Next Article in Journal
Market Efficiency and News Dynamics: Evidence from International Equity Markets
Previous Article in Journal
Asymmetry in Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Consumer Prices: New Perspective from Sub-Saharan African Countries
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Effect of Aid for Trade Policy and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility: Does Institutional and Governance Quality Matter?

by
Sena Kimm Gnangnon
Development Division, World Trade Organization, CH-1211 Geneva, Switzerland
Economies 2019, 7(1), 6; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7010006
Submission received: 31 October 2018 / Revised: 4 January 2019 / Accepted: 9 January 2019 / Published: 14 January 2019

Abstract

:
This article investigates empirically the effect of aid for trade policies and regulations on the volatility of tariffs in the recipient countries. The analysis has used an unbalanced panel dataset of 107 countries over the period from 2002 to 2015. The empirical results, based on the two-step system Generalized Methods of Moments (GMM) approach, show that aid for trade policies and regulations influences negatively and significantly tariff policy volatility in recipient countries. Additionally, the findings indicate that the better the institutional and governance quality in recipient countries, the higher is the reducing effect of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility. These results, therefore, suggest that a scale up of aid for trade policies and regulations to, inter alia, build the capacity of policymakers in recipient countries to contribute to reducing tariffs volatility in these countries, which would, in turn, likely benefit donor countries. Furthermore, improving domestic institutions and governance in recipient countries would further enhance the reducing impact of this aid on tariff volatility, which, once again, benefits both the recipient countries and donor countries.
JEL Classification:
F14; F35

1. Introduction

The launch of the Aid for Trade (AfT) Initiative by the Members of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2005 at the WTO’s Hong Kong Ministerial Conference has triggered a growing interest of the international trade and development communities in the effectiveness of this initiative. It is worth recalling that, according to Paragraph 57 of the WTO’s Hong Kong Ministerial Declaration (see WTO document WT/MIN(05)/DEC—(WTO 2005)), the objective of the AfT Initiative is to “help developing countries, particularly Least developed countries (LDCs), to build the supply-side capacity and trade-related infrastructure that they need to assist them to implement and benefit from WTO Agreements and more broadly to expand their trade.” The Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) has classified AfT into three categories. These include AfT related to economic infrastructure, which encompasses transport and storage, communications, and energy generation and supply. AfT dedicated to building productive capacity, which includes banking and financial services, business and other services, agriculture, forestry, fishing, industry, mineral resources, mining, and tourism. AfT is related to trade policy and regulations, which is comprised of trade policy, regulations, and trade-related adjustment interventions.
Many studies by scholars and researchers have investigated empirically the effectiveness of the AfT, including with respect to recipient countries’ export volumes, export upgrading, and export revenue volatility (see for example OECD/WTO, 2017 for a literature review on the impact of AfT on export performance, (Gnangnon 2018a; Gnangnon and Roberts 2017; Wang and Xu 2018). In a recent study, Gnangnon (2018b) has investigated the impact of AfT flows on domestic trade policies of recipient countries and reported evidence that AfT interventions are conducive to trade policy liberalization. However, so far, little attention has been paid to the effect of AfT on trade policy volatility. The importance of this issue rests on the fact that trade policy volatility, and, particularly, tariff policy volatility makes the business environment less transparent and unpredictable. It increases uncertainty surrounding the trade policy stance and induces higher business and investment costs for businesses and investors. Consumers and producers also suffer from trade policy volatility such as tariff policy volatility, due inter alia, to its eventual effect on domestic prices.
The current article aims to contribute to the literature on the AfT effectiveness by exploring the impact of AfT related to trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility in AfT-recipient countries. It further investigates whether this effect (if any at all) depends on the AfT recipient countries’ quality of institutions and governance. Assessing the impact of AfT related to trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility is all the more relevant that tariff policy uncertainty could have large effects on trade flows and other outcomes (Ashraf et al. 2009; Handley 2014; Handley and Limão 2015; Pierce and Schott 2015).
The literature on the macroeconomic determinants of trade policy volatility is very scant1. One of the rare studies on this issue is Cadot et al. (2008), who have examined the extent to which regional trade agreements (RTAs) influence agricultural trade policy volatility. Their findings suggest that RTAs have exerted a reducing effect on agricultural trade policy volatility. Furthermore, these authors have reported evidence that the WTO’s agricultural agreement has also contributed to lowering agricultural trade policy volatility. In the current study, we postulate that aid for trade policies and regulations would help improve policymakers’ understandings of WTO Agreements and Decisions, and allow them to devise appropriate national trade strategies that would help both promote their trade, and, in particular, exports of goods and services, but also comply with their international obligations vis-à-vis the WTO. In this context, higher aid for trade policies and regulations would lead policymakers in recipient countries to devise trade policies that would result in lower tariffs volatility with a view to ensure a predictable and transparent business environment for businesses involved in international trade activities. Incidentally, since good institutional and governance quality would contribute toward improving the business environment and promoting trade (Ades and Di Tella 1999; Treisman 2000; Faruq 2011; Iqbal and Daly 2014), we expect this reducing effect of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility to be further enhanced in the context of good quality of domestic institutional and governance.
The empirical analysis has been performed on a sample of 107 AfT recipient countries, over the period from 2002 to 2015. Results, based on the two-step system Generalized Methods of Moments (GMM) approach, show that aid for trade policies and regulations are associated with lower tariff policy volatility. Additionally, when this reducing effect is higher, the recipient countries’ institutional and governance quality is better.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses how aid for trade policies and regulations could influence tariff policy volatility. Section 3 presents the model specification that helps address the issue at hand. Section 4 provides some preliminary data analysis. Section 5 presents the econometric methodology to estimate the model, while Section 6 discusses the empirical results. Section 7 deepens the analysis by investigating whether the effect of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility depends on recipient countries’ level of institutional and governance quality. Section 8 concludes the paper.

2. Discussion on the Impact of Aid for Trade Policies and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility

AfT related to trade policies and regulations aims to improve institutional capacity in recipient countries. According to Urpelainen (2009), institutional capacity entails customs operations, compliance with environmental and health regulations in the export markets, implementation of international trade agreements, and competition policy. Thus, AfT for trade policies and regulations aims, inter alia, to help policymakers of recipient countries to better understand and comply with WTO Agreements and Decisions. This would, therefore, allow policymakers to be well equipped to design the trade policies that would help them both comply with WTO Agreements including their commitments at the WTO, while concurrently implementing the national export development strategies that would help their countries better integrate into the multilateral trading system. In this regard, AfT related to trade policies and regulations could be instrumental in helping countries to stabilize their trade policy stance so as to ensure a predictable and transparent domestic trading environment. Against this background, we would expect AfT for trade policies and regulations to induce lower tariff policy volatility and, hence, contribute to promoting a relatively stable tariff policy for businesses and investors. Aid for trade related to trade policies and regulations would be associated with lower tariff policy volatility. This is consistent with the argument of Urpelainen (2009) that building (trade-related) institutional capacity in recipient countries reduces the probability that recipient countries fail to implement liberal trade policies. At the same time, Urpelainen (2009) has cautioned that, even though trade-related institutional capacity building (through AfT related to trade policies and regulations) could increase the pay-off to trade liberalization, it could also increase the pay-off to trade protectionist policies. To illustrate this, he has argued that, while training competent bureaucrats facilitates the removal of quality non-tariff barriers to trade, such as discriminatory health standards, it also allows sophisticated legal strategies of discrimination that help the government cater to organized special interests. In the later scenario, aid for trade policies and regulations would not be associated with a lower tariff policy volatility, and may possibly result in higher tariffs volatility since the government would wish to accommodate domestic lobbies’ interests.

