1. Introduction
The dynamic economy of ASEAN member countries with high growth of outputs requires inflation control, which is based on a good understanding of inflation. Various studies on inflation using national data aggregation have been conducted, but only a few studies have concern about inflation and built a model of inflation based on data from a community of country (
Wardhono et al. 2017). Ideally, the research that examines dynamic inflation using panel data of a community of country is also conducted to better understand inflation. The research is important because ASEAN is a community of big countries with regional growth differences that cause variations in inflation. These variations certainly cannot be seen using aggregate data but can be seen using data of each country. In addition, the calculation of consumer price index compiled by regions of the countries shows that inflation is a phenomenon of the rise in general price level.
Moreover, quoting
Mehrotra et al. (
2007), research using provincial data is important for big countries because the provinces throughout the country have different institutions, economic performance, and level of market development. Economic obstacles between regions, for example, trade obstacles, can also be a source of differences in inflation formation process (
Wardhono et al. 2018). Furthermore, inflation differences between regions reduce the ability of a region to adjust the economic shocks. In addition, the role of inflation and inflation expectations in various areas that have various inflation dynamics also influences the effectiveness of monetary policy.
Research on interprovincial inflation has been carried out by
Mehrotra et al. (
2007) using data of China. In their research, they found the variation of inflation in each province and the forward-looking inflation component in 22 of the 29 provinces studied. Likewise,
Chaban and Voss (
2012) who examined inflation in Canada found a variation of inflation in 10 provinces. The contribution of this research compared to previous inflation studies is the use of panel data of 5 ASEAN countries, in contrast to
Mehrotra et al. (
2007) and
Chaban and Voss (
2012), who used provincial panel data. Furthermore, this research analyzes the dynamic inflation in ASEAN to use the framework of the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) model. In addition, this research will also see the effect of the output gap in each country and the monetary level in each country. Estimation of dynamic inflation used quarter-to-quarter (qtq) inflation data and the method used was the the Generalized Method of Moment (GMM) system for panel data.
2. Literature Review
The development model of dynamic inflation was pioneered by
Calvo (
1983) who created the NKPC model. The NKPC model assumes that in an imperfect competition in the market, companies can set prices based on markup above marginal cost. Furthermore, in every random period, there is a possibility (1 −
) for companies to rearrange the prices and a possibility
for the companies not to change the prices. This condition can be written as
where the aggregate price level,
, consisting of rearranged prices,
, and the old prices,
that did not change. The company’s choice to rearrange the prices can be expressed in the following equation:
where
is the value of optimal markup,
is the discount factor, and
is nominal marginal cost. The sigma sign in Equation (2) shows the new prices, which are arranged based on the whole expectations
. In addition, companies can also choose not to change the prices based on the weighted value of the expectation of future nominal marginal costs. Based on the conditions, Equations (1) and (2) can be arranged in a new equation that generates a new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) model as follows:
where inflation relates to expectations of future inflation and the difference in real marginal cost of its optimum level. In the general condition, aggregate real marginal cost is proportional to the difference between actual output and potential output. By this assumption, the NKPC becomes
where
is the output gap, i.e., actual output minus potential output, (
−
), and
.
For policy implications,
Rudd and Whelan (
2002,
2005a) state that NKPC inflation is influenced completely by forward-looking behavior. There is no inertia in inflation, which means that there is no structural impact of the past inflation on inflation. Then, solving the Equation (4) in a rational assumption obtains the equation:
There are at least three policy implications of the NKPC model presented by
Rudd and Whelan (
2005a,
2005b). The first is the absence of inertia in the inflation model. Inflation is influenced entirely by forward-looking behavior. Second, the involvement of the lag inflation variable as a proxy for the future value from the output gap affecting inflation is not applicable. According to the supporters of NKPC, if the central bank is able to maintain the inflation target with credible policies, the role of lag inflation in the expectation becomes small. In this situation, inflation can be controlled at a low cost. However, if the policy is not credible, inflation expectations are compiled by the public based on the last occurrence of inflation (lag) and not the central bank’s announcement. The latter policy implication is the occurrence of misleading nature of the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU)-based analysis, so NAIRU cannot be used as a macroeconomic policy guideline. Estimation of time-varying NAIRU showing low inflation can be explained by a decrease in NAIRU. Implicitly, this means that the central bank can increase the economic activities without having to increase inflation. In fact, models (4) and (5) show that there is a positive effect between output gap and inflation.
3. Methodology
This research used panel data of 5 countries that exist in ASEAN, ranging from year 2005 quarter 1 through year 2018 quarter 4. Most of the data were taken from the central bank of each country in ASEAN, ASEAN secretariat, International Monetary Fund (IMF), and the World Bank. Some of the variables used in the model are listed in
Table 1.
The following are the dynamic inflation models used in this research and refer to research conducted by
Gali and Gertler (
1999).
where
is inflation,
is output gap, and
is monetary aggregate. Furthermore,
and
are defined as backward-looking and forward-looking parameters. The selection of estimation method is based on the NKPC model. Equation (8) can be rewritten as follows:
where
is the output gap
. In practice,
is usually converted into
, where
symbolizes a step forward of forecast error of inflation (
Vinod 2010). The changes lead to the equation changing into
Thus, an endogeneity problem arises because the error correlation
with the regressor results in inconsistent estimates
,
,
, and
. If there is a problem of endogeneity, then Ordinary Least Square (OLS) is inconsistent and the estimation method that should be used is GMM.
Mileva (
2007) describes how the data panel and a model similar to Equation (8) can face problems. First, the endogeneity problem can appear where the regressor is correlated with the error term. Second, time-invariant characteristics of the province (fixed effect), such as geography and demography, may be correlated with the explanatory variables. The fixed effect in the error term consists of the observed and unobserved effects (
Sadik-Zada 2019). Third, the emergence of a lag variable increases autocorrelation. Fourth, panel data have a short time dimension and relatively large space dimension. To solve the problem that arises,
Mileva (
2007) suggests using the Arellano–Bond GMM estimator or GMM system.
4. Results and Analysis
The testing of data integration order is made toward inflation-quarter data , the output gap , and monetary variable . Order integration testing of panel data used the IPS test of Im, Peseran, and Shin (2003), LLC test of Levin, Lin, and Chu (2002), and Augmented Dickey–Fuller ADF Fisher test and Phillips-Perron Test (PP) Fisher test of Maddala and Wu (1999).
The overall unit root tests, either LLC, IPS, ADF Fisher, or PP Fisher, indicate that the null hypothesis, which contains a unit root, was rejected, so it is concluded that all data are integrated at the order level. The test results in
Table 2 show that
p-value is entirely under 5%, so it is concluded that there were no root units in all variables of level order. Because the data are integrated at the level order, level data in the estimated GMM model are used.
Gali and Gertler (
1999) compare the results of estimated NKPC models to show that the use of output gap in dynamic inflation models is not appropriate. In the explanation, they use a pair of independent variables of future inflation
and output gap
in the NKPC model. The estimation results of the NKPC using independent variable
and the variable of part of labor income share (
) show estimation of a positive parameter for
and (
). The econometric success provides the basis for
Gali and Gertler (
1999) and
Gali et al. (
2005) not to use the output gap, but part of the labor income in the model. Part of labor income is the labor income percentage compared to the total output of economy.
The NKPC model, developed by
Gali and Gertler (
1999), explains that inflation expectations and lag inflation simultaneously affect the prevailing inflation. This model assumes that the company determines the price level based on information on the past inflation (backward-looking rule-of-tumb), while the rest behaves as forward-looking.
Table 3 shows the estimated NKPC in model A using GMM with an instrument variable. Estimating the equation of the NKPC indicates backward-looking, forward-looking parameter estimation, and the significant output gap at α = 5%, which is indicated by a
p-value of all parameters less than 5%. The
p-value for the J-statistic is also greater than 5%. The null hypothesis, which states that there is no overidentification, is accepted. Model A also shows the direction of the coefficient backward-looking, forward-looking, and the output gap according to the theory (positive).
Results of the estimated NKPC model indicate the pattern of formation of inflation expectations is backward-looking and forward-looking. This means that inflation expectations are influenced by the experience of the past inflation and estimation of inflation expectations in the future. Notwithstanding the foregoing, it can be seen that the backward-looking parameter is greater than forward-looking. Hypothesis − = 0 or = is also rejected by the Wald test. The chi-square value (9.31) and prob-value (0.0000) indicate that the value is not equal to . Based on the value of the parameter and Wald test, it is found that the behavior of backward-looking is more dominant in the formation of inflation expectations than that of forward-looking behavior.
Testing the number of parameters of backward-looking and forward-looking, the same as one γb + γf = 1, is also performed using the Wald test. This test is made to determine whether the establishment of expectations is perfect or full. The results of the Wald test with chi-square (1529.9) value and p-value (0.000) conclude that the hypothesis stating γb + γf = 1 is rejected. This means that the formation of inflation expectations is not full and in the long-term, the Phillips curve is not vertical. The test results indicate that inflation is also influenced by the output gap. The conclusion of the Wald test results is in line with the significant value of the output gap parameter λ, and this means that the output gap affects inflation.
NKPC estimation results also show the persistence of inflation in ASEAN. The average time of inflation adjustment of 0.095, which is calculated based on the method presented by Koyck (1954) (in
Gujarati (
2003)) shows that the average length of time of inflation adjustment is 0.095 quarter or approximately 1.1 week. This value indicates the low level of inflation persistence.
Model B shows the estimated results of the NKPC with additional monetary variables. Estimation of model B shows the estimation of
backward-
looking and
forward-
looking parameters, the output gap, and monetary variables is significant at α = 5%, which is indicated by
p-value of all parameters less than 5%. The
p-value for J-statistic is also greater than 5%. The null hypothesis, which states that there is no overidentification, is accepted.
Table 3 also shows the direction of the coefficient of
backward-
looking and
forward-
looking, and the output gap of model B is in accordance with the theory (positive).
Of the estimated model B, it is found that the monetary variable turns out to affect inflation. This means that if relative money supply compared to GDP increases, the inflation will rise, while if it is decreased, it will lead to inflation decrease. In the estimation of model B, it can be seen that the significance level of the backward-looking parameter is always significant at α = 5%. This level of significance is the same as in model A. This means that the additional explanatory variable causes the reduced strength of the forward-looking parameter in influencing inflation.
Even if the level of significance of the forward-looking parameter declines, the estimated results of the NKPC model with a fixed monetary variable shows backward-looking and forward-looking determines the pattern formation of inflation expectations. Inflation is influenced by the experience of inflation in the past time and also the estimated inflation expectations in the future by the backward-looking parameter value greater than that of the forward-looking parameter.
Wald test results with p-value (0.000) for model B concludes that the hypothesis which states that + = 1 is rejected. This means that the formation of inflation expectations is not full in the NKPC model with additional monetary variables. Besides, the meaning of rejection of the hypothesis in the long term of the NKPC model is not vertical. The test results indicate that inflation is also affected by other significant variables in the model. In addition, the average time of inflation adjustment for model B is 0.102. Similar within the NKPC model (model A), the average time needed to adjust the inflation is about one week. This value indicates the low level of inflation persistence.
5. Discussion
According to the baseline NKPC, inflation is mainly an expectations phenomenon—if the central bank controls future inflation expectations, it controls the present value of inflation (
Carré 2008). This explains why the expectations channel of transmission is central to monetary policy: ”markets do the job” instead of the central bank. It is also why ”expectations management” is so crucial in the modern view of optimal monetary policy under the inflation targeting regime—the expectations management is the root of monetary policy efficiency.
Consistency of positive direction parameter estimation of the Phillips curve and NKPC shows that the opinions of
Gali and Gertler (
1999) and
Gali et al. (
2005), which state that the output gap cannot be a proxy for economic activities, cannot be accepted. Based on these results, the use of the output gap in the estimated dynamic inflation model in this research may be confirmed. Moreover, in all estimated models, significant values of the output gap are obtained.
The conclusion that the output gap in ASEAN countries can be accepted as factors affecting inflation is the same as the conclusion of research conducted by
Mehrotra et al. (
2007). Variable significance of national output gap on inflation indicates that demand and supply of outputs in ASEAN are important variables that explain dynamic inflation. The high national economy in ASEAN, which causes actual output to be above its potential, has an implication on inflation in each country, and vice versa.
Based on the estimated NKPC model, either in reduced form (model A) or after the addition of monetary shock variable (model B), it is found that estimation parameters of forward-looking , or backward-looking , are entirely significant and marked positive. These results prove that the formation pattern of inflation expectations is backward-looking and forward-looking. This means that the inflation expectations are influenced by the experience of the past inflation and inflation expectations in the future.
Even if inflation is influenced by the behaviors of
backward-
looking and
forward-
looking, the NKPC estimation model results show that the behavior of
backward-
looking is more dominant than that of forward-looking. However, in all estimated models, the dominant value of component of
backward-
looking decrease when the explanatory variables in the NKPC model is coupled with monetary variables. The findings of the dominance of
backward-
looking behavior is different from the predictions of the NKPC model and previous studies conducted by
Gali and Gertler (
1999);
Gali et al. (
2005);
Abbas and Sgro (
2011); and
Mehrotra et al. (
2007).
The results of the estimation of the model NKPC also find that the dynamics of inflation is not only influenced by expectations that underlie the behavior of the backward-looking and forward-looking. Other explanatory variables such as the output gap and monetary and cyclical variables also influence inflation.
The conclusion states that the money supply in ASEAN that has an effect on regional inflation is the same as the conclusion of previous research that examined the effect of the amount of money on inflation. These results indicate that the regulation of the money supply in ASEAN can be used to control inflation and to prescribe monetary policy at the national level. The final conclusion that can be drawn from the estimation results is that the level of inflation persistence is low. The average value for inflation adjustment time is about one week. This means that if there is a shock that causes inflation to differ from its equilibrium point, economic actors will quickly adjust the existing inflation back to its equilibrium value.
Since 2002, the Philippines has been adopting inflation targeting framework as its guide in reaching price stability for the purpose of determining monetary decisions. The Philippines adopted a floating exchange rate system in 1970 (
Wardhono et al. 2014). This was caused by the existence of government consideration toward a steady exchange rate system that became a treasure of an overexchange rate fluctuation. The implication of the floating exchange rate system was also consistent to ITF. Through this path, exchange rate movement was impacted by actual inflation and expected inflation (Report,
Bangko Sentral NG Pilipinas 2015).
Indonesia has been adopting an inflation targeting framework since 2005, which previously used monetary policy that applied base money as a policy framework. Indonesia has begun to implement a floating exchange rate system since 1997 until now. The purpose of the policy of Bank Indonesia is to maintain exchange rate stability and safeguard the Rupiah value stability, in order to maintain stability in the prices of goods and services reflected in inflation (
Wardhono et al. 2016). A floating exchange rate policy is also consistent with the implementation of the monetary policy framework, i.e., inflation targeting framework. Malaysia is one of the ASEAN members that does not implement an inflation targeting framework as a monetary decision. Malaysia uses the interest rate framework as one of its national monetary decision targets. The main instrument of its monetary decision is the overnight policy rate (OPR). Malaysia seems to implement a flexible inflation target decision, although it does not officially adopt IT as its decision guide. In 2002, Malaysia used the steady exchange rate system; later, on 21 July 2005, it was changed to a floating exchange rate system. This transformation is a response of a structural change that happened in the domestic or international region. Since 2000, Thailand has adopted an inflation targeting framework. Thailand adopted a floating exchange rate system in July 1997, and the system is also consistent with the inflation target policy framework (ITF) adopted by Thailand in 2000. The implication of inflation targeting framework and the floating exchange rate system indicate that the Baht exchange rate is determined by the market. In implementing the system, the Bank of Thailand does not target a fixed amount for the exchange rate, but the Bank of Thailand will intervene in case of excessive volatility, as the Bank of Thailand is consistent with the policy of an inflation targeting framework.