The Sound of Silence: Minorities, Abstention and Democracy
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. The Model
- a
- Initial Conditions (). At the beginning of each simulation run the N voters are distributed in the preference space, adopting a procedure inspired by the preferential attachment algorithm of Barabasi and Albert [31], that we call “preferential displacement”. Specifically, we insert each new voter in a random position of the entire space with a probability of , while the same voter is randomly displaced within the -neighborhood of an existing voter i (i.e., within a circular domain centered in with radius equal to ) with a probability of . The latter voter is selected with a probability proportional to the fraction of other voters already included in the same neighbourhood. In other words, , being the number of voters present in the -neighborhood of i and the total number of voters already displaced in the preference space. At variance with the standard uniform initial conditions, typical of the model, this process will produce an asymmetric distribution of voters, which will tend to visibly aggregate inside a certain (randomly selected, different for each simulation run) region in the preference space. The preferential displacement, on one hand, makes the initial conditions intuitively more realistic, since it is likely that voters’ opinions about the policy under discussion could concentrate from the beginning around a specific combination of target and tools; on the other hand, it will also result to be essential for the Majority formation, as explained later (see step c).Another important feature of the model is that not all the agents are necessarily involved in the voting process: as a matter of fact, a certain percentage of them can decide to abstain from the beginning. These abstained voters neither move nor interact with the other active voters, thus remaining in their initial positions in the preference space for the whole simulation. Since, as discussed before, we would like to model two types of voter abstention, the strategic one (swing voter’s curse) and the non-strategic one (protest abstention), two different ways of selecting the abstained voters in the preference space will be implemented: strategic abstainers will be randomly selected among the N voters, while non-strategic ones will be chosen at margins of the preference space, surrounding active voters. As we will show, though non interacting with the active voters, abstainers will still influence the dynamics of the debate phase just thanks to their presence and to their different placement in the preference space.In panels 1a and 2a of Figure 1 we show an example of initial conditions for two different simulation runs, with voters each and with a percentage of abstention. Voters are arranged according with the preferential displacement procedure: together with the 400 active voters (red points), one can find the abstainers (gray points) who either are randomly distributed in the preference space, if their abstention is strategic (1a), or surround the active voters, if their abstention is non-strategic (2a).
- b
- Debate Process (). In the debate phase, starting at , we implement a standard (discrete) dynamics in two-dimensions involving only the active voters. Each active voter i-th is endowed with a compatibility domain, , defined as a circle centered on her preference profile , with radius equal to the so-called confidence bound, , which in this phase is the same for all the voters. The political debate is modeled as the parallel update, at each time step , of all the voters’ profiles, so that each of them becomes equal to the average of the preference profiles of all the active voters included within her compatibility domain at time t. In other words:In order to calibrate the confidence bound, we introduce a parameter , called “political fragmentation”. By defining , the confidence bound can vary below its critical threshold in the interval , thus producing few clusters when and many clusters when . In presence of non-strategic abstention, the confidence bound is further reduced according with the following expression: , in order to take into account the reduction of the preference space occupied by active voters. The size and the symmetry of the clusters of voters obtained at the end of the debate phase depend on both their initial distribution over the preference space and the degree of abstention. In panels 1b and 2b of Figure 1 we show the aspect of the preference space at time for the two considered simulation runs, where we set : the system has reached its steady state with all the active voters collapsed in several clusters with different sizes for both types of abstention.
- c
- Majority Formation (). After the debate phase, we need some of the newly formed clusters to merge in order to realize some majority. Such a goal can be realized by rescaling, at , the confidence bound of voters in each cluster as , being the size of the cluster to which voter i belongs. In other words, voters belonging to larger clusters will interact with a greater number of other voters, and viceversa. The process goes on until a new steady state is reached at , where some clusters have collapsed to form the relative majority M, whose position is represented by blue points in panels 1c and 2c of Figure 1; the remaining clusters (orange points) are considered together to form the relative minority m (green point), whose position in the preference space coincides with the weighted average of the positions of all the clusters contributing to it. Of course we must require that the size of majority is always greater than the size of minority, i.e., : as anticipated, we verified that this can be realized only with “preferential displacement” initial conditions, which moves the center of gravity of preferences away from the geometric center of the space, thus helping the majority formation (anyway, in case this condition should be still not fulfilled, we stop the simulation and repeat the run starting from new initial conditions).
- d
- Final Decision (). At the beginning of this last phase the confidence bound of all the voters is set at , well above the critical threshold. Therefore, the system quickly moves towards a steady state where all the active voters have collapsed into a single cluster, which represents the final decision emerging (through the voting process) from the compromise between their respective preferences within the two coalitions. The position of such a cluster, reached at time , typically lies somewhere between the positions of the majority and the minority (red point in panels 1d and 2d of Figure 1), depending on both the relative size of the two coalitions and their relative positions at within the preference space.
- For the majority component (M) it is the metric distance between the final position (i.e., the representative preference profile) of the majority cluster and that of the final decision: ;
- For the minority component (m) it is the metric distance between the final position (i.e., the representative preference profile) of the minority cluster and that of the final decision: ;
3. Simulation Results
4. Conclusive Remarks
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Abramowitz, A.I.; Saunders, K.L. Is Polarization a Myth? J. Politics 2008, 70, 542–555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hare, C.; Poole, K.T. The Polarization of Contemporary American Politics. Polity 2014, 46, 411–429. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ramos, M.; Shao, J.; Reis, S.D.S.; Anteneodo, C.; Andrade, J.S.; Havlin, S.; Makse, H.A. How does public opinion become extreme? Sci. Rep. 2015, 5, 10032. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Wilford, A.M. Polarization, number of parties, and voter turnout: Explaining turnout in 26 OECD countries. Soc. Sci. Q. 2017, 98, 1391–1405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Somer, M.; McCoy, J. Deja vu? Polarization and Endangered Democracies in the 21st Century. Am. Behav. Sci. 2018, 62, 3–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Castellano, C.; Fortunato, S.; Loreto, V. Statistical physics of social dynamics. Rev. Mod. Phys. 2009, 81, 591. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Helbing, D.; Brockmann, D.; Chadefaux, T.; Donnay, K.; Blanke, U.; Woolley-Meza, O.; Moussaid, M.; Johansson, A.; Krause, J.; Schutte, S.; et al. Saving Human Lives: What Complexity Science and Information Systems can Contribute. J. Stat. Phys. 2015, 158, 735–781. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Jusup, M.; Holme, P.; Kanazawa, K.; Takayasu, M.; Romic, I.; Wang, Z.; Gecek, S.; Lipic, T.; Podobnik, B.; Wang, L.; et al. Social physics. arXiv 2021, arXiv:2110.01866v1. [Google Scholar]
- Deffuant, G.; Amblard, F.; Weisbuch, G. How can extremism prevail? A study based on the relative agreement interaction model. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 2002, 5, 27. [Google Scholar]
- Hegselmann, R.; Krause, U. Opinion Dynamics and Bounded Confidence Models, Analysis and Simulation. J. Artif. Soc. Soc. Simul. 2002, 5, 1–29. [Google Scholar]
- Weisbuch, G.; Deffuant, G.; Amblard, F.; Nadal, J.-P. Interacting agents and continuous opinions dynamics. In Heterogenous Agents, Interactions and Economic Performance; Cowan, R., Jonard, N., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2003; pp. 225–242. [Google Scholar]
- Yang, Y.; Dimarogonas, D.V.; Hu, X. Opinion consensus of modified Hegselmann-Krause models. Automatica 2014, 50, 622–627. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fu, G.; Zhang, W. Opinion Dynamics of Modified Hegselmann-Krause Model with Group-based Bounded Confidence. IFAC Proc. Vol. 2014, 47, 9870–9874. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Han, W.; Huang, C.; Yang, J. Opinion clusters in a modified Hegselmann-Krause model with heterogeneous bounded confidences and stubbornness. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl. 2019, 531, 121791. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Redner, S. A Guide to First-Passage Processes; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2001. [Google Scholar]
- Galam, S. S. Minority opinion spreading in random geometry. Eur. Phys. J. B 2002, 25, 403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ben-Naim, E. Opinion dynamics: Rise and fall of political parties. Europhys. Lett. 2005, 69, 671. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kang, W.-T. Protest Voting and Abstention Under Plurality Rule Elections: An Alternative Public Choice Approach. J. Theor. Politics 2004, 1, 79–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Droop, H.R. On the Political and Social Effects of Different Methods of Electing Representatives; William Maxwell and Son, Law Booksellers and Publishers: New York, NY, USA, 1869. [Google Scholar]
- Hughes, N. Voting in legislative elections under plurality rule. J. Econ. Theory 2016, 166, 51–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Laslier, J.F. Furthermore, the loser is... plurality voting. In Electoral Systems; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2012; pp. 327–351. [Google Scholar]
- Douglas, W.R. Majoritarianism and Majority Rule. In International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences, 2nd ed.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- McGann, A.J. The Tyranny of the Supermajority: How Majority Rule Protects Minorities. J. Theor. Politics 2004, 16, 53–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lewis, D.C. Direct Democracy and Minority. A Critical Assessment of the Tyranny of the Majority in the American States; Routhledge: London, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Schedler, A. Tyrannies of majorities: A conceptual reassessment. In A Democratization Theory Research Cluster Paper; working paper n.433; Kellogg Institute for International Studies, Notre Dame University: Notre Dame, IN, USA, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Nyirkos, T. The Tyranny of the Majority. History, Concept, and Challenges; Routhledge: London, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Freixas, J. Probabilistic power indices for voting rules with abstention. Math. Soc. Sci. 2012, 64, 89–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dougherty, K.L.; Edward, J. The properties of simple vs. absolute majority rule: Cases where absences and abstentions are important. J. Theor. Politics 2010, 22, 85–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feddersen, T.J.; Pesendorfer, W. Abstention in Elections with Asymmetric Information and Diverse Preferences. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 1996, 93, 381–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fortunato, S.; Latora, V.; Pluchino, A.; Rapisarda, A. Vector Opinion Dynamics in a Bounded Confidence Consensus Model. Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 2005, 16, 1535–1551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barabasi, A.; Albert, R. Statistical mechanics of complex networks. Rev. Mod. Phys. 2002, 74, 4797. [Google Scholar]
- Fortunato, S. On the consensus threshold for the opinion dynamics of Krause-Hegselmann. Int. J. Mod. Phys. C 2005, 16, 259–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
av size maj | maj/min ratio | av size min | av min clusters | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
strategicabstention | value | value | value | value | ||||||||
0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | 0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | 0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | 0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | |
393 | 375 | 340 | 3.67 | 3.00 | 2.13 | 107 | 125 | 160 | 2 | 4 | 11 | |
10% | 342 | 331 | 301 | 3.17 | 2.78 | 2.02 | 108 | 119 | 149 | 2 | 5 | 12 |
20% | 300 | 285 | 262 | 3.00 | 2.48 | 1.90 | 100 | 115 | 138 | 2 | 5 | 12 |
30% | 259 | 245 | 224 | 2.85 | 2.33 | 1.78 | 91 | 105 | 126 | 2 | 5 | 13 |
40% | 215 | 204 | 187 | 2.53 | 2.13 | 1.65 | 85 | 96 | 113 | 3 | 6 | 14 |
50% | 177 | 166 | 153 | 2.42 | 1.98 | 1.58 | 73 | 84 | 97 | 3 | 6 | 14 |
av size maj | maj/min ratio | av size min | av min clusters | |||||||||
nonstrategicabstention | value | value | value | value | ||||||||
0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | 0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | 0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | 0.1 | 0.5 | 0.9 | |
0% | 393 | 375 | 340 | 3.67 | 3.00 | 2.13 | 107 | 125 | 160 | 2 | 4 | 11 |
10% | 362 | 357 | 315 | 4.11 | 3.84 | 2.33 | 88 | 93 | 135 | 2 | 4 | 11 |
20% | 329 | 333 | 287 | 4.63 | 4.97 | 2.54 | 71 | 67 | 113 | 2 | 3 | 9 |
30% | 294 | 293 | 247 | 5.25 | 5.14 | 2.40 | 56 | 57 | 103 | 2 | 3 | 8 |
40% | 292 | 292 | 248 | 5.03 | 5.03 | 2.43 | 58 | 58 | 102 | 2 | 3 | 8 |
50% | 208 | 187 | 157 | 4.95 | 2.97 | 1.69 | 42 | 63 | 93 | 3 | 4 | 10 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Biondo, A.E.; Pluchino, A.; Zanola, R. The Sound of Silence: Minorities, Abstention and Democracy. Entropy 2022, 24, 56. https://doi.org/10.3390/e24010056
Biondo AE, Pluchino A, Zanola R. The Sound of Silence: Minorities, Abstention and Democracy. Entropy. 2022; 24(1):56. https://doi.org/10.3390/e24010056
Chicago/Turabian StyleBiondo, Alessio Emanuele, Alessandro Pluchino, and Roberto Zanola. 2022. "The Sound of Silence: Minorities, Abstention and Democracy" Entropy 24, no. 1: 56. https://doi.org/10.3390/e24010056