3. Model Specification

As noted above, to the best of our knowledge, apart from Cadot et al. (2008) who have focused on the effect of RTAs on agricultural trade policy volatility (and not on the overall tariff policy volatility), no other study has examined the macroeconomic determinants of tariff policy volatility. To explore empirically the effect of aid for trade policies and regulation on tariff policy volatility, we draw on some insights from Cadot et al. (2008) and postulate the following Model (1).
Log ( VOLTARIFF ) i t = β 0 + β 1 Log ( VOLTARIFF ) i t 1 + β 2 Log ( AfTPOL ) i t + β 3 TBGDP i t + β 4 L o g ( G D P C ) i t + β 5 Log ( GROWTHVOL ) i t + β 6 Log ( REERVOL ) i t + β 7 INST i t + μ i + ε i t
where i represents the index of a recipient country of aid for trade policies and regulations and t denotes the time period. Model (1) is estimated using an unbalanced panel dataset comprising 107 recipient countries over the period from 2002 to 2015. β 0 to β 7 are parameters to be estimated. μ i t are countries’ fixed effects. ε i t is a well-behaving error term.
The variable “VOLTARIFF” is the measure of tariffs volatility. It has been calculated over the period from 2002 to 2015 using the method discussed in Chowdhury (1993), and recently employed, inter alia, in Chowdhury (2015). According to this method, the volatility of the tariff is calculated as the moving sample standard deviation of the growth rate of tariffs. The formula used (see Chowdhury 1993, 2015) is shown below.
V t = [ ( 1 k ) ( L o g Q t i 1 L o g Q t i 2 ) 2 ] 1 / 2
where k is the order of the moving average. This generates a time varying measure of the tariffs volatility. In light of the short-term nature of the time series of our panel dataset (2002–2015), we use k = 2 to compute the tariff volatility variable. The tariff data used, in this case, is for each country and for every year including the weighted mean of the applied tariff rate to all products (in percentage). Data on tariffs is extracted from the World Development Indicators (WDI) of the World Bank. The one-year lag of the variable “VOLTARIFF” has been introduced in Model (1) to capture the eventual persistence over time of tariffs’ volatility.
The variable “AfTPOL” is the key variable of interest, and represents the gross disbursements of aid for trade policies and regulations. It has been primarily measured by the real values of the gross disbursements of aid for trade policies and regulations, i.e., the gross disbursements of aid for trade policies and regulations, in constant 2014 US Dollars. This variable is denoted “AfTPOLCST”. For a robustness check, we have also used the ratio of the gross disbursements of aid for trade policies and regulations (in current US Dollar) to recipient country’s GDP (in current US Dollar). This variable is denoted “AfTPOLGDP”. Data on the gross disbursements of aid for trade policies and regulations, in both 2014 constant US Dollars, and current US Dollars is collected from the OECD/DAC-CRS (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development/Donor Assistance Committee)-Credit Reporting System (CRS). Data on GDP (current US Dollar) is extracted from the WDI.
The variables “GROWTHVOL” and “REERVOL” represent, respectively, the volatility of the economic growth rate, and the volatility of the real effective exchange rate. They have been computed using Formula (2): the volatility of the economic growth rate has been calculated as the moving sample standard deviation of the economic growth rate. The volatility of the real effective exchange rate has been calculated as the moving sample standard deviation of the growth rate of the real effective exchange rate. Data on economic growth rates (constant 2010 US$) comes from the WDI, while data on the real effective exchange rate (index base 2005) comes from the database of the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). The inclusion of the variable capturing the economic growth volatility aims to account for the effect of macroeconomic shocks on tariffs policy volatility. Higher economic growth volatility and higher volatility of the real effective exchange could reflect shocks that are affecting the economy and, consequently, incentivize governments to use trade policies, including tariffs to address the adverse economic consequences of these shocks. In this regard, significant changes in tariffs in order to promote and stabilize the economic growth rate would lead to higher tariffs’ volatility. In these circumstances, higher volatility in economic growth, and higher real effective exchange rate volatility would result in higher tariff policy volatility.
The variable “TBGDP” represents a country’s level of trade balance (% GDP), measured as the difference between exports of goods and services and imports of goods and services, as a share of GDP. Data on this variable has been collected from the WDI. Countries with higher trade deficits would be inclined to frequently use tariffs to address these deficits vis-à-vis their trading partners. This could result in higher tariffs volatility. As a result, higher trade deficits might be associated with higher tariff policy volatility (that is, higher trade surpluses would be associated with lower tariffs volatility). Note that we have not applied the natural logarithm to the variable “TBGDP” because it contains negative values.
The variable “GDPC” stands for the real per capita income (constant 2010 US$) of an AfT-recipient country. Extracted from the WDI, it has been included in Model (1) to control for countries’ development levels.
Lastly, the variable “INST” represents the institutional and governance quality. It has been calculated by relying on the factor analysis (notably the Principal Component Analysis, PCA) and, hence, using the first principal components of six indicators of governance (e.g., Globerman and Shapiro 2002; Buchanan et al. 2012; Gnangnon 2018b). These indicators include the voice and accountability, the political stability and absence of violence/terrorism, the regulatory quality, the rule of law, the government effectiveness, and corruption. The first principal component accounts for as much of the variability in the data as possible, and each succeeding component accounts for as much of the remaining variability as possible. Thus, the PCA technique generates linear combinations of object measures (called eigenvectors), which show the greatest statistical variance over all of the objects under consideration. The values of the “INST” indicator ranged between −4.267 and 3.080, with higher values reflecting better institutional and governance quality. For instance, for the variable “TBGDP”, we have not applied the natural logarithm to the variable “INST” because it contains negative values. Data on the six indicators used to compute the index “INST” comes from the Worldwide Governance Indicators2 (see Kaufmann et al. 2010).
Let us now discuss the effect of institutional and governance quality on tariff policy volatility. Institutions are the humanly devised constraints that structure political, economic, and social interactions (North 1990). Thus, they can contribute to shaping the incentive structure in the society that may increase or hamper economic activities. Additionally, they could help reduce uncertainties that arise from incomplete information concerning the behavior of other individuals in the process of interaction, and, therefore, lower transaction costs and improve the business environment. Faruq (2011) has argued that widespread corruption, inefficient bureaucracy, and a high risk of expropriation of private property by the government can create uncertainty among producers and discourage them from investing and innovating over the long term. Iqbal and Daly (2014) have indicated that weak institutions divert resources from a productive sector to an unproductive sector and, hence, promote rent-seeking activities. In the same vein, Beck and Levine (2004) have argued that bad institutions increase the general costs of doing business and enhance the efficiency of resource allocation. Bernard and Jones (1996) have emphasized that good quality institutions enhance the ability of a country to adopt new technologies invented elsewhere, which may play an important role in upgrading the development process of a country. Better institutional and governance quality could also help promote trade flows (e.g., Jansen and Nordås 2004; Li and Samsell 2009; Wu et al. 2012), while trade could, in turn, increase the costs of excessive regulation and induce domestic and foreign investors to sustain pressure on governments to undertake institutional reforms (e.g., Ades and Di Tella 1999; Treisman 2000). In this context, governments would be more willing to reduce the volatility of their trade policies, including their tariffs policy in order to further enhance the predictability of the business environment generated by better institutional and governance quality. We postulate that good institutional and governance quality would help improve the business environment, promote innovation, and enhance trade flows and, consequently, lead recipient countries’ governments to devise tariff policies so as to ensure a predictable and transparent environment for businesses. In doing so, improvement in the quality of institutions and governance would contribute for reducing the uncertainty surrounding tariff policy, and, ultimately, lead to lower tariffs’ volatility. One could also argue that, even in the context of improved governance and institutional quality, countries could experience higher fluctuations of tariffs. This is because governments may be willing to address some short-term macroeconomic imbalances such as trade deficits with its trading partners. In this scenario, good institutional and governance quality would result in higher tariffs’ volatility. Overall, we expect the quality of institutions and governance to be negatively associated with tariffs’ volatility. However, we do not rule out the possibility that a better institutional and governance quality could exert a positive effect on tariffs’ volatility. Additionally, an average positive effect might hide differentiated effects (in terms of sign, statistical significant, and magnitude) across countries in the full sample.
Appendix A displays the list of countries used in the full sample, and Appendix B reports descriptive statistics on the variables used in Model (1).

4. Preliminary Data Analysis

We present in Figure 1 the average share (%) of aid for trade policies and regulations in total AfT. We observe from this figure that this share has severely fluctuated over the considered period. This average has been calculated over the 107 recipient countries of Aid for trade policies and regulations of the panel dataset from 2002 to 2015. In particular, it has significantly dropped from 4.1% in 2002 to 1.64% in 2003, and then rebounded to reach its maximum level (over the full period), i.e., 4.33% in 2007. It has then declined to 2.77% in 2008 (due possibly to the 2008 global financial crisis). Since then, it has experienced ups and downs to reach 3.97% in 2014, and 2.93% in 2015.
To have an idea on the relationship between aid for trade policies and regulations and tariffs’ volatility variables, we present, in Figure 2, the evolution of both the average of AfTPOLCST and the average of VOLTARIFF. Similarly, we display, in Figure 3, the evolution of the average of AfTPOLGDP and the average of VOLTARIFF. The averages of these variables have been calculated over the 107 recipient countries of the panel dataset.
Figure 2 and Figure 3 show that the variables AfTPOLCST and AfTPOLGDP (which have more or less displayed patterns that are to some extent similar to that of Figure 1) have evolved in opposite directions vis-à-vis tariffs volatility. Specifically, in these two figures, tariffs volatility has slightly fluctuated, but it has been on a rising trend. In Figure 2, after a sudden drop from $7.56 million USD in 2002 to $3.61 million USD in 2003, AfTPOLCST has also experienced ups and downs, but it has been on average on a rising trend. However, it has declined from $5.33 million USD in 2014 to $4.98 million USD in 2015. AfTPOLGDP has exhibited a similar pattern to the one in Figure 1. In particular, it represented 0.01767% in 2002, 0.0084% in 2003, and 0.0455% in 2007, which is its highest level over the entire period. It has then suddenly declined to 0.016% in 2008, and then moved up to reach 0.038% in 2011. Since then, it has been on a declining trend to reach 0.0257% in 2015.

5. Econometric Strategy

We first estimate a static version of model (1) (i.e., Model (1) without the one-year lag of the dependent variable as a right-hand side variable) where the variables “AfTPOL” and “TBGDP” have been considered with a one-year lag to mitigate the endogeneity concerns related to the reverse causality issue. While aid for trade policies and regulations could influence tariff policy volatility, it is also possible that the degree of tariff policy volatility in a given recipient country influences the amounts of the aid for trade policies and regulations that the country would obtain from donors. Likewise, while the level of trade balance (trade deficit versus trade surplus levels) would influence tariff policy volatility, we could also expect higher tariff policy volatility to affect trade flows, and, hence, the levels of trade balance. Incidentally, the use of the factor analysis helps severely mitigate the endogeneity concern associated with the eventual reverse causality from the dependent variable to the variable capturing the institutional and governance quality (e.g., Portugal-Perez and Wilson 2012). This endogeneity concern is further mitigated by the fact that the variable INST changes little over time. Against this background, we first estimate the static version of model (1) described above by using the within fixed effect estimator (denoted “FE-DK”) where standard errors have been corrected by means of the Driscoll and Kraay (1998) technique. This technique allows us to take into account the presence of cross-sectional dependence, autocorrelation, and heteroscedasticity in the dataset. Second, we employ the random effects estimator (henceforth denoted “RE”) where standard errors are clustered at the country level. While the fixed effects estimations rely on within-country differences (eventually at the cost of reducing efficiency due to the removal of all between-group variation in the dataset), the random effects estimations capture cross-country and within country differences. The results of the estimations of the different variants of the static specification of Model (1)—using each of the two AfTPOL variables—by means of “FE-DK” and “RE” estimators are reported in Table 1.
However, these estimators could generate biased estimates because using the one-year lag of the variables “AfTPOL” and “TBGDP” might not fully address the endogeneity problem related to the reverse causality concerning these two variables. Additionally, the model may suffer from the omission of the one-year lag of the dependent variable as a right-hand side variable. In the meantime, the estimation of the dynamic specification of Model (1)—with the one-year lag of the dependent variable as a regressor—could lead to biased estimates, which could be severe in a panel dataset with a limited time-period and a large cross-section (the so-called Nickell bias, see Nickell 1981). To address these endogeneity concerns, we employ the popular two-step system Generalized Methods of Moments (GMM) estimator to estimate Model (1) proposed by Blundell and Bond (1998). This estimator is appropriate for dynamic models in the context of panel dataset with a large cross-section (N) and limited time-period (T) like ours (T = 14, and N = 107 in the current analysis), and helps deal with the endogeneity problems induced by the bi-directional causality between regressors and the dependent variable. It entails the combination of the estimation of an equation in differences with an equation in levels where lagged first differences are used as instruments for the levels equation and lagged levels are used as instruments for the first-difference equation. The two-step system GMM estimator has also many advantages over the difference-GMM estimator developed by Arellano and Bond (1991). For example, the two-step system GMM estimator allows using additional moment conditions, which helps reduce the potential biases and imprecision associated with the difference estimator. Furthermore, this estimator helps avoid magnifying gaps when the panel dataset is unbalanced (which is an important weakness of the difference GMM estimator) (see Roodman 2009). To assess whether the two-step system GMM estimator is appropriate for estimating Model (1), we perform several standard diagnostic tests. The first test is the Arellano-Bond test of first-order serial correlation in the error term (denoted AR(1)). The second test is the Arellano-Bond test of no second-order autocorrelation in the error term (denoted AR(2)). The last test is the Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions, which determines the validity of the instruments used in the estimations. Lastly, we report the number of instruments used in the regressions because a higher number of instruments than the number of countries in the regressions may reduce the power of the previously mentioned tests, including the Sargan test (Ziliak 1997, Bowsher 2002, and Roodman 2009). The outcomes of the estimation of Model (1) by means of the two-step system GMM estimator are presented in column (1) of Table 2. The results of the estimation of Model (1) by means of the two-step system GMM estimator are reported in Table 2.

6. Interpretation of Empirical Results

Results across the four columns of Table 1 suggest that aid for trade policies and regulations (in real values or in % GDP) is positively associated with tariffs volatility. However, in the majority of the cases, the estimate is statistically significant only at the 10% level (it is statistically significant at the 1% level only in column (3), i.e., for the model specification with “AfTPOLCST,” estimated with the RE estimator). Across columns (1) and (2), the magnitudes of the effect of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility are quite similar. Concerning control variables, we note that improvements in the trade balance induce lower tariffs’ volatility only in columns (3) and (4)). In the other columns, the estimates are not statistically significant at the 10% level. For all other variables, we find no significant effect (at the 10% level) on tariffs’ volatility.
Turning to the results provided in Table 2, we observe across the two columns of this table that the coefficient of the one-year lag of the dependent variable is always positive and statistically significant, which confirms the persistence of tariff policy volatility over time. Additionally, at the bottom of these columns, we find that the p-values associated with the AR(1) test are always 0, i.e., lower than 0.01 (the 1% level of statistical significance), while the p-values relating to the AR(2) test are higher than 0.10 (i.e., the 10% level of statistical significance). The p-values associated with the Sargan test are always higher than 0.10, and the number of countries is consistently higher than the number of instruments across the two columns of this table. Taken together, these outcomes suggest that the previously mentioned diagnostic tests to check the validity of the two-step system GMM estimator are fully satisfactory. We, therefore, conclude that the two-step system GMM estimator is very appropriate to perform the empirical analysis.
Let us now consider the estimates presented in Table 2. Results in columns (1) and (2) indicate that both real values of aid for trade policies and regulations and aid for trade policies and regulations (% GDP) exert a negative and significant (at the 1% level) effect on tariff volatility. Interestingly, the magnitudes of these two effects are quite similar. Specifically, a 1 dollar increase in aid for trade policies and regulations is associated with a 0.165 percentage decline in tariffs volatility. Likewise, a 1 percentage increase in aid for trade policies and regulations (% GDP) induces a 0.15 percentage decline in tariff volatility.
Concerning control variables, we obtain similar results across the two columns, except for the variable “GROWTHVOL” and “GDPC.” An improvement in trade balance influences negatively and significantly tariffs volatility in recipient countries of aid for trade policies and regulations. Higher volatility of the real effective exchange rate results in lower tariffs volatility, which could reflect the fact that, in the context of severe fluctuations of real effective exchange rate that could adversely affect trading firms, governments tend to mitigate these adverse effects by making tariffs less volatile. Economic growth volatility influences negatively and significantly tariffs’ volatility in column (2), but exerts no significant effect (at least at the 10% level) on tariffs’ volatility in column (1). The argument developed above to explain the negative effect of the volatility of the real effective exchange rate on tariffs’ volatility also applies in this case to explain the possible rationale for the negative effect of growth volatility on tariffs’ volatility. We also obtain that good institutional and governance quality is positively and significantly (at the 1% level) associated with tariffs’ volatility in recipient countries of aid for trade policies and regulations. This result concerning the institutional and governance quality tends to confirm our hypothesis that, even in the context of improvement of the institutional and governance quality, policymakers may regularly change their tariffs (which would lead to higher tariffs’ volatility) in order to address, for example, some macroeconomic imbalances such as higher trade deficits through certain trading partners. Nonetheless, it is worth underlining that this positive effect of institutional and governance quality on tariff volatility represents an average effect across all AfT recipient countries considered in the analysis, and may, therefore, hide different effects (including in terms of magnitude, sign, and statistical significance) across countries in the full sample.
Before turning to the next section, it is worth emphasizing that we have included time dummies in the various specifications of Model (1), including the two aiding trade policies and regulation variables. However, we find no significant effects of these time dummies on the tariff volatility variable. Additionally, the inclusion of these dummies in the model specification does not alter significantly the effects of the AfT variables on the tariff policy volatility. Similar findings are also obtained when we replace the time dummies with a dummy variable aiming to capture the 2007 to 2009 financial crisis.
We further examine whether the effect of each of the two pieces of aid for trade policies and regulations variables on tariff policy volatility varies across sub-groups of countries, and more generally for varying countries’ development levels. To do so, we first consider whether the effect of each of the two pieces of aid for trade policies and regulations variables on tariffs volatility in LDCs (qualified by the United Nations as the poorest and most vulnerable countries in the world—see for more information, see online at: http://unohrlls.org/about-ldcs/) is different from that of non-LDCs. In that respect, a dummy variable (denoted “LDC”) is created, which takes the value 1 for countries qualified as LDCs and 0, otherwise. This dummy variable is subsequently introduced in the specifications of Model (1), along with its interaction with each of the Aid for Trade policies and regulations variables. The results of the estimations of these model specifications are reported in columns (1) and (2) of Table 3. Furthermore, as noted above, we push the analysis further by examining, more generally, the extent to which the effect of the Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility depends on countries’ development levels, which is proxied by their real per capita income. To do so, we include in Model (1) the interaction between the Aid for Trade policies and regulations variable and the real per capita income. The results of the estimation are presented in columns (3) and (4) of Table 3.
Additionally, the puzzling positive effect of the institutional and governance variable on tariffs’ volatility prompts us to examine whether this effect varies across countries, which is for various countries’ development levels. To check these, we introduce in the specifications of Model (1) (that is, with each of the Aid for Trade policies and regulations variables) the interaction between the institutional and governance quality variable and the real per capita income variable. The outcome of the estimation of this model specification using the two-step system GMM estimator is presented in columns (5) and (6) of Table 3.
The results in column (1) suggest that the coefficient related to the interaction variable [LDC × (Log(AfTPOLCST))] is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level, which indicates that real Aid for Trade policies and regulations exerts a higher positive significant effect on tariffs’ volatility in LDCs than in non-LDCs. Specifically, the net effect of the real Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility in LDCs and non-LDCs are, respectively, given by −0.002 (= −0.154 + 0.152) and −0.154. These two outcomes indicate that real Aid for Trade policies and regulations exerts a reducing effect on tariffs volatility even thoughthe magnitude is far higher for non-LDCs than for LDCs (for LDCs, the magnitude of the effect is very small). Likewise, results in column (2) of Table 3 indicate that the net effects of Aid for Trade policies and regulations (% GDP) on tariffs volatility for LDCs and Non-LDCs are given, respectively, by −0.035 (=−0.113 + 0.0776) and −0.113. Once again, these outcomes show that Aid for Trade policies and regulations (% GDP) exert a far higher reducing effect on tariffs volatility in non-LDCs than in LDCs. Turning to results in column (3), we observe that the interaction variables between the real per capita income variable and each of the Aid for Trade policies and regulation variables are negative and statistically significant at the 1% level. Thereby, this indicates that the magnitude of the reducing effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariff volatility increases as countries experience higher development levels. Thus, relatively developed AfT recipient countries tend to experience a higher reducing effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility compared to less developed recipient countries. This clearly confirms the previous finding concerning the higher reducing effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility in LDCs compared to non-LDCs. Similarly, the interaction between the institutional and governance quality variable and the real per capita income variable (see columns (5) and (6) of Table 3) exhibits negative and significant coefficients at the 1% level. This, therefore, suggests that better institutional and governance quality exerts a negative and significant effect on tariffs volatility. The magnitude of this reducing effect increases as countries further develop. In other words, relatively higher developed recipient countries tend to experience a higher reducing effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility than do less developed recipient countries.
Lastly, estimates related to control variables are broadly consistent with those presented in Table 2.

7. Further Analysis: Does the Effect of Aid for Trade Policies and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility Depend on the Institutional and Governance Quality?

The analysis has so far consisted of how Aid for Trade policies and regulations as well as institutional and governance quality could influence tariffs’ volatility. In this section, we investigate whether the effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility depends on the quality of institutions and governance prevailing in the recipient countries. In light of the theoretical discussion provided above concerning the effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations, and institutional and governance quality on tariff policy volatility, we postulate two hypotheses. To recall, on the one hand, AfT related to trade policies and regulations aims, inter alia, to help policymakers in recipient countries of Aid for Trade policies and regulations to better understand and comply with WTO Agreements and Decisions, and, ultimately, ensure the predictability and transparency of their trade policies (including tariffs policies). On the other hand, better institutional and governance quality could help improve the business environment and enhance trade flows, which could, in turn, further improve institutional and governance quality. Taken together, these two arguments suggest that better institutional and governance quality would enhance the negative effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility. At the same time, as noted above, governments of AfT recipient countries may be willing to devise tariffs’ policy that would generate higher tariffs volatility in order to address some macroeconomic imbalances such as trade deficits with their trading partners. Thus, even in the context of good institutions and governance quality, higher Aid for Trade policies and regulations might not necessarily lead to lower tariffs volatility. However, any positive effect in terms of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility could be lower (in magnitude) in countries with higher institutional and governance quality than in countries with lower institutional and governance quality. Alternatively, one could also argue that, even though AfT recipient countries’ institutions and governance are weak, higher AfT related to trade policies and regulations would reduce the magnitude of the positive effect of the low quality of governance and institutions on tariffs volatility. In this scenario, the lower the quality of governance and institutions, the lower the positive effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility would be in this case.
To investigate empirically whether the effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility depends on the level of institutional and governance quality, we estimate a variant of Model (1) in which we include (once) a variable capturing the interaction between each of the “AfTPOL” variables and the variable “INST”. This variant of Model (1) is estimated by using the two-step system GMM approach. The estimations’ results are reported in Table 4. It could be observed from the two columns of this table that, in addition to the persistence over time of the VOLTARIFF variable, all the diagnostic tests relating to the validity of the two-step system GMM approach are satisfactory. Turning now to the estimates, we are particularly interested in two coefficients, which are the coefficient associated with each of the variables “AfTPOL” (in Logs) and the interaction term related to the interaction variable “[INST] × [Log(AfTPOL)]”. In the two columns of Table 4, we obtain that the interaction term as well as the coefficient of each of “AfTPOL” variables are negative and statistically significant at the 1% level. These suggest that the total effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility is, on average, always negative and statistically significant, and the magnitude of this effect increases as countries enjoy better institutional and governance quality. We provide in Figure 4 (for results reported in column (1) of Table 4) and in Figure 5 (for results reported in column (2) of Table 4) a better picture of the effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility. Thus, Figure 4 and Figure 5 show, at the 95% confidence intervals, respectively, the evolution of the marginal impact of “AfTPOLCST” and “AfTPOLGDP” on “VOLTARIFF” for different countries’ levels of institutional and governance quality. The marginal impacts that are statistically significant at the 95% confidence intervals are those encompassing only the upper and lower bounds of the confidence interval that are either above or below the zero line. It could be noted from these two figures that the marginal impact of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariff volatility takes positive and negative values, and declines as countries enjoy better institutional and governance quality. However, this marginal impact is not always statistically significant. In Figure 4, it is statistically significant only for levels of institutional and governance quality strictly higher than the value −2.5 (it is worth recalling that, in the full sample, the values of the variable “INST” range between −4.266 and 3.079). In Figure 5, the marginal effect is statistically significant only for levels of institutional and governance quality strictly higher than the value −3.24. Hence, in Figure 4, countries whose level of institutional and governance quality is strictly lower than −2.5, experience no significant effect of real values of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility. For the other countries, the effect of the real values of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility declines as they enjoy better institutional and governance quality. In other words, for these countries, the better the institutional and governance quality, the higher the reducing effect of real Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility are. The same reasoning applies to Figure 5 (related to Aid for Trade policies and regulations, in % GDP), but with the minimum value being −3.24 for institutional and governance quality (from which the effect of the Aid for Trade policies and regulation becomes statistically significant).

8. Conclusions

This article contributes to the literature on AfT effectiveness by examining, for the first time, the effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility in recipient countries. The analysis has been carried out using an unbalanced panel dataset, which contains 107 recipient countries of Aid for Trade policies and regulations from 2002 to 2015. The findings suggest that Aid for Trade policies and regulations exerts a reducing effect on tariff policy volatility in recipient countries. This result is robust to the alternative use of real values of the gross disbursements of Aid for Trade policies and regulations and the Aid for Trade policies and regulations (% GDP). Interestingly, the analysis has shown that better institutional and governance quality enhances the reducing effect of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariff policy volatility.
These outcomes have several policy implications. First, by increasing their financial support in the form of Aid for Trade policies and regulations to build the capacity of policymakers in recipient countries, donors would contribute toward reducing the volatility of tariffs in these countries. The rise in Aid for Trade policies and regulations may even, in turn, benefit donors. This is because trading firms in the donor countries would enjoy a greater transparency and predictability of trade policies, and tariff policies in the recipient countries could result in a rise of exports from donor countries to the recipient countries. Second, the improvement of domestic institutions and governance in the recipient countries (including, eventually, with the help of donor countries) would enhance the effectiveness of this aid in reducing tariffs’ volatility, and this would, ultimately, benefit both beneficiaries and donor countries. In particular, lower tariffs volatility, thanks inter alia, to Aid for Trade policies and regulations would provide foreign and domestic investors in recipient countries with a predictable trade policy landscape, and, consequently, promote their exports, domestic investment, and foreign investments especially foreign direct investments.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Acknowledgments

This article represents the personal opinions of individual staff members and is not meant to represent the position or opinions of the WTO or its Members. The author would like to express his sincere gratitude to the anonymous Reviewers as well as the Editor for their useful comments on an earlier version this paper. Any errors or omissions are the fault of the author.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. List of countries contained in the entire sample.
Table A1. List of countries contained in the entire sample.
Entire Sample
AlbaniaCroatiaMali ***Sudan ***
AlgeriaDominicaMauritania ***Swaziland
Angola ***Dominican RepublicMauritiusTajikistan
Antigua and BarbudaEcuadorMexicoTanzania ***
ArgentinaEgypt, Arab Rep.MoldovaThailand
ArmeniaEl SalvadorMongoliaTonga
AzerbaijanFijiMoroccoTrinidad and Tobago
Bangladesh ***GabonMozambique ***Tunisia
BarbadosGambia, The ***Myanmar ***Turkey
BelarusGeorgiaNamibiaUganda ***
BelizeGhanaNepal ***Ukraine
Benin ***GrenadaNicaraguaUruguay
BoliviaGuatemalaNiger ***Vanuatu ***
Bosnia and HerzegovinaGuinea-Bissau ***NigeriaVenezuela ***
BotswanaGuyanaOmanVietnam
BrazilHaiti ***PakistanZambia ***
Burkina Faso ***HondurasPanama
Burundi ***IndiaPapua New Guinea
Cabo VerdeIndonesiaParaguay
Cambodia ***JamaicaPeru
CameroonJordanPhilippines
Central African Republic ***KazakhstanRwanda ***
Chad ***KenyaSamoa
ChileKyrgyz RepublicSaudi Arabia
ChinaLao PDR ***Senegal ***
ColombiaMacedonia, FYRSouth Africa
Congo, Dem. Rep ***Madagascar ***Sri Lanka
Congo, Rep.Malawi ***St. Kitts and Nevis
Costa RicaMalaysiaSt. Lucia
Cote d’IvoireMaldivesSt. Vincent and the Grenadines
Note: “***” denotes least developed countries (LDCs).

Appendix B

Table A2. Descriptive statistics on variables used in the analysis.
Table A2. Descriptive statistics on variables used in the analysis.
VariableObservationsMeanStandard DeviationMinimumMaximum
VOLTARIFF101720.09633.1470.0000734568.076
TBGDP1465−7.90315.088−100.97144.373
AfTPOLCST13114,237,6851.59 × 107−89.4364.20 × 108
AfTPOLGDP13040.0250.0958.97 × 10−82.725
GROWTHVOL14802.0312.5550.00128.859
REERVOL13824.8567.4980.002124.326
GDPC14814333.8084262.972205.07221,312.810
INST1482−0.8571.476−4.2663.079

References

  1. Ades, Alberto, and Raphael Di Tella. 1999. Rents, Competition and Corruption. American Economic Review 89: 982–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equations. Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Ashraf, Nava, Xavier Gine, and Dean Karlan. 2009. Findings Missing Markets (and a disturbing epilogue): Evidence from an Export Crop Adoption and Marketing Intervention in Kenya. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 91: 973–90. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Beck, Thorsten, and Ross Levine. 2004. Legal Institutions and Financial Development. NBER Working papers, 10417. Cambridge, MA, USA: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  5. Bernard, Andrews, and Charles Jones. 1996. Productivity and Convergence Across U.S. States and Industries. Empirical Economics 21: 113–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. 1998. Initial Conditions and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Bowsher, Clive G. 2002. On testing overidentifying restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Economics Letters 77: 211–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Buchanan, Bonnie G., Quan V. Le, and Meenakshi Rishi. 2012. Foreign Direct Investment and Institutional Quality: Some Empirical Evidence. International Review of Financial Analysis 21: 81–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Cadot, Olivier, Marcelo Olarreaga, and Jeanne Tschopp. 2008. Does Regionalism Reduce the Volatility of Trade Policy? Paper presented at the World Bank Conference on Political Economy of Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, Washington, DC, USA, May 23–24. [Google Scholar]
  10. Chowdhury, Abdur. 1993. Does exchange rate volatility depress trade flows? Evidence from error-correction models. The Review of Economics and Statistics 75: 700–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Chowdhury, Abdur. 2015. Terms of trade shocks and private savings in the developing countries. Journal of Comparative Economics 43: 1122–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Driscoll, John C., and Aart C. Kraay. 1998. Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation with Spatially Dependent Panel Data. Review of Economics and Statistics 80: 549–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Faruq, Hasan. 2011. How institutions affect export quality. Economic Systems 35: 586–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Globerman, Steven, and Daniel Shapiro. 2002. Global Foreign Direct Investment Flows: The Role of Governance Infrastructure. World Development 30: 1899–919. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Gnangnon, Sèna Kimm. 2018a. Impact of multilateral trade liberalization and aid for trade for productive capacity building on export revenue instability. Economic Analysis and Policy 58: 141–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Gnangnon, Sèna Kimm. 2018b. Aid for trade and trade policy in recipient countries. The International Trade Journal. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Gnangnon, Sèna Kimm, and Michael Roberts. 2017. Aid for Trade, Foreign Direct Investment and Export Upgrading in Recipient Countries. Journal of International Commerce Economics and Policy 8: 1750010. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Handley, Kyle. 2014. Exporting under trade policy uncertainty: Theory and Evidence. Journal of International Economics 94: 50–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Handley, Kyle, and Nuno Limão. 2015. Trade and Investment under Policy Uncertainty: Theory and Firm Evidence. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7: 189–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Iqbal, Nasir, and Vince Daly. 2014. Rent Seeking Opportunities and Economic Growth in Transitional Economies. Economic Modelling 37: 16–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Jansen, Marion, and Hildegunn Kyvik Nordås. 2004. Institutions, Trade Policy and Trade Flows. WTO Staff Working paper ERSD-2004-02. Geneva, Switzerland: World Trade Organization. [Google Scholar]
  22. Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi. 2010. The Worldwide Governance Indicators Methodology and Analytical Issues. World Bank Policy Research N° 5430 (WPS5430). Washington, DC: World Bank. [Google Scholar]
  23. Li, Shaomin, and Darryl P. Samsell. 2009. Why Some Countries Trade More Than Others: The Effect of the Governance Environment on Trade Flows. Corporate Governance: An International Review 17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Mansfield, Edward, and Eric Reihnardt. 2008. International Institutions and the Volatility of International Trade. International Organization 62: 621–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Nickell, Stephen. 1981. Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Effects. Econometrica 49: 1417–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  27. Pierce, Justin, and Peter Schott. 2015. The Surprisingly Swift Decline of U.S. Manufacturing Employment. NBER Working paper 18655. Cambridge, MA, USA: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
  28. Portugal-Perez, Alberto, and John S. Wilson. 2012. Export Performance and Trade Facilitation Reform: Hard and Soft Infrastructure. World Development 40: 1295–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Roodman, David. 2009. A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economic and Statistics 71: 135–58. [Google Scholar]
  30. Rose, Andrew K. 2004. Do WTO Members Have More Liberal Trade Policy? Journal of International Economics 63: 209–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Treisman, Daniel. 2000. The Causes of Corruption: A Cross National Study. Journal of Public Economics 76: 399–457. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Urpelainen, Johannes. 2009. Political-economic problems in trade capacity building. Review of International Organizations 4: 329–59. [Google Scholar]
  33. Wang, Zheng, and Meina Xu. 2018. Aid for trade and the quality of exports. Applied Economics Letters 25: 668–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. WTO (World Trade Organization). 2005. Ministerial Declaration on Doha Work Programme. Paper presented at the Sixth Session of Trade Ministers Conference, Hong Kong, China, December 13–18. [Google Scholar]
  35. Wu, Jun, Shaomin Li, and Darryl Samsell. 2012. Why some countries trade more, some trade less, some trade almost nothing: The Effect of governance environment on trade flows. International Business Review 21: 225–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Ziliak, James P. 1997. Efficient estimation with panel data when instruments are predetermined: An empirical comparison of moment-condition estimators. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 15: 419–31. [Google Scholar]
1
It is nonetheless important to note that studies such as Rose (2004) and, Mansfield and Reihnardt (2008) have looked at the impact of international institutions on the volatility of trade flows, rather than on trade policy volatility.
2
The database is available online at: http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.aspx#home.
Figure 1. Evolution of the share (%) of AfT for trade policy and regulations in total aid for trade policy and tariff volatility over the full sample. Source: Author.
Figure 1. Evolution of the share (%) of AfT for trade policy and regulations in total aid for trade policy and tariff volatility over the full sample. Source: Author.
Economies 07 00006 g001
Figure 2. Evolution of real AfT for trade policy and regulations and tariffs’ volatility over the full sample. Source: Author.
Figure 2. Evolution of real AfT for trade policy and regulations and tariffs’ volatility over the full sample. Source: Author.
Economies 07 00006 g002
Figure 3. Evolution of AfT for trade policy and regulations (% GDP) and tariffs volatility over the full sample. Source: Author.
Figure 3. Evolution of AfT for trade policy and regulations (% GDP) and tariffs volatility over the full sample. Source: Author.
Economies 07 00006 g003
Figure 4. Marginal Impact of “AfTPOLCST” on “TARIFFVOL”, for varying levels of “INST”. Source: Author.
Figure 4. Marginal Impact of “AfTPOLCST” on “TARIFFVOL”, for varying levels of “INST”. Source: Author.
Economies 07 00006 g004
Figure 5. Marginal impact of “AfTPOLGDP” on “TARIFFVOL” for varying levels of “INST”. Source: Author.
Figure 5. Marginal impact of “AfTPOLGDP” on “TARIFFVOL” for varying levels of “INST”. Source: Author.
Economies 07 00006 g005
Table 1. Impact of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility. Estimators. FE-DK and RE.
Table 1. Impact of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariffs’ volatility. Estimators. FE-DK and RE.
VARIABLESFE-DKRE
Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)
(1)(3)(2)(4)
Log(AfTPOLCST)t−10.0672 * 0.0942 ***
(0.0389) (0.0294)
Log(AfTPOLGDP)t−1 0.0688 * 0.0643 *
(0.0374) (0.0349)
TBGDPt-1−0.00966−0.00975−0.0132 **−0.0117 **
(0.00770)(0.00766)(0.00559)(0.00571)
Log(GDPC)−0.08940.07130.1070.142
(0.438)(0.379)(0.101)(0.110)
Log(GROWTHVOL)−0.00352−0.00266−0.00757−0.0105
(0.0311)(0.0307)(0.0401)(0.0398)
Log(REERVOL)0.04720.04740.02570.0288
(0.0464)(0.0462)(0.0452)(0.0449)
INST0.2240.2120.02560.000994
(0.188)(0.191)(0.0669)(0.0703)
Constant2.0862.133−0.01291.343
(3.214)(3.170)(0.978)(0.868)
Observations Countries827 - 106827 - 106827 - 106827 - 106
Within R-Squared0.01040.01050.00850.0088
Between R-Squared 0.13830.0638
Overall R-Squared 0.04560.0329
Note: * p-value < 0.1, ** p-value < 0.05, *** p-value < 0.01. Robust Standard Errors are in parenthesis. For the Random Effects (“RE”) model, standards errors have been clustered at the country-level.
Table 2. Impact of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility. Estimator. Two-step system GMM.
Table 2. Impact of aid for trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility. Estimator. Two-step system GMM.
VARIABLESLog(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)
(1)(2)
Log(VOLTARIFF)t−10.405 ***0.367 ***
(0.0109)(0.0125)
Log(AfTPOLCST)−0.110 ***
(0.0119)
Log(AfTPOLGDP) −0.150 ***
(0.0192)
TBGDP−0.0252 ***−0.0251 ***
(0.00201)(0.00219)
Log(GDPC)0.0729 *−0.122 ***
(0.0396)(0.0331)
Log(GROWTHVOL)−0.0226 **−0.00489
(0.00877)(0.0115)
Log(REERVOL)−0.0278 ***−0.0284 ***
(0.00689)(0.00965)
INST0.244 ***0.236 ***
(0.0202)(0.0277)
Constant2.391 ***1.581 ***
(0.315)(0.281)
Observations Countries759 - 106758 - 106
Number of Instruments9898
AR1 (p-Value)0.00000.0000
AR2 (p-Value)0.31830.2488
Sargan (p-Value)0.77320.3751
Note: * p-value < 0.1, ** p-value < 0.05, *** p-value < 0.01. Robust Standard Errors are in parenthesis. In the two-step system GMM estimations, the variables “AfTPOLCST,” “AfTPOLGDP,” and “TBGDP” have been considered endogenous. The other variables have been considered exogenous. In the regressions, we have used three lags of dependent variable as instruments and two lags of endogenous variables as instruments in order to limit the proliferation of instruments in this regression.
Table 3. Impact of Aid for trade policies and regulations, and institutional and governance quality on tariffs’ volatility for various countries’ development levels. Estimator. Two-Step System GMM.
Table 3. Impact of Aid for trade policies and regulations, and institutional and governance quality on tariffs’ volatility for various countries’ development levels. Estimator. Two-Step System GMM.
VARIABLESLog(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Log(VOLTARIFF)t−10.409 ***0.389 ***0.409 ***0.403 ***0.398 ***0.369 ***
(0.0107)(0.00839)(0.0130)(0.0103)(0.00978)(0.0112)
Log(AfTPOLCST)−0.154 *** 0.533 *** −0.101 ***
(0.0158) (0.101) (0.0123)
LDC × [Log(AfTPOLCST)]0.152 ***
(0.0268)
LDC−2.763 ***−0.0312
(0.404)(0.145)
Log(AfTPOLGDP) −0.113 *** 0.313 *** −0.155 ***
(0.0176) (0.0812) (0.0187)
LDC × [Log(AfTPOLGDP)] 0.0776 ***
(0.0218)
[Log(GDPC)] × [Log(AfTPOLCST)] −0.0792 ***
(0.0126)
[Log(GDPC)] × [Log(AfTPOLGDP)] −0.0542 ***
(0.00994)
[Log(GDPC)] × [INST] −0.134 ***−0.127 ***
(0.0183)(0.0263)
TBGDP−0.0214 ***−0.0200 ***−0.0266 ***−0.0225 ***−0.0193 ***−0.0207 ***
(0.00201)(0.00125)(0.00246)(0.00184)(0.00207)(0.00349)
Log(GDPC)−0.104 **−0.165 ***1.123 ***−0.410 ***−0.209 ***−0.346 ***
(0.0406)(0.0324)(0.173)(0.0856)(0.0600)(0.0636)
Log(GROWTHVOL)−0.0163 *−0.0213 ***−0.0163 **−0.0150 *−0.0270 ***−0.00531
(0.00882)(0.00751)(0.00822)(0.00787)(0.00869)(0.0110)
Log(REERVOL)−0.0409 ***−0.0376 ***−0.0310 ***−0.0379 ***−0.0394 ***−0.0423 ***
(0.0107)(0.0102)(0.00923)(0.00795)(0.00696)(0.0113)
INST0.0813 **0.188 ***0.0970 ***0.267 ***1.337 ***1.264 ***
(0.0316)(0.0339)(0.0302)(0.0364)(0.149)(0.222)
Constant4.402 ***2.186 ***−6.384 ***3.961 ***4.675 ***3.482 ***
(0.461)(0.211)(1.431)(0.695)(0.486)(0.576)
Observations of Countries759 - 106758 - 106759 - 106758 - 106759 - 106758 - 106
Number of Instruments1001001001009999
AR1 (p-Value)0.00000.00000.00000.00000.00000.0000
AR2 (p-Value)0.24560.23250.31660.29310.28590.2349
Sargan (p-Value)0.60190.52000.73100.54880.75970.4213
Note: * p-value < 0.1, ** p-value < 0.05, *** p-value < 0.01. Robust Standard Errors are in parenthesis. In the two-step system GMM estimations, the variables “AfTPOLCST,” “AfTPOLGDP,” and “TBGDP” have been considered endogenous. The other variables have been considered exogenous. In the regressions, we have used 2 lags of dependent variable as instruments and 2 lags of endogenous variables as instruments in order to limit the proliferation of instruments in this regression.
Table 4. Does the impact of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility depend on countries’ level of Institutional and Governance Quality? Estimator. Two-Step System GMM.
Table 4. Does the impact of Aid for Trade policies and regulations on tariffs volatility depend on countries’ level of Institutional and Governance Quality? Estimator. Two-Step System GMM.
VARIABLESLog(VOLTARIFF)Log(VOLTARIFF)
(1)(2)
Log(VOLTARIFF)t−10.399 ***0.363 ***
(0.0108)(0.0118)
Log(AfTPOLCST)−0.146 ***
(0.0233)
[INST] × [Log(AfTPOLCST)]−0.0450 ***
(0.0124)
Log(AfTPOLGDP) −0.200 ***
(0.0241)
[INST] × [Log(AfTPOLGDP)] −0.0498 ***
(0.00997)
TBGDP−0.0261 ***−0.0267 ***
(0.00346)(0.00194)
Log(GDPC)0.130 **−0.0278
(0.0602)(0.0255)
Log(GROWTHVOL)−0.0294 ***0.00104
(0.00880)(0.0142)
Log(REERVOL)−0.0305 ***−0.0247 ***
(0.00684)(0.00705)
INST0.767 ***−0.103
(0.140)(0.0735)
Constant2.350 ***0.495
(0.338)(0.302)
Observations Countries759 - 106758 - 106
Number of Instruments9999
AR1 (p-Value)0.00000.0000
AR2 (p-Value)0.38080.3094
Sargan (p-Value)0.66450.4029
Note: * p-value < 0.1, ** p-value < 0.05, *** p-value < 0.01. Robust Standard Errors are in parenthesis. In the two-step system GMM estimations, the variables “AfTPOLCST,” “AfTPOLGDP,” and “TBGDP” were considered endogenous. The other variables were considered exogenous. In the regressions, we have used 3 lags of dependent variable as instruments and 2 lags of endogenous variables as instruments in order to limit the proliferation of instruments in this regression.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Gnangnon, S.K. Effect of Aid for Trade Policy and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility: Does Institutional and Governance Quality Matter? Economies 2019, 7, 6. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7010006

AMA Style

Gnangnon SK. Effect of Aid for Trade Policy and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility: Does Institutional and Governance Quality Matter? Economies. 2019; 7(1):6. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7010006

Chicago/Turabian Style

Gnangnon, Sena Kimm. 2019. "Effect of Aid for Trade Policy and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility: Does Institutional and Governance Quality Matter?" Economies 7, no. 1: 6. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7010006

APA Style

Gnangnon, S. K. (2019). Effect of Aid for Trade Policy and Regulations on Tariff Policy Volatility: Does Institutional and Governance Quality Matter? Economies, 7(1), 6. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies7010006

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop