial Estate. Therefore, this cost has to be subsidised by the PEA.
The table also shows that the DUoSS charge always guarantees cost recovery. Therefore, the charges for SPPs and their customers are higher than those in other methods when the network is only ~16% utilised. The DUoSS charge can give almost the same rate as the TU cost-based method if the DisCo-op sets the utilisation factor to the rate of network usage, i.e., 0.16 or 16%. However, this means that the DisCo-op will subsidise the other 84% of the cost.
Table 11 illustrates the charges when the network is simulated at ~80% utilisation (i.e., five times the current usage). When the distribution system is more effectively utilised without any critical flows being breached, and with the same usage ratios, the DUoSS charge rate is cheaper, and the total charges remain the same as when the network is only 16% utilised. This property can be used as a signal to make both the customers and the DisCo-op aware of the network utilisation, as well as to indicate plans for future network reinforcement.
As mentioned in Section 1, the results in Table 10 and Table 11 confirm that the distribution usage charges (D) in the uniform tariff (UT) cannot guarantee the cost recovery of a local system. In Table 10, the charge is less than the actual cost. Meanwhile, the charge from the tariff exceeds the actual cost even though the network is still not fully utilised, as shown in Table 11.
It is noted that, from the study data which is obtained from the PEA report as shown in Table 10, the utilisation rate of the network in the Amata City Industrial Estate is about 16%. This data is used to scale up the simulation in other cases and to observe when the network is fully utilised, as illustrated in Table 11. It is found that when the usage rate is above 80%, the safety limit of some parts of the network is breached, which causes an additional cost for network reinforcement. To prevent confusion, it is worth keeping the cost components of both scenarios on the same page. Therefore, the simulation between the network is ~16% utilised, and ~80% utilised is chosen for comparison.
In the postage stamp, TU cost-based, and national rate methods, the information of each customer’s usage is absent because the charges are only designed for the SPPs. Therefore, the SPPs have to distribute the charges to their customers themselves. With the DUoSS charge, every usage detail is traceable. The usage pattern and the pricing signal for individual users, including the SPP, can be captured. The charge for future investment can be calculated and sent to related users fairly and equitably. The user behaviour data are also a good source for extensive data analysis in the future.

6. Comparison between the DisCo-Op Model and the Traditional Wheeling Model

This paper introduces DisCo-op—a novel distribution system management model based on the concept of the cooperative—to manage a combined, single, multi-owned distribution system. The core issue is resolving the multiple ownership problems in overlapping areas, ensuring cooperation amongst distribution owners and eliminating the complexity of the wheeling model and investment redundancy. This issue is relevant to almost all countries with similar power sector structures. Table 12 presents a comparison between the DisCo-op model, the multi-owned distribution system when each network is physically separated (Figure 2) and the integrated distribution system with a traditional wheeling model (Figure 3).
Regarding economic efficiency, the comparison is made based on network expansion, planning, and a chance of redundancy in network construction. Therefore, the DisCo-op is the best way when compared to the others because it unites the direction of network expansion and the planning of the entire network.
From the network operation point of view, the independent network is the easiest way to operate. However, in the DisCo-op model, the iDSO is established to help operate the network.
Regarding network investment and reinforcement, the DUoSS can guarantee deferring the investment to the right time, while the reinforcement in another model depends only on the network owner’s decision.
Regarding the network users, the DisCo-op treats every network user without discrimination. Every user will be charged according to their actual usage.
The DUoSS is designed with the ability to calculate by using a simple spreadsheet. As a result, the customers can quickly understand their usage charges, rewards and penalties in a period with little understanding of engineering and financial terms, such as power flow analysis, network benchmark cost or related factors. It differs from the wheeling model, which may require a complicated explanation, as mentioned in Figure 4.
The DisCo-op model opens up competition on generation. The DisCo-op will be a single juristic person for the distribution network, where the new players can compete with others with the same rules and regulations as the other.
For the network owners themselves, the core principle of the DisCo-op is profit sharing from mutual benefit. However, unlike the separated and integrated networks with wheeling charges, the profit is from the sole business.
Regarding network management, it is obvious that the separated network is the most straightforward model for managing. However, the DisCo-op model is designed to manage the network as simply as possible through the cooperatives and iDSO.

7. Conclusions

When the DisCo-op model is adopted, the SPPs and NDAs can cooperate for their mutual benefit. Due to the unique character of the cooperative, the voting rights of each member are equal in order to ensure a balance of power and secure the system. Meanwhile, the net profit of the DisCo-op is returned to each member in the form of dividends. The cooperative treats all of its members fairly and equitably and distributes benefits based on their contributions.
Under the proposed model, a straightforward approach for determining the DUoSS charges between grid owners and customers is introduced to replace the existing complicated wheeling charge calculations. When testing the model, the results showed that this approach can create a fair scenario because it is calculated based on the actual usage of every network user.
To describe the fair scenario, in the numerical example for Amata City Industrial Estate, the amount of the total charge will always recover the actual cost for any usage rating, regardless of the subsidisation. Moreover, the numerical example for the integrated IEEE test system ensures that the proportion of the network cost is distributed to each user fairly, depending on the actual network usage.
Furthermore, once the distribution networks have become a single system, it is possible to identify congested lines that breach their safety capacity as well as the unused lines in the entire network. Therefore, overinvestment can be avoided by utilising this information.
Finally, due to the key components of the DUoSS charge (i.e., for O and M and future investment), all essential costs are already covered in the charge rate. Therefore, this approach can guarantee that the network will always have sufficient funds to maintain and continuously develop its infrastructure.
It should be noted that the proposed DUoSS methodology possesses a plug-and-play feature. As long as the business model and profit-sharing persist, the future investment and O and M charges in the DUoSS charge can be replaced with other, more suitable methodologies depending on each circumstance and requirement in a local context.
Instead of the redundancy of distribution system investment amongst many network owners—i.e., the SPPs and NDAs—especially in overlapping areas, they can form business alliances to obtain mutual benefit and improve economic efficiency. Moreover, their cooperation can improve the distribution system, making it highly reliable and sustainable.

Author Contributions

Project administration, methodology, software, validation, formal analysis, resources, data curation, writing—original draft preparation, visualization, funding acquisition, P.C.; conceptualization, methodology, validation, formal analysis, verification, investigation, resources, writing—review and editing, supervision, N.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The research leading to this study has received funding from the Faculty of Engineering at Thammasat University under grant agreement No 01/2559.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

Financial support granted by the faculty of engineering at Thammasat University is greatly appreciated and acknowledged.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Abbreviations

DDistribution usage charge in UT
DLDistribution usage charge for local system
DisCo-opDistribution cooperative
DSODistribution system operator
DUoSSDistribution use-of-sharing-system charge, expressed in GBP
E and PExpansion and planning
iDSOIndependent distribution system operator
NRINet return on investment
MWhMegawatt hours
NDANational distribution authority
NDSNational distribution system
NRINet return on investment
O and MOperation and maintenance
PDSPrivate distribution system
SPPSmall power producer
TTransmission usage charge in UT
UTUniform tariff
Indices
iNetwork user i in distribution system
jDUoSS calculation period in period td
kNetwork user k     { a ,   p ,   c }
a = national distribution authority (NDA)
p = small power producer (SPP)
c = customer
mDisCo-op’s member m
nDistribution line n of the playing field
tDUoSS calculation period
t d Dividend calculation period
Parameters
y n Benchmark future network reinforcement rate of line n (GBP/kW)
f n c f Critical flow of line n (kW)
ϕ r NDA’s regulatory factor
ϕ U T I L I S E DisCo-op’s utilisation factor
f n c a p   Maximum capacity of line n (MW)
E P C n Actual network operation and maintenance equivalent periodic cost of line n (GBP)
S h a r e s i , t d Number of shares held by member i at period td (GBP)
Variables
F I n v C t Future network reinforcement cost calculated for period t (GBP)
O M C t Operation and maintenance cost of the existing network calculated for period t (GBP)
E q Equalisation cost to balance actual cost and calculated cost (GBP)
F I n v C k   Future network reinforcement cost for user k (GBP)
O M C k   Operation and maintenance cost for user k (GBP)
E q k   Equalisation cost for user k (GBP)
Y i Benchmark future network reinforcement rate at circuit i (GBP/kW)
P G i , k o f f p e a k   Power flow from user k’s generation in circuit i in the off-peak period (kW)
P D i , k p e a k   Power flow for user k’s demand in circuit i in the peak period (kW)
R W i , p   Monetary reward for network contribution for the SPP for circuit i (GBP)
R W i , c   Monetary reward for network contribution for the customers for circuit i (GBP)
f n a Actual flows of line n (kW)
f n d Power flow caused by demand in line n (kW)
f n g Power flow caused by generation in line n (kW)
E P C   n o m Network operation and maintenance equivalent periodic cost of line n (GBP)
F n Sharing factor of line n
W n o m Operation and maintenance charge rate of line n (GBP/kW)
f n , k Power flows in line n that belong to user k (MW)
S u r p l u s t d The surplus of the cooperative for period td (GBP)
E x p e n s e t d   Actual O and M expenses for period td (GBP)
I n c o m e t d   Actual income collected from DUoSS for period td (GBP)
E & P t d   Actual saving reserved for future expansion and planning for period td (GBP)
D i v m , t d Dividend for member m for period td (GBP)
C o n t r i b m , t d   Contribution of member m for period td (GBP)
I n v e s t m , t d   Amount of investment from member m for period td (GBP)
S p e n d m , t d   Spending of member m for period td (GBP)
F I n v C m , j Future network reinforcement charge paid by member m for period j (GBP)
R W m , j Reward received by member m for period j (GBP)
O M C m , j Charge for network operation and maintenance paid by member m for period j (GBP)

References

  1. Sukunta, M. PURPA-Qualifying Capacity Increases, but It’s Still a Small Portion of Added Renewables. Available online: https://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.php?id=36912 (accessed on 16 August 2018).
  2. Li, J.; Ma, G.; Li, T.; Chen, W.; Gu, Y. A Stackelberg game approach for demand response management of multi-microgrids with overlapping sales areas. Sci. China Inf. Sci. 2019, 62, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. PEA. Pricing Distribution System Use or Connection Service (Wheeling Charge); The Provincial Electricity Authority (PEA): Bangkok, Thailand, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  4. Thitapars, S.; Prukpanit, P.; Leeprechanon, N. The Distribution Service Pricing for Third-Party Access to Preserve the Responsibility of National Distribution Service Operator in Thailand: The Case of Industrial Estates. Int. Trans. J. Eng. Manag. Appl. Sci. Technol. 2022, 13, 1–18. [Google Scholar]
  5. Energy Sector Management Assistance Program. Mini Grids in Cambodia: A Case Study of a Success Story; The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank Group: Washington, DC, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  6. ADB. Philippines Energy Sector Assessment, Strategy, and Road Map; Asian Development Bank: Mandaluyong, Philippines, 2018; p. 56. [Google Scholar]
  7. Ruff, L.E. Stop Wheeling and Start Dealing: Resolving the Transmission Dilemma. Electr. J. 1994, 7, 24–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Leeprechanon, N.; David, A.K.; Moorthy, S.S.; Liu, F. Transition to an electricity market a model for developing countries. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2002, 17, 885–894. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Jadhav, A.M.; Abhyankar, A.R. Emergence of distribution system operator in the Indian power sector and possible way ahead. Energy Policy 2022, 160, 112650. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Mousavi, M.; Wu, M. A DSO Framework for Market Participation of DER Aggregators in Unbalanced Distribution Networks. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2022, 37, 2247–2258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. COOP Cooperative Identity, Values & Principles. Available online: https://www.ica.coop/en/cooperatives/cooperative-identity (accessed on 9 May 2021).
  12. Frederick, D.A. Co-ops 101: An Introduction to Cooperatives; United States Department of Agriculture: Washington, DC, USA, 1997.
  13. Tremblay, E.; Hupper, A.; Waring, T.M. Co-operatives exhibit greater behavioral cooperation than comparablebusinesses: Experimental evidence. J. Co-Oper. Organ. Manag. 2019, 7, 100092. [Google Scholar]
  14. Frank, T.; Mbabazize, M.; Shukla, J. Savings and Credit Cooperatives (Sacco’s) Services’ Terms and Members’ Economic Development in Rwanda: A Case Study of Zigama Sacco Ltd. Int. J. Community Coop. Stud. 2015, 3, 1–56. [Google Scholar]
  15. Ghauri, S.; Mazzarol, T.; Soutar, G.N. Why do SMEs join Co-operatives? A comparison of SME owner-managers and Co-operative executives views. J. Co-op. Organ. Manag. 2021, 9, 100128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Verhees, F.J.H.M.; Sergaki, P.; Duk, G.V. Building up active membership in cooperatives. A Mediterr. J. Econ. Agric. Environ. 2015, 14, 42–52. [Google Scholar]
  17. Shleifer, A. A Theory of Yardstick Competition. RAND J. Econ. 1985, 16, 319–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Spann, R.M. Rate of Return Regulation and Efficiency in Production: An Empirical Test of the Averch-Johnson Thesis. Bell J. Econ. Manag. Sci. 1974, 5, 38–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. EGAT. EGAT ft Annoucement. Available online: http://www.egat.co.th/ft/20200807%20Direct%20Rate_Nov2018_Additional%2016Jul2020.pdf (accessed on 16 July 2020).
  20. Energy Policy and Planning Office. PricewaterhouseCoopers Thailand: Electricity Power Tariff; Energy Policy and Planning Office: Bangkok, Thailand, 2005.
  21. Levett, J.L. Distribution Wheeling for Small Power Producers Within Industrial Estates; National Energy Policy Office: Bangkok, Thailand, 1997.
  22. Lee, W.; Lin, C.; Swift, L. Wheeling Charge under a Deregulated Environment. IEEE Trans. Ind. Appl. 2001, 37, 1778–1783. [Google Scholar]
  23. Sood, Y.; Padhy, N.; Gupta, H. Wheeling of power under deregulated environment of power system-a bibliographical survey. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2002, 17, 870–878. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Bialek, J. Tracing the flow of electricity. IEE Proc.—Gener. Transm. Distrib. 1996, 143, 313–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Bialek, J. Topological generation and load distribution factors for supplement charge allocation in transmission open access. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 1997, 12, 1185–1193. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Kirschen, D.; Allan, R.; Strbac, G. Contributions of individual generators to loads and flows. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 1997, 12, 52–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Ng, W.Y. Generalized Generation Distribution Factors for Power System Security Evaluations. IEEE Trans. Power Appar. Syst. 1981, PAS-100, 1001–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Yang, Z.; Lei, X.; Yu, J.; Lin, J. Objective transmission cost allocation based on marginal usage of power network in spot market. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2020, 118, 105799. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Li, R.; Yokoyama, R.; Chen, L. A Pricing Method for Transmission Loss Based on Sensitivity Analysis. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2006, 21, 1201–1208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Cory, B. Pricing in electricity transmission and distribution. In Proceedings of the 8th Mediterranean Electrotechnical Conference on Industrial Applications in Power Systems, Computer Science and Telecommunications (MELECON 96), IEEE, Bari, Italy, 16 May 1996; Volume 1. [Google Scholar]
  31. Picciariello, A.; Reneses, J.; Frias, P.; Söder, L. Distributed generation and distribution pricing: Why do we need new tariff design methodologies? Electr. Power Syst. Res. 2015, 119, 7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Yang, Z.; Zhong, H.; Xia, Q.; Kang, C.; Chen, T.; Li, Y. A structural transmission cost allocation scheme based on capacity usage identification. IEEE Transactions on Power Systems 2016, 31, 2876–2884. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Mancera, C.T.; Monroy, A.C. Pricing of Distribution Networks with Distributed Generation: Application of Nodal Pricing. In Proceedings of the Innovative Smart Grid Technologies (ISGT Latin America), 2011 IEEE PES Conference, IEEE, Medellin, Colombia, 19–21 October 2011. [Google Scholar]
  34. Jenkins, N.; Ekanayake, J.B.; Strbac, G. Distributed Generation. The Institution of Engineering and Technology: London, UK, 2010; pp. 143–164. [Google Scholar]
  35. Gholizadeh-Roshanagh, R.; Zare, K. Electric power distribution system expansion planning considering cost elasticity of demand. IET Gener. Transm. Distrib. 2019, 13, 5229–5236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Mazzola, L.; Denzler, A.; Christen, R. Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading in Microgrids: Towards an Integrated Open and Distributed Market. In Proceedings of the 2020 International Conference on Electrical Engineering and Control Technologies (CEECT), IEEE, Melbourne, VIC, Australia, 10–13 December 2020. [Google Scholar]
  37. Paudel, A.; Beng, G.H. A Hierarchical Peer-to-Peer Energy Trading in Community Microgrid Distribution Systems. In Proceedings of the 2018 IEEE Power & Energy Society General Meeting (PESGM), IEEE, Portland, OR, USA, 5–10 August 2018. [Google Scholar]
  38. Khajeh, H.; Firoozi, H.; Laaksonen, H.; Shafie-Khah, M. Peer-to-peer flexibility trading of end-users at distribution networks. CIRED—Open Access Proc. J. 2020, 2020, 797–799. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Zhong, W.; Xie, S.; Xie, K.; Yang, Q.; Xie, L. Cooperative P2P Energy Trading in Active Distribution Networks: An MILP-Based Nash Bargaining Solution. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2020, 12, 1264–1276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Teotia, F.; Mathuria, P.; Bhakar, R. Peer-to-peer local electricity market platform pricing strategies for prosumers. IET Gener. Transm. Distrib. 2020, 14, 4388–4397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Zhong, W.; Xie, K.; Liu, Y.; Xie, S.; Xie, L. Nash Mechanisms for Market Design Based on Distribution Locational Marginal Prices. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2022, 37, 4297–4309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Hayes, A. Patronage Dividend. Available online: https://www.investopedia.com/terms/p/patronagedividend.asp (accessed on 5 May 2021).
  43. Cathy, C.-O. How Worker Co-ops Decide to Share Profits. Available online: https://cdi.coop/profit-sharing-in-worker-coops/ (accessed on 13 March 2021).
  44. IEEE Resources | PES Test Feeder—13-bus Feeder. Available online: http://site.ieee.org/pes-testfeeders/files/2017/08/feeder13.zip (accessed on 17 May 2020).
Figure 1. Microgrids with overlapping areas.
Figure 1. Microgrids with overlapping areas.
Energies 16 02163 g001
Figure 2. Multi-owned distribution systems when each network is physically separated.
Figure 2. Multi-owned distribution systems when each network is physically separated.
Energies 16 02163 g002
Figure 3. Integrated distribution system with a traditional wheeling model.
Figure 3. Integrated distribution system with a traditional wheeling model.
Energies 16 02163 g003
Figure 4. The complexity of wheeling charge transactions.
Figure 4. The complexity of wheeling charge transactions.
Energies 16 02163 g004
Figure 5. Distribution operation and management structure with the cooperative concept.
Figure 5. Distribution operation and management structure with the cooperative concept.
Energies 16 02163 g005
Figure 6. Distribution operation and management structure based on the cooperative concept. (a) Ownership function. (b) Operational function.
Figure 6. Distribution operation and management structure based on the cooperative concept. (a) Ownership function. (b) Operational function.
Energies 16 02163 g006
Figure 7. DUoSS calculation algorithm.
Figure 7. DUoSS calculation algorithm.
Energies 16 02163 g007
Figure 8. Operation of the proposed model under cooperative principles.
Figure 8. Operation of the proposed model under cooperative principles.
Energies 16 02163 g008
Figure 9. Dividend calculation algorithm.
Figure 9. Dividend calculation algorithm.
Energies 16 02163 g009
Figure 10. Integrated IEEE 13 bus test system in peak and off-peak periods.
Figure 10. Integrated IEEE 13 bus test system in peak and off-peak periods.
Energies 16 02163 g010
Figure 11. A part of the distribution system of the Amata City Industrial Estate under Thailand’s Provincial Electricity Authority (PEA).
Figure 11. A part of the distribution system of the Amata City Industrial Estate under Thailand’s Provincial Electricity Authority (PEA).
Energies 16 02163 g011
Figure 12. Grandfathered concept of the distribution system of the Amata City Industrial Estate from Thailand’s Provincial Electricity Authority (PEA).
Figure 12. Grandfathered concept of the distribution system of the Amata City Industrial Estate from Thailand’s Provincial Electricity Authority (PEA).
Energies 16 02163 g012
Table 1. Literature review summaries.
Table 1. Literature review summaries.
Literature GroupRef.Summary
Transmission and Distribution management model[7,8,9,10]The primary focus of this group is the transmission and distribution management model. These models are interesting but may need to adapt a bit for overlapping sales areas. Therefore, these concepts have been applied to develop a novel distribution management model in this paper.
Cooperatives model[11,12,13,14,15,16]The primary focus of this group is the concept of cooperatives. Therefore, these papers are used to support the cooperative concept of the proposed model.
Wheeling Charges[4,22,23]These methods are traditional methods that are currently used. A method is chosen from this group for comparison in the numerical example.
Power flows analysis and tracing[24,25,26,27,28,29]Some approaches are chosen to be fundamental calculations of the distribution pricing model in this paper.
Distribution Use-of-System charges (DUoS)[30,31,32,33,34,35]Some approaches are chosen to adapt to the distribution pricing model in this paper.
Optimal price for Electricity Trading[2,36,37,38,39,40,41]The primary focus of this group is to review the current trend in energy pricing studies. A gap regarding network usage pricing is identified.
Table 2. Distribution usage charge and dividend for each member.
Table 2. Distribution usage charge and dividend for each member.
Network UsersDL (GBP)E&P (GBP)O&M (GBP)D (GBP)
A31.5622 58.3014
B113.9299 108.2740
C148.2242 466.4110
D34.2901 77.0411
Total—NDA328.00645.1000322.9064710.0275
E194.2448 322.7397
F170.0302 209.8953
G33.0661 40.4049
H115.1716 82.0384
Total—SPP512.51270.0000512.5127655.0783
NRI (GBP)10,000.0000 Surplus (GBP)10,000.0000
Shares (%) Dividend (GBP)
NDA47.10 4710.0000
SPP52.90 5290.0000
Table 3. Integrated IEEE 13 bus test system’s network cost.
Table 3. Integrated IEEE 13 bus test system’s network cost.
CircuitYi
(GBP/kW/Period)
Safety Limit
Capacity * (MW)
Maximum
Capacity (MW)
EMC
(GBP/Circuit)
EPC
(GBP/Circuit)
AA-AB
AA-A, AB-N
A-B, N-O
0.0116.0020.003000.0050.00
0.0116.0020.003000.0050.00
0.0116.0020.003000.0050.00
B-C, O-P
C-D, P-Q
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
B-E, O-R
E-F, R-S
B-G, O-T
G-H, T-U
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
0.0116.0020.003000.0050.00
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
H-I, U-V
G-J, T-W
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
0.031.001.251800.0030.00
J-K, W-X0.031.001.251800.0030.00
J-L, W-Y0.031.001.251800.0030.00
G-M, T-Z0.0116.0020.003000.0050.00
Total 62,400.00990.00
Defined PeriodPeak9.00 a.m.–9.00 p.m.Off-peak9.00 p.m.–9.00 a.m.
Regulatory factor5%
* Critical flows.
Table 4. DUoSS charge calculation for network reinforcement for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
Table 4. DUoSS charge calculation for network reinforcement for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
CircuitService ProviderPower Flows (MW)Critical Flows
(MW)
Yi
(GBP/kW/
Period)
Cumulative Network Reinforcement Cost
(GBP/kW)
Network Reinforcement
Charges (GBP)
Total Charges
(GBP)
Actual Cost
(GBP)
PeakOff-Peak PeakOff-PeakPeakOff-Peak
AA-ABNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.27Energies 16 02163 i00219.4716.000.010.00−0.010.000.000.00194.70
AA-ANDAEnergies 16 02163 i0013.27Energies 16 02163 i0010.5316.000.010.000.000.000.000.000.00
A-BNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0013.27Energies 16 02163 i0010.5316.000.010.000.000.000.000.000.00
B-CNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.40Energies 16 02163 i0010.251.000.030.000.000.000.000.000.00
B-ENDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.40Energies 16 02163 i0010.031.000.030.000.000.000.000.000.00
B-GNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0012.47Energies 16 02163 i0010.2516.000.010.000.000.000.000.000.00
C-DSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.40Energies 16 02163 i0010.251.000.030.000.000.000.000.000.00
E-FNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.23Energies 16 02163 i0010.021.000.030.000.000.000.000.000.00
G-HNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0011.01Energies 16 02163 i0010.031.000.030.030.000.03 × 170 = 5.100.005.1030.30
G-JNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.30Energies 16 02163 i0010.031.000.030.000.000.000.000.000.00
G-MNDA - -16.000.010.000.000.000.000.000.00
H-INDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.84Energies 16 02163 i0010.021.000.030.000.000.03 × 840 = 25.200.0025.200.00
J-KNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.17Energies 16 02163 i0010.011.000.030.030.000.000.000.000.00
J-LNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.13Energies 16 02163 i0010.011.000.030.000.000.000.000.000.00
AB-NSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.27Energies 16 02163 i00219.4716.000.010.00−0.020.00−0.02 × −2000 = 400.00400.00194.70
N-OSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0013.27Energies 16 02163 i0010.5316.000.010.00−0.020.000.000.000.00
O-PSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.40Energies 16 02163 i0010.251.000.030.00−0.020.000.000.000.00
O-RSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.40Energies 16 02163 i0010.031.000.030.00−0.020.00−0.02 × 10 = −0.20−0.200.00
O-TSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0012.47Energies 16 02163 i0010.2516.000.010.00−0.020.00−0.02 × 200 = −4.00−4.000.00
P-QSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.40Energies 16 02163 i0010.251.000.030.00−0.020.00−0.02 × 250 = −5.00−5.000.00
R-SSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.23Energies 16 02163 i0010.021.000.030.00−0.020.00−0.02 × 20 = −0.40−0.400.00
T-USPPEnergies 16 02163 i0011.01Energies 16 02163 i0010.031.000.030.03−0.020.03 × 170 = 5.10−0.02 × 10 = −0.204.9030.30
T-WSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.30Energies 16 02163 i0010.031.000.030.00−0.020.000.000.000.00
T-ZSPP - -16.000.010.00−0.020.000.000.000.00
U-VSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.84Energies 16 02163 i0010.021.000.030.00−0.020.03 × 840 = 25.20−0.02 × 20 = −0.4024.800.00
W-XSPPEnergies 16 02163 i0010.17Energies 16 02163 i0010.011.000.030.03−0.020.00−0.02 × 10 = −0.20−0.200.00
W-YNDAEnergies 16 02163 i0010.13Energies 16 02163 i0010.011.000.030.00−0.020.00−0.02 × 10 = −0.20−0.200.00
Total 60.60389.40450.00450.00
Equalisation 0.00
Accumulative Charges 450.00450.00
* Energies 16 02163 i001 Power Flows by current. Energies 16 02163 i002 Power Flows against current.
Table 5. DUoSS calculation for O and M for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
Table 5. DUoSS calculation for O and M for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
CircuitEPC (GBP) ϕUTILISE = 1Line Capacity
(MW)
Rate   ( W n o m )
(GBP/kW)
Sharing Factor (F)
PeakOff-Peak
AA-AB
AA-A
A-B
50.0020.000.002674.07411.0272
50.0020.000.00266.116237.7358
50.0020.000.00266.116237.7358
B-C
B-E
30.001.250.02523.12505.0000
30.001.250.02523.125041.6667
B-G
C-D
E-F
G-H
50.0020.000.00268.097280.0000
30.001.250.02523.12505.0000
30.001.250.02525.434862.5000
30.001.250.02521.237641.6667
G-J
G-M
30.001.250.02524.166762.5000
50.0020.000.0026N/AN/A
H-I30.001.250.02521.488162.5000
J-K30.001.250.02527.3529125.0000
J-L30.001.250.02529.6154125.0000
AB-N50.0020.000.002674.07411.0272
N-O50.0020.000.00266.116237.7358
O-P30.001.250.02523.12505.0000
O-R30.001.250.02523.125041.6667
O-T50.0020.000.00268.097280.0000
P-Q30.001.250.02523.12505.0000
R-S30.001.250.02525.434862.5000
T-U30.001.250.02521.237641.6667
T-W30.001.250.02524.166762.5000
T-Z50.0020.000.0026N/AN/A
U-V30.001.250.02521.488162.5000
W-X30.001.250.02527.3529125.0000
W-Y30.001.250.02529.6154125.0000
Total990.00
UserTotal Usages (MW)Charges (GBP)Total (GBP)
PeakOff-PeakPeakOff-Peak
AA (NDA)ϕr = 0.05−44.50−44.50−89.00
D1.60001.500075.84113.88189.72
E0.51000.050018.8412.5331.38
F0.92000.120057.0056.57113.57
G3.48001.000061.9082.70144.61
H0.68000.060014.3714.6429.01
I4.20000.1400102.5360.77163.30
K0.85000.070058.4251.39109.81
L0.65000.070052.1051.39103.47
N (DER)0.000037.88000.00102.14102.14
Q1.26610.750082.2787.76170.03
R0.36810.020021.5811.4933.07
S0.72800.060060.6954.48115.17
T2.51160.400080.5361.81142.34
U0.53810.030017.1013.5930.69
V3.49870.0800116.0158.68174.69
X0.70810.040061.1550.34111.49
Y0.54150.040054.1850.34104.52
Unused Circuits (DisCo-op)100.00100.00200.00
Total 990.00990.001980.00
Table 6. Total DUoSS charge summary for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
Table 6. Total DUoSS charge summary for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
UserService
Provider
FInvC
(GBP)
Reward
(GBP)
O&M
(GBP)
Total DUoSS
(GBP)
ENDA0.00000.000031.381331.3813
FNDA0.00000.0000113.5679113.5679
GNDA0.00000.0000144.6048144.6048
HNDA5.10000.000029.009134.1091
INDA25.20000.0000163.2949188.4949
KNDA0.00000.0000109.8071109.8071
LNDA0.00000.0000103.4725103.4725
YNDA0.0000−0.2000104.5152104.3152
Total—NDA Customer30.3000−0.2000799.6528829.7528
DSPP0.00000.0000189.7206189.7206
QSPP0.0000−5.0000170.0302165.0302
RSPP0.0000−0.200033.066132.8661
SSPP0.0000−0.4000115.1716114.7716
TSPP0.0000-4.0000142.3388138.3388
USPP5.1000−0.200030.694035.594
VSPP25.2000−0.4000174.6921199.4921
XSPP0.0000−0.2000111.4920111.292
Total—SPP Customer30.3000−10.4000967.2054987.1054
Regulatory Payment—NDA −89.0000−89.0000
Unused Lines—DisCo-op 200.0000200.0000
Total 400.0000−10.60001980.00002430.0000
Table 7. Wheeling approach simulation for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
Table 7. Wheeling approach simulation for the integrated IEEE 13 bus test system.
UserService
Provider
Postage Stamp Rate
(GBP/kW)
Power Flows
(MW)
Network Usage Charges
(GBP)
Total
(GBP)
PeakOff-PeakPeakOff-PeakPeakOff-Peak
ENDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.170.0147.67645.894953.5713
FNDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.230.0264.503411.789876.2932
GNDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30901.160.2325.3213117.8981443.2195
HNDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.170.0147.67645.894953.5713
INDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.840.02235.577511.7898247.3673
KNDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.170.0147.67645.894953.5713
LNDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.130.0136.45845.894942.3533
YSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.130.0142.95613.090446.0465
Total—NDA Customer 887.4977168.14781055.6455
DNDA0.28040.2804 + 0.30900.400.25112.179882.6078194.7876
QSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.400.25132.17253.0904209.4328
RSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.170.0156.17336.180859.2637
SSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.230.0275.999261.808282.1800
TSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30901.160.2383.30033.0904445.1085
USPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.170.0156.17336.180859.2637
VSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.840.02277.56233.0904283.7431
XSPP0.3090 + 0.02140.30900.170.0156.17333.090459.2637
Total—SPP Customer 1149.7341203.65741353.3915
Total 2037.2318371.80522409.0370
Table 8. Dividends for each member.
Table 8. Dividends for each member.
Network UserShares
(GBP)
FInvC
(GBP)
O&M
(GBP)
ContributionDividend
(GBP)
Surplus10,000.00
E 0.000031.5622
F 0.0000113.9299
G 0.0000148.2242
H 5.100029.1901
I 25.2000163.6568
K 0.0000109.9881
L 0.0000103.6535
Y 0.0000104.5152
NDA 0.00000.0000
Total540.0030.3000804.72000.47104709.62
D 0.0000194.2448
Q 0.0000170.0302
R 0.000033.0661
S 0.0000115.1716
T 0.0000142.3388
U 5.100035.794
V 25.2000199.8921
X 0.0000111.492
SPP 0.0000194.2448
Total450.0030.30001064.28000.52905290.38
Grand Total990.0060.60001869.00001.000010,000.00
Table 9. System parameters of the Amata City Industrial Estate from [3] (August 2018).
Table 9. System parameters of the Amata City Industrial Estate from [3] (August 2018).
System Load Parameters for Wheeling Charge Calculation
Designed Capacity (kW)540,000.00
Defined Maximum Capacity (DMC) (kW)410,400.00
Defined Load for Customers (kW)277,000.00
Reserved Wheeling Capacity (kW)133,400.00
Contract Wheeling Capacity (kW)-
FeederMV—Maximum Demand (kW)FeederMV—Maximum Demand (kW)
AKA019683.65AKA058988.05
AKA0211,150.27AKA0611,244.88
AKA0312,921.05AKA07360.00
AKA04257.20AKA0811,653.98
Total66,259.08
Table 10. Cost recovery comparison between the study results in the PEA’s report [3] and the DisCo-op DUoSS charge when the network is used at ~16% utilisation.
Table 10. Cost recovery comparison between the study results in the PEA’s report [3] and the DisCo-op DUoSS charge when the network is used at ~16% utilisation.
MethodPEA’s
Contribution
ϕr = 5%
(THB ‘000)
SPP and
SPP’s Customers
(THB ‘000)
PEA’s Customers
(THB ‘000)
Total
(THB ‘000)
Actual Cost
(THB ‘000
per Month)
TOU Tariff-1287.257520.578807.8224,113.30
Postage Stamp-568.973324.123893.0924,113.30
TU Cost-Based−194.65597.423490.333893.0924,113.30
DisCo-op DUoSS—Monthly
ϕUTILISE = 1−1205.672820.3522,498.6224,113.3024,113.30
ϕUTILISE = 0.16−194.66455.353632.403893.093893.09
Network Usage Rate = Actual Use/DMC = 66.26/410.40 = 0.16
Table 11. Cost recovery comparison between the study results in the PEA’s report [3] and the DisCo-op DUoSS charge when the network is simulated at ~80% utilisation.
Table 11. Cost recovery comparison between the study results in the PEA’s report [3] and the DisCo-op DUoSS charge when the network is simulated at ~80% utilisation.
MethodPEA’s
Contribution
ϕr = 5%
(THB ‘000)
SPP and
SPP’s Customers
(THB ‘000)
PEA’s Customers
(THB ‘000)
Total
(THB ‘000)
Actual Cost
(THB ‘000
per Month)
TOU Tariff-6436.2437,602.8644,039.1024,113.30
Postage Stamp-2844.8416,620.6219,465.4624,113.30
TU Cost-Based−973.272987.0917,451.6519,465.4624,113.30
DUoSS—Monthly
ϕUTILISE = 1−1205.672820.3522,498.6224,113.3024,113.30
ϕUTILISE = 0.81−973.272276.7318,162.0119,465.4619,465.46
Network Usage Rate = Actual Use/DMC = (66.26 × 5)/410.40 = 0.81
Table 12. Comparison between the DisCo-op model and the multiple ownership wheeling model.
Table 12. Comparison between the DisCo-op model and the multiple ownership wheeling model.
TopicDisCo-op ModelMulti-Owned Distribution
System When Each Network Is Physically Separated
Integrated Distribution
System with a Traditional Wheeling Model
1. Economic Efficiency
-
Network expansion and planning
-
Redundancy network construction prevention
BestWorstModerate
2. Network Operation
-
Easy to operate the network
ModerateBestModerate
3. Network Reinforcement
-
Network reliability
-
Defer investment to the right time
BestModerateModerate
4. Non-DiscriminationBestN/AWorst
5. Easy to UnderstandModerateBestWorst
6. Competition in GenerationsBestWorstModerate
7. Benefit to the Network Owners
-
Profit sharing
BestN/AWorst
-
Simple network management scheme
ModerateBestWorst
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Chiraprawattrakun, P.; Leeprechanon, N. Distribution System Management Model Based on the Cooperative Concept of Unifying the Multi-Owned Networks. Energies 2023, 16, 2163. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052163

AMA Style

Chiraprawattrakun P, Leeprechanon N. Distribution System Management Model Based on the Cooperative Concept of Unifying the Multi-Owned Networks. Energies. 2023; 16(5):2163. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052163

Chicago/Turabian Style

Chiraprawattrakun, Pornthep, and Nopbhorn Leeprechanon. 2023. "Distribution System Management Model Based on the Cooperative Concept of Unifying the Multi-Owned Networks" Energies 16, no. 5: 2163. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16052163

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop