Next Article in Journal
Macroeconomic Determinants of Islamic Banking Products in Indonesia
Previous Article in Journal
Mining Booms and Sustainable Economic Growth in Mongolia—Empirical Result from Recursive Dynamic CGE Model
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Industrial Productivity Divergence and Input-Output Network Structures: Evidence from Japan 1973–2012

1
Graduate School of Economics, Nagoya University, Aichi 464-8601, Japan
2
Graduate School of International Development, Nagoya University, Aichi 464-8601, Japan
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2019, 7(2), 52; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7020052
Submission received: 9 May 2019 / Revised: 24 May 2019 / Accepted: 25 May 2019 / Published: 31 May 2019

Abstract

:
Since the early 1990s, there have been larger and increasing labor productivity differences across industries in Japan. More specifically, a clear pattern of sigma and beta divergence across industries is observed. To shed light on these stylized facts, we first evaluate the input–output structure of Japan through the lens of a community-detection algorithm from network theory. Results from this analysis suggest the existence of two input–output network structures: a densely-connected group of industries (a stationary community), whose members remain in it throughout the period; and a group of industries (a transitional community) whose members do not belong to this first group. Next, we re-evaluate the industrial divergence pattern of Japan in the context of each network structure. Results suggest that divergence is mostly driven by the transitional community. Interestingly, since 2007, a pattern of sigma convergence started to re-appear only in the stationary community. We conclude suggesting that industrial divergence and instability in community membership are not necessarily indicative of low productivity performance.

1. Introduction

When analyzing the aggregate data of an economy regarding its growth performance, it is not possible to determine which sectors are leading this trend. By working with partitioned data, we can study the differences in productivity across groups while also obtaining some insights about different trends throughout the aforementioned sectors. By working with partitioned data, we aim to uncover important heterogeneous outcomes that could be masked when using wider data aggregations.
In this paper we first show that, since the early 1990s, there have been larger and increasing labor productivity differences across industries in Japan. This raises the question of whether there could be a group or cluster of industries whose productivity is behaving differently from that of the rest of the economy. Community detection algorithms from network science allow us to deal with these kind of issues through the partitioning of a network into smaller subsets. Fortunato and Hric (2016) define a community as a subnetwork whose nodes have a higher probability of being linked to other nodes in the subnetwork than to any of the remaining nodes of the network. In our paper, nodes represent industries and links between them constitute the trade that they perform. Input–output tables can be translated as directed weighted networks.1
By relying on input-output data from the Japanese Industrial Productivity Database of the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI), our interest in this paper is twofold: First, what kind of input–output network structures (industrial communities) characterize the Japanese economy? Second, to what extent is the productivity of the members of each network community converging?
Techniques to detect network communities have a long history. Girvan and Newman (2002) and Newman and Girvan (2004) proposed a simple yet powerful method to find these type of structures within networks, and since then the literature has grown enormously. More recently, other methods to detect communities such as Degree-corrected Stochastic Block Models (Karrer and Newman 2011) and the Louvain method (Blondel et al. 2008) were developed. Good surveys on these literatures are Fortunato (2010) and Fortunato and Hric (2016).
The analysis of economic structures and sectors dates back to the 1940s with the foundational analysis of Leontief (See for example Leontief (1944)). Even though the economic structure into sectors of an economy is related to a network, it is not the same as a social network. Both economic sectors and social networks can be graphed and understood through the use of nodes and links, but their interpretation is different. Social networks rest on behavior, incentives and relationships between the actors or agents under study; economic sectors build upon market and technological requirements and their structure is more stable.2
Although social networks play a traditional role in the literature, there is an emerging literature such as Acemoglu et al. (2012), Acemoglu et al. (2016) and Carvalho (2014) that in recent years use input–output data and networks to understand macro patterns and their fluctuations. Other authors as Kagawa et al. (2013) and Cerina et al. (2015) find network communities of industries in input-output tables by employing alternative community detection methods. Zhu et al. (2014) study the international trade network through a community detection algorithm and analyze the relationship between globalization and regionalization. del Río-Chanona et al. (2017) study the World Input Output Network, concentrating on the importance that countries or sectors have and find that these break into two groups: one group based on renewable resources and the other into non-renewable ones.
In order to detect clusters of industries in the Japanese economy, we employ the leading eigenvector algorithm for community detection developed by Newman (2006). This method consists in utilizing the leading eigenvalue and eigenvector of the modularity matrix to perform a spectral optimization of the modularity index, developed by Newman and Girvan (2004). An advantage that network portioning has is that when detecting clusters of industries, the limits between groups can be established based on measure such as the modularity index. The optimization performed by the modularity finds groups strongly connected by maximizing the connections of members inside the community while minimizing the connections between different groups. The problem is that this method can be computationally demanding. The method by Newman (2006) is computationally more efficient than other algorithms.
The first step of this procedure involves calculating the leading eigenvector of the modularity matrix and then partitioning the network into two. This is done in a way that the splitting maximizes the modularity index by relying on the leading eigenvector. This process is iterated and it re-partitions the network at each step until the modularity index is no longer positive. The resulting groups from these partitions consist on the communities that are detected.
Through this algorithm, we detect a stable community for the whole period under study. Because sometimes members of a community “leave” and/or “join” it in different years, it becomes difficult to derive results from communities in an intertemporal fashion due to a lack of consistency in their composition. Therefore, we proceed to define a different type of community, which we call the stationary community. It results from the intersection of members of a given community throughout the entire period. In other words, the stationary community consists only of members that remain “inside” the community for the entire period under study: 1973–2012. This allows us to examine only the industries that belong to a community and compare their performance with those of other communities or that belong to none at all. To the best of our knowledge, this has not been done before.
The community we obtain is composed of 44 out of 108 industries of the economy. These industries consist largely of globally non-tradable goods, such as local services. Although it is not clear-cut, by largely we mean that the ratio of services to non-services is higher in the stationary community. This is due to limitations that community detection algorithms sometimes have in avoiding the overlap of some communities. This is an ongoing research in the field of network science and is being worked upon (see for example Fortunato and Hric (2016) for further insights). We collect the remaining sectors of the economy into what we call the transitional community, the complement of the stationary community.
Given these two kinds of groups, we next evaluate to what extent the productivity of the members is converging. The study of economic convergence has been at the center of the modern literature on economic growth and development at least since the seminal work of Solow (1956). The empirical literature on economic convergence that started with the seminal work of Baumol (1986) has rapidly evolved in the last three decades.3 Among the early pioneers, Barro and Sala-i Martin (1992a) studied convergence across countries, Barro and Sala-i Martin (1992b) focused on regional convergence, and Bernard and Jones (1996) focused on industries. Compared to cross-country convergence, regional and industrial convergence are more likely to be expected. This is because the regions and industries of a country are more likely to share common institutional and technological environments. Furthermore, labor mobility across regions and industries acts as a powerful force for convergence.
When applied to the whole economy, the classical convergence analysis of Barro and Sala-i Martin (1992a) suggests that Japan is characterized by two distinct productivity eras. On the one hand, the 1973–1990 period is characterized by a clear pattern of labor productivity convergence across industries; on the other, the 1990–2012 period is characterized by increasing productivity dispersion and a process of industrial divergence. When applied to the two kinds of network communities, the convergence analysis suggests that in more recent years, at least, overall divergence appears to be driven by the divergence patterns of the transitional community. Interestingly, since 2007, a pattern of convergence started to appear only in the stationary community.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the methods and data. Section 3 presents some overall facts about productivity dispersion and industrial divergence in Japan. Section 4 shows the results of the convergence analysis for each network community. Finally, Section 5 offers some concluding remarks with suggestions for further research.

2. Methods and Data

2.1. Input-Output Network Analysis

In order to partition the input-output data into communities we made use of the modularity index, which is defined as:
Q = 1 4 m i j A i j P i j s i s j
where m is the number of links in the network, A i j is the adjacency matrix and s i s j takes a value of 1 if i and j belong to the same group or a value of 1 otherwise. Additionally, we define P i j = k i k j 2 m , where k i is the degree of node i. There are 2 m link ends in the network so the probability that a node j is attached to one end of these is k j 2 m , and the expected number of links between nodes i and j is given by P i j . The whole equation is divided by 4 m so that it is normalized to the interval 1 , 1 .
We can rewrite (1) as:
Q = 1 4 m s T Bs
Q is a measure of assortative mixing in the network.4 Positive values imply assortativity while negative ones indicate disassortativity. The matrix B is a real symmetric matrix called the modularity matrix and it works in optimizing the modularity index, while the vector s represents an eigenvector of B. The modularity matrix is defined as:
B i j = A i j P i j = A i j k i k j 2 m .
To obtain the maximum modularity, the vector s is utilized. This vector is set proportional to the eigenvector u 1 , which corresponds to the dominant eigenvalue of B. For this, a value of +1 is assigned to the ith elements of u 1 having a non-negative value and a value of −1 is given otherwise. These two options represent the partition in which the node related to the i-th element will be placed. This process is iterated until the modularity is no longer positive, that is, there is no more positive assortativity.

2.2. Stationary and Transitional Communities

The method by Newman (2006) detects communities only for a network at a given time. Since we are working with many years (i.e., a network per year), the members of the communities may change throughout time. In other words, they could “enter” and “exit” a given community a number of times in the period under study. Therefore we need to define what a community is for the case of an intertemporal or evolving network. Ideally, members of a given community should remain in it for the period of time that we are interested in analyzing. We will call this type of community a stationary community which we define as:
S C i = t = 0 n C i , t , with C i , t being community i in year t .
Equation (4) tells us that members that remain in the same community for every year under study, will form the stationary community. If even for a single year a member is not present, then it will not be considered a part of the stationary community and will be excluded from it. Nodes that do not belong to a stationary community are considered part of the transitional community or, in set-theoretical terms, the complement of the stationary communities. We note that the transitional community is not a community in the traditional definition, but simply a way for us to compare it with the stationary community.

2.3. Sigma and Beta Convergence Analysis

The work of Sala-i Martin (1996) highlights the importance of two classical summary measures of convergence: sigma and beta convergence. In the context of our paper, the former refers to the reduction of productivity dispersion across industries and the latter refers to the existence of catch-up effects (that is, the extent at which unproductive industries are catching up with the more productive ones). Furthermore, as shown by Furceri (2005), these two measures are closely related. To attain sigma convergence, beta convergence is a necessary condition, yet it is not a sufficient one.
More specifically, sigma convergence is commonly measured by either the standard deviation of the logarithm of the variable under study (labor productivity in the case of this paper) or by its coefficient of variation. In this paper, we use the former and define it as follows:
σ t 1 N 1 i = 1 N l o g x i , t l o g ( x t ) ¯ 2 ,
where σ t is the labor productivity dispersion across industries at time t, N is the number of industries in the sample, x i , t is the labor productivity of industry i at time t, and l o g ( x t ) ¯ is the average of the natural logarithm of industrial labor productivity at time t.
Beta convergence in its simplest form5 indicates the inverse relationship between the growth rate of a variable and its initial level. In this paper, we estimate this relationship as follows:
1 t l o g x i , t x i , 0 = α 1 e β t t l o g x i , 0 + u t ,
where the term in the right side of Equation (6) is the average annual growth rate of labor productivity in industry i, β is the speed of convergence, x i , 0 is the initial level of labor productivity, and u t is a random disturbance.

2.4. Data

For our analysis we relied on the input–output tables of the Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry (RIETI). More specifically, we use the 2015 version of the Japanese Industrial Productivity Database (JIP Database 2015). Covering Japan’s economy over the 1970–2012 period, this database contains information about 108 industries.6 However, in order to construct a balanced panel dataset, the 1973–2012 period was evaluated. The labor productivity analysis was also based on this database. In particular, the series of gross real output and the number of workers were used to compute the labor indicator used in the paper.
Recent labor productivity studies have used the total number of work-hours to compute a more intensive measure of labor productivity. Thus, one could question the use of the number of workers in the computation of labor productivity. Yet, in our database, at least, it turns out to be that work-hours and the number of workers were highly correlated. For instance, the correlation coefficient between these two indicators was 0.98 and 0.99 in 1973 and 2012 respectively. Moreover, this high correlation has been stable over the entire 1973–2012 period. Thus, from an empirical standpoint, the selection of any of these indicators may not drastically affect the robustness of the results, particularly for the time trends.7
Since the community detection algorithm of Newman (2006) worked better with undirected and unweighted networks, we constructed networks with these characteristics from the Input-Output tables for each year we study. First, we symmetrized the data in the matrices. For this, we added each matrix with its transpose and we replaced with zeros the main diagonal of the matrices we obtained.8 Finally, we replaced the positive entries in the matrices with ones and with zeros any entries that have negative values or zeros.

3. Some Stylized Facts: Productivity Dispersion and Divergence

Figure 1 and Figure 2 document both the overall increase in labor productivity and the increase in its dispersion across industries. Panel (a) of each figure measures labor productivity as the ratio of industrial value-added (in millions of yen, 2000 prices) to the number of workers; panel (b), on the other hand, is based on the ratio of industrial gross output (in millions of yen, 2000 prices) to the number of workers. The increase in labor productivity dispersion is most noticeable and systematic in Figure 2b. In this figure, labor productivity is measured as the median gross output per worker and its dispersion is computed as the inter-quartile range (IQR).
Compared to the other three figures, Figure 2b is particularly more informative for the following two reasons. First, both the median and the IQR are less sensitive to extremely large or small values (outliers). Second, compared to value-added, gross output does not contain negative values. Positive values are required for the convergence analysis since it is based on the logarithm of output.
Figure 3 shows a U-shaped pattern that summarizes the convergence-divergence dynamics of industrial labor productivity in Japan. The dotted line indicates the actual evolution of the industrial dispersion. The solid line is a polynomial regression fit. Following previous studies on sigma convergence, the dispersion was measured as the standard deviation of the logarithm of output, which in this case is gross-output per worker. Given these measures, it was clear that most of the post-war history of industrial productivity in Japan was characterized by two distinct eras. On the one hand, as the dispersion decreased in the 1973–1990 period, there was a clear process of productivity convergence. On the other hand, as the dispersion increased in the 1990–2012 period, there was also a clear process of productivity divergence, which appears to be slowing down in more recent years.
Interestingly, the timing of the U-shaped pattern of labor productivity convergence/divergence matches closely with the Japanese asset price bubble’s collapse of 1991 and its related economic stagnation of the 1990s and 2000s. Before the bubble’s collapse, Japan achieved fast economic growth that allowed it to catch up with the most advanced economies of Europe and North America. Figure 3 provides some further insights about this catch-up process. Specifically, the fast economic growth of Japan appears to be associated with a reduction of labor productivity gaps across industries. After the bubble’s collapse, however, overall economic growth in Japan stagnated. Moreover, the right-side of the U-shaped pattern of Figure 3, suggests that economic stagnation was accompanied with increasing productivity gaps across industries.
Consistent with the pattern of sigma convergence-divergence, Figure 4 also highlights the two distinct productivity eras of Japan by using the beta convergence approach. On the one hand, in the 1973–1990 period, the least productive industries have been catching up with the more productive ones. On the other, in the 1998–2012 period, this pattern is reversed. In other words, in more recent years, the least productive industries of Japan are not being able to catch up with the more productive ones.9
As previously noted, before its asset price bubble’s collapse, Japan grew very fast and its industrial productivity gaps tended to decrease. In this context, panel (a) of Figure 4 shows that this decrease is explained in part by the faster productivity growth of the least productive industries. Among these industries,10 the ones that experienced the fastest growth rates between 1973 and 1993 were electronic data processing machines (11 percent), household electrical appliances (7 percent), and semiconductor devices and circuits (6 percent).
In contrast, after the bubble’s collapse, Japan stagnated and its industrial productivity gaps tended to increase. In this context, Panel (b) of Figure 4 shows that the this increase is explained in part by the negative productivity growth of the least productive industries. Among these industries, the ones that experienced the largest negative growth rates are waste disposal services (−3.1 percent), private and non-profit education services (−2.6 percent), and private and non-profit hygiene services (−2.4 percent).

4. Results and Discussion

We first partition the network formed from the input-output data and get a community that is made of 44 out of 108 industries. The result of this partition can be seen in Table A1 of Appendix A. The formation of this group of industries can be explained because its members have strong connections among themselves, while having weaker connections with the rest of the economy. This is the idea of a community. This stationary community turns out to be composed by a large number of service-related industries.11 Among them, finance and real estate (construction, finance, insurance, and so forth), transportation and related services (railway, road transportation; and the like) and health and welfare-related services (medical, hygiene, education). Since the remaining sectors of the economy were not present in the stationary community, we gathered them in the transitional community. These are shown in Table A2 of Appendix A. These results are similar to those proposed by the Melitz model (Melitz 2003): the tradable goods sector tends to be more productive while the non-tradable one tends to be less productive.12
Figure 5 shows the structural differences of the two communities through the lens of both a standard centrality-and-dispersion analysis and the sigma convergence analysis. First, panel (a) and (b) present a simple analysis of centrality and dispersion similar to that of Figure 2. In terms of relative performance, the median labor productivity of the transitional community (panel b) has increased at a faster pace and, as a result, it ended up at a higher productivity level by the year 2012. These two panels also highlight the evolution of the productivity gaps within each community. Here again, the transitional community is particularly more interesting because the productivity gaps across industries (as measured by the interquartile range IQR) have drastically increased since the mid-1990s.
Panels (c) and (d) present the results of the partition through the lens of the sigma convergence approach. Both communities show a clear pattern of initial convergence (the dispersion decreases) followed by a period of divergence (the dispersion increases). The process of divergence in the transitional community (panel d), however, started earlier and appears to continue, although at a slower pace, in more recent years. In contrast, the stationary community appears to be starting a new wave of convergence since the year 2007.
Figure 6 shows the structural differences of the two communities through the lens of the beta convergence analysis. Similar to the sigma convergence results, both communities show a period of significant convergence followed by a period of lack of convergence. Furthermore, in the 1973–1993 period (panels a and c), the speed of beta convergence across industries in the stationary community is faster compared to that in the transitional community. In the 1993–2012 period, however, the slope of the regression lines (and the beta convergence coefficient) is not statistically different from zero in both communities.
By focusing on the 1998–2012 sub-period, however, panels (b) and (d) of Figure 6 highlight an emerging difference between the two communities. If the slopes of the regression lines were to become statistically significant as new years are added to the analysis, then we could expect a significant pattern of beta convergence in the stationary community and a divergence pattern in the transitional community. These two processes, in turn, would reinforce the previously identified patterns of Figure 5, in which a new process of convergence may be appearing in the stationary community and a process of divergence may be continuing in the transitional community.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we use input–output tables of Japan and analyze the productivity behavior of different community networks at the industry level. For this purpose, we implement the community detection algorithm of Newman (2006). Results from this analysis suggest the existence of two input-output network communities: a densely-connected group of industries (a stationary community), whose members remain in it throughout the period; and a group of industries (a transitional community) whose members do not belong to this first group. In terms of composition, the stationary community appears to be largely composed by service-related industries. Among them, finance and real estate, transportation and related services and health and welfare-related services.
Given these two kinds of network communities, we next evaluate to what extent the productivity of the members is converging. Results suggest that in more recent years, at least, industrial productivity divergence appears to be driven by the divergence patterns of the transitional community. Interestingly, since 2007, a pattern of convergence started to appear only in the stationary community. We also observe that productivity divergence and instability in community membership are not necessarily indicative of low economic performance. On average, divergent (and transitional) industries turn out to have a higher productivity level than their stationary counterparts. This finding could suggest that the members of the transitional community are diverging (or escaping) from a low-productivity equilibrium, while the members of the stationary community are converging towards one.
In the context of these findings, we could suggest at least two promising directions for further research. First, one could apply alternative community detection algorithms such as the Degree-corrected Stochastic Block Model (Karrer and Newman 2011) and the Louvain Method (Blondel et al. 2008). Second, the convergence analysis could be based on frameworks that emphasize both technological heterogeneity and transitional modeling. Among them, the work of Phillips and Sul (2007a) and Phillips and Sul (2007b) may prove useful. By extending this kind of research in any of these directions, one could test whether these alternative techniques produce relatively similar or contrasting results.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, A.D. and C.M.; formal analysis, A.D. and C.M.; investigation, A.D. and C.M.; writing—original draft, A.D. and C.M.; writing—review and editing, A.D. and C.M.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Industries in the stationary community.
Table A1. Industries in the stationary community.
JIP 2015
No.Industry No.Industry Name
11Rice, wheat production
22Miscellaneous crop farming
34Agricultural services
45Forestry
511Miscellaneous foods and related products
613Beverages
715Textile products
818Pulp, paper, and coated and glazed paper
919Paper products
1021Leather and leather products
1122Rubber products
1227Chemical fibers
1328Miscellaneous chemical products
1430Petroleum products
1535Miscellaneous ceramic, stone and clay products
1641Miscellaneous fabricated metal products
1757Precision machinery and equipment
1858Plastic products
1959Miscellaneous manufacturing industries
2060Construction
2162Electricity
2264Waterworks
2367Wholesale
2468Retail
2569Finance
2670Insurance
2771Real estate
2872Housing
2973Railway
3074Road transportation
3175Water transportation
3277Other transportation and packing
3386Rental of office equipment and goods
3487Automobile maintenance services
3588Other services for businesses
3689Entertainment
3798Education (public)
38100Medical (public)
39101Hygiene (public)
40102Social insurance and social welfare (public)
41104Medical (non-profit)
42105Social insurance and social welfare (non-profit)
43107Others (non-profit)
44108Activities not elsewhere classified
Table A2. Industries in the transitional community.
Table A2. Industries in the transitional community.
JIP 2015
No.Industry No.Industry Name
13Livestock and sericulture farming
26Fisheries
37Mining
48Livestock products
59Seafood products
610Flour and grain mill products
712Prepared animal foods and organic fertilizers
814Tobacco
916Lumber and wood products
1017Furniture and fixtures
1120Printing, plate making for printing and bookbinding
1223Chemical fertilizers
1324Basic inorganic chemicals
1425Basic organic chemicals
1526Organic chemicals
1629Pharmaceutical products
1731Coal products
1832Glass and its products
1933Cement and its products
2034Pottery
2136Pig iron and crude steel
2237Miscellaneous iron and steel
2338Smelting and refining of non-ferrous metals
2439Non-ferrous metal products
2540Fabricated constructional and architectural metal products
2642General industry machinery
2743Special industry machinery
2844Miscellaneous machinery
2945Office and service industry machines
3046Electrical generating, transmission, distribution and industrial apparatus
3147Household electric appliances
3248Electronic data processing machines, digital and analog computer equipment and accessories
3349Communication equipment
3450Electronic equipment and electric measuring instruments
3551Semiconductor devices and integrated circuits
3652Electronic parts
3753Miscellaneous electrical machinery equipment
3854Motor vehicles
3955Motor vehicle parts and accessories
4056Other transportation equipment
4161Civil engineering
4263Gas, heat supply
4365Water supply for industrial use
4466Waste disposal
4576Air transportation
4678Telegraph and telephone
4779Mail
4880Education (private and non-profit)
4981Research (private)
5082Medical (private)
5183Hygiene (private and non-profit)
5284Other public services
5385Advertising
5490Broadcasting
5591Information services and internet-based services
5692Publishing
5793Video picture, sound information, character information production and distribution
5894Eating and drinking places
5995Accommodation
6096Laundry, beauty and bath services
6197Other services for individuals
6299Research (public)
63103Public administration
64106Research (non-profit)

References

  1. Abreu, Maria, Henri L. F. De Groot, and Raymond J. G. M. Florax. 2005. A meta-analysis of β-convergence: The legendary 2%. Journal of Economic Surveys 19: 389–420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Acemoglu, Daron, Ufuk Akcigit, and William Kerr. 2016. Networks and the macroeconomy: An empirical exploration. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 30: 273–335. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Acemoglu, Daron, Vasco M. Carvalho, Asuman Ozdaglar, and Alireza Tahbaz-Salehi. 2012. The network origins of aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 80: 1977–2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i Martin. 1992a. Convergence. Journal of Political Economy 100: 223–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Barro, Robert T., and Xavier Sala-i Martin. 1992b. Regional growth and migration: A Japan-United States comparison. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 6: 312–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Baumol, William J. 1986. Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: What the long-run data show. The American Economic Review 76: 1072–85. [Google Scholar]
  7. Bernard, Andrew B., and Charles I. Jones. 1996. Comparing apples to oranges: Productivity convergence and measurement across industries and countries. The American Economic Review 86: 1216–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Blondel, Vincent D., Jean-Loup Guillaume, Renaud Lambiotte, and Etienne Lefebvre. 2008. Fast unfolding of communities in large networks. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment 2008: P10008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Carvalho, Vasco M. 2014. From micro to macro via production networks. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28: 23–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Cerina, Federica, Zhen Zhu, Alessandro Chessa, and Massimo Riccaboni. 2015. World input-output network. PLoS ONE 10: e0134025. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Del Río-Chanona, Rita María, Jelena Grujić, and Henrik Jeldtoft Jensen. 2017. Trends of the world input and output network of global trade. PLoS ONE 12: e0170817. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Fortunato, Santo. 2010. Community detection in graphs. Physics Reports 486: 75–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Fortunato, Santo, and Darko Hric. 2016. Community detection in networks: A user guide. Physics Reports 659: 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Furceri, Davide. 2005. β and σ-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality. Economics Letters 89: 212–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Girvan, Michelle, and Mark E. J. Newman. 2002. Community structure in social and biological networks. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA 99: 7821–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Islam, Nazrul. 2003. What have we learnt from the convergence debate? Journal of Economic Surveys 17: 309–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Kagawa, Shigemi, Shunsuke Okamoto, Sangwon Suh, Yasushi Kondo, and Keisuke Nansai. 2013. Finding environmentally important industry clusters: Multiway cut approach using nonnegative matrix factorization. Social Networks 35: 423–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Karrer, Brian, and Mark E. J. Newman. 2011. Stochastic blockmodels and community structure in networks. Physical Review E 83: 016107. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  19. Leontief, Wassily. 1944. Output, employment, consumption, and investment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 58: 290–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Melitz, Marc J. 2003. The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71: 1695–725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Newman, Mark E. J. 2006. Finding community structure in networks using the eigenvectors of matrices. Physical Review E 74: 036104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  22. Newman, Mark E. J., and Michelle Girvan. 2004. Finding and evaluating community structure in networks. Physical Review E 69: 026113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Phillips, Peter C. B., and Donggyu Sul. 2007a. Some empirics on economic growth under heterogeneous technology. Journal of Macroeconomics 29: 455–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Phillips, Peter C. B., and Donggyu Sul. 2007b. Transition modeling and econometric convergence tests. Econometrica 75: 1771–855. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 1996. The classical approach to convergence analysis. The Economic Journal 106: 1019–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Solow, Robert M. 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Zhu, Zhen, Federica Cerina, Alessandro Chessa, Guido Caldarelli, and Massimo Riccaboni. 2014. The rise of china in the international trade network: A community core detection approach. PLoS ONE 9: e105496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1.
Directed networks can have a node connect to another without the latter necessarily connecting to the first. Weighted networks are those with weights in their links, which allows for asymmetric relationships.
2.
We acknowledge and thank the insightful comments of an anonymous referee who helped improving this section.
3.
See the work of Abreu et al. (2005) and Islam (2003) for some comprehensive reviews of this literature.
4.
Assortativity refers to the tendency of nodes in a network to connect with others with similar characteristics while dissasortativity implies the opposite case.
5.
The simplest form of beta convergence, also known as absolute beta convergence, is commonly used for the study of production units that share common technological and institutional environments.
6.
For the labor productivity convergence analysis, however, 107 industries are considered. This is because there is no systematic data on the number of workers for the Housing industry (JIP code 72).
7.
From a conceptual standpoint, however, using the number of work-hours allows for a more precise definition of labor productivity.
8.
We do not take into account self-loops in the networks since communities are defined considering only linkages between different nodes.
9.
There is an important statistical difference when comparing the regression lines of Figure 4. In panel (a) the relationship is statistically significant, whereas in panel (b) it is not. Indeed, when we estimate a linear relationship for the 1990–2012 period the regression line is actually flat.
10.
Based on panel (a) of Figure 4, relatively low productivity industries are those whose labor productivity was less than 6 in log terms. Although this threshold is arbitrary, its selection is just for illustration purposes.
11.
As we noted in the introduction, community detection algorithms sometimes produce communities with some overlap. In our case this means that there may be some industries from the non-service sector present too. Ways to solve this type of issues are actively being researched in the field.
12.
We tested and compared these results with the Louvain algorithm (Blondel et al. 2008) as a robustness check. The resulting communities obtained mostly coincide with those from the Newman (2006) algorithm we used.
Figure 1. Mean labor productivity and dispersion (standard deviation).
Figure 1. Mean labor productivity and dispersion (standard deviation).
Economies 07 00052 g001
Figure 2. Median labor productivity and dispersion (inter-quartile range).
Figure 2. Median labor productivity and dispersion (inter-quartile range).
Economies 07 00052 g002
Figure 3. Sigma convergence and divergence.
Figure 3. Sigma convergence and divergence.
Economies 07 00052 g003
Figure 4. Beta convergence and divergence.
Figure 4. Beta convergence and divergence.
Economies 07 00052 g004
Figure 5. Sigma convergence approach: stationary and transitional communities.
Figure 5. Sigma convergence approach: stationary and transitional communities.
Economies 07 00052 g005
Figure 6. Beta convergence approach: stationary and transitional communities.
Figure 6. Beta convergence approach: stationary and transitional communities.
Economies 07 00052 g006

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Domínguez, A.; Mendez, C. Industrial Productivity Divergence and Input-Output Network Structures: Evidence from Japan 1973–2012. Economies 2019, 7, 52. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7020052

AMA Style

Domínguez A, Mendez C. Industrial Productivity Divergence and Input-Output Network Structures: Evidence from Japan 1973–2012. Economies. 2019; 7(2):52. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7020052

Chicago/Turabian Style

Domínguez, Alvaro, and Carlos Mendez. 2019. "Industrial Productivity Divergence and Input-Output Network Structures: Evidence from Japan 1973–2012" Economies 7, no. 2: 52. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7020052

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop