Next Article in Journal
Determinants of Vietnamese Listed Firm Performance: Competition, Wage, CEO, Firm Size, Age, and International Trade
Previous Article in Journal
China and Special Drawing Rights—Towards a Better International Monetary System
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Concept Paper

What They Did Not Tell You about Algebraic (Non-) Existence, Mathematical (IR-)Regularity, and (Non-) Asymptotic Properties of the Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) Model

by
Michael McAleer
1,2,3,4,5
1
Department of Finance, Asia University, Taichung 41354, Taiwan
2
Discipline of Business Analytics, University of Sydney Business School, Sydney 2006, Australia
3
Econometric Institute, Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, 3062 PA Rotterdam, The Netherlands
4
Department of Economic Analysis and ICAE, Complutense University of Madrid, 28040 Madrid, Spain
5
Institute of Advanced Sciences, Yokohama National University, Yokohama 240-8501, Japan
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12(2), 61; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12020061
Submission received: 11 March 2019 / Revised: 1 April 2019 / Accepted: 5 April 2019 / Published: 9 April 2019

Abstract

:
In order to hedge efficiently, persistently high negative covariances or, equivalently, correlations, between risky assets and the hedging instruments are intended to mitigate against financial risk and subsequent losses. If there is more than one hedging instrument, multivariate covariances and correlations have to be calculated. As optimal hedge ratios are unlikely to remain constant using high frequency data, it is essential to specify dynamic time-varying models of covariances and correlations. These values can either be determined analytically or numerically on the basis of highly advanced computer simulations. Analytical developments are occasionally promulgated for multivariate conditional volatility models. The primary purpose of this paper is to analyze purported analytical developments for the only multivariate dynamic conditional correlation model to have been developed to date, namely the widely used Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) model. Dynamic models are not straightforward (or even possible) to translate in terms of the algebraic existence, underlying stochastic processes, specification, mathematical regularity conditions, and asymptotic properties of consistency and asymptotic normality, or the lack thereof. This paper presents a critical analysis, discussion, evaluation, and presentation of caveats relating to the DCC model, with an emphasis on the numerous dos and don’ts in implementing the DCC model, as well as a related model, in practice.

1. Introduction

Hedging financial investments is tantamount to insuring against possible losses arising from risky portfolio allocation. In order to hedge efficiently, persistently high negative covariances or equivalently, correlations, between risky assets and the hedging instruments are intended to mitigate against financial risk and subsequent losses.
It is possible to hedge against risky assets using one or more hedging instruments as the benchmark, which requires the calculation of multivariate covariances and correlations. As optimal hedge ratios are unlikely to remain constant using high frequency data, it is essential to specify dynamic time-varying models of covariances and correlations.
Modeling, forecasting, and evaluating dynamic covariances between hedging instruments and risky financial assets requires the specification and estimation of multivariate models of covariances and correlations. These values can either be determined analytically or numerically on the basis of highly advanced computer simulations. High frequency time periods, such as daily data, can lead to either conditional or stochastic volatility, where analytical developments are occasionally promulgated for the former, but always numerically for the latter.
The purpose of this paper is to analyze purported analytical developments for the only multivariate dynamic conditional correlation model to have been developed to date, namely Engle’s (2002) widely used Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) model. As dynamic models are not straightforward (or even possible) to translate in terms of the algebraic existence, underlying stochastic processes, specification, mathematical regularity conditions, and asymptotic properties of consistency and asymptotic normality, or the lack thereof, these are evaluated separately.
For the variety of detailed possible outcomes mentioned above, where problematic issues arise constantly and sometimes unexpectedly, a companion paper by the author evaluates the recent developments in modeling dynamic conditional covariances on the basis of the Full BEKK (named for Baba, Engle, Kraft and Kroner) model (see McAleer 2019). Both papers are intended as Topical Collections to bring the known and unknown results pertaining to DCC into a single collection.
The remainder of the paper presented is as follows. The DCC model is presented in Section 2, which will enable a subsequent critical analysis and emphasis on a discussion, evaluation, and presentation of caveats in Section 3 of the numerous dos and don’ts in implementing the DCC model, as well as a related model, in practice.

2. Model Specification

Some, though not all, of the results in this section are available in the extant literature, but the interpretation of the models and their non-existent underlying stochastic processes, as well as the discussions and caveats in the following sections, are not available. Much of the basic material relating to the univariate and multivariate specifications in Section 2.1, Section 2.2 and Section 2.3 overlap with the presentation in McAleer (2019).
Two earlier papers that questioned the need, usefulness, and practical differences between DCC and the associated multivariate Full BEKK conditional covariance model (see Baba et al. (1985) and Engle and Kroner (1995) for further details) are given in Caporin and McAleer (2012, 2013). Among other queries, the latter authors suggested referring to DCC as a “representation” for purposes of filtering the data, rather than as a model. However, the technical issue and interpretation as to what data are actually being filtered, namely the returns shocks or standardized residuals, and conditional correlations or covariances, was not settled.
The first step in estimating DCC is to estimate the standardized shocks from the univariate conditional mean returns shocks. The most widely used univariate conditional volatility model, namely GARCH (acronym for Generalized AutoRegressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity), is presented briefly, followed by DCC.
Consider the conditional mean of financial returns, as follows:
y t = E ( y t | I t 1 ) +   ε t   ( 1 )
where the returns, y t = Δ log P t   , representing the log-difference in financial asset prices ( P t ) ,   I t 1 , constitute the information set at time t-1, and ε t is a conditionally heteroskedastic returns shock that has the same unit of measurement as the returns. In order to derive conditional volatility specifications, it is necessary to specify, wherever possible, the stochastic processes underlying the returns shocks, ε t .

2.1. Univariate Conditional Volatility Models

Univariate conditional volatilities can be used to standardize the conditional covariances in alternative multivariate conditional volatility models to estimate conditional correlations, which are particularly useful in developing dynamic hedging strategies. The most widely used univariate model, GARCH, is presented below as an illustration because the focus of the paper is on estimating and testing DCC.

2.2. Random Coefficient Autoregressive Process and GARCH

Consider the random coefficient autoregressive process of order one:
ε t = ϕ t ε t 1 + η t ,
where
ϕ t ~ i i d ( 0 , α ) ,
η t ~ i i d ( 0 , ω ) ,
and η t = ε t / h t is the standardized residual.
The standardized residual is a unit-free measure, and it is a financial fundamental as it represents a riskless asset.
Tsay (1987) derived the ARCH(1) (acronym for AutoRegressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity) model of Engle (1982) from Equation (1) as:
h t = E ( ε t 2 | I t 1 ) = ω + α ε t 1 2
where h t is conditional volatility and I t 1 is the information set available at time t-1. The mathematical regularity condition of invertibility is used to relate the conditional variance, h t   , in Equation (3) to the returns shocks, ε t , which has the same measurement as y t in Equation (1), thereby yielding a valid likelihood function of the parameters given the data.
The use of an infinite lag length for the random coefficient autoregressive process in Equation (2), with appropriate geometric restrictions (or stability conditions) on the random coefficients, leads to the GARCH model of Bollerslev (1986). From the specification of Equation (2), it is clear that both ω and α should be positive as they are the unconditional variances of two independent stochastic processes. The GARCH model is given as:
h t = E ( ε t 2 | I t 1 ) =   ω + α ε t 1 2 + β h t 1
where α is the short run ARCH effect, and β , which lies in the range (−1,1), is the GARCH contribution to the long run persistence of returns shocks.
From the specification of Equation (2), it is clear that both ω and α should be positive as they are the unconditional variances of two independent stochastic processes. It should be emphasized that the random coefficient autoregressive process is a sufficient condition to derive ARCH, but to date the ARCH specification has not been derived from any other known underlying stochastic process.

2.3. Multivariate Conditional Volatility Models

Multivariate conditional volatility GARCH models are often used to analyze the interaction between the second moments of returns shocks to a portfolio of assets, and can model the possible risk transmission or spillovers among different assets.
In order to establish volatility spillovers in a multivariate framework, it is useful to define the multivariate extension of the relationship between the returns shocks and the standardized residuals, that is, η t = ε t / h t . The multivariate extension of Equation (1), namely:
y t = E ( y t | I t 1 ) + ε t ,
can remain unchanged by assuming that the three components in the above equation are now m × 1 vectors, where m is the number of financial assets.
The multivariate definition of the relationship between ε t and η t is given as:
ε t = D t 1 / 2 η t
where D t = d i a g ( h 1 t , h 2 t , , h m t ) is a diagonal matrix comprising the univariate conditional volatilities. Define the conditional covariance matrix of ε t as Q t . As the m × 1 vector,   η t , is assumed to be iid for all m elements, the conditional correlation matrix of ε t , which is equivalent to the conditional correlation matrix of η t , is given by Γ t .
Therefore, the conditional expectation of the process in Equation (4) is defined as:
Q t = D t 1 / 2 Γ t D t 1 / 2 .
Equivalently, the conditional correlation matrix, Γ t , can be defined as:
Γ t = D t 1 / 2 Q t D t 1 / 2 .
Equation (5) is useful if a model of Γ t is available for purposes of estimating the conditional covariance matrix, Q t , whereas Equation (6) is useful if a model of Q t is available for purposes of estimating the conditional correlation matrix,   Γ t .
Both Equations (5) and (6) are instructive for a discussion of asymptotic properties. As the elements of D t are consistent and asymptotically normal, the consistency of Q t in Equation (5) depends on consistent estimation of Γ t , whereas the consistency of Γ t in Equation (6) depends on consistent estimation of Q t . As both Q t and Γ t are products of matrices, and the inverse of the matrix D t is not asymptotically normal, even when D t is asymptotically normal, neither the Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimates (QMLE) of Q t nor Γ t will be asymptotically normal, especially based on the definitions that relate the conditional covariances and conditional correlations given in Equations (5) and (6).
The vector random coefficient autoregressive process of order one is the multivariate extension of Equation (2), and is given as:
ε t = Φ t ε t 1 + η t
where
  • ε t and η t   are m × 1 vectors,
  • Φ t is an m × m matrix of random coefficients,
  • Φ t ~ i i d ( 0 , A ) ,
  • η t ~ i i d ( 0 , Q Q ) .
Technically, a vectorization of a full (that is, non-diagonal) matrix A to vec A can have dimensions as high as m 2 × m 2 , whereas a half-vectorization of a symmetric matrix A to vech A can have dimensions as low as m ( m 1 ) / 2 × m ( m 1 ) / 2 . The matrix A is crucial in the interpretation of symmetric and asymmetric weights attached to the returns shocks.

2.4. DCC Model

This section presents the DCC model, as given in Engle (2002), which does not have an underlying stochastic specification that leads to its derivation. Without distinguishing between dynamic conditional covariances and dynamic conditional correlations, Engle (2002) presented the DCC specification as:
Q t = ( 1 α β ) Q ¯ + α η t 1 η t 1 + β Q t 1
where Q ¯ is assumed to be a positive definite with unit elements along the main diagonal; the scalar parameters are assumed to satisfy the stability condition, α + β < 1, where the two parameters do not have the same interpretation as in the univariate GARCH model; the standardized shocks, η t = ( η 1 t , , η m t ) , which are not necessarily iid, are given as η i t = ε i t / h i t ; and D t is a diagonal matrix with typical element h i t , i = 1, …, m. As m is the number of financial assets, the multivariate definition of the relationship between ε t and η t is given as ε t = D t η t .
In view of Equations (5) and (6), as the matrix in Equation (8) does not satisfy the definition of a correlation matrix, Engle (2002) uses the following standardization:
R t = ( d i a g ( Q t ) ) 1 / 2 Q t ( d i a g ( Q t ) ) 1 / 2 .
There is no clear explanation given for the standardization in Equation (9) or, more recently, in Aielli (2013), especially as it does not satisfy the definition of a correlation matrix, as given in Equation (6). The standardization in Equation (9) might make sense if the matrix Q t was the conditional covariance matrix of ε t or η t , although this is not made clear. Indeed, in the literature relating to DCC, it is not clear whether Equation (8) refers to a conditional covariance or a conditional correlation matrix, although the latter is simply assumed without any clear explanation.
Despite the title of the paper, Aielli (2013) also does not provide any stationarity conditions for the DCC model, and does not mention the mathematical regularity condition of invertibility at the univariate of multivariate level. On the basis of Equation (8)—which does not relate the conditional covariance matrix, Q t , in Equation (8) to the returns shocks, ε t , which has the same measurement as y t in Equation (1)—invertibility does not hold. As there is no connection between Q t and y t , there is not a valid likelihood function of the parameters given the data.
It follows that there can be no first or second derivatives of the non-existent likelihood function, so the Jacobian and Hessian matrices do not exist. Therefore, there cannot be an analytical derivation of any asymptotic effects relating to consistency and asymptotic normality.

3. Vector Random Coefficient Moving Average Process

The random coefficient moving average process is presented in its original univariate form in Section 3.1, as in Marek (2005), with an extension to its multivariate counterpart in Section 3.2, in order to derive the univariate and multivariate conditional volatility models, respectively, as well as the associated invertibility conditions at the univariate and multivariate levels. Some practical applications of the DCC model are also discussed.

3.1. Univariate Process

Marek (2005) proposed a linear moving average model with random coefficients (RCMA). It should be emphasized that the random coefficient moving average process is a sufficient condition to derive a novel univariate conditional volatility model.
In this section, we extend the univariate results of Marek (2005) using an m-dimensional vector random coefficient moving average process of order p, which is used as an underlying stochastic process to derive the DCC model. A novel conditional volatility model is derived, which is given as a function of the standardized shocks rather than of the returns shocks, as in the univariate ARCH model in Equation (3).
Consider a univariate random coefficient moving average process given by:
ε t = θ t η t 1 + η t
where η t ~ iid ( 0 , ω ) . The sequence { θ t } is assumed to be independent of η t 1 , η t , η t + 1 , , which is called the Future Independence Condition, with mean zero and variance α . It is also assumed to be measurable with respect to I t , where I t is the information set generated by the random variable, { ε t , ε t 1 , }. Furthermore, it is assumed that the process { ε t } is stationary and invertible, such that η t I t .
Without the measurability assumption on { θ t } it would be difficult to obtain results on invertibility. As demonstrated in McAleer (2018), an important special case of the model arises when { θ t } is iid, that is, not measurable with respect to I t , in which case the conditional and unconditional expectations of ε t are zero, and the conditional variance of ε t is given by:
h t = E ( ε t 2 | I t 1 ) = ω + α η t 1 2 ,
which differs from the ARCH model in Equation (3) in that the returns shock is replaced by the standardized shock. This is a new conditional volatility model, especially as conditional volatility is expressed in terms of a riskless random variable rather than the returns shock, which has the same measurement, and hence risk, as the returns, y t .
McAleer (2018) showed that, as η t ~ iid ( 0 , ω ) , the unconditional variance of ε t is given as:
E ( h t ) = ( 1 + α ) ω .
The use of an infinite lag length for the random coefficient moving average process in Equation (10), with appropriate restrictions on θ t , would lead to a generalized ARCH model that differs from the GARCH model of Bollerslev (1986) as the returns shock would be replaced with a standardized shock.
A sufficient condition for stationarity is that the vector sequence υ t = ( η t , θ t η t 1 ) is stationary. Moreover, according to Lemma 2.1 of Marek (2005), a new sufficient condition for invertibility is that:
E [ log | θ t | ] < 0 .
The stationarity of υ t = ( η t , θ t η t 1 ) and the invertibility condition in Equation (12) are new results for the univariate ARCH(1) model given in Equation (11), as well as its direct extension to GARCH models.

3.2. Multivariate Process

Extending the analysis to a vector random coefficient moving average (RCMA) model of order p, McAleer (2018) derives a special case of DCC(p,q), namely DCC(p,0), as follows:
ε t = j = 1 p θ j t η t j + η t
where εt and ηt are both m × 1 vectors, and θ j t , j = 1, …, p are random m × m matrices, independent of η t 1 , η t , η t + 1 , .
As the dimension of the unconditional variance of θ j t is m, if the conditional variance matrix is not restricted parametrically, the dynamic conditional covariance matrix of (13) would depend on the product of the variance of θ j t , with dimensions between m ( m 1 ) / 2 and m 2 , neither of which would be conformable with the dimension of η t j . Under specific assumptions, it is possible to derive the conditional covariance matrix of ε t in Equation (11).
If θ j t in Equation (13) is given as:
θ j t = λ j t I m ,   with   λ j t ~ i i d ( 0 , α j ) ,   j   =   1 ,   ,   p ,
where λ j t is a scalar random variable, the dynamic conditional covariance matrix is given as:
H t = E ( ε t ε t | I t 1 ) = Ω + j = 1 p α j η t j η t j .
The DCC model in Equation (8) is obtained by letting p in Equations (13) and (14), setting α j = α β j 1 , and standardizing Q t in Equation (14) to obtain a conditional correlation matrix. For the case p = 1 in Equation (14), the appropriate univariate conditional volatility model is given in the new model in Equation (11), which uses the standardized shocks, in contrast to the standard ARCH in Equation (3), which uses the returns shocks. Moreover, the DCC model adds only one parameter, α 1 , when p = 1, so it is parsimonious in terms of its parametric representation.
As in the univariate case, it should be emphasized that the vector random coefficient moving average process is a sufficient condition to derive DCC, but to date the DCC specification has not been derived from any other known underlying multivariate stochastic process.
The derivation in McAleer (2018) of DCC in Equation (14) from a vector random coefficient moving average process is important as it: (i) demonstrates that DCC is, in fact, a dynamic conditional covariance model of the returns shocks rather than a purported dynamic conditional correlation model; (ii) provides the motivation, which is presently missing, for the standardization of the conditional covariance model in Equation (9) to obtain the conditional correlation model; and (iii) shows that the appropriate ARCH or GARCH model as a first step in calculating DCC is based on the standardized shocks rather than on the returns shocks.

4. Discussion and Caveats Regarding DCC

The results in the previous section allow a clear discussion of the caveats associated with the widely used DCC model. The deficiencies and limitations in virtually all published papers that use the deeply flawed DCC model are given below. The discussion and caveats are presented in a clear and entirely straightforward manner that would seem to need no further elaboration.
(1)
Engle (1982) developed an autoregressive model of conditional correlations, ARCH, based on the conditional returns shocks.
(2)
Bollerslev (1986) extended ARCH by adding a lagged dependent variable to obtain Generalized ARCH, GARCH.
(3)
The GARCH (1,1) parameters must satisfy the regularity conditions of positivity as they are the unconditional variances from a univariate random coefficient autoregressive process (see Tsay 1987; McAleer 2014).
(4)
However, the coefficient of the arbitrary lagged conditional variance is a positive or negative fraction (see Bollerslev 1986).
(5)
The novel results in Tsay (1987) were extended to a vector random coefficient stochastic process, which is a sufficient condition to derive Diagonal BEKK as in McAleer et al. (2008).
(6)
The DCC model does not satisfy the definition of a conditional correlation matrix, as the purported conditional correlations do not satisfy the definition of a correlation, except by an untenable assumption.
(7)
There is as yet no underlying stochastic process that leads to the DCC model, so that there are no regularity conditions relating to its specification.
(8)
The regularity conditions include invertibility, which is essential in relating the iid standardized residuals to the returns data.
(9)
As invertibility does not hold, it follows that there is no likelihood function, and hence no derivatives that would enable the derivation of asymptotic properties for the Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimates (QMLE) of the estimated parameters.
(10)
Therefore, any statements regarding the purported “statistical significance” of the estimated parameters are meaningless and lack statistical validity.
(11)
It follows that any empirical results based on the DCC estimates are fatally flawed and lack statistical validity (see McAleer (2018) for a critical analysis).
(12)
Marek (2005) proposed a novel univariate Random Coefficient Moving Average (RCMA) process, which is a sufficient condition that leads to a conditional heteroskedastic process based on the standardized residuals rather than the conditional returns shocks.
(13)
McAleer (2018) extended the univariate RCMA stochastic process to a multivariate random coefficient moving average process, which is a sufficient condition to demonstrate that DCC can be derived from a vector RCMA process.
(14)
It follows that DCC is not a Dynamic Conditional Correlation model, but rather a Dynamic Conditional Covariance model, although both can retain the acronym DCC.
(15)
Several years earlier than Engle (2002), Tse and Tsui (2002) proposed a Varying Conditional Correlation (VCC) model that does satisfy the definition of a correlation recursively for each observation.
(16)
As stated in the published versions of both papers, the paper by Tse and Tsui (2002) was submitted to the journal in December 1998, 25 months earlier than the submission by Engle (2002), and accepted in May 2001, 7 months earlier than the submission and acceptance of Engle (2002).
(17)
However, as in the case of DCC, the VCC model has no underlying stochastic process that leads to its specification as a dynamic correlation matrix.
(18)
Therefore, there are no regularity conditions relating to VCC, including invertibility, which is essential in relating the iid standardized residuals to the returns data.
(19)
Consequently, the QMLE of the estimated parameters of VCC do not possess any asymptotic properties as the likelihood function does not exist.
(20)
It is somewhat surprising that the DCC model has been widely estimated using real data, without any apparent computational difficulties, despite the fact that the model does not actually exist!
(21)
Such computational outcomes would almost certainly arise from the parsimonious addition of only one parameter when p = 1, even when the value of m is high for the large financial portfolios that are observed in practice.
(22)
In short, VCC shares all the existence, specification, mathematical, and statistical deficiencies of DCC.
(23)
If these two models are to be considered at all, except in connection with algebraic non-existence, with the absence of an underlying stochastic process, mathematical irregularity, and unknown asymptotic statistical properties, or alternatively in the presence of problems that should be avoided at all costs, it is advisable that DCC and VCC be used with extreme and utter caution in empirical practice.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

The author has benefited from very helpful comments and suggestions from three reviewers, and stimulating discussions with Manabu Asai, Massimiliano Caporin, Chia-Lin Chang, Christian Hafner, Shiqing Ling, Adrian Pagan, Peter Phillips, and Teodosio Perez Amaral. For financial support, the author is most grateful to the Australian Research Council and the Ministry of Science and Technology (MOST), Taiwan.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Aielli, Gian Piero. 2011. Dynamic conditional correlation: On properties and estimation. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 31: 282–99. [Google Scholar]
  2. Baba, Yoshihisa, Robert Engle, Dennis Kraft, and Kenneth Kroner. 1985. Multivariate simultaneous generalized ARCH. Unpublished Paper. San Diego: University of California. [Google Scholar]
  3. Bollerslev, Tim. 1986. Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Journal of Econometrics 31: 307–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Caporin, Massimiliano, and Michael McAleer. 2012. Do we really need both BEKK and DCC? A tale of two multivariate GARCH models. Journal of Economic Surveys 26: 736–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Caporin, Massimiliano, and Michael McAleer. 2013. Ten things you should know about the dynamic conditional correlation representation. Econometrics 1: 115–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Engle, Robert F. 1982. Autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity, with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econornetrica 50: 987–1007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Engle, Robert F. 2002. Dynamic conditional correlation: A simple class of multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 20: 339–50. [Google Scholar]
  8. Engle, Robert F., and Kenneth F. Kroner. 1995. Multivariate simultaneous generalized ARCH. Econometric Theory 11: 122–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Marek, Tomáš. 2005. On invertibility of a random coefficient moving average model. Kybernetika 41: 743–56. [Google Scholar]
  10. McAleer, Michael. 2014. Asymmetry and leverage in conditional volatility models. Econometrics 2: 145–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. McAleer, Michael. 2018. Stationarity and invertibility of a dynamic correlation matrix. Kybernetika 54: 363–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. McAleer, Michael. 2019. What They Did Not Tell You about Algebraic (Non-)Existence, Mathematical (Ir-)Regularity and (Non-)Asymptotic Properties of the Full BEKK Dynamic Conditional Covariance Model. Unpublished paper. Taichung, Taiwan: Department of Finance, Asia University. [Google Scholar]
  13. McAleer, Michael, Felix Chan, Suhejla Hoti, and Offer Lieberman. 2008. Generalized autoregressive conditional correlation. Econometric Theory 24: 1554–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Tsay, Ruey S. 1987. Conditional heteroscedastic time series models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 82: 590–604. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Tse, Yiu Kuen, and Albert K. C. Tsui. 2002. A multivariate generalized autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity model with time-varying correlations. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 20: 351–62. [Google Scholar]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

McAleer, M. What They Did Not Tell You about Algebraic (Non-) Existence, Mathematical (IR-)Regularity, and (Non-) Asymptotic Properties of the Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) Model. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 61. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12020061

AMA Style

McAleer M. What They Did Not Tell You about Algebraic (Non-) Existence, Mathematical (IR-)Regularity, and (Non-) Asymptotic Properties of the Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) Model. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2019; 12(2):61. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12020061

Chicago/Turabian Style

McAleer, Michael. 2019. "What They Did Not Tell You about Algebraic (Non-) Existence, Mathematical (IR-)Regularity, and (Non-) Asymptotic Properties of the Dynamic Conditional Correlation (DCC) Model" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12, no. 2: 61. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12020061

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop