Next Article in Journal
Exergy Analysis of a Syngas-Fueled Combined Cycle with Chemical-Looping Combustion and CO2 Sequestration
Previous Article in Journal
Description of Seizure Process for Gas Dynamic Spray of Metal Powders from Non-Equilibrium Thermodynamics Standpoint
Previous Article in Special Issue
Correction: Wolpert, D.H. The Free Energy Requirements of Biological Organisms; Implications for Evolution. Entropy 2016, 18, 138
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Stationary Stability for Evolutionary Dynamics in Finite Populations

1
Independent, Playa del Rey, CA 90293, USA
2
Department of Mathematics & Statistics, San José State University, One Washington Square, San Jose, CA 95192, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Entropy 2016, 18(9), 316; https://doi.org/10.3390/e18090316
Submission received: 3 April 2016 / Revised: 24 July 2016 / Accepted: 16 August 2016 / Published: 25 August 2016
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Information and Entropy in Biological Systems)

Abstract

:
We demonstrate a vast expansion of the theory of evolutionary stability to finite populations with mutation, connecting the theory of the stationary distribution of the Moran process with the Lyapunov theory of evolutionary stability. We define the notion of stationary stability for the Moran process with mutation and generalizations, as well as a generalized notion of evolutionary stability that includes mutation called an incentive stable state (ISS) candidate. For sufficiently large populations, extrema of the stationary distribution are ISS candidates and we give a family of Lyapunov quantities that are locally minimized at the stationary extrema and at ISS candidates. In various examples, including for the Moran and Wright–Fisher processes, we show that the local maxima of the stationary distribution capture the traditionally-defined evolutionarily stable states. The classical stability theory of the replicator dynamic is recovered in the large population limit. Finally we include descriptions of possible extensions to populations of variable size and populations evolving on graphs.

Graphical Abstract

1. Introduction

Finite population evolutionary dynamics are of broad interest for both application and theory [1,2,3,4,5,6,7,8]; in particular, concepts of evolutionary stability have been widely-studied [6,7,8,9], and recently applied to finite populations [10] with mutation (and weak selection) [11]. Many evolutionary dynamics, such as the replicator equation, effectively assume infinite population sizes which allows a variety of tools from dynamical systems to be applied. Lyapunov stability theorems are crucial tools in the study of dynamical systems and evolutionary dynamics and there is a long history of Lyapunov stability results in evolutionary game theory and mathematical biology [8,12,13,14,15]. Evolutionary dynamics in finite populations are commonly modeled as Markov processes, such as the Moran and the Wright–Fisher processes [16,17,18,19,20], which are not deterministic; in the case of the Moran process, the replicator equation can be recovered in a large population limit [21,22]. Such stochastic models lack Lyapunov stability theorems. The theory of Markov processes, however, provides powerful analytic tools, notably the stationary distribution, capturing the long-run behavior of a process. We will show that there is an intimate connection between the stationary distributions of these processes and the celebrated theory of evolutionary stability. See Figure 1 for a motivating example of the main theorem in a population of three types.
In particular, for populations of finitely many replicating types, we define a Lyapunov-like quantity, namely a quantity that is positive-definite, decreasing toward an “equilibrium” locally, and minimal at the equilibrium, for a large class of birth-death processes we call the incentive process [24], including the Moran process and the Fermi process [25]. We then show local maxima of the stationary distribution of the Markov processes are local minima of the Lyapunov quantity for sufficiently large populations, which in turn are generalized evolutionarily stable states. In this manner, we have effectively extended the folk theorem of evolutionary dynamics [26,27] to these stochastic processes, including those with mutation (in fact we generally require some mutation for the stationary distribution to exist). Similar yet more nuanced results hold for the Wright–Fisher process on two types. For dynamics on populations of three types, such as the famous rock-scissors-paper dynamics, we show that similar results hold for the Moran process, and that the stationary distribution and Lyapunov quantity recapitulate the phase portraits of the replicator equation. Our main results apply to populations with any finite number of types. Finally we demonstrate some extensions to the dynamics of birth-death processes in structured populations, i.e., in the context of evolutionary graph theory, and of populations of variable size.
The use of information-theoretic quantities such as cross entropy and relative entropy [28] date back at least to [12] and [13]. Recently author Harper used generalizations from statistical thermodynamics [29] to extend the well-known Lyapunov stability result for the replicator dynamic to a large class of geometries [30], simultaneously capturing the facts that the relative entropy is a Lyapunov function for the replicator dynamic and the Euclidean distance is a Lyapunov function for the projection dynamic [14]. (Local versions of such results were given first in [31] using Riemannian geometry.) Author Fryer extended the local Lyapunov result for the relative entropy from the replicator dynamic to a class of dynamics known as the incentive dynamics [32], which includes the logit, Fermi, and best-reply dynamics, and introduced the concept of an incentive stable state (ISS) as a generalization of evolutionary stability [8]. The authors results were combined and further extended to various time-scales (including the standard discrete and continuous time-scales) in [33], yielding a vastly general form of the classical Lyapunov stability theorem of [13]. Now we extend some of these results to finite populations.
We proceed by applying a local/discrete variant of relative entropy to the study of Markov processes and drawing inspiration from methods from statistical inference. Bayesian inference is analogous to the discrete replicator dynamic [34] and relative entropy is a commonly used measure of convergence of an inference process. Simply stated, given a particular population state, we look at the expected next state of the system, formed by weighting the adjacent states by the transition probabilities of moving to those states, and compare this expected state to the current state via the standard relative entropy function (and others) from information theory. Intuitively, a population state is stable if the expected population state is close to current state. Indeed, we show that extrema of the stationary distribution minimize relative entropy between the expected state and the current state for a variety of processes. In particular we focus on the incentive process with mutation, a mapping of Fryer’s incentive dynamic to finite populations, first introduced in [35], a generational version called the k-fold incentive process, and the Wright–Fisher process.
We can say more, in fact. For the distance between the expected next state and the current state, we can use any of the information-theoretic q-divergences [33], which range from the Euclidean distance ( 1 / 2 ) x y 2 for q = 0 to the relative entropy for q = 1 . The Euclidean distance will give the best results for finite populations since it is well-defined on the boundary of the simplex as well as the interior, and will detect stable points everywhere. The relative entropy, however, will yield the best connection to deterministic dynamics in the limit that N , where we recapture the classical results for the replicator equation.
The authors explored the incentive process without mutation in [24], investigating the fixation probabilities of the process in the absence of mutation. Together these two approaches give a complete characterization of the behavior of the incentive process, whether the “equilibria” of the process are the boundary fixation states or if there are interior maxima of the stationary distribution. Stationary distributions of the Moran process and variants with mutation have been studied by Claussen and Traulsen [36] and others, e.g., [1]. We note that the incentive processes captures a similar set of processes as Sandholm’s microfoundations approach using revision protocols [37,38,39].

1.1. Incentive Proportionate Selection with Mutation

The incentive process was briefly introduced in the appendix of [35], as a generalization of the Moran process incorporating the concept of an incentive. An incentive is a function that mediates the interaction of the population with the fitness landscape, describing the mechanisms of many dynamics via a functional parameter, including replicator and projection dynamics, and logit and Fermi processes. A Fermi incentive is frequently used to avoid the general issue of dividing by zero when computing fitness proportionate selection [25,40]. The authors described the fixation probabilities of the incentive process without mutation in [24]. We now describe the incentive process with mutation, which captures a variety of existing processes, such as those used in [1] and [36].
Let a population be composed of n types A 1 , A n of size N with a i individuals of type A i so that N = a 1 + + a n . We will denote a population state by the tuple a = ( a 1 , , a n ) and the population distribution by a ¯ = a / N . Define a matrix of mutations M where 0 M i j 1 may be a function of the population state for our most general results, but we will typically assume in examples that for some constant value μ, the mutation matrix takes the form M i j = μ / ( n 1 ) for i j and M i i = 1 μ . Finally we assume that we have a function φ ( a ¯ ) = ( φ 1 ( a ¯ ) , , φ n ( a ¯ ) ) which takes the place of a i f i ( a ) in the Moran process. See Table 1 for a variety of example incentives. We will denote the normalized distribution derived from the incentive function as φ ¯ .
The incentive process is a Markov process on the population states defined by the following transition probabilities, corresponding to a birth-death process where birth is incentive-proportionate with mutation and death is uniformly random. To define the adjacent population states, let i α β be the vector that is 1 at index α, 1 at index β, and zero otherwise, with the convention that i α α is the zero vector of length n. Every adjacent state of state a for the incentive process is of the form a + i α β for some 1 α , β n . At a population state a we choose an individual of type A i to reproduce proportionally to its incentive, allowing for mutation of the new individual as given by the mutation probabilities. The distribution of incentive proportionate selection probabilities is given by p ( a ¯ ) = M ( a ¯ ) φ ¯ ( a ¯ ) ; explicitly, the i-th component is:
p i ( a ¯ ) = k = 1 n φ k ( a ¯ ) M k i k = 1 n φ k ( a ¯ )
We also randomly choose an individual to be replaced, just as in the Moran process. This yields the transition probabilities:
T a a + i α , β = p α ( a ¯ ) a ¯ β for α β T a a = 1 b adj a , b a T a b
We will mainly consider incentives that are based on fitness landscapes of the form f ( a ¯ ) = A a ¯ for a game matrix A; some authors do not allow self-interaction and use fitness landscapes of the form, e.g.,
f 1 ( i ) = G 11 ( i 1 ) + G 12 ( N i ) N 1 f 2 ( i ) = G 21 i + G 22 ( N i 1 ) N 1
for a game matrix G.
For our purposes the difference will have little impact. Though we primarily investigate two one-parameter families of incentives defined in terms of a fitness landscape, we note that the incentive need not depend on a fitness landscape or the population state at all. The Fermi process of Traulsen et al. is the q-Fermi for q = 1 [25], and q = 0 is called the logit incentive, which is used in, e.g., [42]. The q-replicator incentive has previously been studied in the context of evolutionary game theory [30,33] and derives from statistical-thermodynamic and information-theoretic quantities [43]. Recently human population growth in Spain has been shown to follow patterns of exponential growth with scale-factors q 1 [44]. Other than the best-reply incentive, which we will consider primarily as a limiting case of the q-Fermi, we will assume that all incentives are positive definite φ ( k ) > 0 if 0 < k < N to avoid the restatement of trivial hypotheses in the results that follow. For the q-Fermi incentives, positivity is of course guaranteed for all landscapes. This is particularly convenient for three-type dynamics since the mean-fitness can frequently be zero (for zero-sum games such as the rock-paper-scissors game), which would cause the transition probabilities to be ill-defined. We will also typically assume that incentives are continuous in the population distribution, that is, that they are discretized versions of continuous functions on the probability simplex.
At first glance the introduction of incentives might seems like just an alteration of the fitness landscape. While it is true that on the interior of the probability simply many incentives can be re-written as nonlinear fitness functions, there are significant advantages to the change in perspective from fitness-proportionate selection to incentive proportionate-reproduction. In particular, the authors showed in [33] that incentives ultimately lead to a deeper understanding of evolutionary stability and a substantial improvement in the ability to find Lyapunov functions (via formal and geometric considerations) for a wide-range of evolutionary dynamics. Moreover, when dynamics interact with the boundary, such as innovative and non-forward invariant dynamics, incentives yield a better description of evolutionary stability. Finally, we can study how a population interacts with the same fitness landscape by varying the incentive function and its parameters rather than the fitness landscape itself.

1.2. The Wright–Fisher Process

In contrast to the Moran process, which models a population in terms of individual birth-death events, the Wright–Fisher process is a generational model of evolution [18,20]. Each successive generation is formed by sampling, proportionally to incentive, the current generation. Define the Wright–Fisher Process with mutation for evolutionary games by the following multinomial transition probabilities:
T a b = N b i p i ( a ¯ ) b i
where p i ( a ¯ ) is defined as before in Equation (1). This is a slight generalization of the basic process as given by Imhof and Nowak to include mutation, though we will not consider parameters for intensity of selection via the 1 w , w linear combination approach as in [18]. In contrast to the Moran process, the Wright–Fisher process is not tri-diagonal, rather every state is accessible from every other state, so long as the incentive-proportionate probabilities are non-zero.

1.3. k-Fold Incentive Process

Since the Wright–Fisher process is a generational process, replacing the entire population in each iteration, and the incentive process is an atomic process, they can exhibit very different behaviors. Consider the following process, which will be referred to as the k-fold incentive process, as an intermediate between the two types of processes. Define each step of the process as k steps of the Moran process, so that k = 1 is the Moran process, and k = N , where N is the population size, yields a generational processes derived from the incentive process. The crucial difference is the simultaneity of the replication events, as all occur instantaneously for the Wright–Fisher process, so the transition probabilities for the k-fold process differ in general.
The transition probabilities of the k-fold process can be computed directly from the transition matrix of the incentive process (Equation (2)) by simply computing the k-th power of the transition matrix. The entries of the transition matrix, T k a b correspond to the probability of moving from population state a to population state b in exactly k steps of the Moran process.

1.4. Stationary Distributions

For a deterministic dynamic there are notions of long-term behavior, such as an ω-limit set [45], and powerful tools such as the Lyapunov stability theorems. For Markov processes we lack any notion of deterministic behavior since the population trajectories can only be determined probabilistically from previous states. We do, however, have a tool that does not exist in the deterministic setting: the stationary distribution of the Markov process. The stationary distribution is a probability distribution on the states of the process, indicating the likelihood of finding the population in any particular state in the long-run. It is characterized in multiple ways, of which we will use that facts that (1) the stationary distribution s is the left eigenvector of the transition matrix with eigenvalue one, that is s = s T ; and (2) the rows of the limit T k x converges to the stationary distribution for any starting distribution x as k .
Stationary distributions for the Moran process in two dimensions and some recently-studied generalizations are given in several recent works [1,36,46,47,48,49,50]; stationary distributions for both the Moran process and the Wright–Fisher process have been studied in [51]; a number of formulas for various finite population processes are given in [52] and [53]. The n = 2 solution only relies on the fact that the transition matrix is tridiagonal, and so applies to the incentive process with mutation without modification. The components s a of the stationary distribution satisfy the detailed-balance condition s a T a b = s b T b a (also known as the local balance condition) and such processes have a stationary distribution given by the following formula. For any sequence of states j 0 , j 1 , , j k ,
s j k = s j 0 i = 0 k 1 T j i j i + 1 T j i + 1 j i
where s j 0 can be obtained from the normalization i s i = 1 . This particular formulation relies on the fact that the transitions between neighboring states are nonzero, which we assume is valid throughout. For games with more than two types, none of the processes described so far satisfy the detailed-balance condition in general [19], though the neutral landscape is reversible for some choices of mutation matrix. It is, however, always the case that the global balance conditions are satisfied:
s a a adj b T a b = b adj a s b T b a
which follows easily from the fact that the stationary distribution is the left eigenvector of the transition probability matrix s T = s . Though we will not be able to give explicit closed forms in the higher dimensional cases (in general they are not known), the global balance equations will be sufficient for our analytic purposes. Exact analytic forms for the stationary distribution of the Wright–Fisher process are similarly not known. Nevertheless, from a computational perspective, for any concrete values of the various parameters of these processes, the stationary distribution can be computed fairly efficiently for relatively large populations.

1.5. Notions of Stability

Intuitively, a population state is stable if there is a reluctance of the population to move from that state. We characterize this in multiple ways. Evolutionary stability has been studied extensively and is closely related to the concept of a Nash equilibrium, which can be loosely described as a state in which no strategy has incentive to deviate from. Commonly an evolutionarily stable state (ESS) is defined as a state x ^ such that ( x ^ x ) · f ( x ) > 0 for all x in a neighborhood of x ^ . In [41], Fryer defines an incentive stable state (ISS) as a generalization of evolutionary stability, and shows that there is a generalization of the well-known Lyapunov theorem for the replicator equation. The authors ported the notion of an incentive stable state to the incentive process in [24]. In some cases an ISS for a particular incentive is again an ESS, such as for the best-reply incentive, and the Fermi incentive. We will give a generalization of those definitions in this work for completeness.
From the Moran process, an analogous form for the standard equation for an interior evolutionary stable state (ESS) for a 2 × 2 game can be obtained by equating the fitness functions of the two types in the population, matching the fact that for the replicator equation any interior rest point has equal fitness across all types [54]. This can similarly be obtained by equating the transition probabilities T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) = T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) for the Moran process, which also reproduces the correct form of Fryer’s ISS in equality for the incentive process, and adds i = 0 and i = N to set of potential stable points (for the Moran process). Since we do not (yet) have inequality in a neighborhood (as in the definition of a standard ESS) from this derivation we will refer to such states as candidate ISS. Explicitly, we define a candidate ISS as a population state a such that a ¯ = p ( a ¯ ) . For μ = 0 and the replicator incentive, this definition implies that f i ( a ¯ ) = f j ( a ¯ ) for all i and j, which is typical for an ESS. Note that solutions of the ISS candidate equation in a finite population will often not be integral.
Although we lack a Lyapunov theory for Markov processes, it is nevertheless desirable to have a quantity that is locally minimal at stable states and decreasing locally otherwise as an indicator of stability. Such a function yields another method of computation of candidate ISS without having to solve the ISS candidate equation, which might be very difficult. We combine this desire with the idea that a stable state for a stochastic process should remain close to itself by defining the expected distribution resulting from a single iteration of the incentive process
E ( a ¯ ) = 1 N b adj a b T a b
We then consider distance functions such as D 1 ( a ) = D K L ( E ( a ¯ ) | | a ¯ ) where D K L ( x , y ) = i x i log ( x i / y i ) is the relative entropy or Kullback–Leibler divergence, a commonly-used measure of distance between probability distributions.
For this purpose, we define the following one-parameter distance function
D ^ d ( x , y ) = 1 2 x y 2 , if d = 0 D K L ( x , y ) , if d = 1 1 1 d i x i 2 d y i 2 d 2 d y i 1 d ( x i y i ) , if 0 < d < 1
This family has the property that D ^ d 1 < D ^ d 2 if d 1 < d 2 , which is an simple consequence of a more general definition (see [30]), and all have the property that D ^ d ( x , y ) = 0 iff x = y . We will also make use of the fact that they are all bounded above (on our state spaces) by the χ-squared distance [55]
D χ 2 ( x , y ) = i x i y i 2 x i
In what follows, we will write D d ( a ) for D ^ d ( E ( a ¯ ) , a ¯ ) . This brings us to our first propositions. The first gives two forms for the expected distribution of the incentive, both of which are simple algebraic consequences of the definitions given so far. For two-type populations, the second form is, explicitly,
E ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ + 1 N T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) [ 1 1 ]
Proposition 1. 
For the incentive process, we have two forms for the expected distribution:
1.
E ( a ¯ ) = N 1 N a ¯ + 1 N p ( a ¯ )
2.
E ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ + 1 N α , β , α β i α β T a a + i α β = a ¯ + 1 N α , β , α < β i α β T a a + i α β T a a i α β
Proposition 2. 
For both the incentive process and the Wright–Fisher process, the following are equivalent:
1.
a ¯ = p ( a ¯ ) (ISS Candidate definition)
2.
E ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ , that is, a ¯ is a fixed point of E
3.
D d ( a ) = 0 for all 0 d 1
Proof of Proposition 2. 
(Part 2) For Wright–Fisher follows from the fact that the expected value of a multinomial distribution is just p ( a ¯ ) . The others follow easily from the previous proposition and Equation (1). ☐
For the k-fold incentive process the natural notion of expected distribution E k ( a ) is the k-th iterate of E as defined for the incentive process. We will not give a closed form for E k ; the following proposition will suffice for our purposes, and is also an easy consequence of our definitions.
Proposition 3. 
Let E ( a ¯ ) be defined as for the incentive process. Then for the k-fold incentive process, E k ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ if and only if E ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ .
Hence for all three processes we have that ISS candidates are equivalent to fixed points of the expected distribution function. This definition captures the usual notion of ISS/ESS as follows. We can write (loosely) that a ¯ = p ( a ¯ ) φ ¯ ( a ¯ ) ( 1 μ ) + μ / ( n 1 ) 1 , where n is the number of types in the population, so that if, e.g., μ O ( 1 / N ) or is otherwise relatively small, we have asymptotically that a ¯ φ ¯ ( a ¯ ) , i.e., a fixed point of φ ¯ (and so a candidate for incentive stability). For the replicator incentive, this implies that f i ( a ¯ ) = f j ( a ¯ ) for all i , j , which is the case for an ESS, as above. Our results are true regardless of the form of the mutation matrix, but the stable points need not coincide with the ISS of the incentive for large or imbalanced mutations (which is a feature). We note that Garcia et al. have found that the form of the mutations can significantly alter to locations of stable points [56].
The stationary distribution yields our final notion of stability. A state is a local maximum of the stationary distribution if it has a larger stationary probability than any of its immediate neighboring states. We define a candidate ISS to be an ISS if the stationary distribution at the candidate is locally maximal, and we call such local maxima stationary stable in general. Intuitively, a stable state of the dynamic should occur at some notion of a maximum of the stationary distribution since it indicates the likelihood of finding the process in any particular state, in the long run, and a tendency to remain in the state. Our main results are that in many cases, for sufficiently large populations, local maxima and minima of the stationary distribution are ISS candidates.
We note that several authors (e.g., [46,48,49,50]) have used the stationary distribution as a solution criterion, looking at average abundance of each population type computed by weighting the population states by the stationary distribution. While the authors of this paper find this to be an interesting approach, we use the stationary distribution to measure the stability of particular population states rather than as a measure on individual types. To see how these differ, consider that for any symmetric process on two types, the average abundance is equal for the two types [46]. For instance, the neutral landscape and the landscape given by a = 1 = d , b = 2 = c for the replicator incentive would have both have equal abundance for the two types and a stationary distribution with maximum at ( N / 2 , N / 2 ) , but so would the neutral landscape as μ 0 , in which the stationary distribution would be locally maximal at the two fixation states ( 0 , N ) and ( N , 0 ) [57] and zero at the central point. In all these cases strategy abundance gives an intuitive aspect of “equally-likely to be represented” in the long run, yet taking the average loses information about the manner in which this representation manifests (coexistence of all types or domination by a single type). In all cases the given states are stationary stable.

2. Results

2.1. Main Theorem for Two-Type Incentive Processes

First we show that when the stationary distribution is locally maximal or minimal, the distance between E ( a ¯ ) and a ¯ is minimal. We require a technical lemma to prove the main theorem that concerns continuity of incentive-proportionate replication probabilities. The crux of the proof is essentially that from the stationary distribution we have that if ( i , N i ) is local maximum or minimum of the stationary distribution then
T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) = T ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) ( i , N i )
Note there are two directions for the path through the states in Equation (4), ending with i i + 1 or i i 1 , so there is a second solution to the ISS max/min criteria as well. To satisfy E ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ we need
T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) = T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) .
So we need “equality” of the right-hand sides to ensure that these criterion are both satisfied, and we can argue that this is the case for sufficiently large N by appealing to continuity. This should not be surprising—in both cases, the population is shifting by one in the same direction, and as N gets larger, these points are closer together since i / N ( i + 1 ) / N for large N.
Lemma 1. 
Suppose the vector of incentive proportionate selection probabilities p as defined in Equation (1) is a continuous function of a ¯ and let ϵ > 0 . Then for the incentive process defined in Equation (2), there exists an integer N such that for N > N we have that
T ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) ( i , N i ) T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) < ϵ .
Proof. 
Since p is a continuous function of a ¯ , so is p * ( a ¯ ) = ( 1 p ( a ¯ ) ) * a ¯ . Let a ¯ + = a ¯ + i 1 , 2 / 2 and a ¯ = a ¯ + i 2 , 1 / 2 . For ϵ > 0 we simply need to choose N large enough so that the set of population states is sufficiently fine-grained enough so that | T a ¯ + a ¯ T a ¯ a ¯ | = p * ( a ¯ + ) p * ( a ¯ ) < ϵ . Continuous functions on compact spaces (the simplex) are uniformly continuous, so p * continuous implies there is δ > 0 such that if | a ¯ b ¯ | < δ then p * ( a ¯ ) p * ( b ¯ ) < ϵ for all a and b. Since | a ¯ + a ¯ | = 2 / N , N > N = 2 / δ is sufficient. ☐
If the incentive function is continuous as a function of a ¯ , and the mutations are constant or otherwise continuous as functions of a, then we have that p ( a ¯ ) is also continuous, satisfying the hypothesis of the lemma.
Theorem 1. 
For a continuous incentive and mutation matrix, there is a sufficiently large N so that local maxima and minima of the stationary distribution of the incentive process are local minima of the distance D d for 0 d < 1 ; interior extrema are local minima of the relative entropy D 1 .
Proof. 
If ( i , N i ) is a maximum or minimum of the stationary distribution then by the formula for the stationary distribution (Equation (4)) we must have that the last term in the product passes through 1 so that the stationary distribution switches from increasing to decreasing (or vice versa). By continuity there is j ( i 1 , i + 1 ) where the ratio is exactly equal to one by the intermediate value theorem, and so the state ( j , N j ) satisfies T ( j , N j ) ( j + 1 , N j 1 ) = T ( j + 1 , N j 1 ) ( j , N j ) . Note that i and j are not necessarily equal, and j may not be an integer (not a true state of the process). This is the difference between being a local extremum of the stationary distribution on a partition of the simplex and being a local extremum of the associated continuous function on the simplex. To complete the proof we will assume that N is sufficiently large enough that the states corresponding to i and j are close so that we can assume that | T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) T ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) ( i , N i ) | < ϵ (by continuity).
Let ϵ > 0 . Then by the lemma and the triangle inequality, for sufficiently large N, we have that:
T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) T ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) ( i , N i ) + T ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) ( i , N i ) T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) < 2 ϵ
For the χ 2 -distance, we have that, by Proposition 2 (at interior states):
D χ 2 ( a ) < N * 2 N 2 T ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) T ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) 2 < 8 N ϵ 2 ,
and similarly at boundary states for D d , 0 < d < 1 . This shows that D d vanishes for large N at the extremum. For neighboring states, the divergence between the state and the expected next state does not vanish: if this were the case, the transition probabilities between the adjacent states would be equal, and the stationary probabilities equal, contradicting the assumption of a local stationary extremum. Therefore D d ( a ) is locally minimal. ☐
A maximum of the stationary distribution need not occur when T i i is maximal, hence it is not a good definition of stability. The converse of the theorem is not true; the Lyapunov quantity may be minimized but fail to have a local maximum or minimum of the stationary distribution. While we have only proven that the theorem for large N for arbitrary continuous incentives, it may be possible to make sharper estimates based on the form of the incentive. As we will see from the examples for dimensions greater than 2, for linear landscapes the theorem seems to hold for almost any N with few exceptions.
For the replicator equation, it is known that there is at most one asymptotically stable interior state for linear fitness landscapes. We have a similar result in this context as a corollary.
Corollary 1. 
For two-type populations and linear fitness landscapes with the Moran process, if μ 0 as N then there is at most one interior stationary stable state as N .
Note that the hypothesis that μ 0 is necessary, otherwise one can find counterexamples with multiple interior stationary maximum for specific parameters, e.g., μ = 6 / 25 , and game matrix given by a = 1 = d , b = 0 = c produces a process with interior local maxima at a / N = 2 / 5 , 3 / 5 . In fact for this game, any μ ( 0 , 1 / 4 ) produces two interior solutions, a / N = 1 / 2 ± 1 4 μ / 2 , so long as N is large enough for the solutions to be more than 1 / N from the boundaries. (Note that Theorem 1 still holds.)

2.2. k-Fold Incentive Process

These two propositions show that the main theorem for locally-balanced birth-death processes will apply to the k-fold incentive process for all k.
Proposition 4. 
The stationary distribution of a Markov process X is the same as the stationary distribution of the process X k , defined by the k-th power of the transition matrix.
Proof. 
The stationary distribution of a Markov chain can be obtained by the rows of the matrix defined by
s = lim m T m = lim m T k m
and so the stationary distributions of the k-fold incentive process are the same for all k, given a fixed transition matrix T. ☐
The next proposition follows easily from the fact that the k-fold incentive process has the same stationary distribution and the definition of matrix multiplication.
Proposition 5. 
If a Markov process X satisfies the detailed-balance condition, so does the process X k defined by the k-th power of the transition matrix.
Corollary 2. 
Theorem 1 holds for the k-fold incentive process for two-type populations.

Examples

As an illustration of how large N may need to be, we consider the q-replicator incentive and game matrix defined by a = 1 = d , b = 2 = c . Direct substitution shows that a ¯ 1 = 1 2 is a solution to the ISS candidate equation for all q and μ. (Note that for q = 1 , a = 0 and a = N are also solutions.) For the two stationary extrema equations, we have that a ¯ 1 = 1 2 ± 1 2 N . For large N, these solutions all converge to a ¯ = ( 1 2 , 1 2 ) . Even for small N, these solutions differ only by a small amount ( 1 2 N ). Similarly, for the landscape given by a = 0 = d , b = 1 = c , we can give an explicit formula for the stationary distribution for arbitrary μ (see [35]):
s ( 0 , N ) = s ( N , 0 ) = 1 2 + 2 μ ( 2 N 2 ) s ( j , N j ) = 2 μ 2 + 2 μ ( 2 N 2 ) N j
Since only the binomial factor depends on j, it is clear that ( N / 2 , N / 2 ) is the local maximum of the stationary distribution for any μ and any N 2 . So we see explicitly that the property of being stationary stable is dependent on the population size N.
Let the fitness landscape be defined by the q-replicator incentive and the game matrix a = 2 = b , c = 1 = d (the Moran landscape with relative fitness r = 2 ) and let μ = 0 . 001 for N = 100 . As shown in [24], for q 1 there is an internal candidate ISS. We consider three cases. For q = 1 , there is no ISS (the transition probabilities never intersect), and no internal local maximum of the stationary distribution. The latter is true for q = 2 as well, but there is a state where the transitions intersect, and D d ( x ) is locally minimal at this state ( x ( 33 , 67 ) ), which shows that a candidate ISS need not be stable in the sense of the stationary distribution. An imbalanced mutation rate can force an internal equilibrium for q = 2 , for instance with μ 12 = 0 . 05 and μ 21 = 0 . 0005 . For q = 0 , the projection incentive, there is a local maximum of the stationary distribution (at i = 67 ). It is unique and D d ( x ) is minimal.
It is possible to have multiple interior stationary stable states for the replicator incentive with q 1 . For example, the following parameters give a process with two local maxima of the stationary distribution: N = 50 , μ = 0 . 1 , q = 1 . 5 , and the neutral fitness defined by a = b = c = d = 1 . It is also possible to have an internal local stationary maximum as well as a boundary maximum, e.g., for N = 50 , μ 12 = 0 . 1 , μ 21 = 0 . 01 , q = 0 . 5 , fitness landscape defined by a = 20 , b = 1 , c = 7 , d = 10 .

2.3. Main Theorem for Globally Balanced Incentive Processes

In general, incentive processes for more than two-types need not be locally-balanced, so we cannot use Equation (4) to establish the main theorem. In fact, it appears to rarely be the case (the neutral landscape is an exception in some cases), though computations indicate that in some cases, the detailed balance condition is nearly satisfied, and Equation (4) produces a good approximation of the stationary distribution. Regardless, we now generalize Theorem 1 to globally-balanced incentive processes. The proof strategy is similar to the locally-balanced case, using the global balance equation instead.
Any probability inflow-outflow balanced state, i.e., any state such that a adj b T a b = b adj a T b a , will minimize the distance between the expected next state and the current state. We will call such states probability flow neutral. This could happen in principle at, e.g., a saddle point, but since we are mostly concerned with stationary maxima for stability purposes, we will focus on maxima.
Proposition 6. 
For a continuous incentive and mutation matrix and sufficiently large N, local maxima and minima of the stationary distribution are probability flow neutral. Precisely, for ϵ > 0 , there is an N such that for N > N ,
a a d j b T a b b a d j a T b a < ϵ
Proof. 
We prove just the maximal case. Suppose we have local maxima a of the stationary distribution and let ϵ > 0 . Since all the transition probabilities are continuous in the population state, so is the stationary distribution, which is therefore uniformly continuous and bounded by M. For sufficiently large N we can choose ϵ so that | s b / s a 1 | < ϵ / ( n 2 M ) for states b adjacent to a. By the global balance equation,
s a a adj b T a b = b adj a s b T b a ,
so dividing through by s a and using the above inequality for s b / s a ,
a adj b T a b b adj a T b a = b adj a s b s a 1 T b a < ϵ / ( n 2 M ) b adj a T b a < ϵ .
 ☐
We take it as given that stationary extrema occur at probability flow neutral states, knowing that the population states may differ by a small amount. Now we show that stationary extrema minimize the distance functions D d . While the relative entropy ( d = 1 ) is only well-defined on the interior of the simplex, the same result holds when the state space is restricted to a boundary simplex of lower dimension. This means that the relative entropy can still detect boundary stable points of the same process on the restricted subspace, but the other D d do so on the full simplex.
Theorem 2. 
For a continuous incentive and mutation matrix on n types, there is a sufficiently large N so that probability flow neutral states of the incentive process are local minima of the distance functions D d for 0 d < 1 ; interior extrema are local minima of the relative entropy D 1 .
Proof. 
Since the proof is similar to the two-type case, we just sketch the proof. Let ϵ > 0 and suppose that a is a probability flow neutral state of the process:
a adj b T a b b adj a T b a < ϵ
We have that E ( a ¯ ) a ¯ = 1 N α β T a a + i α β T a a i α β i α β , and we use continuity to choose a sufficiently large N so to replace right-hand terms with T a + i α β a (as in the lemma before Theorem 1). Then we have that
D d ( a ) < N * n N 2 a adj b T a b b adj a T b a 2 < n N ϵ 2
 ☐
Since the k-fold incentive process has the same stationary distribution as the k = 1 case, and since the expected value functions agree at equilibrium via Proposition 1, we have the next theorem as an immediate corollary. This shows in particular that the connection between the stationary distribution and evolutionarily stable states can hold for generational processes.
Theorem 3. 
Theorem 2 holds for the k-fold incentive process.

2.4. Three Type Examples

Here we give several interesting examples using Bomze’s classification of three-type phase portraits for the replicator dynamic with linear fitness landscape (see [58] and the additions and corrections [59]). We use the Fermi incentive for all examples. A full list corresponding to each of the 48 phase portraits is available online at http://marcharper.net/stationary_examples/index.html. Figure 2 gives stationary distributions and expected distances for the following game matrices, to illustrate Theorem 2.

2.5. Rock-Scissors-Paper Games

The rock-scissors-paper game is given by a matrix of the form:
0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0
In [42] (online supplement), Andrae et al. give steady-state distributions for the rock-scissors-paper game in the context of entropy production. Figure 3 contains stationary distributions for the rock-scissors-paper game; these are qualitatively similar to those in Figure 4 of [42]. Traulsen et al. consider the average drift of a relative entropy equivalent Lyapunov quantity in [25] for the Moran process in a finite population, and find that convergence depends on the value of N. The rock-scissor-paper game for the Moran process does not yield a detail-balanced Markov process [42], and because of the cyclic-nature of the process, the transitions are particularly removed from detailed-balance. This is reflected in the fact that the stationary distribution can take many iterations of the transition matrix to converge. These plots also illustrate that the stability of particular states depends significantly on the mutation rate.

2.6. Four Types

For completeness, we include a higher dimensional example. Consider the incentive process defined by the Fermi incentive, N = 60 , μ = 1 / N and the game matrix
M 4 = 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 1
Although we cannot easily plot the full stationary distribution, we can plot the two-dimensional boundary simplices. Figure 5 gives the D 0 expectation distance and the stationary distribution for two of the four faces. Three are the same; the fourth, where a 4 = 0 , is distinct, and similar to the stationary distribution in Figure 1. From inspection of the game matrix, we would predict that ( N / 3 , N / 3 , N / 3 ) is an ISS for the distinct face. The three similar faces have boundary ISS such as ( N / 2 , 0 , N / 2 ) . Note that the stationary distribution and D 0 expected distances are computed for the full process on the three-dimensional state space; only the two-dimensional faces are plotted.

2.7. The Wright–Fisher Process

The Wright–Fisher process behaves differently than the Moran process for many combinations of parameters; see, e.g., [18]. In general, even for two-types, the Wright–Fisher process is not locally balanced [19]. Because of the combinatorial complexity of the process, the Wright–Fisher process is often studied via diffusion-type approximations. In some cases, these differential equations produce a qualitatively similar result to our main theorem for the incentive process. For instance in [60], the authors show that for the replicator incentive, the limiting distribution of the diffusion approximation concentrates on ESS. Combined with the fact that E ( a ¯ ) is the same as for the incentive process (Proposition 1), one can reasonably expect some subset of the parameters to produce a similar result to Theorem 1 for the Wright–Fisher process. See Figure 2 for examples.
We give an partial analog of Theorem 1 for the Wright–Fisher process. Crucially, note that a local maximum of the stationary distribution of the Wright–Fisher process is in fact a global maximum since every state is connected directly to every other state (assuming that that transition probabilities are never zero), and therefore is necessarily unique.
Theorem 4. 
Suppose a given incentive and mutation matrix are continuous. For the Wright–Fisher process, suppose that the stationary distribution has a global maximum at a, is symmetric about the maximum, and is otherwise vanishingly small (if the maximum is not central). Then for sufficiently large N, the state a is an ISS candidate and a minimum of the distance D d .
Proof. 
We only give the case for n = 2 in detail. Since the stationary distribution satisfies s = s T , we have that
s i + 1 s i = k s k T k i + 1 T k i
where s i + 1 denotes an adjacent state and by continuity for some j we must have that T j j + 1 T j j 1 = 0 (at the maximum since the distribution is symmetric). A bit of algebra shows that this occurs when
( N j ) p 1 ( j ) = ( j + 1 ) ( 1 p 1 ( j ) )
For sufficiently large N, solutions to this equation are the same as those of the ISS candidate equation. For n > 2 , looking at all the immediately adjacent states leads to p α ( a ¯ ) a ¯ β = p β ( a ¯ ) a ¯ α for large N, which implies by summation that p ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ . ☐
Computationally, we can compute the stationary distribution of the Wright–Fisher process for any combination of parameters for smaller N 100 easily. Figure 2 and Figure 6 give a variety of computational examples, some of which suggest that a more general version of Theorem 4 holds. Note the sensitivity to the mutation rate μ. Qualitatively, Figure 1 is similar for the Wright–Fisher process on the interior. Figures for all 48 of the landscape in Bomze’s classification are also available online at http://people.mbi.ucla.edu/marcharper/stationary_stable/3x3/.

3. Discussion and Extensions

3.1. Non-Constant Populations

Like the Moran process, the incentive and Wright–Fisher processes keep the population at a fixed size. Here we give an example that suggests that the methods used in this manuscript could be useful for processes with variably sized populations. We use the process defined in [61], and note that there are other models of variable population size process and dynamics in the literature, such as [62].
We modify the Moran process by inserting a coin-flip in each step to determine if a birth event or death event is to take place. The probability of this intermediate step can depend on the population state, and so can define a carrying capacity for the population. For instance, we could take a curve that has probability one of a birth event if the population has size M = 1 , is 1 / 2 for 1 < M < N , and is 0 for M = N . Clearly there are many variations on this probability, and the Moran process is a special case, if we separate the birth and death events.
Figure 7a shows the stationary distribution of such a process with the replicator incentive for the fitness landscape defined by a = 1 = d and b = 2 = c and the birth probabilities described in the previous paragraph. Now the ternary plot shows the population states ( a 1 , a 2 ) where a 1 + a 2 < N ; the rightward coordinate is the population size N. The right plot is D 0 of the expected next state from the current state, where the neighboring states now may have a total population size that is greater or less by one. On the right hand plot, the Lyapunov quantity is minimal when a 1 = a 2 , as we might expect from the fitness landscape and the examples earlier in the paper. These minima occur at the maxima of the stationary distribution as expected, since for a 1 + a 2 = M < N , we would expect the stationary max for M fixed to be a 1 = a 2 = M / 2 . We leave a precise extension of the main theorem to such processes as an open question.

3.2. Evolutionary Graph Theory

Many authors now study Moran-like processes for populations distributed on graphs [63,64,65], with evolutionary games on cycles [66,67], and lattices [68], and in more generality [69].
So far we have been working in a fully-connected population, that is, a population on a complete graph in the sense that every replicator interacts with every other replicator (not to be confused with the graph defined by the transitions of the Markov processes). We outline how a result analogous to Theorem 1 could hold for populations on graphs. A birth-death process on a graph is again a Markov process, and we consider an incentive process on two-types. Let the graph be a cycle with global birth selection and local death replacement.
We argue for the stationary stability of some states over others. Suppose that the replicators are distributed A , B , A , B , about the cycle (i.e., a proper coloring), as in Figure 8a. Then any reproductive event A B or B A will necessarily change the state, since every vertex has adjacent neighbors of the other type. Such a state is inherently unstable, and will have a small presence in the stationary distribution.
Similarly, we can follow this reasoning to conclude that the most stable configurations will have the least possible interactions between the two types. In the case of a cycle, this means that the population is segregated into two connected subpopulations, as depicted in Figure 8b. All that remains is to determine the relative sizes of the two subpopulations. Proceeding in the spirit of Theorem 1, we look for states such that the population state’s probability of moving up ( i , N i ) ( i + 1 , N i 1 ) is the same as the probability of moving down ( i , N i ) ( i 1 , N i + 1 ) . For very small μ, only replication events at the interface of the two subpopulations will affect the graph state. Suppose that subpopulations are of distribution a = ( i , N i ) . Then we have that the probability of increasing the size of the subpopulation of type A 1 (red) is simply p 1 ( a ¯ ) ( 2 / a 1 ) ( 1 / 2 ) since we must choose an A 1 individual to reproduce, it has to be one of the two on the interface between the subpopulations, and we have to randomly chose the individual of type A 2 (blue) to be replaced. Similarly for the subpopulation of A 2 individuals, and these transitions are equal when a 2 p 1 ( a ¯ ) = a 1 p 2 ( a ¯ ) , i.e., when the subpopulations are in the ISS proportions. We have verified computationally that this is in fact the case for some two player games, such as a = 1 = d , b = 2 = c and the neutral landscape for 2 N 14 . Specifically, there is a particular value of μ such that these configurations are stationary stable for each N tested (when consolidated via cyclical symmetry). For N = 2 , this value is analytically computable to be μ = 1 / 3 , and μ 1 / N appears sufficient computationally in other cases. For larger N the number of states in the Markov chain is too large for a direct approach.
A similar line of reasoning applies to the random graph (with edges that exist at random with a given probability), and so we conjecture that analogous results should hold for the random graph and k-regular graphs (and likely others).

3.3. Vanishing Mutation

Throughout, we have explicitly assumed that the mutation rates are (at least) nonzero so as to guarantee the existence of the stationary distribution. In [70,71,72] (and also [49]), it is shown that as μ 0 , the stationary distribution concentrates on the boundary states for the Moran process (and some others), and is given in terms of the fixation probabilities of the process. These results complement those of this manuscript, connecting stationary stability with fixation probabilities. In other words, it is trivially the case that for μ = 0 , the fixation states are stationary stable for, e.g., the Moran process on linear landscapes, since they are locally maximal for the stationary distribution. That they are ISS/ESS also depends on the incentive—this would be true for the the Moran process (e.g., p ( ( 0 , 1 ) ) = ( 0 , 1 ) in the n = 2 case) but not necessarily for, e.g., the projection incentive on the neutral landscape.

3.4. Existence of ISS Candidates

We have left the question of whether stationary stable states or ISS candidates exist as a prerequisite for the results presented thus far. For fixed μ and other parameters fixed, there may not be a value of N such that p ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ for an arbitrary incentive, but the converse is true: μ = n 1 n , where n is the number of types, gives p i ( a ¯ ) = 1 n for all i, so the central point of the simplex is an ISS candidate, and it is stationary stable (the process is equivalent to the neutral landscape, which has a known stationary distribution for all n for this mutation matrix [47]). Computationally we have observed for fixed population size, there is often a critical value of μ that determines if there is an internal stationary maximum, which is not surprising given that the processes often fixate when μ 0 . Hence there are may be analogs to Theorems 1 and 2 such that for fixed N, there exists a mutation matrix that yields a stationary maximum that is also evolutionarily stable, or some other relationship between μ and N that achieves this.

3.5. Large Population Limit

We have shown above that the relative entropy D K L ( E ( a ¯ ) , a ¯ ) is locally minimal for evolutionary stable states, and so we can view Theorem 2 as a finite population analog of the fact that D K L ( x ^ x ) is a Lyapunov function for the replicator dynamic when x ^ is evolutionarily stable. Explicitly, Traulsen et al. show [9,21,22,73,74] essentially that the Moran process maps to the stochastic replicator equation with mean dynamic x ˙ = T + ( x ) T ( x ) (in the n = 2 case). The stable rest points of this dynamic are those that satisfy the ISS candidate condition when we replace a ¯ with x, and we have that the relative entropy is locally minimal at these points. Moreover, this limiting process shows that any stable rest point of the replicator dynamic must be a limit of stationary stable states for some sufficiently large N (the stationary states are by definition rational and the rest point could be irrational).
What happens to the stationary distribution in the large population limit? Consider the explicit stationary distribution in Equation (7). For large N, we have that the stationary distribution converges to a binomial distribution with p = 1 / 2 . Scaling to the simplex [ 0 , 1 ] , we have that the stationary distribution is, by the normal approximation to the binomial, a normal distribution centered at 1 / 2 with variance 1 / ( 4 N ) . As N , the stationary distribution becomes a delta function centered on the ESS. Furthermore, since the replicator equation is deterministic, the expected next state is also a deterministic quantity, and naturally replaced by the ESS x ^ , and so the Lyapunov quantity becomes the function D K L ( x ^ | | x ) . This is essentially why the stationary distribution and the relative entropy capture the properties of the vector field of the replicator equation, as in Figure 1. We highly encourage the reader to compare Figure 9 to the Figure 1.4 of [25] for a striking visualization of the relationship between a Lyapunov quantity (essentially equivalent to the relative entropy) for the replicator dynamic and the functions D d that we have defined in this work. Sandholm et al. also derive a number of large population limits of the stationary distribution for similar processes [52,53].
The key difference between the distance functions is the natural geometry of the simplex, the Shahshahani geometry [75], is closely associated with the relative entropy. Forward-invariance of the replicator equation is a property acquired because of the limit N , and not true for the Markov processes considered above. This substantially changes the character of the limits as x i 0 since for integral population states, the process gets no closer to zero than 1 / N .

4. Materials and Methods

All computations were performed with python code available at https://github.com/marcharper/stationary. This package can compute exact stationary distributions for detail-balanced processes and approximate solutions for all other cases mentioned in this manuscript. All plots created with matplotlib [76] and python-ternary https://github.com/marcharper/python-ternary, except the vector field in the graphical abstract, created with Dynamo [23].

5. Conclusions

We have introduced the concept of stationary stability for finite populations and have shown that it captures the traditional notion of evolutionary stability. In the large population limit, our results limit to the known Lyapunov theory of evolutionary stability via Traulsen et al.’s mapping of the Moran process to the replicator equation. We have demonstrated that stationary stability works for all mutation rates and for a large class of incentives, connects with the fixation theory of the Moran process, and likely extends to finite populations on graphs.
Crucially, we have given Lyapunov quantities that are very easy to compute as a means of understanding the stationary distribution, which can be very difficult to study analytically, and for which the stationary distribution can not be characterized in closed form (currently). These quantities derive from information-theoretic distance functions ranging from the Euclidean distance to the relative entropy (or Kullback–Leibler divergence).

Acknowledgments

This work was partially supported by the Office of Science (BER), U.S. Department of Energy, Cooperative Agreement No. DE-FC02-02ER63421. The authors thank the anonymous reviewers for their comments. Some of the work was done at the University of California Los Angeles and Pomona College.

Author Contributions

Marc Harper and Dashiell Fryer designed the numerical experiments, wrote the code, and wrote the paper. Both authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Taylor, C.; Fudenberg, D.; Sasaki, A.; Nowak, M.A. Evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations. Bull. Math. Biol. 2004, 66, 1621–1644. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Nowak, M.A.; Sasaki, A.; Taylor, C.; Fudenberg, D. Emergence of cooperation and evolutionary stability in finite populations. Nature 2004, 428, 646–650. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  3. Ficici, S.G.; Pollack, J.B. Effects of finite populations on evolutionary stable strategies. In Proceedings of the 2nd Annual Conference on Genetic and Evolutionary Computation, Las Vegas, NV, USA, 8–12 July 2000; pp. 927–934.
  4. Fogel, G.B.; Andrews, P.C.; Fogel, D.B. On the instability of evolutionary stable strategies in small populations. Ecol. Model. 1998, 109, 283–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Noble, A.E.; Hastings, A.; Fagan, W.F. Multivariate Moran Process with Lotka-Volterra Phenomenology. Phys. Rev. Lett. 2011, 107, 228101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  6. Taylor, P.D.; Jonker, L.B. Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics. Math. Biosci. 1978, 40, 145–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Smith, J.M. Evolution and the Theory of Games; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  8. Weibull, J.W. Evolutionary Game Theory; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  9. Traulsen, A.; Pacheco, J.M.; Imhof, L.A. Stochasticity and evolutionary stability. Phys. Rev. E 2006, 74, 021905. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  10. Wild, G.; Taylor, P.D. Fitness and evolutionary stability in game theoretic models of finite populations. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B 2004, 271, 2345–2349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  11. Antal, T.; Traulsen, A.; Ohtsuki, H.; Tarnita, C.E.; Nowak, M.A. Mutation-selection equilibrium in games with multiple strategies. J. Theor. Biol. 2009, 258, 614–622. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  12. Bomze, I.M. Cross entropy minimization in uninvadable states of complex populations. J. Math. Biol. 1991, 30, 73–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Akin, E.; Losert, V. Evolutionary dynamics of zero-sum games. J. Math. Biol. 1984, 20, 231–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  14. Sandholm, W.H.; Dokumacı, E.; Lahkar, R. The projection dynamic and the replicator dynamic. Games Econ. Behav. 2008, 64, 666–683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Sato, Y.; Akiyama, E.; Crutchfield, J.P. Stability and diversity in collective adaptation. Physica D 2005, 210, 21–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Moran, P.A.P. The Statistical Processes of Evolutionary Theory; Clarendon Press: New York, NY, USA, 1962. [Google Scholar]
  17. Moran, P.A.P. Random processes in genetics. Proc. Camb. Philos. Soc. 1958, 54, 60–71. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Imhof, L.; Nowak, M. Evolutionary game dynamics in a Wright–Fisher process. J. Math. Biol. 2006, 52, 667–681. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  19. Taylor, C.; Iwasa, Y.; Nowak, M.A. A symmetry of fixation times in evoultionary dynamics. J. Theor. Biol. 2006, 243, 245–251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. Ewens, W.J. Mathematical Population Genetics: I. Theoretical Introduction; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2004; Volume 27. [Google Scholar]
  21. Traulsen, A.; Claussen, J.C.; Hauert, C. Coevolutionary dynamics: from finite to infinite populations. Phys. Rev. Lett. 2005, 95, 238701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  22. Traulsen, A.; Claussen, J.C.; Hauert, C. Coevolutionary dynamics in large, but finite populations. Phys. Rev. E 2006, 74, 011901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  23. Franchetti, F.; Sandholm, W.H. An Introduction to Dynamo: Diagrams for Evolutionary Game Dynamics. Biol. Theory 2012, 8, 167–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Harper, M.; Fryer, D. Incentive Processes in Finite Populations. 2013; arXiv:1306.2389. [Google Scholar]
  25. Traulsen, A.; Hauert, C. Stochastic evolutionary game dynamics. Rev. Nonlinear Dyn. Complex. 2009, 2, 25–61. [Google Scholar]
  26. Cressman, R. Evolutionary Dynamics and Extensive Form Games; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2003; Volume 5. [Google Scholar]
  27. Hofbauer, J.; Sigmund, K. Evolutionary game dynamics. Bull. Am. Math. Soc. 2003, 40, 479–519. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Kullback, S.; Leibler, R.A. On information and sufficiency. Ann. Math. Stat. 1951, 22, 79–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Naudts, J. Generalised Thermostatistics; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  30. Harper, M. Escort evolutionary game theory. Physica D 2011, 240, 1411–1415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Hofbauer, J.; Sigmund, K. Adaptive dynamics and evolutionary stability. Appl. Math. Lett. 1990, 3, 75–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Fryer, D. The Kullback–Liebler Divergence as a Lyapunov Function for Incentive Based Game Dynamics. 2012; arXiv:1207.0036. [Google Scholar]
  33. Harper, M.; Fryer, D. Lyapunov Functions for Time-Scale Dynamics on Riemannian Geometries of the Simplex. Dyn. Games Appl. 2014, 5, 318–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Shalizi, C.R. Dynamics of Bayesian updating with dependent data and misspecified models. Electron. J. Stat. 2009, 3, 1039–1074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Harper, M. Inherent randomness of evolving populations. Phys. Rev. E 2014, 89, 032709. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  36. Claussen, J.C.; Traulsen, A. Non-Gaussian fluctuations arising from finite populations: Exact results for the evolutionary Moran process. Phys. Rev. E 2005, 71, 025101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  37. Sandholm, W.H. Excess payoff dynamics and other well-behaved evolutionary dynamics. J. Econ. Theory 2005, 124, 149–170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Sandholm, W.H. Stochastic Evolutionary Game Dynamics: Foundations, Deterministic Approximation, and Equilibrium Selection. Available online: http://www.ams.org/meetings/short-courses/ams-evgame-sandholm.pdf (accessed on 18 August 2016).
  39. Sandholm, W.H. Stochastic imitative game dynamics with committed agents. J. Econ. Theory 2012, 147, 2056–2071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Traulsen, A.; Pacheco, J.M.; Nowak, M.A. Pairwise comparison and selection temperature in evolutionary game dynamics. J. Theor. Biol. 2007, 246, 522–529. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  41. Fryer, D.E. On the existence of general equilibrium in finite games and general game dynamics. 2012; arXiv:1201.2384. [Google Scholar]
  42. Andrae, B.; Cremer, J.; Reichenbach, T.; Frey, E. Entropy production of cyclic population dynamics. Phys. Rev. Lett. 2010, 104, 218102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  43. Tsallis, C. Possible generalization of Boltzmann–Gibbs statistics. J. Stat. Phys. 1988, 52, 479–487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Hernando, A.; Hernando, R.; Plastino, A.; Plastino, A.R. The workings of the maximum entropy principle in collective human behaviour. J. R. Soc. Interface 2013, 10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  45. Hofbauer, J.; Sigmund, K. Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  46. Antal, T.; Nowak, M.A.; Traulsen, A. Strategy abundance in 2 × 2 games for arbitrary mutation rates. J. Theor. Biol. 2009, 257, 340–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  47. Khare, K.; Zhou, H. Rates of convergence of some multivariate Markov chains with polynomial eigenfunctions. Ann. Appl. Probab. 2009, 19, 737–777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Gokhale, C.S.; Traulsen, A. Strategy abundance in evolutionary many-player games with multiple strategies. J. Theor. Biol. 2011, 283, 180–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  49. Allen, B.; Tarnita, C.E. Measures of success in a class of evolutionary models with fixed population size and structure. J. Math. Biol. 2012, 68, 109–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  50. Wu, B.; Traulsen, A.; Gokhale, C.S. Dynamic Properties of Evolutionary Multi-player Games in Finite Populations. Games 2013, 4, 182–199. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Huillet, T.E. On Discrete-Time Multiallelic Evolutionary Dynamics Driven by Selection. J. Probab. Stat. 2010, 2010, 580762. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Sandholm, W.H. Simple formulas for stationary distributions and stochastically stable states. Games Econ. Behav. 2007, 59, 154–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Sandholm, W.H.; Staudigl, M. Large Deviations and Stochastic Stability in the Small Noise Double Limit, I: Theory. Available online: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2424044 (accessed on 18 August 2016).
  54. Nowak, M.A. Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life; Belknap Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  55. Sayyareh, A. A new upper bound for Kullback–Leibler divergence. Appl. Math. Sci 2011, 67, 3303–3317. [Google Scholar]
  56. García, J.; Traulsen, A. The structure of mutations and the evolution of cooperation. PLoS ONE 2012, 7, e35287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  57. Fudenberg, D.; Imhof, L.; Nowak, M.A.; Taylor, C. Stochastic Evolution as a Generalized Moran Process. Available online: http://scholar.harvard.edu/files/fudenberg/files/stochastic_evolution.pdf (accessed on 18 August 2016).
  58. Bomze, I.M. Lotka-Volterra equation and replicator dynamics: A two-dimensional classification. Biol. Cybern. 1983, 48, 201–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Bomze, I.M. Lotka-Volterra equation and replicator dynamics: New issues in classification. Biol. Cybern. 1995, 72, 447–453. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Chalub, F.A.; Souza, M.O. The frequency-dependent Wright–Fisher model: Diffusive and non-diffusive approximations. J. Math. Biol. 2014, 68, 1089–1133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  61. Harper, M. Inferring Fitness in Finite, Variably-sized, and Dynamically-structured Populations. 2013; arXiv:1303.4566. [Google Scholar]
  62. Melbinger, A.; Cremer, J.; Frey, E. Evolutionary game theory in growing populations. Phys. Rev. Lett. 2010, 105, 178101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  63. Lieberman, E.; Hauert, C.; Nowak, M.A. Evolutionary dynamics on graphs. Nature 2005, 433, 312–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  64. Szabó, G.; Fath, G. Evolutionary games on graphs. Phys. Rep. 2007, 446, 97–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Ohtsuki, H.; Pacheco, J.M.; Nowak, M.A. Evolutionary graph theory: Breaking the symmetry between interaction and replacement. J. Theor. Biol. 2007, 246, 681–694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  66. Ohtsuki, H.; Nowak, M.A. Evolutionary games on cycles. Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B 2006, 273, 2249–2256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  67. Van Veelen, M.; Nowak, M.A. Multi-player games on the cycle. J. Theor. Biol. 2012, 292, 116–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  68. Szabó, G.; Borsos, I. Evolutionary potential games on lattices. Phys. Rep. 2016, 624, 1–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Perc, M.; Gómez-Gardeñes, J.; Szolnoki, A.; Floría, L.M.; Moreno, Y. Evolutionary dynamics of group interactions on structured populations: A review. J. R. Soc. Interface 2013, 10, 20120997. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  70. Fudenberg, D.; Imhof, L.A. Imitation processes with small mutations. J. Econ. Theory 2006, 131, 251–262. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Fudenberg, D.; Nowak, M.A.; Taylor, C.; Imhof, L.A. Evolutionary game dynamics in finite populations with strong selection and weak mutation. Theor. Popul. Biol. 2006, 70, 352–363. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  72. Fudenberg, D.; Imhof, L.A. Monotone imitation dynamics in large populations. J. Econ. Theory 2008, 140, 229–245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Pacheco, J.M.; Traulsen, A.; Nowak, M.A. Active linking in evolutionary games. J. Theor. Biol. 2006, 243, 437–443. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  74. Zhou, D.; Qian, H. Fixation, transient landscape, and diffusion dilemma in stochastic evolutionary game dynamics. Phys. Rev. E 2011, 84, 031907. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  75. Shahshahani, S. A New Mathematical Framework for the Study of Linkage and Selection; American Mathematical Society: Providence, RI, USA, 1979. [Google Scholar]
  76. Hunter, J.D. Matplotlib: A 2D graphics environment. Comput. Sci. Eng. 2007, 9, 90–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. (a) Vector field for the replicator dynamic with Fermi selection, with fitness landscape defined by game matrix 7 in Bomze’s classification (above); made with Dynamo [23]; (b) Stationary distribution of the Moran process with Fermi selection ( N = 60 , β = 0 . 1 , μ = 3 2 N ) which is locally maximal at the interior stable rest point; (c) Euclidean distance between each population state and the expected next state; local minima correspond to rest points of the vector field; (d) Relative entropy of each state and the expected next state. For the heatmaps the boundary has not been plotted to make the interior more visible.
Figure 1. (a) Vector field for the replicator dynamic with Fermi selection, with fitness landscape defined by game matrix 7 in Bomze’s classification (above); made with Dynamo [23]; (b) Stationary distribution of the Moran process with Fermi selection ( N = 60 , β = 0 . 1 , μ = 3 2 N ) which is locally maximal at the interior stable rest point; (c) Euclidean distance between each population state and the expected next state; local minima correspond to rest points of the vector field; (d) Relative entropy of each state and the expected next state. For the heatmaps the boundary has not been plotted to make the interior more visible.
Entropy 18 00316 g001
Figure 2. (ac) Relative entropy of the expected next state with the current state D 1 ( a ) for Fermi incentives ( q = 1 , β = 1 ) for the incentive process with μ = 3 2 1 N for game matrices 2, 20, and 47 in Bomze’s classification. (df) Stationary distributions for the incentive process for the same parameters.
Figure 2. (ac) Relative entropy of the expected next state with the current state D 1 ( a ) for Fermi incentives ( q = 1 , β = 1 ) for the incentive process with μ = 3 2 1 N for game matrices 2, 20, and 47 in Bomze’s classification. (df) Stationary distributions for the incentive process for the same parameters.
Entropy 18 00316 g002
Figure 3. Stationary distributions for the rock-scissors-paper game for N = 60 with the Fermi incentive, β = 1 . We have 2 3 μ = 1 N ( a ) , 1 N ( b ) , 1 N 3 / 2 (c).
Figure 3. Stationary distributions for the rock-scissors-paper game for N = 60 with the Fermi incentive, β = 1 . We have 2 3 μ = 1 N ( a ) , 1 N ( b ) , 1 N 3 / 2 (c).
Entropy 18 00316 g003
Figure 4. Demonstration of Theorem 1, for the Moran process (replicator incentive) with game matrix given by a = 1 = d , b = 2 , c = 3 , population size N = 100 , μ = 1 / 1000 , which has an ESS at approximately ( 33 , 67 ) . (a) Transition probabilities T i i + 1 (blue) and T i i 1 (green); (b) Relative entropy D ( a ¯ ) ; (c) Stationary distribution.
Figure 4. Demonstration of Theorem 1, for the Moran process (replicator incentive) with game matrix given by a = 1 = d , b = 2 , c = 3 , population size N = 100 , μ = 1 / 1000 , which has an ESS at approximately ( 33 , 67 ) . (a) Transition probabilities T i i + 1 (blue) and T i i 1 (green); (b) Relative entropy D ( a ¯ ) ; (c) Stationary distribution.
Entropy 18 00316 g004
Figure 5. (a) Stationary distribution for the three common faces for the incentive process for matrix M 4 above, N = 40 ; (b) D 0 expected distances for the faces shown in (a); (c) Stationary distribution for the face with a 4 = 0 ; (d) D 0 expected distances for the face shown in (c).
Figure 5. (a) Stationary distribution for the three common faces for the incentive process for matrix M 4 above, N = 40 ; (b) D 0 expected distances for the faces shown in (a); (c) Stationary distribution for the face with a 4 = 0 ; (d) D 0 expected distances for the face shown in (c).
Entropy 18 00316 g005
Figure 6. (ac) Relative entropy of the expected next state with the current state D 1 ( a ¯ ) for Fermi incentives ( q = 1 , β = 1 ) for the Wright Fisher process with μ = 3 2 1 N for game matrices 2, 20, and 47 in Bomze’s classification (same as Figure 2; (df) Stationary distributions for the Wright–Fisher process; (gi) Stationary distributions with μ = 1 2 1 N . The bottom row has relative entropies that are slightly different (notably the lower left vertex of the middle column plots), but they are very similar to the top row and so omitted.
Figure 6. (ac) Relative entropy of the expected next state with the current state D 1 ( a ¯ ) for Fermi incentives ( q = 1 , β = 1 ) for the Wright Fisher process with μ = 3 2 1 N for game matrices 2, 20, and 47 in Bomze’s classification (same as Figure 2; (df) Stationary distributions for the Wright–Fisher process; (gi) Stationary distributions with μ = 1 2 1 N . The bottom row has relative entropies that are slightly different (notably the lower left vertex of the middle column plots), but they are very similar to the top row and so omitted.
Entropy 18 00316 g006
Figure 7. (a) Stationary distribution for a Moran-like process with non-constant population size with the replicator incentive for the fitness landscape defined by a = 1 = d and b = 2 = c , maximum population size N = 40 , μ = 0 . 01 . The coordinates are ( a 1 , a 2 , a 1 + a 2 ) , with the population size a 1 + a 2 increasing to the top and right; (b) D 0 distance between the expected next state and the current state. As expected, minima occur along the line a 1 = a 2 with a local minima of D 1 at ( 20 , 20 ) . We have taken the root of D 1 to exaggerate the variation visually. Sigmoid (s-curve) probabilities for the birth-death decision behave similarly.
Figure 7. (a) Stationary distribution for a Moran-like process with non-constant population size with the replicator incentive for the fitness landscape defined by a = 1 = d and b = 2 = c , maximum population size N = 40 , μ = 0 . 01 . The coordinates are ( a 1 , a 2 , a 1 + a 2 ) , with the population size a 1 + a 2 increasing to the top and right; (b) D 0 distance between the expected next state and the current state. As expected, minima occur along the line a 1 = a 2 with a local minima of D 1 at ( 20 , 20 ) . We have taken the root of D 1 to exaggerate the variation visually. Sigmoid (s-curve) probabilities for the birth-death decision behave similarly.
Entropy 18 00316 g007
Figure 8. Two configurations for an incentive process on a cycle. (a) The configuration is inherently unstable since any non-mutation replication will alter the configuration; (b) The configuration is much more stable. For small mutation rates, only replication events on the interface between the two subpopulations can alter the configuration.
Figure 8. Two configurations for an incentive process on a cycle. (a) The configuration is inherently unstable since any non-mutation replication will alter the configuration; (b) The configuration is much more stable. For small mutation rates, only replication events on the interface between the two subpopulations can alter the configuration.
Entropy 18 00316 g008
Figure 9. (a) D 0 for the 40-fold incentive process, Fermi incentive ( β = 1 ), Rock-Paper-Scissors matrix (Bomze’s 17), N = 80 ; Local minima occur at the boundary states and at the center; (b) D 1 for the same process; Compare to Figure 1.4 in [25], which depicts a Lyapunov quantity equivalent to the relative entropy for the replicator equation.
Figure 9. (a) D 0 for the 40-fold incentive process, Fermi incentive ( β = 1 ), Rock-Paper-Scissors matrix (Bomze’s 17), N = 80 ; Local minima occur at the boundary states and at the center; (b) D 1 for the same process; Compare to Figure 1.4 in [25], which depicts a Lyapunov quantity equivalent to the relative entropy for the replicator equation.
Entropy 18 00316 g009
Table 1. Incentives for some common dynamics. The projection incentive [14] is simply the q-replicator with q = 0 . Another way of looking at the projection incentive on the Moran landscape is simply as a constant incentive, since the incentive itself is a constant function in i. The logit incentive is the q-Fermi with q = 0 . For more examples see Table 1 in [41].
Table 1. Incentives for some common dynamics. The projection incentive [14] is simply the q-replicator with q = 0 . Another way of looking at the projection incentive on the Moran landscape is simply as a constant incentive, since the incentive itself is a constant function in i. The logit incentive is the q-Fermi with q = 0 . For more examples see Table 1 in [41].
DynamicsIncentive
Projection φ i ( a ¯ ) = f i ( a ¯ )
Replicator φ i ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ i f i ( a ¯ )
q-Replicator φ i ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ i q f i ( a ¯ )
q-Fermi φ i ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ i q exp ( β f i ( a ¯ ) ) j a ¯ j q exp ( β f j ( a ¯ ) )
Best Reply φ i ( a ¯ ) = a ¯ i B R i ( a ¯ )

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Harper, M.; Fryer, D. Stationary Stability for Evolutionary Dynamics in Finite Populations. Entropy 2016, 18, 316. https://doi.org/10.3390/e18090316

AMA Style

Harper M, Fryer D. Stationary Stability for Evolutionary Dynamics in Finite Populations. Entropy. 2016; 18(9):316. https://doi.org/10.3390/e18090316

Chicago/Turabian Style

Harper, Marc, and Dashiell Fryer. 2016. "Stationary Stability for Evolutionary Dynamics in Finite Populations" Entropy 18, no. 9: 316. https://doi.org/10.3390/e18090316

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop