Next Article in Journal
Optimal and Non-Optimal MACD Parameter Values and Their Ranges for Stock-Index Futures: A Comparative Study of Nikkei, Dow Jones, and Nasdaq
Previous Article in Journal
Target2: The Silent Bailout System That Keeps the Euro Afloat
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

ECB Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Bank Default Risk

Department of Economics, Ghent University, Sint-Pietersplein 5, 9000 Ghent, Belgium
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16(12), 507; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16120507
Submission received: 28 October 2023 / Revised: 30 November 2023 / Accepted: 1 December 2023 / Published: 7 December 2023
(This article belongs to the Section Banking and Finance)

Abstract

:
Euro Area banks have been confronted with unprecedented monetary policy actions by the ECB. Monetary policy may affect bank risk profiles, but the consequences may differ for short-term risk versus long-term or structural bank risk. We empirically investigated the association between the ECB’s monetary policy stance and market-perceived short-term and long-term bank risk, using the term structure of default risk captured by bank CDS spreads. The results demonstrated that, during the period 2009–2020, ECB expansionary monetary policy diminished bank default risk in the short term. However, we did not observe a similar decline in long-term bank default risk, since we documented that monetary stimulus is associated with a steepening of the bank default risk curve. The reduction of bank default risk was most pronounced during the sovereign debt crisis and for periphery Euro Area banks. From 2018 onwards, monetary policy accommodation is associated with increased bank default risk, both short-term and structurally, which is consistent with the risk-taking hypothesis under which banks engage in excessive risk-taking behavior in their loan and securities portfolios to compensate profitability pressure caused by persistently low rates. The increase in perceived default risk is especially visible for banks with a high reliance on deposit funding.
JEL Classification:
C58; G21; G32; E52

1. Introduction

How does a prolonged period of accommodative monetary policy affect the risk profile of banks? Since banks are the dominant channel of financial intermediation in the Euro Area, this question is not only relevant to assess the effectiveness of the transmission of monetary policy, but also to assess the ultimate impact of monetary policy on financial stability. Since the issue is high on the agenda of central banks and macroprudential authorities, it has received increasing attention in academic research. While there is little doubt about the beneficial effect of lower policy rates on the risk profile of banks in the short run, there is a lively debate about the consequences of long spells of low or even negative interest rates on bank risk-taking, both theoretically and empirically. We contribute to this literature by distinguishing between the short-run and longer-term effects of ECB monetary policy on bank default risk, using the entire term structure of bank CDS spreads. Since CDS spreads are a market-based measure of bank credit risk, analyzing not only the level of default risk, as has been performed in almost all prior studies, but also the slope of the risk curve across the maturity structure allowed us to disentangle how monetary policy affects bank risk profiles in the short run and in the longer run, as judged by market participants.
Our results demonstrated that, during the period 2009–2020, the ECB’s expansionary monetary policy diminished bank default risk in the short term, confirming the results in Soenen and Vander Vennet (2022). However, we did not observe a similar decline in long-term bank default risk, since we documented that monetary stimulus is associated with a steepening of the bank default risk curve. The reduction of bank default risk was most pronounced during the sovereign debt crisis and for periphery Euro Area banks. From 2018 onwards, monetary policy accommodation is associated with increased bank default risk, both short-term and structurally, which is consistent with the risk-taking hypothesis under which banks engage in excessive risk-taking behavior in their loan and securities portfolios to compensate profitability pressure caused by persistently low rates. The increase in perceived default risk is especially visible for banks with a high reliance on deposit funding. Our findings have implications for the conducting of monetary policy and the use of macroprudential tools to contain bank risk-taking in periods of accommodative monetary policy.
The paper unfolds in the following way. In Section 2, we review the literature and elaborate on our contribution. In Section 3 and Section 4, we provide the details on the data and the empirical specification. Section 5 contains the empirical results. Section 6 concludes the paper and formulates policy considerations.

2. Literature and Hypotheses

Monetary policy may affect bank profitability and bank risk through various channels. In order to formulate the hypotheses, we considered the different channels and argue how they influence bank risk in the short run and in the long run. In the short run, there is little doubt that stimulating monetary policy benefits banks. Lower short-term interest rates cause higher net interest margins, since a decrease in interest rates affects short-term bank liabilities, such as demand and savings deposits, immediately, while lower interest rates are only applied to new loans (Jäger and Grigoriadis 2017; Saunders and Cornett 2018). Moreover, banks relying on wholesale funding benefit from the lower interbank rates (Szczerbowicz 2015). At the same time, lower interest rates increase asset prices, allowing banks to realize capital gains in their securities portfolio, boosting profits and capital (Falagiarda and Reitz 2015). Lower policy rates are typically associated with better macroeconomic conditions through the interest rate channel (Peersman 2004). The more-benign economic environment is associated with lower non-performing loans (NPLs) for banks and, hence, lower bank asset risk. Lower interest rates also increase the value of real assets, such as plant and equipment or house prices, which serve as collateral, so that collateralized bank loans become more secure. All these effects should improve the risk profile of banks in the short run.
In the literature, there is broad agreement that the accommodative monetary policy of the ECB stimulated the economy (Altavilla et al. 2018, 2019) and that bank funding and lending conditions were eased considerably (Rostagno et al. 2019). Moreover, the monetary policy actions taken by the ECB during the banking and sovereign crisis contributed positively to bank stability because they restored the capacity of the banking system to provide financial intermediation services, and they acted as a circuit breaker of adverse macrofinancial feedback loops (Albertazzi et al. 2020). The hypothesis is that these beneficial effects should be reflected in lower short-run bank default risk. Hence, our expectation is that accommodative monetary policy is associated with lower bank risk, reflected in lower CDS spreads (Soenen and Vander Vennet 2022). In the longer run, however, persistently low interest rates may affect bank risk behavior and, hence, alter the banks’ risk profile. First, most banks still derive the largest part of their profits from their core intermediation activity. When interest rates remain low for longer periods, the net margin compresses because there is a zero lower bound on retail deposit rates (Heider et al. 2019). Moreover, when the central bank undertakes asset purchases, this pushes down the yield curve, which causes bank interest margins to contract even more. Banks may try to maintain profitability by cutting costs and shifting to non-interest income (Brei et al. 2020; Lopez et al. 2020), but eventually low policy rates are associated with lower bank profitability (Borio and Gambacorta 2017; Claessens et al. 2018; Molyneux et al. 2019). Altavilla et al. (2019) argued that, initially, the ECB’s Asset Purchase Program and negative deposit facility rates had a close to zero net effect on banks’ ROA since positive effects (capital gains on securities and better credit quality) compensated the decline in the banks’ net interest margins, but they acknowledge that a low-for-long interest rate environment eventually does hurt bank profitability. In a low for longer interest rate environment, capital gains are temporary in nature. Once realized, they are gone. Worse, when QE stops, interest rates may rise and cause valuation losses on securities accounted at a fair value. In the same vein, once banks have absorbed their legacy NPLs, the positive effect on profitability diminishes or, when policy rates are increased and the business cycle turns, banks may be confronted with new bad loans (Bonfim and Soares 2018).
How do these longer-term effects translate into the banks’ risk profile? From a risk perspective, the pressure on bank profitability implies a lower capacity to generate capital internally, which adversely affects bank risk and impairs the transmission of monetary policy (Gambacorta and Shin 2018). More importantly, beyond this static effect, bank risk behavior may change. Over a longer horizon, compressing margins may cause a search for yield and push banks to increase their risk appetite (Adrian and Shin 2009; Borio and Zhu 2012). One concern relates to the potential increase in risk-taking reflected in the underpricing of risk. Indeed the objective of accommodating monetary policy measures is to promote bank portfolio rebalancing away from safe assets; hence, a higher bank risk appetite may be warranted as it is an important part of the transmission mechanism. The relevant question is whether or not monetary policy causes excessive risk-taking by banks, since this could hamper financial stability, and this may be reflected in higher bank CDS spreads. Rajan (2006) argued that accommodative monetary policy implies lower market rates, which may induce a search-for-yield by financial institutions. Banks confronted with diminishing revenues as a consequence of lower rates may increase their risk appetite and invest in higher-risk loans and securities (Altunbas et al. 2012; Jiménez et al. 2014; Paligorova and Santos 2017). Central bank balance sheet policies may expose the banks to subsequent liquidity shocks (Acharya et al. 2023). Finally, prolonged periods of low policy rates, accompanied by depressed long-term interest rates due to quantitative easing, may induce banks to extrapolate low-risk assessments into their lending decisions, and this may increase their risk tolerance (Adrian and Shin 2009; Borio and Zhu 2012). For the Euro Area banking system, the evidence of risk-taking behavior is mixed. For the case of the ECB’s negative deposit facility rate, Demiralp et al. (2021); Heider et al. (2019) and Schelling and Towbin (2022) found that banks more reliant on retail deposit funding cut lending relative to their peers, but also that these intermediaries tilted their loan supply towards more-risky borrowers. Also, it has been shown that lower policy rates induce risk-taking more for banks with lower capital ratios (Bonfim and Soares 2018; Jiménez et al. 2014). However, Albertazzi et al. (2020) examined how banks price risk, and they concluded that the additional risk taken in the post-2014 period was not inadequately priced. Similar mixed evidence has been reported for the rebalancing of bank securities portfolios. Bubeck et al. (2020) reported that, since the introduction of negative policy rates, banks reliant on deposit funding exhibit search-for-yield behavior in the composition of their securities portfolios. Crosignani et al. (2020) and Carpinelli and Crosignani (2021) showed that banks have used inexpensive ECB LTRO funding to increase their exposures to domestic government bonds, thereby exacerbating the bank–sovereign nexus. This behavior caused the emergence of the bank–sovereign doom loop. Albertazzi et al. (2020) confirmed that, since the start of the APP, banks’ bond portfolios have shifted through an active rebalancing out of the safest categories of securities into other investment-grade bonds. However, they argued that, over the same period, this effect was more than offset by positive rating migration caused by improved macroeconomic conditions. Moreover, they showed that banks’ portfolio rebalancing has not translated into a loading up of domestic sovereign debt securities, not even in those economies where such securities offer higher yields. Lamers et al. (2022) showed that, after a period of risk-seeking behavior in the sovereign crisis era, banks shifted towards a more-sound risk–return trade-off in the management of their sovereign portfolios post-2014, i.e., the period of asset purchases by the ECB, which is characterized by declining long-term rates and, hence, higher incentives for yield-seeking behavior.
From this overview, we concluded that the impact of stimulating monetary policy on bank default risk may depend on the time horizon. Some of the risk-taking incentives may play in the short run, but they may be compensated by higher profitability, which may allow banks to increase their capital buffers. The lower short-run default risk should be reflected in lower CDS spreads, as demonstrated in Soenen and Vander Vennet (2022). Some risk-taking effects may only become apparent over a longer time horizon. When banks accumulate risky assets, investors may exert market discipline by reassessing the banks’ risk profile, which should be observable in the CDS market. The contribution of this study is that we explicitly distinguish between short-term and long-term effects on bank credit risk associated with monetary policy. Since the ECB gradually implemented stronger measures aimed at credit easing and quantitative easing, and even introduced negative policy rates, this time-varying policy setting should offer fertile ground to investigate the impact of ECB policies on perceived short-term and structural Euro Area bank risk. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to use the entire term structure of bank default risk captured by their CDS spreads for different maturities to analyze this research question. Moreover, we extend the analysis by investigating differences across core and periphery Euro Area banks and by considering the reliance of banks on deposit funding as a distinctive characteristic determining the relationship between monetary policy and the banks’ perceived credit risk profile. We tested the following hypotheses:
Hypothesis 1.
Accommodative monetary policy is associated with lower bank risk in the short run. We expect a negative relationship between accommodative monetary policy and short-term bank default risk.
Hypothesis 2.
Accommodative monetary policy is associated with an increasing slope of the credit risk yield curve. Due to incentives for risk-taking, bank CDS spreads for longer maturities increase more or decline less than short-term CDS spreads.
Hypothesis 3.
Banks with a higher reliance on deposit funding have stronger incentives for risk-taking behavior due to the zero lower bound on retail deposits.

3. Data and Sample Selection

We constructed a dataset containing the daily CDS spreads of banks, daily market variables, and yearly bank-specific control variables. The CDS spreads were retrieved from Markit. The bank-specific and market variables were obtained from BankFocus and Refinitiv, respectively. We limited the sample to banks that met the selection criteria with regard to their CDS spreads1 and bank-specific variables2.
The application of the selection criteria resulted in a sample of 45 banks from 9 Euro Area countries during the period of 2009–2020. These banks represent a large share of the Euro Area banking sector. The sample period covers the post-crisis era and includes both the Great Financial Crisis, the sovereign debt crisis in Europe, and the start of the corona pandemic. An overview of the banks in the sample is provided in Table 1.

3.1. Term Structure of Bank Default Risk

We captured bank default risk by their CDS spreads because they are a market-based, unbiased measure of bank default risk (Altavilla et al. 2018). Our dataset consisted of CDS spreads on senior bonds with maturities between 6 months and 20 years, which we used to estimate the term structure of bank default risk, i.e., banks’ default risk at different maturity dates. Similar to the yield curve estimation of government bonds, we used a regression analysis, where CDS spreads are explained by a number of factors. This method, first applied in Nelson and Siegel (1987) and refined in Svensson (1994) and Diebold and Li (2006), allows the identification of various yield curve shapes. In this paper, we used the yield curve estimation method developed in Svensson (1994), which is also used by the ECB. The shape of the yield curve is explained by a four-factor model, which are interpreted as the level, slope, and two curvatures. We aggregated daily CDS spreads into a weekly default risk curve3. Hence, for each bank and each week in our sample, we estimated the following model:
C D S i , t , w ( τ ) = β i , 0 , w + β i , 1 , w 1 e λ 1 τ λ 1 τ + β i , 2 , w 1 e λ 1 τ λ 1 τ e λ 1 τ + β i , 3 , w 1 e λ 2 τ λ 2 τ e λ 2 τ
where C D S i , t , w ( τ ) is the CDS spread of bank i on day t in week w, with a remaining maturity τ . The first loading β i , 0 , w captures the long-run level of the default risk curve of bank i in week w. Similarly, the loading on the slope of the default risk curve is captured by β i , 1 , w . The loadings on the first and second curvature factors are β i , 2 , w and β i , 3 , w , respectively.
Since we are interested in capturing the order of magnitude of the slope of the yield curve on a weekly basis, we opted for the parsimonious model specification as in Svensson (1994) and Diebold and Li (2006). We argue that the model parameters of Svensson (1994) can be more efficiently estimated in small samples than in, e.g., the arbitrage-free Nelson–Siegel model of Christensen et al. (2009). Furthermore, Coroneo et al. (2011) showed that, although the Nelson–Siegel model is empirical in nature, the overlap with the level, slope, and curvature loadings of arbitrage-free models is significant.
In Figure 1, we show a graphical representation of the four factors. The level of the default risk curve can be interpreted as the long-run credit risk of the bank, since the other factors affect the default risk curve in the short and medium term. Hence, after both the slope and curvature factors have converged to 0, the level is the only factor that remains to capture the shape of the default risk curve. The slope of the default risk curve is captured by the second factor, since this factor decays from 1 at a hypothetical maturity of 0 months towards 0. Negative values for the loading of the slope factor, β i , 2 , w , represent an upward-sloping default risk curve. Finally, the curvatures of the default risk curve are identified by the third and fourth factor. The factor increases from zero, reaches a maximum, and subsequently, converges back towards 0. The speed of adjustment of both the slope and curvature factors is determined by the decay rate λ 1 and λ 2 . Similar to Diebold and Li (2006), we chose the value of the decay rate such that it maximizes the curvature loading in the medium term, which we approximate as maturities between 30 and 60 months. The values that maximize the loadings on the medium term at exactly 30 and 60 months are λ 1 = 0.0609 and λ 2 = 0.0299 , respectively4. Figure 1 displays the evolution of each factor in the four-factor model at a number of maturity dates. The level remains 1 at each maturity date, while the slope converges from 1 at a maturity of 0 months towards 0 as the maturity of the CDS spread increases. The curvature factors load minimally on very short-term and long-term maturities, but increase medium-term CDS spreads, which load more heavily on it. Throughout this paper, we use the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter of the model of Svensson (1994) to disentangle short-term and long-term effects. We derived that C D S i , t , w ( + ) equals β 0 . As a result, we used the level parameter to capture long-term effects in the CDS market. Mathematically, the slope parameter ( β 1 ) corresponds to C D S i , t , w ( + ) C D S i , t , w ( 0 ) . It follows that the sum ( β 0 + β 1 ) captures short-term effects on bank CDS spreads.
In Figure 2, we show the evolution of the parameters of the default risk curve and its dispersion between the banks in our sample. The level of the default risk curve captures the long-term default risk of banks as perceived by markets. The global financial crisis and the sovereign debt crisis led to pronounced increases in perceived bank default risk and, hence, also the level factor loading. Also, the 2016–2017 period was characterized by an increase of bank CDS spreads caused by uncertainty with regard to the viability of certain bank business models in the Euro Area. Finally, the start of the corona pandemic was not associated with an increase in the perceived long-run default risk of banks. The slope parameter was on average negative and notably lower during the sovereign debt crisis. A negative slope parameter translates into a higher increase of the default risk curve of banks, which means that, during the sovereign debt crisis, the spread difference between the short-term and long-term default risk of banks was higher.

3.2. Identifying Monetary Policy

Since our focus is on the impact of monetary policy on bank risk, we need to identify the monetary policy stance in the Eurozone in the post-2008 period. We cannot use the policy rate because of the zero lower bound constraint, and similarly, we cannot use the ECB balance sheet because some important monetary policy measures did not affect the balance sheet (e.g., OMT was pre-announced by the Draghi ‘whatever it takes’ speech in July 2012, operationally implemented in September 2012, but subsequently never activated). Finally, different conventional and unconventional policy measures were announced simultaneously (e.g., in January 2015, APP was announced jointly with a decrease in the Deposit Facility Rate and strengthened forward guidance) and were often largely anticipated. When reviewing the potential approaches to identify monetary policy (Rossi 2021), we opted for a structural VAR because incorporating a broad set of financial market indicators allowed us not only to identify actual ECB monetary policy decisions, but also to capture anticipation effects and instances in which financial markets judge that monetary policy actions are insufficient, given the prevailing market conditions. For the CDS market, current and future financial conditions are relevant to assess the default risk of banks.
Therefore, we estimated a time series of exogenous monetary policy shocks by modeling a set of relevant financial market variables in a structural VAR model at a daily frequency as in Wright (2012), Rossi (2021), and Lamers et al. (2019):
Y t = A 1 Y t 1 + + A p Y t p + R v t
where Y t is an N-dimensional vector of endogenous variables, v t an N-dimensional vector of orthogonal structural innovations with mean zero and A 1 , , A p , and R are N × N time-invariant parameter matrices. The reduced-form residuals corresponding to this structural model are given by the relationship ε t = R v t .
To estimate the structural VAR, we used a set of variables that capture the pass-through of monetary policy to the financial sector. Following Rogers et al. (2014), we selected those variables that are expected to respond most to a monetary policy shock. More specifically, as we conducted the analysis for the Euro Area, we included the German 10-year bond yield, the VSTOXX, the CDS spread of Spain, a market index, and the 5-year forward inflation expectation. The identification of the policy shock is based on the identification-through-heteroskedasticity strategy, proposed by Rigobon and Sack (2004), which assumes that a structural monetary policy shock is more volatile on announcement days of a central bank. The main idea is that a structural monetary policy shock for the Euro Area has a higher volatility on days where the ECB makes monetary policy announcements. Based on the differences in the volatility of the shock during both regimes, the structural VAR was uniquely identified. The only assumption was that there is some kind of heteroskedastic pattern in the monetary policy shock while all other shocks are homoskedastic:
V a r v t = Ω t = Ω ( 0 ) = diag ω 1 , ω 2 , , ω N if n o a n n o u n c e m e n t Ω ( 1 ) = diag ω 1 * , ω 2 , , ω N if a n n o u n c e m e n t
It can be shown that, as long as the covariance matrix of the reduced-form errors v t changes on announcement days, these assumptions suffice to uniquely identify the first column of the structural impact multiplier R and the structural monetary policy shocks, except for their scale and sign. The model can be estimated following the iterative estimation procedure outlined in Lanne and Lütkepohl (2008)5. We normalized the monetary policy shock by fixing the response on the impact of one of the included variables to a unit monetary policy shock. We define a unit expansionary monetary policy shock as a shock that decreases the 5-year CDS spread of Spain with 5 percentage points6. This identification-through-heteroskedasticity approach is widely used in the literature to identify monetary policy shocks, for example Rogers et al. (2014), Arai (2017), Lamers et al. (2019), and Rossi (2021). We estimated a VAR of order 2 over a sample period from 1 October 2008 to 31 December 2020. This methodology allowed us to identify monetary policy shocks that capture the effect of the main ECB announcements and potential anticipation effects, e.g., the OMT program was implemented in September 2012, yet it was already announced two months earlier. The financial variables in the VAR capture these potential anticipation effects. It is the combination of actual ECB announcements and anticipation effects that determines the macrofinancial environment in which the CDS market assesses bank default risk.
Figure 3 shows cumulative monetary policy shocks, which we label as the monetary policy stance. A sequence of positive monetary policy shocks indicates that monetary policy becomes more expansionary, and therefore, the cumulative series reflects the monetary policy stance with respect to the prevailing economic environment and expectations of financial markets. Similarly, a drop in the series may reflect a tightening of monetary policy, but may also capture the lack of monetary policy action or even that there were expansionary announcements that failed to live up to financial market expectations. Figure 3 shows that the shocks are able to capture important monetary policy announcements, as well as the anticipation of some measures. In October 2008, the financial crisis hit the economy, and the monetary policy was initially perceived to be not sufficiently expansionary. Once the ECB stepped up its policy actions with substantial repo rate decreases and the launch of longer-term refinancing operations, the monetary policy stance reverted to expansionary. The LTRO and Covered Bond Purchase Program (CBPP1) announcement in May 2009 and the SMP announcement in May 2010 are among the largest expansionary daily shocks and can, therefore, be considered as surprises to financial markets. In the following years, the monetary policy stance was somewhat volatile, with periods of restrictive monetary regimes followed by expansionary shocks in the monetary policy stance, caused by events such as the ECB president Mario Draghi’s London speech in July 2012. The OMT announcement in September 2012 appears to have been largely anticipated following this July Draghi speech in which he alluded to the implementation of additional unconventional monetary policy measures. The QE period, which started in 2015, is sometimes perceived as a period of restrictive monetary policy, probably because of economic uncertainty stemming from the economic and political environment (e.g., Brexit). From 2017 onwards until March 2020, the sustained monetary easing was considered by financial markets as effectively stimulating the economy, although the ECB kept interest rates unchanged and primarily used the forward guidance that interest rates would remain low until at least the summer of 2019. In March 2020, the corona pandemic worsened the prevailing economic conditions, which resulted in a significant negative shock to the overall stance of monetary policy until the ECB introduced the Pandemic Emergency Purchase Program (PEPP). An interesting example of the potential divide between policy intentions and market perception was described by Rostagno et al. (2019) in their account of the first 20 years of ECB monetary policy. In December 2015, the Governing Council decided to lower the deposit facility rate by 10 basis points. However, the authors concluded that the markets expected a larger reduction in the deposit facility rate; hence, despite the intention of the ECB to be accommodating, the policy actions did not meet the expectations of financial markets (Rostagno et al. 2019). This resulted in a tightening of the monetary policy stance, as is reflected in our Figure 3, illustrating that our indicator of the monetary policy stance succeeded in identifying divergences between intended policy outcomes and actual market perceptions. This is an important value added of the identification approach since our objective was to assess the impact of the monetary policy stance on a market-based indicator of the banks’ risk profile.

3.3. Control Variables: Bank-Specific and Market Variables

Next to the prevailing macroeconomic conditions, the risk profile of a bank is determined by the strategic choices that constitute the bank’s business model and affect the associated performance outcomes in terms of profitability and risk. To control for bank fundamentals, we included variables capturing the asset structure, funding mix, and the bank’s capital strength. The balance sheet control variables are the loans-to-assets ratio (LTA) as a proxy for the importance of the bank’s lending activity and the proportion of deposits in total liabilities (DEP) as a measure of the funding mix. Capital strength is captured by the unweighted capital ratio (CAP). Capital buffers have been shown to decrease banks’ market beta (Baele et al. 2007), as well as their systemic risk (Laeven et al. 2016), and several papers have demonstrated that higher capital before the crisis increased the likelihood of survival and enhanced bank performance in distressed periods (Berger and Bouwman 2013; Vazquez and Federico 2015). Finally, we included the natural logarithm of total assets (SIZE) as a proxy for any potential size-related benefits in terms of banks’ perceived risk profile. In terms of outcome variables, we focused on profitability, i.e., return on assets (ROA), and we included a measure of the quality of the bank’s lending portfolio, i.e., non-performing loans to total loans (NPL).
The risk profile of the bank may be affected by prevailing financial market conditions. We included the VSTOXX as a measure of market volatility, since it has been shown to be an indicator of uncertainty and risk (Baele et al. 2020; Nave and Ruiz 2015). Additionally, we include the Euro Stoxx 50 stock index to capture financial market conditions.
The descriptive statistics for the bank factor loadings, bank-specific variables, and market volatility are reported in Table 2.

4. Methodology

Since we hypothesized that monetary policy may be associated with differential effects on short-term versus long-term bank default risk, captured by the term structure of bank credit risk, our empirical analysis proceeded as follows. First, we estimated a baseline model of banks’ default risk term structure components with the monetary policy stance of the ECB and bank-specific control variables as the main explanatory variables. More specifically, we analyzed the impact of the monetary policy stance on the short-term and long-term default risk, which we derived from the bank default risk curve. As described in Section 3, short-term bank default risk is described as the sum of the level and slope parameter ( β 0 , i , w + β 1 , i , w ) of Equation (1), whilst banks’ long-term default risk is captured by the level parameter ( β 0 , i , w ) only. Second, we analyzed whether or not the impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank default risk is significantly different by estimating the impact of the monetary policy stance on the slope of the bank default risk curve.
We estimated the impact of monetary policy stance on short-term and long-term bank default risk, measured by bank CDS spreads, using the following model:
D e f a u l t R i s k i , t = α i + β M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t + k = 1 K ζ k B a n k C o n t r o l s k , i , t + l = 1 L γ l M a c r o C o n t r o l s l , t + ε i , t
where D e f a u l t R i s k i , t represents bank i’s short-term or long-term bank default risk in week t. M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t captures the monetary policy stance of the first day of week t, estimated with an SVAR and identification-through-heteroskedasticity approach. We controlled for the banks’ business model by including a number of bank control variables ( B a n k C o n t r o l ) and for macroeconomic conditions with the inclusion of the Euro Stoxx 50 index and the VSTOXX ( M a c r o C o n t r o l s ) . The model controls for unobserved heterogeneity at the bank level by including bank fixed effects ( α i ) . We did not include a time fixed effect, since this would not allow us to identify the impact of the monetary policy stance on bank default risk. With this methodological setup, we answer our main research questions. First, if there is a negative association between the monetary policy stance and short-term and long-term bank default risk, we argue that the accommodative monetary policy of the ECB reduces bank default risk, both immediately, as well as structurally. Second, if there is a positive association between the monetary policy stance and the slope of the banks’ default risk curve, we inferred that the impact of monetary policy is heterogeneous between short-term and long-term bank default risk, which may signal bank risk-taking behavior. Therefore, we estimated the following model:
S l o p e i , t = α i + β M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t + k = 1 K ζ k B a n k C o n t r o l s k , i , t + l = 1 L γ l M a c r o C o n t r o l s l , t + ε i , t
where S l o p e i , t is the second factor of the four-factor model in Equation (1). To make the interpretation of the results more intuitive, we estimated the impact of monetary policy on β 1 . Hence, a positive association between the slope and monetary policy indicates an increase of the slope and, thus, also a widening of short-term and long-term bank default risk due to an accommodative monetary policy shock.
Finally, we analyzed our third hypothesis, i.e., whether or not the transmission of monetary policy towards bank default risk, both in the short and long term, is different for banks with a high and low reliance on deposits. We argue that banks with a high reliance on deposits are more induced to exhibit risk-taking behavior after a prolonged period of low interest rates, based on Heider et al. (2019), who found that, when the ECB’s deposit facility rate turned negative, banks with high deposits tilted their loan supply towards more-risky borrowers. To analyze whether or not accommodative monetary impacts high- and low-deposit banks differently, we estimated Model 4 for banks situated in the highest and lowest deposits-to-liabilities quartile separately.

5. Results

5.1. ECB Monetary Policy and Bank Credit Risk

In Table 3, we analyze the impact of monetary policy shocks on bank default risk, based on Equations (4) and (5). The results in columns (1) and (2) show the impact of the stance of monetary policy on the banks’ short-term and long-term default risk, captured with CDS spreads, while column (3) displays the impact on the slope of the banks’ default risk curve. We define short-term default risk as the instantaneous market-perceived default risk of the bank, which is captured by β 0 , i , w β 1 , i , w from the Svensson model in Equation (1). Long-term default risk is represented by β 0 , i , w . We saturated each model with bank fixed effects and additionally controlled for observable bank characteristics and the macroeconomic environment. We clustered the standard errors at the bank level.
Our main result in Table 3 is that an accommodative monetary policy shock is associated with declining bank CDS spreads in the short-term (minus 4.44 basis points per unit of monetary stimulus), but does not affect long-term bank default risk7. Hence, CDS market investors judge that monetary stimulus is associated with a decline in the immediate default probability of banks, but this beneficial effect is not extended to the banks’ structural tail risk. The finding that ECB monetary stimulus lowers short-term bank default risk is consistent with Altavilla et al. (2018), who documented declining bank CDS spreads following all major ECB monetary policy announcements, and with Soenen and Vander Vennet (2022), who reported a negative association between ECB monetary policy easing and Euro Area bank CDS spreads. These findings indicated that banks are perceived to benefit from the more-benign economic conditions associated with monetary accommodation. The finding that this is not the case for long-term bank default risk is consistent with the arguments developed in Altavilla et al. (2019), who asserted that positive effects from monetary stimulus (positive effect on the macroeconomy and bank asset quality, capital gains due to lower interest rates) may be compensated by the negative consequences of persistently low interest rates (pressure on banks’ interest margins in general and the effect of the negative interest rate on the deposit facility in particular), leading to a zero net effect. To determine whether or not monetary policy alters the shape of the bank default risk term structure, the third column presents the impact of monetary policy shocks on the slope of the bank default risk curve ( β 1 ). We found a positive and significant coefficient indicating that the slope of the credit curve increases by 4.3 basis points per unit of monetary policy stimulus8. In principle, a steepening of the default risk curve would be consistent with risk-taking behavior by the banks. However, the steeper slope is only caused by lower short-term banks CDS spreads, not a perceived increase in the longer-term default risk of the banks. Hence, we cannot conclude that the CDS market anticipates excessive risk-taking by banks caused by a protracted period of monetary accommodation. Nevertheless, finding that lower short-term risk is not accompanied by a similar decline in long-term default risk does point to market participants’ concerns that the beneficial effect of monetary policy stimulus on bank default risk does not extend to the structural tail risk of Euro Area banks. In Section 5.3, we further explore the time variation in the association between monetary policy and bank credit risk.
Another noteworthy result in Table 3 relates to the impact of the banks’ deposit funding ratio on bank default risk. A higher deposit ratio is associated with lower short-term risk, indicating that markets consider that having access to stable funding makes banks more resilient. However, a higher deposit ratio is associated with a steeper credit risk curve, which is consistent with Heider et al. (2019), who argued that banks relying on deposit funding are confronted with compressing interest margins caused by monetary accommodation, and this results in increased risk-taking behavior in their syndicated lending. Similarly, Bubeck et al. (2020) reported that high-deposit banks exhibit higher risk-taking in their securities portfolio (see Section 5.4 for a more-detailed analysis).

5.2. Core versus Periphery: Euro Area Banks

When analyzing the impact of ECB monetary policy, a natural extension is to consider potential differences between core and periphery Euro Area banks. Differences in the impact of monetary policy on bank risk profiles in the core versus the peripheral countries may be driven by the fact that monetary policy transmission differs across countries, e.g., OMT had a more-pronounced downward effect on interest rates in the Euro Area periphery (Krishnamurthy et al. 2018). Moreover, Soenen and Vander Vennet (2022) showed that there is a direct beneficial effect of monetary policy on the risk profile of banks, which is amplified by an indirect through-the-sovereign effect. Fratzscher and Rieth (2019) reported that the bank–sovereign nexus works in both directions, with sovereign risk impacting bank risk and vice versa. Therefore, we analyzed the heterogeneous impact of ECB monetary policy on short- and long-term bank default risk depending on whether the banks are located in the periphery (i.e., Ireland, Italy, Spain, or Portugal) or core countries. We interacted the monetary policy stance with a dummy variable equal to 1 when a bank is headquartered in a periphery country, 0 otherwise:
D e f a u l t R i s k i , t = α i + β 1 M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t + β 2 M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t × P e r i p h e r y i + k = 1 K ζ k B a n k C o n t r o l s k , i , t + l = 1 L γ l M a c r o C o n t r o l s l , t + ε i , t
where P e r i p h e r y i is a dummy variable that equals 1 if bank i at time t is located in either Ireland, Italy, Spain, or Portugal.
The interpretation of the coefficients in Table 4 proceeds as follows. The first row (monetary policy without interaction) captures the effect of monetary policy shocks for core banks; the second row adds the interaction with periphery banks; hence, the total effect on bank risk for the periphery banks is the sum of the first and second row. We found that an accommodative monetary policy shock has a beneficial effect on the default risk of banks in the short run. This effect is significant for core Euro Area banks, and it is amplified for periphery banks, although the interaction term remains insignificant. For core banks, we even found that ECB monetary policy accommodation is associated with a lower long-term default risk, indicating that the CDS market attaches a lower default probability to their entire term structure of default risk, but the effect is more pronounced in the short run, as evidenced by the positive and significant coefficient on monetary policy in the slope regression in the first row of column 3. For periphery banks, the combination of the first two rows leads to a non-negative effect of monetary policy on long-term default risk. Since the periphery banks’ interaction coefficient is positive and significant (at the 10% level) in the slope regression, this suggests that CDS market participants view that risk-taking incentives are particularly present for periphery banks.

5.3. Time Variation of the Effect of Monetary Policy on Bank Credit Risk

In terms of time variation, it would be natural to hypothesize that bank risk-taking incentives associated with accommodative monetary policy would only materialize once the pressure on their profitability turns out to be persistent. Since the Great Financial Crisis, the ECB has implemented various types of conventional (interest rate changes) and unconventional monetary policy instruments, ranging from credit easing (e.g., (T)LTROs), quantitative easing (e.g., the asset purchase programs), and forward guidance, to even implementing a negative interest rate policy (negative rates on the deposit facility) (Rostagno et al. 2019). These policies have been introduced at various stages over the period under investigation, and they may impact the risk profile of banks differently. The interest rate decreased the initially supported bank net interest margins, and the LTRO lowered the cost of the funding of banks, but once the ECB started applying negative interest rates on its deposit facility and once forward guidance pointed at low-for-long interest rates, bank interest margins and profitability may be affected negatively (Borio and Gambacorta 2017; Claessens et al. 2018; Molyneux et al. 2019). Moreover, Ampudia and Van den Heuvel (2018) reported that the expected increase of stock valuations that usually accompanies policy rate decreases reverses for European banks in the period of low and even negative interest rates. Confronted with compressing interest margins, banks may seek to increase non-interest income or improve their cost efficiency (Brei et al. 2020; Lopez et al. 2020). Yet, the persistent pressure on profitability may incentivize banks to search for yield, activating a risk-taking channel (Borio and Zhu 2012), which may become stronger as interest rates remain low for longer and even enter negative territory. Banks may seek higher yields in higher-risk pockets in their lending and securities portfolio (Bubeck et al. 2020; Heider et al. 2019). The ultimate effect of monetary policy on bank profitability and the banks’ risk profile is the net result of beneficial effects (e.g., better economic conditions) and potential negative side effects (e.g., risk-taking) (see Altavilla et al. 2019; Albertazzi et al. 2020). If banks are considered to engage in excessive risk-taking, i.e., taking risks that are not adequately priced, this should be associated with higher perceived bank default risk and, hence, higher long-term CDS spreads. To investigate this hypothesis, we examined whether or not the impact of changes in the monetary policy stance on the banks’ risk profile differs in consecutive periods of ECB monetary accommodation.
In order to investigate the time-varying pattern of the impact of ECB monetary policy actions on bank risk, we interacted the monetary policy variable with year dummies. We estimated the following model:
D e f a u l t R i s k i , t = α i + k = 1 K β k M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t × Y e a r k + l = 1 L ζ l B a n k C o n t r o l s l , i , t + m = 1 M γ l M a c r o C o n t r o l s m , t + ε i , t
where Y e a r k is a dummy variable, which equals 1 during year k and 0 otherwise. Since we were interested in the transmission of monetary policy to bank risk in a given year, the dummy variables equal 1 during that year only.
Table 5 presents the results. We only show the coefficients of the interaction terms of monetary policy with the year dummies for short-term and long-term bank default risk. It is immediately clear that there is a distinct time pattern for the way in which ECB policy actions have impacted bank risk. In the years up to 2012, there was a significant negative association between monetary stimulus and bank default risk, and this effect was more pronounced for short-term compared to long-term bank default risk. In other words, accommodative monetary policy was efficient in reducing perceived bank risk during the sovereign debt crisis of 2010–2012. This reduction in perceived bank risk coincides with the execution by the ECB of its Securities Market Program (SMP), which was effective from May 2010 until September 2012 and was designed to purchase government securities of stressed peripheral Euro Area countries, as well as the July 2012 Draghi ‘whatever it takes’ speech announcing the OMT program. In 2010, the ECB also launched its bank covered bond program, and the first wave of LTRO aimed at easing the funding conditions of Euro Area banks. These findings are consistent with the results in Soenen and Vander Vennet (2022), who showed that monetary policy is not only associated with lower bank CDS spreads directly, but also indirectly, through lower sovereign spreads. In the period following the sovereign debt crisis, the impact of monetary policy shocks on bank risk was not significant, with the exception of 2016–2017 in the case of the long-term bank default risk. One possible explanation may be the impact of the asset purchase program launched in 2015, which was in full operation during those years and may have allowed banks to reap capital gains in their bond portfolios and may have enabled them to start selling parts of the non-performing loans, especially banks in distressed countries. From 2018 onwards, we observed a positive and significant coefficient on the interaction term, and this held for both short-term and long-term bank default risk. This finding is consistent with the risk-taking hypothesis under which banks shift to riskier assets in an attempt to compensate shrinking interest margins and pressure on their overall profitability.
In order to combine the geographical (core versus periphery) and the time dimension, we estimated Equation (7) for the core and periphery country banks separately and present the evidence in Figure 4. The results showed that the accommodative monetary policy was associated with a significant decline in perceived bank default risk in the sovereign crisis era, both for short-term risk and structural default risk, and this beneficial effect was more pronounced for the banks in the periphery. From 2013 onwards, monetary policy action no longer seemed to significantly affect bank default risk. During the final years of the sample period, the beneficial impact totally disappeared and turned into a positive association between ECB accommodation and bank default risk, indicating that a prolonged period of very low interest rates is perceived to incentivize banks to increase their risk profile. These results are consistent with the evidence presented in Heider et al. (2019) and Bubeck et al. (2020); they also corroborated the finding in Lamers et al. (2019) that ECB monetary policy accommodation is associated with an increase of the systemic risk of periphery Euro Area banks.

5.4. High versus Low Deposits

The final step in our analysis was to consider the reliance of banks on deposit funding. Most banks rely to a substantial degree on deposits as a stable source of funding, and the deposit rates banks offer are affected by the central bank policy rate. The transmission of policy rates to deposit rates is usually stronger when interest rates decline, because this increases banks’ net interest margins. Yet, ever since the ECB started applying a negative interest rate on its bank deposit facility in June 2014, we have observed a reluctance by banks to transmit these negative rates to their retail deposits (some banks do apply negative rates on corporate or institutional deposits). As a result, the zero lower bound on retail deposit funding combined with decreasing lending rates caused by monetary policy accommodation puts pressure on banks’ interest margins and may increase their appetite for higher risk in their asset portfolio (Bubeck et al. 2020; Demiralp et al. 2021; Heider et al. 2019; Schelling and Towbin 2022). In order to investigate the time-varying impact of monetary policy on bank default risk depending on the banks’ reliance on deposit funding, we adopted a similar estimation as in Equation (7) and, now, differentiated between high- and low-deposit banks. Based on the proportion of deposits over total liabilities, we define high-deposit banks as those in the upper quartile of our sample, while low-deposit banks are those in the lowest quartile9. Figure 5 shows the results of the estimation of Equation (7) for high- and low-deposit banks. In the first time period (2010–2013), monetary policy stimulus was associated with lower perceived bank default risk, both short-term and long-term, but while the effect was only marginally significant for low-deposit banks, it was significant for high-deposit banks and very pronounced for the short-term default risk (up to 75 basis points per unit of monetary policy accommodation). Banks with a high reliance on deposit funding benefited from the lower interest rates in terms of net interest margins, and this translated into a more-benign risk profile. Moreover, banks with a high reliance on interbank funding, which in times of stress may turn out to be volatile, are regarded as more risky since the Great Financial Crisis (Huang and Ratnovski 2011). Banks with access to stable deposits avoid the ‘dark side of wholesale funding’ and are perceived to be less risky. The beneficial effect of deposit funding reverses in the period of 2018–2020, because persistently low interest rates induce high-deposit banks to increase the risk profile of their lending portfolio, as well as their securities portfolio (Bubeck et al. 2020; Heider et al. 2019). This translates into a positive and significant association between monetary policy accommodation and perceived bank default risk, both short-term and long-term, and particularly pronounced for high-deposit banks (blue line in the right panel of Figure 5).
To confirm the significance of the deposit channel, we additionally analyzed the heterogeneous impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank default risk depending on the degree of bank deposit funding. This estimation was realized by the following specification:
D e f a u l t R i s k i , t = α i + β 1 M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t + β 2 M o n e t a r y P o l i c y t × D e p o s i t s i , t + k = 1 K ζ k B a n k C o n t r o l s k , i , t + l = 1 L γ l M a c r o C o n t r o l s l , t + ε i , t
where D e p o s i t s i , t is the deposit ratio of bank i in year t. The results in Table 6 confirm the presence of a deposit channel for banks’ long-term default risk. The aggregated impact of an accommodative monetary policy measure on long-term bank default risk increased by 0.04 for each percentage point increase in the deposit ratio of banks.

6. Conclusions

Euro Area banks have witnessed a stressful decade, with a banking crisis, a sovereign debt crisis, and a global pandemic, which have led to unprecedented monetary policy actions by the ECB. We argue that monetary policy may affect bank risk profiles and especially that the consequences of monetary accommodation may differ for short-term bank credit risk versus long-term or structural bank risk. This was our motivation to empirically investigate the association between the ECB’s monetary policy stance and market-perceived short-term and long-term bank default risk, proxied by the short- and long-term component of the term structure of bank credit risk, captured by bank CDS spreads.
Our main findings can be summarized as follows. The results demonstrated that, during the period of 2009–2020, the ECB’s expansionary monetary policy on average diminished bank default risk in the short term. However, we did not observe a similar decline in long-term bank default risk, since we documented that monetary stimulus is associated with a steepening of the bank default risk term structure curve. The reduction of bank default risk due to accommodative monetary policy actions was most pronounced during the sovereign debt crisis, which can be ascribed to the fact that monetary policy actions not only decreased bank risk directly, but also loosened the nexus between banks and sovereigns. Our results further indicated that the beneficial impact of expansionary monetary policy actions during the sovereign debt crisis on bank default risk is most pronounced for peripheral banks. After 2013, the impact of monetary policy on bank default risk on average turned largely neutral until 2018. From 2018 onwards, the results suggested that monetary policy accommodation is associated with increased bank default risk, in the short term, but also structurally. These results are compatible with the risk-taking hypothesis, suggesting that the CDS market perceives increased incentives for banks to engage in excessive risk-taking behavior in their loan and securities portfolios in an attempt to compensate the compression of their net interest margins due to persistently low interest rates. We documented that the increase in perceived default risk, both short-term and structurally, is especially visible for banks with a high reliance on deposit funding, which confirmed the hypothesis that banks with more deposit funding are affected by the zero lower bound on retail deposits and, as a result, are most prone to exhibiting excessive risk behavior.
Our findings have implications for the effectiveness of monetary policy, since the transmission of policy actions may differ for core and periphery countries and for high- and low-deposit banks. Since banks remain the most-important channel of monetary policy transmission in the Euro Area, heterogeneous effects of policy actions on the banks’ risk profiles may affect the transmission to the real economy. Our finding that a prolonged period of low interest rates may induce excessive risk-taking behavior by some banks suggests that macroprudential policy may have an important role to play since targeted macroprudential measures may be effective tools for curbing excessive risk-taking by banks.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, T.B., N.S., R.V.V.; Methodology, T.B., N.S., R.V.V.; Formal analysis, T.B., N.S., R.V.V.; Data curation, T.B., N.S., R.V.V.; Writing; Review, T.B., N.S., R.V.V.; Editing, T.B., N.S., R.V.V. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by Research Foundation Flanders (FWO) grant number G00298N.

Data Availability Statement

The data used in this study are from proprietary databases.

Acknowledgments

We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments from Koen Inghelbrecht, Kris Boudt, Glenn Schepens, Astrid Van Landschoot, Martien Lamers, Thomas Present, Mathieu Simoens, and Aaron Blomme.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Notes

1
If the frequency of the CDS spread quotes was less than 25% over the sample period of 2008–2018, the bank was omitted from the sample.
2
We included only those banks with loans/assets or deposits/liabilities ratios above 20% to ensure that we focused on banks engaged in financial intermediation. The combination of the selection criteria with regard to CDS spreads and bank-specific variables implies that our sample is limited to large and predominantly listed banks.
3
We aggregated daily CDS spreads in order to have a sufficient number of observations.
4
The results with alternative decay rates are qualitatively similar.
5
For details on the estimation procedure, we refer to Lamers et al. (2019).
6
Using other variables to identify a unit shock and using the CDS spread of, e.g., Italy, to calibrate an accommodative shock yielded an almost identical shock series.
7
The differences in banks’ short- and long-term credit risk may be partly explained by a difference in their underlying liquidity. To check that this does not partly explain our results, we estimated the same model directly on the 1-year and 5-year CDS spreads, which have a more comparable liquidity. We interpreted the 1-year CDS as short-term credit risk and the 5-year as long-term credit risk. The results remained qualitatively similar, so we assumed that our results were not affected by possible differences in liquidity.
8
We ran a series of robustness checks to verify whether or not the baseline results hold under different assumptions. When we winsorized the data more (5–95%, in order to avoid potential outliers), left out the CDS spreads with a maturity of 6 months (to take into account potential liquidity concerns for these short CDS contracts), or left out inverted term structures (typically in 2011), the findings were robust: expansionary monetary policy shocks were associated with a significant lowering of short-term CDS spreads and a significant steepening of the slope of the term structure.
9
In a similar vein, banks credit risk may be affected differently by monetary policy based on the level of capitalization of banks. However, including the banks’ capital ratios with interaction terms yields no significant coefficients.

References

  1. Acharya, Viral V., Rahul S. Chauhan, Raghuram Rajan, and Sascha Steffen. 2023. Liquidity Dependence and the Waxing and Waning of Central Bank Balance Sheets. NBER Working Paper Series, No. 31050. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  2. Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin. 2009. Money, Liquidity, and Monetary Policy. American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 99: 600–5. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Albertazzi, Ugo, Francesca Barbiero, David Marques-Ibanez, Alexander Popov, Costanza Rodriguez D’Acri, and Thomas Vlassopoulos. 2020. Monetary Policy and Bank Stability: The Analytical Toolbox Reviewed. ECB Working Paper Series, No. 2377. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Altavilla, Carlo, Desislava Andreeva, Miguel Boucinha, and Sarah Holton. 2019. Monetary Policy, Credit Institutions and the Bank Lending Channel in the Euro Area. ECB Occasional Paper No. 222. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Altavilla, Carlo, Luca Brugnolini, Refet S. Gürkaynak, Roberto Motto, and Giuseppe Ragusa. 2019. Measuring Euro Area Monetary Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 108: 162–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Altavilla, Carlo, Miguel Boucinha, and José-Luis Peydró. 2018. Monetary Policy and Bank Profitability in a Low Interest Rate Environment. Economic Policy 33: 531–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Altunbas, Yener, Leonardo Gambacorta, and David Marques-Ibanez. 2012. Do Bank Characteristics Influence the Effect of Monetary Policy on Bank Risk? Economics Letters 117: 220–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ampudia, Miguel, and Skander Van den Heuvel. 2018. Monetary Policy and Bank Equity Values in a Time of Low Interest Rates. ECB Working Paper Series, No. 2199. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Arai, Natsuki. 2017. The Effects of Monetary Policy Announcements at the Zero Lower Bound. International Journal of Central Banking 13: 159–96. [Google Scholar]
  10. Baele, Lieven, Geert Bekaert, Koen Inghelbrecht, and Min Wei. 2020. Flights to Safety. Review of Financial Studies 33: 689–746. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Baele, Lieven, Olivier De Jonghe, and Rudi Vander Vennet. 2007. Does the Stock Market Value Bank Diversification? Journal of Banking and Finance 31: 1999–2023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Berger, Allen N., and Christa H. S. Bouwman. 2013. How Does Capital Affect Bank Performance During Financial Crises. Journal of Financial Economics 109: 146–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Bonfim, Diana, and Carla Soares. 2018. The Risk-Taking Channel of Monetary Policy: Exploring All Avenues. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 50: 1507–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Borio, Claudio, and Haibin Zhu. 2012. Capital Regulation, Risk-Taking and Monetary Policy: A Missing Link in the Transmission Mechanism? Journal of Financial Stability 8: 236–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Borio, Claudio, and Leonardo Gambacorta. 2017. Monetary Policy and Bank Lending in a Low Interest Rate Environment: Diminishing Effectiveness? Journal of Macroeconomics 54: 217–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Brei, Michael, Claudio Borio, and Leonardo Gambacorta. 2020. Bank Intermediation Activity in a Low-Interest-Rate Environment. Economic Notes 49: e12164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Bubeck, Johannes, Angela Maddaloni, and José-Luis Peydró. 2020. Negative Monetary Policy Rates and Systemic Banks’ Risk-Taking: Evidence from the Euro Area Securities Register. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 52: 197–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Carpinelli, Luisa, and Matteo Crosignani. 2021. The Design and Transmission of Central Bank Liquidity Provisions. Journal of Financial Economics 141: 27–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Christensen, Jens H. E., Francis X. Diebold, and Glenn D. Rudebusch. 2009. An arbitrage-free generalized Nelson–Siegel term structure model. Econometrics Journal 12: 33–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Claessens, Stijn, Nicholas Coleman, and Michael Donnelly. 2018. “Low-For-Long” Interest Rates and Banks’ Interest Margins and Profitability: Cross-Country Evidence. Journal of Financial Intermediation 35: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Coroneo, Laura, Ken Nyholm, and Rositsa Vidova-Koleva. 2011. How arbitrage-free is the Nelson–Siegel model? Journal of Empirical Finance 18: 393–407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Crosignani, Matteo, Miguel Faria-e-Castro, and Luís Fonseca. 2020. The (Unintended?) Consequences of the Largest Liquidity Injection Ever. Journal of Monetary Economics 112: 97–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Demiralp, Selva, Jens Eisenschmidt, and Thomas Vlassopoulos. 2021. Negative interest rates, excess liquidity and retail deposits: Banks’ reaction to unconventional monetary policy in the euro area. European Economic Review 136: 103745. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Diebold, Francis X., and Canlin Li. 2006. Forecasting the Term Structure of Government Bond Yields. Journal of Econometrics 130: 337–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Falagiarda, Matteo, and Stefan Reitz. 2015. Announcements of ECB Unconventional Programs: Implications for the Sovereign Spreads of Stressed Euro Area Countries. Journal of International Money and Finance 53: 276–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Fratzscher, Marcel, and Malte Rieth. 2019. Monetary Policy, Bank Bailouts and the Sovereign-Bank Risk Nexus in the Euro Area. Review of Finance 23: 745–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Gambacorta, Leonardo, and Hyun Song Shin. 2018. Why bank capital matters for monetary policy. Journal of Financial Intermediation 35: 17–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Heider, Florian, Farzad Saidi, and Glenn Schepens. 2019. Life below Zero: Bank Lending under Negative Policy Rates. Review of Financial Studies 32: 3728–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Huang, Rocco, and Lev Ratnovski. 2011. The Dark Side of Bank Wholesale Funding. Journal of Financial Intermediation 20: 248–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Jäger, Jannik, and Theocharis Grigoriadis. 2017. The Effectiveness of the ECB’s Unconventional Monetary Policy: Comparative Evidence from Crisis and Non-Crisis Euro-area Countries. Journal of International Money and Finance 78: 21–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Jiménez, Gabriel, Steven Ongena, José-Luis Peydró, and Jésus Saurina. 2014. Hazardous Times for Monetary Policy: What Do Twenty-Three Million Bank Loans Say About the Effects of Monetary Policy on Credit Risk-Taking? Econometrica 82: 463–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Krishnamurthy, Arvind, Stefan Nagel, and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen. 2018. ECB Policies Involving Government Bond Purchases: Impact and Channels. Review of Finance 22: 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Laeven, Luc, Lev Ratnovski, and Hui Tong. 2016. Bank size, capital, and systemic risk: Some international evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance 69: S25–S34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Lamers, Martien, Frederik Mergaerts, Elien Meuleman, and Rudi Vander Vennet. 2019. The Tradeoff between Monetary Policy and Bank Stability. International Journal of Central Banking 15: 1–42. [Google Scholar]
  35. Lamers, Martien, Thomas Present, Nicolas Soenen, and Rudi Vander Vennet. 2022. BRRD Credibility and the Bank-Sovereign Nexus. Applied Economics Letters 30: 1308–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Lanne, Markku, and Helmut Lütkepohl. 2008. Identifying Monetary Policy Shocks via Changes in Volatility. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40: 1131–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Lopez, Jose A., Andrew K. Rose, and Mark M. Spiegel. 2020. Why Have Negative Nominal Interest Rates Had Such a Small Effect on Bank Performance? Cross Country Evidence. European Economic Review 124: 103402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Molyneux, Philip, Alessio Reghezza, and Ru Xie. 2019. Bank Margins and Profits in a World of Negative Rates. Journal of Banking and Finance 107: 105613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Nave, Juan M., and Javier Ruiz. 2015. Risk Aversion and Monetary Policy in a Global Context. Journal of Financial Stability 20: 14–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Nelson, Charles R., and Andrew F. Siegel. 1987. Parsimonious Modeling of Yield Curves. The Journal of Business 60: 473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Paligorova, Teodora, and João A. C. Santos. 2017. Monetary Policy and Bank Risk-Taking: Evidence from the Corporate Loan Market. Journal of Financial Intermediation 30: 35–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Peersman, Gert. 2004. The Transmission of Monetary Policy in the Euro Area: Are the Effects Different Across Countries? Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 66: 285–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Rajan, Raghuram G. 2006. Has Finance Made the World Riskier? European Financial Management 12: 499–533. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Rigobon, Roberto, and Brian Sack. 2004. The Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices. Journal of Monetary Economics 51: 1553–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Rogers, John H., Chiara Scotti, and Jonathan H. Wright. 2014. Evaluating Asset-Market Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policy: A Multi-Country Review. Economic Policy 29: 749–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Rossi, Barbara. 2021. Identifying and Estimating the Effects of Unconventional Monetary Policy in the Data: How to Do It And What Have We Learned? The Econometrics Journal 24: C1–C32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Rostagno, Massimo, Carlo Altavilla, Giacomo Carboni, Wolfgang Lemke, Roberto Motto, Arthur Saint Guilhem, and Jonathan Yiangou. 2019. A Tale of Two Decades: The ECB’s Monetary Policy at 20. ECB Working Paper Series, No. 2346. Frankfurt: European Central Bank. [Google Scholar]
  48. Saunders, Anthony, and Marcia Millon Cornett. 2018. Financial Institutions Management: A Risk Management Approach. New York: McGraw-Hill. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Schelling, Tan, and Pascal Towbin. 2022. What lies beneath—Negative interest rates and bank lending. Journal of Financial Intermediation 51: 100969. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Soenen, Nicolas, and Rudi Vander Vennet. 2022. ECB Monetary Policy and Bank Default Risk. Journal of International Money and Finance 122: 102571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Svensson, Lars E. O. 1994. Estimating and Interpreting Forward Interest Rates: Sweden 1992–1994. Discussion Paper Nr. 1051. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. [Google Scholar]
  52. Szczerbowicz, Urszula. 2015. The ECB Unconventional Monetary Policies: Have They Lowered Market Borrowing Costs for Banks and Governments? International Journal of Central Banking 11: 91–127. [Google Scholar]
  53. Vazquez, Francisco, and Pablo Federico. 2015. Bank Funding Structures and Risk: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of Banking and Finance 61: 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Wright, Jonathan H. 2012. What does Monetary Policy do to Long-term Interest Rates at the Zero Lower Bound? The Economic Journal 122: F447–F466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Yield curve factors of the four-factor Svensson model (Svensson 1994). The graph shows the evolution of each factor: level, slope, and two curvatures with a decay rate of λ 1 = 0.0609 and λ 2 = 0.0299 , respectively.
Figure 1. Yield curve factors of the four-factor Svensson model (Svensson 1994). The graph shows the evolution of each factor: level, slope, and two curvatures with a decay rate of λ 1 = 0.0609 and λ 2 = 0.0299 , respectively.
Jrfm 16 00507 g001
Figure 2. Bank default risk curve loadings. The top row displays the time series of the level and slope parameters, whilst the bottom row shows the first and second curvature loadings. The level, slope, and curvatures are estimated weekly, by aggregating CDS spreads (daily) of the given week. The solid black line represents the median value of the variables in a given week, while the darker and lighter blue areas show the 25th−75th and the 10th−90th percentiles for a given week.
Figure 2. Bank default risk curve loadings. The top row displays the time series of the level and slope parameters, whilst the bottom row shows the first and second curvature loadings. The level, slope, and curvatures are estimated weekly, by aggregating CDS spreads (daily) of the given week. The solid black line represents the median value of the variables in a given week, while the darker and lighter blue areas show the 25th−75th and the 10th−90th percentiles for a given week.
Jrfm 16 00507 g002
Figure 3. ECB monetary policy stance. Time series of the cumulative monetary policy shocks for the Euro Area, estimated using an identification-through-heteroskedasticity approach proposed by Rigobon and Sack (2004). An increase in the monetary policy stance reflects an accommodative monetary policy change; a decrease captures restrictive monetary policy changes. We highlight some of these announcement dates: (a) the ECB starts its first Covered Bond Purchase Program (CBPP1) and announces a one-year LTRO; (b) the ECB announces its Securities Markets Program; (c) the ECB increases its MRO interest rate; (d) ECB President Mario Draghi states that the ECB “is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve the euro”; (e) the ECB introduces the Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) program; (f) the ECB announces it will start buying public-sector securities (EUR 60 billion per month until September 2016); (g) the ECB decreases the deposit facility rate to −0.3% and extends its APP program until the end of March 2017; (h) the ECB extends its APP for EUR 30 billion until at least September 2018; (i) the ECB offers the forward guidance that interest rates will remain low until the summer of 2019; (j) the ECB announces its pandemic emergency purchase program (EUR 750 billion until end 2020).
Figure 3. ECB monetary policy stance. Time series of the cumulative monetary policy shocks for the Euro Area, estimated using an identification-through-heteroskedasticity approach proposed by Rigobon and Sack (2004). An increase in the monetary policy stance reflects an accommodative monetary policy change; a decrease captures restrictive monetary policy changes. We highlight some of these announcement dates: (a) the ECB starts its first Covered Bond Purchase Program (CBPP1) and announces a one-year LTRO; (b) the ECB announces its Securities Markets Program; (c) the ECB increases its MRO interest rate; (d) ECB President Mario Draghi states that the ECB “is ready to do whatever it takes to preserve the euro”; (e) the ECB introduces the Outright Monetary Transactions (OMT) program; (f) the ECB announces it will start buying public-sector securities (EUR 60 billion per month until September 2016); (g) the ECB decreases the deposit facility rate to −0.3% and extends its APP program until the end of March 2017; (h) the ECB extends its APP for EUR 30 billion until at least September 2018; (i) the ECB offers the forward guidance that interest rates will remain low until the summer of 2019; (j) the ECB announces its pandemic emergency purchase program (EUR 750 billion until end 2020).
Jrfm 16 00507 g003
Figure 4. Evolution of the impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank CDS spreads over time.
Figure 4. Evolution of the impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank CDS spreads over time.
Jrfm 16 00507 g004
Figure 5. Evolution of the impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank credit risk over time, for banks with a high and low reliance on deposit funding.
Figure 5. Evolution of the impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank credit risk over time, for banks with a high and low reliance on deposit funding.
Jrfm 16 00507 g005
Table 1. Overview of the bank sample.
Table 1. Overview of the bank sample.
NameCountry
Erste Group BankAustria
Raiffeisen Bank InternationalAustria
Raiffeisen Zentralbank osterreichAustria
UniCredit Bank AustriaAustria
BNP Paribas FortisBelgium
KBC BankBelgium
Banque Federative du Credit MutuelFrance
BNP ParibasFrance
Credit AgricoleFrance
Credit LyonnaisFrance
NatixisFrance
Societe GeneraleFrance
Bayerische LandesbankGermany
CommerzbankGermany
Deutsche BankGermany
Hamburg Commercial BankGermany
IKB Deutsche IndustriebankGermany
Landesbank Baden-WurttembergGermany
UniCredit BankGermany
Governor and Company of the Bank of IrelandIreland
Permanent TSB Group HoldingsIreland
Banca ItaleaseItaly
Banca Monte dei Paschi di SienaItaly
Banca Nazionale del LavoroItaly
Banca Popolare di Milano Societa per AzioniItaly
Banco BPMItaly
Banco Popolare Societa CooperativaItaly
Intesa SanpaoloItaly
Mediobanca-Banca di Credito FinanziarioItaly
UniCreditItaly
Unione di Banche ItalianeItaly
ABN AMRO GroupNetherlands
Cooperatieve RabobankNetherlands
ING BankNetherlands
NIBC BankNetherlands
Banco Comercial PortuguesPortugal
Caixa Geral de DepositosPortugal
Novo BancoPortugal
Banco Bilbao Vizcaya ArgentariaSpain
Banco de SabadellSpain
Banco Popular EspanolSpain
Banco SantanderSpain
BankiaSpain
BankinterSpain
CaixaBankSpain
Table 2. Descriptive statistics. Bank-specific data, market data, and CDS spreads are obtained from BankFocus, Refinitiv, and Markit, respectively.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics. Bank-specific data, market data, and CDS spreads are obtained from BankFocus, Refinitiv, and Markit, respectively.
VariablesMEANSDP1P50P99
Level203.49151.7250.24165.05811.48
Slope−65.22296.26−265.01−92.41955.14
Curvature 1150.81302.71−299.67135.68686.45
Curvature 2−150.18505.31−1059.96−118.01301.84
Monetary Policy Stance−8.3610.34−26.01−6.897.83
Euro Stoxx 501066.09252.61585.431090.251553.88
VSTOXX22.428.1111.6420.8248.59
CAP6.352.062.526.3312.84
Size19.261.1916.6219.2221.45
LTA57.5116.7215.3260.7988.87
NPL7.808.221.135.4836.91
ROA0.090.73−2.680.251.05
DEP47.3116.835.8448.5585.19
Table 3. Impact of ECB monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank default risk and on the slope of the default risk term structure curve. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations used bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
Table 3. Impact of ECB monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank default risk and on the slope of the default risk term structure curve. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations used bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
(1)(2)(3)
Short-TermLong-TermSlope
Monetary Policy−4.44 ***−0.144.30 ***
(1.58)(0.38)(1.31)
CAP21.60−9.97−31.57
(27.29)(10.01)(21.77)
NPL−4.130.854.98
(3.34)(0.77)(3.28)
SIZE146.26−66.69−212.95 **
(112.23)(43.69)(88.16)
DEP−11.79 ***−1.2410.55 ***
(3.26)(0.90)(2.74)
ROA−107.14 ***−50.02 ***57.12 *
(34.05)(9.58)(29.46)
LTA4.812.09 **−2.72
(4.46)(0.98)(4.08)
Euro Stoxx−0.18 ***−0.17 ***0.01
(0.06)(0.02)(0.06)
VSTOXX1.46−0.29−1.76 *
(1.17)(0.35)(1.03)
Bank fixed effectsYesYesYes
Time fixed effectsNoNoNo
R 2 0.180.270.11
No. Obs.23,50523,50523,505
No. Banks454545
Table 4. Impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank default risk and on the slope of the default risk term structure curve for the core and peripheral Euro Area banks. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations use bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
Table 4. Impact of monetary policy on short-term and long-term bank default risk and on the slope of the default risk term structure curve for the core and peripheral Euro Area banks. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations use bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
(1)(2)(3)
Short-TermLong-TermSlope
Monetary Policy−2.95 ***−0.81 *2.14 ***
(1.06)(0.46)(0.77)
Monetary Policy × Periphery−2.821.584.40 *
(3.19)(1.01)(2.59)
Bank fixed effectsYesYesYes
Time fixed effectsNoNoNo
Bank control variablesYesYesYes
Macro control variablesYesYesYes
R 2 0.20.290.13
No. Obs.23,50523,50523,505
No. Banks454545
Table 5. Time variation in the association between ECB monetary policy and short-term and long-term bank credit risk, using year dummies. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations use bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
Table 5. Time variation in the association between ECB monetary policy and short-term and long-term bank credit risk, using year dummies. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations use bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
(1)(2)
Short-TermLong-Term
Monetary Policy × 2009−8.05 *−1.83
(4.25)(1.75)
Monetary Policy × 2010−21.37 **−13.40 ***
(8.61)(3.54)
Monetary Policy × 2011−37.50 ***−11.44 ***
(11.50)(3.17)
Monetary Policy × 2012−28.26 ***−18.85 ***
(5.09)(2.16)
Monetary Policy × 20132.881.04
(3.64)(1.97)
Monetary Policy × 2014−0.743.02 ***
(1.04)(0.74)
Monetary Policy × 20152.01 *1.15
(1.10)(0.78)
Monetary Policy × 2016−4.61−8.20 **
(2.82)(3.60)
Monetary Policy × 2017−9.40−12.82 **
(8.20)(5.79)
Monetary Policy × 20186.738.38 ***
(4.36)(2.16)
Monetary Policy × 20199.50 ***5.24 ***
(2.96)(1.65)
Monetary Policy × 202010.60 ***6.08 ***
(2.40)(0.95)
Bank fixed effectsYesYes
Time fixed effectsNoNo
Bank control variablesYesYes
Macro control variablesYesYes
R 2 0.240.46
No. Obs.23,50523,505
No. Banks4545
Table 6. Impact of deposits on the transmission of monetary policy, based on Equation (8). This table shows the heterogeneous association between monetary policy, bank characteristics, and macro controls on short- and long-term bank default risk based on bank deposits. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations use bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
Table 6. Impact of deposits on the transmission of monetary policy, based on Equation (8). This table shows the heterogeneous association between monetary policy, bank characteristics, and macro controls on short- and long-term bank default risk based on bank deposits. Short-term default risk is estimated as the sum of the level ( β 0 ) and slope ( β 1 ) parameter from the Svensson model. Long-term default risk is defined by the level parameter. All estimations use bank fixed effects to control for unobserved heterogeneity and macro variables to control for common macroeconomic shocks. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the bank level. *, **, and *** represent significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level, respectively.
(1)(2)
Short-TermLong-Term
Monetary Policy−6.84 **−2.29 *
(2.78)(1.36)
Monetary Policy × Deposits0.050.04 *
(0.05)(0.03)
Bank fixed effectsYesYes
Time fixed effectsNoNo
R 2 0.180.27
No. Obs.23,50523,505
No. Banks4545
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Beernaert, T.; Soenen, N.; Vander Vennet, R. ECB Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Bank Default Risk. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16, 507. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16120507

AMA Style

Beernaert T, Soenen N, Vander Vennet R. ECB Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Bank Default Risk. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2023; 16(12):507. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16120507

Chicago/Turabian Style

Beernaert, Tom, Nicolas Soenen, and Rudi Vander Vennet. 2023. "ECB Monetary Policy and the Term Structure of Bank Default Risk" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 16, no. 12: 507. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16120507

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop