Next Article in Journal
Time to Assess Bias in Machine Learning Models for Credit Decisions
Next Article in Special Issue
Audit Committee Diversity, Analysts’ Forecast Accuracy and Earnings Management: Evidence from Malaysia
Previous Article in Journal
Digital Twin: Financial Technology’s Next Frontier of Robo-Advisor
Previous Article in Special Issue
Ownership Structure and Firm Performance in the Middle East: A Meta-Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Theoretical Investigation on the Optimal Contracting for Directors Holding Multiple Directorships

Reh School of Business, Clarkson University, Potsdam, NY 13676, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15(4), 164; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040164
Submission received: 22 February 2022 / Revised: 27 March 2022 / Accepted: 29 March 2022 / Published: 4 April 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Corporate Governance and Its Impact on Accounting and Finance II)

Abstract

:
This paper is the first (to our knowledge) to analytically model the optimal contracting for a member of the board of directors who holds multiple directorships. Prior literature has found conflicting evidence on the overall effect of multiple directorships on shareholder welfare: busy board members are usually detrimental to firm operating performance due to the limited time and effort they are able to devote to each board; however, multiple directorships can be beneficial to firms if the board members gain knowledge and expertise through their multiple appointments. The objective of our study is to expand the research on the effects of multiple directorships on shareholder welfare by modeling the relationship between optimal incentives (pay–performance sensitivity) and the number of directorships. Modeling within the Linear–Exponential–Normal framework, and solving using Subgame-Perfect Nash Equilibrium, we find that this relationship is positive when efforts across directorships are either substitutive or complementary, which highlights another potential significant downside to multiple directorships: companies need to offer high incentive-based pay to compete for directors’ efforts, leading to high-risk premia and welfare loss to shareholders. Our results may be of interest to policy makers considering setting limits on the number of board seats that may be held by directors at public companies, as well as shareholders considering appointing directors with multiple appointments.

1. Introduction

A unique feature of the independent director market is multiple directorships. According to Institutional Shareholder Services (RiskMetrics), more than half of all independent directors hold numerous directorships (Brown et al. 2019). Prior literature has focused on whether multiple directorships result in overcommitted (or “overboarded”) directors, whose time and attention are stretched too thinly to properly complete their duties on any given board, and thus multiple directorships can destroy shareholder value and be detrimental to monitoring and corporate governance (Fich and Shivdasani 2006; Ahn et al. 2010; Andres et al. 2013; Falato et al. 2014; Hauser 2018; Al Lawati and Hussainey 2021). On the other hand, serving on multiple boards allows directors to gain access to valuable skills and industry information that can help their performance in advising managers on strategy (Field et al. 2013; Kuang and Sharma 2014; Brown et al. 2019; Liu et al. forthcoming). This study develops an analytical model of directors holding multiple board seats in order to examine another important, and heretofore unexplored, aspect of multiple directorships: optimal contracting for directors’ compensation.
The academic literature has exhaustively studied executive compensation (e.g., see Holstrom 1979; Grossman and Hart 1983; Jensen and Murphy 1990; Core et al. 1999; Becht et al. 2003; Masulis 2020; Choi et al. 2021; Wang et al. forthcoming). However, research on director compensation is relatively underexplored (Brick et al. 2006; Adams et al. 2010; Chen et al. 2019; Donelson et al. forthcoming; Melis and Rombi 2021). In particular, theoretical analysis on the board of directors is scarce in two key areas: (1) analytical models of multiple directorships, and (2) director compensation. To the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to analytically model the optimal contracting for directors with multiple directorships. More specifically, we model multiple directorships and optimal contracting in order to explore several research questions: (1) are multiple directorships associated with more or less incentive-based pay? (2) is this affected by whether director efforts on multiple boards are complementary or substitutive? and (3) what are the determinants of the optimal number of board seats and optimal compensation structure for an outside director? These questions are interesting and important because they may shed light on the interaction between different companies’ boards. In addition, investigating these issues deepens our understanding of the trade-offs between risk sharing and incentive provisions. Last, the answers to these questions may yield important policy implications, especially with respect to the public policy debate on whether directors’ multiple board seats should be limited.
In our model, multiple companies compete for a director’s efforts. An outside director can determine the number of boards they will serve on before the companies offer compensation contracts including performance payments (pay–performance sensitivity, hereafter, PPS, and fixed salary). Next, the director chooses efforts for each company. In the end, the output for each company is realized, and the companies make payments to the outside director.
Our model yields a number of new results. First, when the number of directorships is exogenous, there are two effects regarding the relationship between the number of directorships N and incentives (or PPS): the competition effect and the task interaction effect. As the number of directorships increases, the competition effect means that more companies compete for the same directors to serve on their board. Thus, companies offer more significant incentives, leading to a positive relationship between the number of directorships and the level of incentive-based pay. This means that, empirically, we should observe a positive association between multiple directorships and incentive-based pay; thus, this opens the door for future empirical studies to test this theoretical prediction.
Next, for the task interaction effect, directors’ efforts may be complementary or substitutive across tasks. When efforts are substitutive, as directorships increase, it is more costly to induce the director to work hard; this means that firms face a higher marginal cost of incentivizing the director to work harder, leading to a negative relationship between the number of directorships and incentives. In practice, substitutive efforts could exist in multiple scenarios: for example, when board members serve on the boards of firms in different industries (which is possible, due to non-compete agreements limiting directors’ service on competitor boards), and thus knowledge synergies are scarce, or if they serve on difference committees on different boards.
On the contrary, when efforts are complementary, as directorships increase, it is less costly to induce the director to work hard; this leads to a positive relationship between the number of directorships and the incentives, as the marginal cost of incentivizing the director to work harder is lower. In practice, complementary efforts for board members with multiple directorships are likely quite common, as directors frequently specialize in a given industry, and thus knowledge gained on one board may be useful to another board.
However, overall, our model concludes that multiple directorships are positively associated with incentive-based pay whether director efforts are substitutive or complementary: (1) when efforts are complementary, the association between incentives and the number of directorships is positive, since both the competition and task interaction effects are positive; (2) when efforts are substitutive, the relationship is still positive, because the competition effect dominates the task interaction effect. This yields some interesting and novel predictions, paving the way for future empirical research on interlocked board synergies, director pay structure, and firm performance.
Further, we examine how the optimal number of directorships is determined endogenously and the optimal incentives. We numerically conduct comparative static analyses, as the closed-form solutions are not available. The numerical analyses yield a number of findings on the optimal number of directorships and substitutive efforts: (1) outside directors with greater abilities serve on more boards, (2) less risk-averse directors also serve on more boards, (3) the riskier the firms are, the fewer directorships the outside director holds, and (4) the optimal number of directorships decreases with the degree of substitution. Moreover, after endogenizing the optimal number of directorships, we find some results on optimal incentives with substitutive efforts: (1) companies provide more muted incentives for more risk-averse directors, (2) the optimal incentives decrease with companies’ riskiness, (3) directors with greater abilities are offered stronger incentives, and (4) the optimal incentives increase with the degree of substitution.
This paper may help inform the policy debate on potential restrictions on the number of board seats that outside directors of public firms may hold. Although there are currently no broad policy restrictions in the US, there exists investor pressure toward such regulation, as investors are increasingly resistant to “overboarded” or busy directors (Papadopoulos 2019). In fact, many companies have their own policies limiting director board seats (about 44% of Russell 3000 companies have such policies), although the limits tend to be high, at a maximum of four or more board seats (Tonello 2020). In contrast, the maximum number of directorships an independent director can hold in China is five. Further, the Professional Organization for Non-Executive Directors recommends devoting 1.5 days per week to each board seat; therefore, one can easily imagine that directors holding multiple appointments might be “too busy” to successfully fulfill their role at each board. The primary board policy restrictions in the U.S. relate to majority board independence requirements under the Sarbanes–Oxley Act (SOX): in the era immediately preceding SOX, circa 1998–2002, there were many prominent accounting frauds and scandals due to the breakdown in corporate governance at public U.S. firms. Under SOX, adopted in 2002, public company boards are required to have a majority of independent directors. Our study lends evidence to this general policy debate by offering evidence of another drawback to overboarded directors: the cost to shareholders and firms from offering excessive incentive-based pay in order to attract directors with multiple board seats, leading to high-risk premia and welfare losses.
This paper is also relevant to the empirical literature on busy boards and their effect on firm value, which tends to be mixed. Several studies find that busy directors (or directors with multiple board seats) are detrimental to find value (Fich and Shivdasani 2006; Ahn et al. 2010; Falato et al. 2014; Hauser 2018), or associated with aggressive firm practices (Andres et al. 2013; Al Lawati and Hussainey 2021), presumably because they are too busy to monitor firm and executive activity. Others document a positive effect of multiple directorships on advising activity (Field et al. 2013), and/or operating activity, especially when directors serve on board seats with strong connections (Brown et al. 2019). Finally, several studies document that directors with multiple board seats may excel at allocating time and monitoring efforts toward the audit committee and firm audit monitoring, perhaps due to concerns about their reputation (Kuang and Sharma 2014; Liu et al. forthcoming).
Our paper contributes to this literature on the benefits and costs of multiple directorships in several ways. First, we propose a heretofore unexplored cost of director busyness: the incentive pay required to attract these directors, which can be detrimental to shareholder welfare. In fact, we find that, due to the competition effect, the relationship between multiple directorships and incentive-based pay is positive, whether director efforts on multiple boards are complementary or substitutive. We also offer many testable hypotheses for empirical studies, including cross-sectional predictions on the optimal number of directorships and optimal incentives. For example, our findings on director effort complementarity and substitutability speak more broadly to studies on firm strategy and operations (Adamides and Karacapilidis 2020). In summary, Table 1 displays a SWOT analysis of the current literature and policy debate on multiple directorships, including our findings.
This paper is also associated with the literature on common agency (e.g., see Martimort 1996; Dixit et al. 1997; Martimort and Stole 2002; Bergemann and Valimaki 2003). Bernheim and Whinston (1986) show that a noncooperative menu auction has an efficient equilibrium among the principals. There have been some applications. For example, Grossman and Helpman (1994) apply the model to the setting of tariffs lobbying, and Dixit (1996) applies it to producer taxes and subsidies. This line of literature on common agency focuses on whether the efficient outcome can be achieved. However, our paper focuses on the relationship between incentives, the number of principals, and their determinants. This relationship has not heretofore been explored in the existing literature.
Finally, this paper builds on the Linear–Exponential–Neutral (LEN) framework. According to Lambert (2001), the model in this paper belongs to the class of multi-action models using the LEN framework (e.g., Bushman and Indjejikian 1993; Feltham and Xie 1994; Hemmer 1995; and Rajan and Reichelstein 2004). In particular, it is related to the optimal number of partnerships (Huddart and Liang 2005; and Liang et al. 2008). Huddart and Liang (2005) investigate optimal partnership size, profit shares, and inventive payments when every partner performs the same tasks and find that smaller or larger partnerships dominate medium-sized partnerships. Liang et al. (2008) explore the optimal team size and monitoring in organizations and document complementarities between team size and monitoring and between worker talent and managerial monitoring ability. The distinguishing feature of our model is that multiple principals offer incentive contracts simultaneously to compete for the same agent’s costly efforts. Thus, the interplay between principals plays a key role, and the externality one principal imposes on others needs to be considered.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses prior literature. The model is presented in Section 3. Section 4 concludes the paper. Appendix A and Appendix B contain all of the proofs.

2. Literature Review

There is a broad body of literature on multiple directorships, with mixed findings on the effects of multiple directorships on firm outcomes. First, Ferris et al. (2003) find no evidence that directors with multiple directorships shirk their responsibilities to serve on board committees or are associated with more securities fraud litigation. These findings are consistent with Fama and Jensen’s (1983) reputation hypothesis. However, a number of studies find that multiple directorships harm firm value because directors are too busy to devote sufficient time and attention to each board seat. Fich and Shivdasani (2006) find that companies with busy boards are less profitable and have lower sensitivity of CEO turnover to financial performance. Ahn et al. (2010) find that firms where independent directors hold more outside board seats have more negative abnormal returns. Falato et al. (2014) find that an exogenous increase in board busyness (due to sudden director deaths at another board the director serves on) negatively impacts firm value. Hauser (2018) finds that an exogenous decrease in board busyness (due to M&A terminating another board that the director serves on) is associated with increases in firm value. Still others find that directors with multiple board seats and audit committee membership engage in aggressive practices: Andres et al. (2013) find that firms with busier boards (defined using the degree of board connections) are associated with poorer firm performance and higher executive pay, while Al Lawati and Hussainey (2021) report that overlapped audit committee members and chairs are associated with more aggressive tax avoidance.
On the other hand, multiple directorships can lead to synergies, or complementarities, across different companies the same director serves on (i.e., “interlocked boards”). For example, if a director serves on the boards of two companies in the same industry simultaneously, the more effort she invests in one company, the more familiar she will be with the industry. Thus, her marginal cost of effort will be lower. Directors serving on well-connected boards also gain access to contacts and knowledge that can benefit each additional board they serve on. Consistent with this idea, Field et al. (2013) find that busy boards are associated with higher firm value for IPO firms. Brown et al. (2019) find that an exogenous decrease in director busyness (due to M&A terminating a board) is associated with null or negative effects to operating performance and advising when directors lose access to a very well-connected board, which suggests that connections gained from multiple appointments can be beneficial to director performance. Further, Liu et al. (forthcoming) find that directors who serve on multiple audit committees allocate their time and effort to each committee based on firm risk, which implies that directors may be able to successfully allocate their time and energy to where it is most needed. Indeed, Kuang and Sharma (2014) find that they are associated with less aggressive earnings management, presumably due to the potential adverse effects of restatements on their reputation.
A relatively smaller body of literature examines director compensation. Brick et al. (2006) document that director pay displays characteristics of cronyism: director pay is positively associated with CEO pay, and negatively associated with firm performance. Chen et al. (2019) similarly find that excess director compensation is symptomatic of cronyism and agency problems. Melis and Rombi (2021) find that country-level institutional characteristics as well as firm- and director-level characteristics drive observed variation in the compensation of independent directors. Finally, Donelson et al. (forthcoming) examine how changes in director litigation risk affect director compensation.
We know of no previous studies connecting multiple directorships with the structure of director compensation and incentive-based pay. Our study combines these two literatures—the literature on the benefits and costs of multiple directorships, and the literature on director compensation—by modeling the association between multiple directorships and director compensation structure in order to reach important and novel findings on director busyness and director pay.

3. Model and Method

3.1. Model

In the initial model, an outside director works for N companies simultaneously. Within the LEN (Linear–Exponential–Normal) framework, we assume the outside director’s effort can improve the companies’ outputs. However, efforts are unobservable, and payments can only be based on the actual output, which equals the effort plus a random noise, i.e., y i   m i + ϵ i where ϵ i     N   ( 0 ,   σ i 2 ) and ϵ i is independently and identically distributed across i ,   i     { 1 ,   2 , ,   N   } . For simplicity, we assume σ i 2 = σ 2 for all i in the initial model and consider the case of different variances in the extension. The outside director is risk-averse with exponential utility, and the risk-aversion coefficient is γ. Therefore, her utility maximization problem is equivalent to maximizing the certainty equivalence C E = E [ ( b i y i + k i ) 1 2 γ V a r [ ( b i y i + k i ) ] C ( m 1 , m 2 , m N )   where   C ( m 1 , m 2 , m N ) = c ( m 1 2 + m 2 2 + + m N 2 + p i = 1 N j < i m i m j ) . When p ≥ 2, the substitution among efforts is so strong that the outside director exerts all effort on a single company, which is unrealistic. Thus, we assume that p < 2 in the following analysis. We allow the parameter p to be negative, which means there is complementarity (synergy) among the effort spent in different companies. However, when p is negative, we assume it is not so negative that the total cost C ( m 1 , m 2 , m N ) would be negative, suggesting that p 2 N ( N 1 ) . Generally, the cost function’s parameter p captures the degree of substitution and complementarity among the effort spent on different companies. On the one hand, a director has limited time and energy, and works for several companies simultaneously. If she exerts more effort m i in firm i , her marginal cost for firm j , C m j , is higher, which is the case when efforts are substitutive. On the other hand, there could also be synergy among efforts spent on different companies. For example, if an outside director works for several companies in the same industry, she gains valuable knowledge and connections within the industry. Thus, if she exerts more effort at firm i , her marginal cost for firm j , C m j   , can be lower. Aside from the assumption that the director is risk-averse, the companies’ shareholders can hold a diversified portfolio. Thus, it is assumed that the companies are risk-neutral, and their objectives are to maximize the expected profits.
At the beginning of the game, the outside director can choose the number of directorships N, becoming common knowledge. N is exogenously given in the initial model. The compensation scheme for outside directors is modeled as a fixed payment k i plus some share of the company’s output b i y i . Following the literature on CEO compensation, we call b i PPS. In this model, the outside director has bargained with the N companies. The companies pick incentives b i   ( i   1 ,   2 ,   N   )   and the director chooses a fixed payment k i and efforts to spend in each company m i subject to the director’s incentive compatibility (IC) constraint and the companies’ rationality (IR) constraint that companies’ profit is greater than or equal to the outside option. The justification for this assumption is that there is not enough supply of directors. The director has more bargaining power and can set the fixed salary to extract the surplus. The outside options for all the N companies are assumed to be u ¯ . For simplicity, the outside option is normalized to be zero in the following analyses.
To summarize, the timeline of the model is as follows:
  • At t = 0, the director chooses the number of companies (N) that she will serve on, and this information is common knowledge afterward.
  • At t = 1, in the negotiation, the N companies simultaneously offer a bonus or incentive rate { b i } i = 1 N and fixed salary { k i   } i = 1 N to the director.
  • At t = 2, the director decides whether to accept the contracts or not. If she accepts, she exerts effort for each company, i.e., { m i } i = 1 N . These efforts are unobservable.
  • At t = 3, given efforts { m i } i = 1 N , the output of the N companies { y i } i = 1 N are realized, and the payments to the director { k i + b i y i } i = 1 N   are made to the director.
The backward induction approach is employed to solve the game, and the solution concept is SPNE (Subgame-Perfect Nash Equilibrium). At t = 2, given the choice of N and the incentive contracts { b i ,   k i } i = 1 N , the director chooses efforts { m i } i = 1 N to maximize her utility. Lemma 1 gives the director’s optimal effort as the best response to the incentive contracts.
Lemma 1.
Given the number of directorships, N, and incentive contracts ( { b i } i = 1 N ) offered by companies, the outside director chooses efforts { m i } i = 1 N to maximize her utility, and the optimal efforts are m i * = 1 c ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) [ ( 2 2 p + p N ) b i p ( j i b j ) ] for all i = 1 , 2 N .
Proof .
Please see Appendix A. □
This result is intuitive and straightforward. If firm i offers stronger incentives, the director will exert more effort for firm i . If p is positive, the efforts are substitutive. The lower the incentives other companies provide, the more efforts the director will exert on firm i . If p is negative, the efforts are complementary, so the stronger the incentives firm j offers, the more effort the director exerts for firm i. If the effort is less costly (the parameter c is smaller), the levels of effort for all companies are higher.
Then, given the outside director’s optimal effort choice, the optimal linear contract is summarized in Proposition 1.
Proposition 1.
The optimal contract offered by each company is b i * = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N ) + ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) c r σ 2 ,   i = 1 , 2 N , and the corresponding fixed payments are k i = ( 1 b i ) b i * c 1 ( 2 p + p N ) u ¯ . For the solution to exist, the restriction on parameters should be such that 2 N ( N 1 ) p < 2 ( N 1 ) and the outside option should not be too large, u ¯ ( 1 b i * ) b i * c 1 ( 2 p + p N ) . The outside option u   ¯ is normalized to be zero.
Proof .
Please see Appendix A. □
The interior solution only exists if the value function is still positive, so the outside option cannot be too large. For simplicity, the outside option is normalized to be zero in the following analyses.

3.2. Comparative Static Analysis When the Number of Directorships N Is Treated as Exogenous

From the above proposition in Section 3.1, we know that the incentive (PPS) b i * depends on the riskiness of companies σ 2 , the coefficient of risk-aversion of the director γ, the cost of efforts c (or equivalently, the ability of the director), the number of directorships N , and the parameter p . In this subsection, some comparative static analyses are conducted.
First, the following proposition summarizes the comparative static analyses of incentive (PPS) b i * , considering parameters c, γ, p, and σ 2 .
Proposition 2.
The comparative static analyses suggest that b i * c < 0 , b i * γ < 0 , and b i * σ 2 < 0 . Concerning b i * p , the results show that b i * p < 0 when p < 0 and b i * p > 0 when p > 0 .
Proof .
Please see Appendix A. □
The standard trade-off between risk-sharing and incentive provisions still applies here. Companies provide lower incentives for more risk-averse directors, since it is more costly to expose them to risk. Risk-sharing is more critical for riskier companies, leading to lower incentives in equilibrium. If a director has greater ability (i.e., the coefficient c in the cost function is smaller), the director’s efforts are more valuable. Thus, companies offer stronger incentives to induce the director to work hard. Regarding the comparative static analyses on p, when p > 0 ,   b i * p > 0 , suggesting that when efforts become more substitutive, the optimal incentives are greater because companies face fiercer competition. On the other hand, when p < 0, b i * p < 0 , suggesting that when efforts become more complementary (p < 0 and p becomes more negative), the optimal incentives are greater due to companies’ strategic behavior. Specifically, company i would like to offer greater incentives, attracting more effort for firm i , which in turn reduces the marginal cost for other companies, and induces them to provide more significant incentives and attract more efforts for other firms. This is beneficial to firm i itself due to the reduced marginal cost. This phenomenon is similar to strategic complements in industrial organizations (Bulow et al. 1985; Fudenberg and Tirole 1989).
Next, we summarize the relationship between incentives and the number of directorships N in the following proposition:
Proposition 3.
The marginal effect of the number of directorships N on the optimal incentive bis positive, i.e., b i * N > 0 .
Proof .
Please see Appendix A. □
When the number of directorships is exogenously given, when exploring the relationship between the number of directorships N and incentives (or PPS), there are two effects: the competition effect and the task interaction effect. As the number of directorships increases, the competition effect suggests that more companies compete for the same director’s effort. Thus, companies will offer more significant incentives, leading to a positive relationship between the number of directorships and incentives. The task interaction effect depends on whether efforts are complementary or substitutive across tasks. When efforts are substitutive with more directorships, it becomes more costly to induce the director to work hard, leading to a negative relationship between the number of directorships and incentives. However, when efforts are complementary, with more directorships, it is less costly to induce the director to work hard, leading to a positive relationship between the number of directorships and the incentives. However, overall, the model finds that: (1) when efforts are complementary, the association between incentives and the number of directorships is positive, since both the competition and task interaction effects are positive, and (2) when substituting efforts, the relationship is still positive because the competition effect dominates the task interaction effect.
In summary, when the number of directorships is exogenous, whether efforts are substitutive or complementary, the relationship between the number of directorships and incentives is always positive, i.e., with more multiple directorships, companies offer more significant incentives.

3.3. Special Case: p = 0

After solving the model, it is interesting to consider a special case and compare the results to those from other classical models. Corollary 1 provides the results when p = 0.
Corollary 1.
When p = 0, the optimal contract is b i * ( p = 0 ) = 1 1 + 2 c r γ σ 2 , the same as the classical one-principal-one-agent Linear–Exponential–Neutral (LEN) framework.
Proof .
Plugging in p = 0 into the expression for b i * gives us b i * ( p = 0 ) = 1 1 + 2 c r γ σ 2 .
When p = 0, this model is equivalent to the one-principal-one-agent Linear–Exponential–Neutral (LEN) framework. The intuition for the equivalence is straightforward. Unlike the one-principal-one-agent framework, multiple principals compete for a director’s efforts. The interaction occurs through the non-separability in the cost function, and depending on whether p is positive or negative, if the director exerts more effort for company i , the marginal cost for effort at other companies may increase or decrease. When p = 0, the efforts are neither substitutive nor complementary, and thus there is no interaction between contracts offered by different companies. So, the result restores the one-principal-one-agent framework.

3.4. Determining the Optimal Number of Directorships

After solving the optimal contracts given the director’s choice of the number of companies to work for N, we turn to the outside director’s optimal decision of this number at the beginning of the game. The following proposition implicitly specifies the optimal number of directorships the outside director chooses and its determinants.
Proposition 4.
The optimal number of directorships N is determined by the director to maximize the following objective function:
P a y o f f = N 1 c ( 2 p + p N ) ( b i * b i * 2 2 ) N 1 2 γ σ 2 b i * 2   where   b i * = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) c γ σ 2 + ( 2 2 p + p N ) .
Proof .
Please see Appendix A. □
In the above proposition, the companies’ outside options are normalized to zero. To maximize her payoff, the director decides the optimal number of directorships (N). The function Payoff (.) is complicated, and it is impossible to get a closed-form solution from the first-order condition. We then conduct some numerical analyses on the optimal number of directorships N.
When p < 0, the efforts are complementary. The more directorships the director holds, the lower the “equivalent” cost, and thus, the director would like to hold as many directorships as possible. The boundary condition in Proposition 1 determines the optimal number of directorships. This case is less interesting. Thus, we only focus on the cases with substitutive efforts in the following numerical analysis. When p > 0, efforts are substitutive. Following Figure 1, the payoff first increases and then decreases with the number of directorships. The number of directorships that generate the highest payoff for the director is denoted as the optimal number of directorships. We also try other parameter values and find similar patterns. However, as we cannot get a closed-form solution, this conclusion may not hold with some parameter values.

3.5. Comparative Static Analyses on the Optimal Number of Directorships and the Optimal Incentives

Some comparative static analyses on the optimal number of directorships considering parameters are available using numerical calculations.
First, in Graph 2.1 of Figure 2, the relationship between the optimal number of directorships and p is negative. Intuitively, when efforts become more substitutive, serving on more boards will increase the “equivalent” cost of efforts, and thus, the director serves on a few boards.
Second, in Figure 2, from the graphs, we can see that the relationships between the optimal number of directorships and c (the cost of effort), γ, and σ 2 are all negative. Intuitively, these three graphs can be explained as: (1) the outside director with greater ability (whose parameter c in the cost function is smaller) serves on more boards, (2) the less risk-averse director serves on more boards, and (3) the riskier the firms, the smaller the number of directorships the outside director holds, i.e., N * c < 0 , N * γ < 0 , N * σ 2 < 0 . Again, there is a caveat that these results may not hold with other parameter values.
After determining the optimal number of directorships, using numerical analyses, we can recalculate the comparative static analyses for the optimal incentive b i * at the optimal number of directorships N * .
From the graphs of Figure 3, when p > 0, the optimal incentive (PPS) b i * is increasing with the degree of substitution. Intuitively, the optimal incentives are greater because companies face fiercer competition.
From Figure 3, we find that the standard trade-off between risk-sharing and incentive provisions still applies even after endogenizing the optimal number of directorships. Companies provide lower incentives for more risk-averse directors, since it is more costly to incentivize them to be exposed to risk. Risk-sharing is more critical for riskier companies, leading to lower incentives. Directors with greater ability are offered stronger incentives. Of course, these results may not hold with other parameter values.

4. Conclusions

Outside directors are crucial to a company’s corporate governance. A unique phenomenon in the outside director market is that outside directors frequently hold multiple board seats, and so they work for multiple firms simultaneously. To our knowledge, this paper is the first to analytically model the relationship between the number of directorships and incentive contracts. We find that when the number of directorships is exogenous, the relationship between the number of directorships N and incentive-based pay (PPS) is always positive, i.e., with more directorships, companies should offer more incentive-based pay. More specifically, the model finds that: (1) when efforts are complementary across boards, the association between incentive pay and the number of directorships is positive, since both the competition and task interaction effects are positive; and (2) when efforts are substitutive, the overall relationship is still positive, because the competition effect dominates the task interaction effect.
Next, we find some results on the determinants of the optimal number of directorships an outside director chooses, as well as optimal incentive contracting. Using comparative static analyses, we find that within some parameter values, with substitutive efforts, outside directors with greater ability serve on more boards, less risk-averse directors serve on more boards, and riskier firms have fewer multiple directorships. Moreover, when efforts across companies are more substitutive, outside directors serve on fewer boards. Numerical comparative static analyses on optimal incentives, after endogenizing the number of directorships, N, find that companies provide more muted incentives for more risk-averse directors, optimal incentives decrease with the companies’ riskiness, directors with a greater ability are offered stronger incentives, and optimal incentives increase with the degree of substitution.
All of our findings may be applied to empirical research, and offer avenues for researchers to test new predictions on the associations between multiple directorships, director pay, and complementarities or interlocks across boards of directors. For example, future empirical research based on our models may examine whether multiple directorships are associated with incentive-based pay, and whether director effort complementarity or substitutability (which may be measured by board interlocks, or the degree of firm similarity among interlocked boards) affect this association. Further, our findings contribute to the policy discussion on proposed limits to the number of board seats that outside directors may serve on by offering evidence of a previously unexplored consequence of multiple directorships: in order to attract directors with multiple board seats, firms must offer high incentive-based pay, leading to higher risk premia and welfare losses than the socially optimal level.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, G.L. and A.B.B.; methodology, formal analysis, data curation and writing—original draft preparation, G.L.; writing—review, validation, editing and supervision, A.B.B. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Proofs

Proof of Lemma 1.
Given incentive contracts { k i , b i } i = 1 { N ) , the outside director will choose { m i }   i = 1 N to maximize the Certainty Equivalent.
Thus, the optimization problem becomes:
Max U d = C E = i = 1 N [ b i E ( y i | m i ) 1 2 γ b σ 2 ] c ( m 1 2 + m 2 2 + + m N 2 + p i = 1 N j < i m i m j ) .
Subject to m i 0 for all i (non-negativity constraint).
We know that E ( y i | m i ) = E ( m i + e i | m i ) = m i .
From the First Order Condition, U d m i = b i c [ ( 2 p ) m i + p j = 1 N m j ] = 0 , i = 1 , 2 N .
Summing up all the N First Order Conditions results in:
i = 1 N b i c [ ( 2 p ) ( i = 1 N m i ) + p N ( i = 1 N m i ) ] = 0  
which implies i = 1 N m i = i = 1 N b i c ( 2 p + p N ) .
Plugging the above equation into the First Order Condition, we can get:
m i * = 1 c ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) [ ( 2 2 p + p N ) b i p ( j i b j ) ] ,   i = 1 , 2 N
Proof of Proposition 1.
Given the outside director’s best response function { m i } i = 1 N , company i will choose the contract { b i } i = 1 N to maximize the expected profit or surplus. The optimization problem is as follows:
Max E π i = ( 1 b i ) E y i k i = m i k i b i m i .
Subject to (IC for directors) m i * = 1 c ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) [ ( 2 2 p + p N ) b i p   ( j i b j ) ] > 0 .
The first-order condition considering the optimal PPS gives:
b i * = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) c γ σ 2 + ( 2 2 p + p N )
Then, we can plug in the solution for b i into the expression for the optimal effort to get:
m i * = b i * c 1 ( 2 p + p N ) = 1 c ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) c γ σ 2 + ( 2 2 p + p N )
In addition, the director picks k i so that the firm’s profit is equal to the outside option.
(IR for the firm) m i b i m i k i = 0 (for simplicity, assuming that u i ¯ = u ¯ = 0 , i = 1 , 2 N )
From the above IR constraint, we can get:
k i = ( 1 b i ) m i u ¯ = ( 1 b i * ) b i * c 1 ( 2 p + p N ) u ¯
where
b i * = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) c γ σ 2 + ( 2 2 p + p N )
The parameter restriction is that 2 N ( N 1 ) p < 2 ( N 1 ) and the outside option u ¯ ( 1 b i * ) b i * c 1 ( 2 p + p N ) .
Proof of Proposition 2.
Simple calculations imply: b i * c < 0 ; b i * γ < 0 ; b i * σ 2 < 0 .
Next, we want to determine the sign of b i * p .
From b i * = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N ) + ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) c r σ 2 , we know
( 1 b i * 1 ) 1 c γ σ 2 = ( 1 + p 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p )
Therefore,
[ ( 1 b i * 1 ) 1 c γ σ 2 ] p = ( 1 + p 2 2 p + p N ) + ( 2 p ) 2 2 p + p N ( N 2 ) p ( 2 2 p + p N ) 2 = 2 ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N ) 2
So, [ ( 1 b i * 1 ) 1 c γ σ 2 ] p < 0 when p > 0 and [ ( 1 b i * 1 ) 1 c γ σ 2 ] p > 0 when p < 0 .
Thus, b i * p < 0 when p < 0 and b i * p > 0 when p > 0 .
Proof of Proposition 3.
Define t = c γ σ 2
Then, 1 b i = 1 + t ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N )
( 1 b i 1 ) t ( 2 p ) = 2 p + p N 2 2 p + p N = 1 + p 2 2 p + p N = 1 + 1 2 p 2 + N
A simple calculation shows that b i * N > 0 .
Proof of Proposition 4.
We know that the director’s utility equals all payments from the N companies minus the cost of efforts and minus the risk premium, i.e., E π { d } = N ( b i m i + k i ) N γ σ 2 b i 2 2 C ( m 1 , m N ) .
After plugging in the expressions, we get
P a y o f f = N 1 c ( 2 p + p N ) ( b b 2 2 ) N t c b 2   where   b = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) c γ σ 2 + ( 2 2 p + p N )
As before, the companies’ outside options are normalized to zero.
Proof of Proposition A1.
m i = 1 c ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) [ ( 2 2 p + p N ) b i p ( j i b j ) ] , i = 1 , 2 N
Then m i b i = ( 2 2 p + p N ) c ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) and m i b j = p c ( 2 p ) ( 2 p + p N ) for j i .
In the multitask model, the total profit for the principal who hires the director to perform N tasks is T P = i = 1 N [ m i 1 2 γ b i 2 σ 2 c m i ( m i + p j i m j ) ] = ( i = 1 N m i ) 1 2 γ σ 2 ( i = 1 N b i 2 ) ( 1 p ) c ( i = 1 N m i 2 ) p c ( i = 1 N m i ) 2 .
The First Order Condition gives: i = 1 , 2 N
T P b i = m i b i + ( N 1 ) m i b j γ σ 2 b i 2 ( 1 p ) c [ m i m i b i + ( N 1 ) m j m j b i ] 2 p c ( i = 1 N m i ) [ m i m i b i + ( N 1 ) m j m j b i ] = 0
In equilibrium, m i * = 1 c ( 2 p + p N ) b i * , i = 1 , 2 N .
Then, using N equations, we can solve for:
b i , M T * = ( 2 p + p N ) c γ σ 2 ( 2 p + p N ) 2 + 2 ( 1 p + p N ) , i = 1 , 2 N , where the subscript MT stands for multitask.
We recall that the optimal incentive under a common agency in the first model is:
b i , C A * = ( 2 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) c γ σ 2 + ( 2 2 p + p N )
Next, we want to show that when p > 0 ,   b i , M T * < b i , C A and, when p 0 , b i , M T * b i , C A .
Define t = c γ σ 2 > 0 , when p > 0 we need to show:
b i , M T * = ( 2 p + p N ) t ( 2 p + p N ) 2 + 2 ( 1 p + p N ) < ( 2 2 p + p N ) t ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 p ) + ( 2 2 p + p N )
Because the denominator is always positive, it is equivalent to show:
( 2 p + p N ) 2 ( 2 p ) t + ( 2 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N ) < ( 2 p + p N ) 2 ( 2 p + p N ) t + 2 ( 1 p + p N ) ( 2 2 p + p N )
which can be reduced to p N ( 2 p + p N ) 2 t p ( N 1 ) < 0 .
We know that t = c γ σ 2 > 0 , so, when p > 0 , the above inequality holds.
Similarly, we can show that, when p < 0 , b i , M T * > b i , C A .

Appendix B. Comparison between the Common Agency Setting and Multitask Model

The distinguishing feature of the initial model from the multitask model is that in the initial model, N companies offer contracts to compete for a director’s efforts, and they do not consider the negative externality they impose on other companies. However, in the (one-principal-one-agent) multitask model, the principal considers this externality and offers contracts for the multiple tasks, which is the case where N companies cooperate in the initial model. In this subsection, we derive the optimal contract in the multitask setting and compare it to the initial model. The following proposition gives the optimal contracts under the multitask setting.
Proposition A1.
Under the multitask (MT) setting, the optimal contract is
b i , M T * = ( 2 p + p N ) c γ σ 2 ( 2 p + p N ) 2 + 2 ( 1 p + p N ) .
Moreover, when p > 0 , b i , M T * < b i , C A * , and when p < 0 , b i , M T * > b i , C A * where b i , C A * is the optimal incentive in the initial model of the common agency.
Proof .
Please see Appendix A. □
Compared to the common agency setting, there is only one principal in the multitask model, and she hires the director to perform tasks for all the N companies. Thus, she considers the externality one company exerts on other firms when offering incentives. When p > 0 where efforts are substitutive, there is a negative externality when a company increases the incentive/bonus rate b. After taking this negative externality into account, the equilibrium incentives in the multitask model would be more muted than those under the common agency setting. On the contrary, when p < 0 , the efforts are complementary, and there is a positive externality when a company increases the bonus rate b i . The only principal in the multitask setting takes this positive externality into account. Thus, the equilibrium incentives under the multitask model would be greater than those under the common agency setting.

References

  1. Adamides, Emmanuel, and Nikos Karacapilidis. 2020. Information technology for supporting the development and maintenance of open innovation capabilities. Journal of Innovation & Knowledge 5: 29–38. [Google Scholar]
  2. Adams, Renee B., Benjamin E. Hermalin, and Michael S. Weisbach. 2010. The role of boards of directors in corporate governance: A conceptual framework and survey. Journal of Economic Literature 48: 58–107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  3. Ahn, Seoungpil, Pornsit Jiraporn, and Young Sang Kim. 2010. Multiple directorships and acquirer returns. Journal of Banking and Finance 34: 2011–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Al Lawati, Hidaya, and Khaled Hussainey. 2021. Do overlapped audit committee directors affect tax avoidance? Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14: 487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Andres, Christian, Inga van den Bongard, and Mirco Lehmann. 2013. Is busy really busy? Board governance revisited. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 40: 1221–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Becht, Marco, Patrick Bolton, and Ailsa Roell. 2003. Corporate governance and control. In Handbook of the Economics of Finance. Edited by G. M. Constantinides, M. Harris and R. M. Stulz. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 1, pp. 1–109. [Google Scholar]
  7. Bergemann, Dirk, and Juuso Valimaki. 2003. Dynamic common agency. Journal of Economic Theory 111: 23–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Michael D. Whinston. 1986. Common agency. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 54: 923–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Brick, Ivan E., Oded Palmon, and John K. Wald. 2006. CEO compensation, director compensation, and firm performance: Evidence of cronyism? Journal of Corporate Finance 12: 403–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Brown, Anna Bergman, Jing Dai, and Emanuel Zur. 2019. Too busy or well-connected? Evidence from a shock to multiple directorships. The Accounting Review 94: 83–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bulow, Jeremy I., John D. Geanakoplos, and Paul D. Klemperer. 1985. Multimarket oligopoly: Strategic substitutes and complements. Journal of Political Economy 93: 488–511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Bushman, Robert M., and Raffi J. Indjejikian. 1993. Accounting income, stock price, and managerial compensation. Journal of Accounting and Economics 16: 3–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Chen, Jie, Marc Goergen, Woon Sau Leung, and Wei Song. 2019. CEO and director compensation, CEO turnover and institutional investors: Is there cronyism in the UK? Journal of Banking and Finance 103: 18–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Choi, Sunhwa, Sunyoung Kim, Sewon Kwon, and Jae Yong Shin. 2021. Analyst forecasts and target setting in executive annual bonus contracts. Journal of Management Accounting Research 33: 19–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Core, John E., Robert W. Holthausen, and David F. Larcker. 1999. Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics 51: 371–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Dixit, Avinash. 1996. Special-interest lobbying and endogenous commodity taxation. Eastern Economic Journal 22: 375–88. [Google Scholar]
  17. Dixit, Avinash, Gene M. Grossman, and Elhanan Helpman. 1997. Common agency and coordination: General theory and application to government policymaking. Journal of Political Economy 105: 752–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Donelson, Dain C., Elizabeth Tori, and Christopher G. Yust. Forthcoming. The effects of independent director litigation risk. Contemporary Accounting Research. [CrossRef]
  19. Falato, Antonio, Dalida Kadyrzhanova, and Ugur Lel. 2014. Distracted directors: Does board busyness hurt shareholder value? Journal of Financial Economics 113: 404–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen. 1983. Separation of ownership and control. The Journal of Law and Economics 26: 301–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Feltham, Gerald A., and Jim Xie. 1994. Performance measure congruity and diversity in multitask principal/agent relations. The Accounting Review 69: 429–53. [Google Scholar]
  22. Ferris, Stephen P., Murali Jagannathan, and Adam C. Pritchard. 2003. Too busy to mind the business? Monitoring by directors with multiple board appointments. The Journal of Finance 58: 1087–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Fich, Eliezer M., and Anil Shivdasani. 2006. Are busy boards effective monitors? The Journal of Finance 61: 689–724. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Field, Laura, Michelle Lowry, and Anahit Mkrtchyan. 2013. Are busy boards detrimental? Journal of Financial Economics 109: 63–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Fudenberg, Drew, and Jean Tirole. 1989. Noncooperative game theory for industrial organizations: An introduction and overview. Handbook of Industrial Organization 1: 259–327. [Google Scholar]
  26. Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1994. Protection for sale. The American Economic Review 84: 833–50. [Google Scholar]
  27. Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart. 1983. An analysis of the principal-agent problem. Econometrica 51: 7–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Hauser, Roie. 2018. Busy directors and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics 128: 16–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Hemmer, Thomas. 1995. On the interrelation between production technology, job design, and incentives. Journal of Accounting and Economics 19: 209–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Holstrom, Bengt. 1979. Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics 10: 74–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Huddart, Steven, and Pierre Jinghong Liang. 2005. Profit-sharing and monitoring in partnerships. Journal of Accounting and Economics 40: 153–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Jensen, Michael C., and Kevin J. Murphy. 1990. Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy 98: 225–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Kuang, Chunli, and Vineeta D. Sharma. 2014. Voluntary audit committee characteristics, incentives, and aggressive earnings management: Evidence from New Zealand. International Journal of Auditing 18: 76–89. [Google Scholar]
  34. Lambert, Richard A. 2001. Contracting theory and accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics 32: 3–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Liang, Pierre Jinghong, Madhav V. Rajan, and Korok Ray. 2008. Optimal team size and monitoring in organizations. The Accounting Review 83: 789–822. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Liu, Xinming, Gerald J. Lobo, Hung-Chao Yu, and Zhen Zheng. Forthcoming. Multiple directorships and audit committee effectiveness: Evidence from effort allocation. European Accounting Review.
  37. Martimort, David. 1996. Exclusive dealing, common agency, and multi-principal incentive theory. The RAND Journal of Economics 27: 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Martimort, David, and Lars Stole. 2002. The revelation and delegation principles in common agency games. Econometrica 70: 1659–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  39. Masulis, Ronald W. 2020. A survey of recent evidence on boards of directors and C.E.O. incentives. Asia-Pacific Journal of Financial Studies 49: 7–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Melis, Andrea, and Luigi Rombi. 2021. Country-, firm-, and director-level risk and responsibilities and independent director compensation. Corporate Governance: An International Review 29: 222–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Papadopoulos, Kosmas. 2019. Director Overboard: Global Trends, Definitions, and Impact. Harvard Law School Forum on Corporate Governance. Available online: https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2019/08/05/director-overboarding-global-trends-definitions-and-impact/ (accessed on 21 February 2022).
  42. Rajan, Madhav V., and Stefan Reichelstein. 2004. A perspective on “Asymmetric information, incentives, and intra-firm resource allocation”. Management Science 50: 1615–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Tonello, Matteo. 2020. Corporate Board Practices in the Russell 3000 and S&P 500. Harvard Law School forum on Corporate Governance. Available online: https://corpgov.law.harvard.edu/2020/10/18/corporate-board-practices-in-the-russell-3000-and-sp-500/ (accessed on 21 February 2022).
  44. Wang, Weixiao, Lijuan Zhang, Mark Wilson, and Tejshree Kala. Forthcoming. SEC Compensation-related Comment Letters and Excess CEO Compensation. European Accounting Review. [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Relationship between payoff and the number of directorships.
Figure 1. Relationship between payoff and the number of directorships.
Jrfm 15 00164 g001
Figure 2. Comparative Static Analysis on the Optimal Number of Directorships.
Figure 2. Comparative Static Analysis on the Optimal Number of Directorships.
Jrfm 15 00164 g002
Figure 3. Comparative static analysis on the optimal incentive b i * , after endogenizing N.
Figure 3. Comparative static analysis on the optimal incentive b i * , after endogenizing N.
Jrfm 15 00164 g003
Table 1. SWOT analysis (strengths, weaknesses, opportunities, threats) of the effects of multiple directorships on firm welfare.
Table 1. SWOT analysis (strengths, weaknesses, opportunities, threats) of the effects of multiple directorships on firm welfare.
SWOT Analysis on Multiple Directorships
STRENGTHSWEAKNESSES
Directors can gain knowledge and connections from multiple board appointments that can help them in advising. Research shows that “busy” directors are stronger in advising (Field et al. 2013) and that directors suffer from losing multiple appointments when those appointments are especially well-connected boards (Brown et al. 2019). Directors with multiple appointments have reputational concerns for the director labor market, and so they often excel at monitoring on the audit committee (Kuang and Sharma 2014; Liu et al. forthcoming).Directors may be too time constrained to devote sufficient time and attention to each board, which leads to weaker monitoring over executive compensation and financial reporting quality (Fich and Shivdasani 2006; Ahn et al. 2010; Falato et al. 2014; Hauser 2018), and aggressive firm practices (Andres et al. 2013; Al Lawati and Hussainey 2021). Our study finds that firms need to pay large incentive pay to attract directors with multiple board seats, and incentives increase in the number of board seats. This excessive incentive pay is a deadweight loss to firms seeking to attract directors with multiple board seats.
OPPORTUNITIESTHREATS
Investors increasingly vote against board members who are “too busy”; thus, there exists investor pressure toward limiting the number of board seats that may be held by directors at public firms (Papadopoulos 2019). Such policy has been under consideration for some time in the US, and is similar to existing policy in China, limiting board seats to a maximum of 5. Some U.S. firms have their own shareholder policies limiting the number of board seats their directors may serve on, such as a maximum of four additional board seats (Tonello 2020).Board members who are overly busy can harm shareholder value (see papers cited above under “weaknesses”. Similarly, excessive incentive pay to attract directors with multiple board seats is detrimental to shareholder welfare. The Professional Organization for Non-Executive Directors recommends devoting 1.5 days per week to each public company board seat (Brown et al. 2019). It is difficult to imagine that board members with many appointments are able to devote this amount of time to firm oversight.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Lin, G.; Brown, A.B. Theoretical Investigation on the Optimal Contracting for Directors Holding Multiple Directorships. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15, 164. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040164

AMA Style

Lin G, Brown AB. Theoretical Investigation on the Optimal Contracting for Directors Holding Multiple Directorships. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2022; 15(4):164. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040164

Chicago/Turabian Style

Lin, Guoyu, and Anna Bergman Brown. 2022. "Theoretical Investigation on the Optimal Contracting for Directors Holding Multiple Directorships" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 15, no. 4: 164. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040164

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop