1. Introduction
In the early 1990s, the economy of Brazil witnessed a radical shift in the exchange rate and trade policy directions toward economic liberalization, which led to high inflows of capital into the country. The existing empirical literature documents said that the policy directions have had success in stabilizing domestic prices and reviving investment and saving decisions, as well as economic growth (see
Bogdanski et al. 2000;
Frenkel and Ros 2006;
Muinhos 2004;
Albuquerque and Portugal 2005;
Albuquerque and Portugal 2006;
Correa and Minella 2010;
Fernandes and Novy 2010). Despite these improvements, the Brazilian economy has been rather dwindling and unimpressive, as the appreciation of the real exchange rate ends up hurting the country’s competitiveness, thereby increasing the unemployment rate. According to the economic indicators’ reports on Brazil published by
Banco Central do Brasil (
2018), the unemployment rate in the first quarter of 2017 was 13.7%. This declined to 13.0% in the second quarter, 12.4% in the third quarter, and 11.8% in the fourth quarter. These rates are much higher than 4.3% and 7.1% in 1990 and 2002, respectively, as reported by
Frenkel and Ros (
2006). This situation portends worrisome implications for the loss of human capital and an increase in the risk of social exclusion (
Nagore and van Soest 2016).
There is vast literature that suggests a relationship between the unemployment rate and real exchange rate (see
Belke and Gros 2002;
Fan and Song 2006;
Frenkel and Ros 2006;
Demir 2010;
Feldmann 2011). This strand of literature sees the real exchange rate as a major determinant of production costs of the firms, investment and saving decisions, as well as future earnings uncertainty. Theoretically, a depreciation of the real exchange rate (RERT) causes exports to be cheaper and imports to be more expensive and, consequently, the exporting country would gain trade competitiveness. For the exporting country to increase the quantity of exported goods, they have to keep their prices unchanged in the domestic currency. If peradventure, they are facing high adjustment costs, then it may be difficult to increase quantity; rather, they have to increase prices. On the contrary, an appreciation of the RERT causes exports to become expensive and imports to be relatively cheaper; hence, the exporting country will lose trade competitiveness if they do not change their prices in the domestic currency. If the effect of appreciation is significantly large, then reducing export prices may hamper the profit margins. In this sense,
Delatte and López-Villavicencio (
2012) argue that the exporting country may prefer to absorb the effect of appreciation so as to increase profit margins and pass a significant part of the effect of depreciation to consumers, if only they have the market powers to set prices. Generally, the effect of the real exchange rate on unemployment could be negative or positive, depending on the specific characteristics of the market. If the rigidities in the labor market significantly improve the bargaining powers of the labor, wages will increase and the net return of the firms will fall (see
Darby et al. 1999;
Belke and Kaas 2004).
The empirical studies on the effects of the real exchange rate on unemployment rate focused mostly on developed economies, while only a few such studies concentrated on emerging and developing economies (see
Frenkel and Ros 2006;
Demir 2010). In the case of Latin America,
Frenkel and Ros (
2006) find that the real exchange rate is a major determinant of unemployment in the region. Similarly,
Edwards (
1989) reveals that an appreciation of the real exchange rate would decrease employment in the manufacturing sector of the developing countries, while
Faria and León-Ledesma (
2005) show that the long-run equilibrium effect of the real exchange rate on employment occurs through the channel of trade openness. Therefore, they conclude that an appreciation of the real exchange rate would cause employment to decrease. Supporting this strand of literature,
Fan and Song (
2006), using the manufacturing data in China during the period 1980–2003, reveal that a depreciation of the real exchange rate promotes employment growth in manufacturing industries, but wage growth is not influenced by the real exchange rate. Furthermore,
Feldmann (
2011), using data on 17 countries for the period 1982–2003, finds that even though the magnitude of the effect is small, high exchange rate volatility increases the unemployment rate. Providing contrasting evidence,
Burgess and Knetter (
1998) find that the manufacturing employment in Germany and France does not respond to exchange rate volatility; hence, it is slow to adjust itself to the long-run equilibrium rate. Supporting this finding,
Galindo et al. (
2006) reveal that real exchange rate depreciation has a negative employment effect on the industries with high dollarization liability. This implies that a depreciation of the real exchange rate would increase the unemployment rate. Considering both the short- and long-run,
Chang (
2011) reveals that exchange rate uncertainty and unemployment have an equilibrium relationship in the long-run, while in the short-run, the impact of exchange rate uncertainty on unemployment is large, irrespective of all the measures of uncertainty applied. Similarly,
Nyahokwe and Ncwadi (
2013), who assess the impact of exchange rate volatility on unemployment in South Africa, examine the impacts of the real exchange rate, exports, real interest rate, and GDP on unemployment. However, in the short-run, only the real interest rate and exports have a significant impact in explaining unemployment.
In view of the foregoing literature, it is pertinent at this point to state clearly that the extant literature only focused on the linear relationship between the real exchange rate and unemployment (or employment growth) in both the short- and long-run. This relationship, as examined by the previous studies, might exhibit asymmetric effects in either the long-run or short-run, or possibly in both the short- and long-run, especially when prices are particularly rigid downwards and quantities are rigid upwards (
Delatte and López-Villavicencio 2012;
Apergis 2015). Therefore, the main objective of this paper is to test the effects of the real ERPT on unemployment in Brazil. Given that Brazil is the largest open economy in the Latin American region, based on the size of its gross domestic product (GDP) (
The World Bank 2015), and the fact that the economy has been susceptible to the exchange rate shocks on its macroeconomic variables, it is important to understand the dynamics of the real ERPT on unemployment. This will help in designing an appropriate monetary policy framework in response to the effects of the external shocks on the economy of Brazil. Therefore, the contribution of this study can be viewed in two ways: (1) Even though empirical literature on the real ERPT has gained currency over the years, a great deal of it seeks to examine the extent of the ERPT on imports and domestic prices (
Usman and Musa 2018) and others on gold price fluctuations (
Balcilar et al. 2017). The few empirical studies on the effects of RERT on unemployment extensively applied linear models, mostly based on Johansen cointegration and error correction models (VECM). These models invariably assume a linear relationship between the variables. The findings from those studies could be misleading if there exists a nonlinearity in the relationship. Therefore, to the best of our knowledge, this is the first time an asymmetric effect of the real ERPT on unemployment is examined for Brazil. (2) The paper uses a linear ARDL and nonlinear ARDL model recently proposed by
Pesaran et al. (
2001) and
Shin et al. (
2014). These methodologies have the enviable advantages over the multivariate Johansen cointegration and VECM, which are used extensively in previous studies. Specifically, we use bounds testing procedure to establish a long-run relationship between RERT and unemployment for the linear and nonlinear models. Unlike Johansen cointegration and VECM, the ARDL bounds testing approach does not follow the underlying assumption that all the variables must be integrated of the same order. Whether the variables are integrated of order one, I(1) and I(0), or mutually cointegrated, the method would yield accurate and reliable estimates (See
Pesaran et al. 2001).
Figure 1 illustrates the behavior of the real effective exchange rate (REERT) and that of the unemployment in Brazil from 1981M01 to 2015M11. The figure shows that the REERT and unemployment rate have witnessed large fluctuations over the years. These fluctuations are attributed to an increase in unemployment and inflation in the 1980s. However, the crawling peg system was very successful in bringing down the rate of inflation over time. The inflation declined, on average, from 2076% in 1994 to 3.2% in 1998, before the system was jettisoned for a more flexible system of exchange rate because of the financial crisis that erupted the economy (
Alemán 2011). Furthermore, since the global financial crisis of 2008, and its severe effects on the economies of the world, the REERT has been declining, while the unemployment rate has been increasing in Brazil.
The rest of this paper has been structured as follows.
Section 2 presents the data and describes the two methodologies used in this study, which are based on the linear and nonlinear ARDL model.
Section 3 is the presentation of results concerning the estimations of the linear and nonlinear ARDL models. Finally,
Section 4 provides some concluding remarks and policy implications of the findings.
3. Empirical Results and Discussion
The time plots of the variables in
Figure A1 and
Figure A2 suggest that there is no trend in the series, but structural breaks in each of the variables are evident. These breaks are more conspicuous in their first differences. The implication of this result is that the nonstationarity tests would be conducted using only the model with intercept. The results of the ADF and Zivot–Andrews unit root tests are presented in
Table 1. The result of the ADF suggests that the unemployment rate is not stationary at this level. However, after its first difference, the variable becomes stationary at a 1% level of significance. In the case of the real exchange rate, the result indicates the existence of stationarity at a 5% level of significance. After the first difference, it is evident that the real exchange rate is highly significant, easily passing the 1% test of significance in all the models. Furthermore, the Zivot–Andrews test with appropriate lag lengths reveals a slightly different outcome. From the result (see
Table 1), it is clear that the unemployment rate and the real exchange rate are stationary in all the models after their first differences. In other words, the null hypothesis of no stationarity is only rejected after their first differences. This signifies that the variables are integrated of order one, I(1), in all the three models with their corresponding break-points
2.
Table 2 reports the results of long- and short-run symmetry tests using the Wald test. The result clearly shows that the test statistic exceeds the critical value in the long-run, hence the relationship between the RERT and unemployment exhibits asymmetries in the long-run. The implication of this result is that the long-run null hypothesis that
is rejected at a 5 percent level of significance, suggesting that applying linear models in this regard would lead to misspecification of the model. Turning to the short-run symmetric test, the result suggests that the null hypothesis,
, cannot be rejected. Therefore, allowing for linear models are most appropriate for analyzing the dynamic interactions between RERT and unemployment for Brazil.
Table 3 presents the results of the linear and nonlinear bounds testing cointegration using Equations (4) and (6), respectively. The tests clearly show that the
(
F-statistic)
3 value exceeds the upper critical value of the bounds calculated by
Pesaran et al. (
2001) at 5% for linear specification and 1% for nonlinear specification. Therefore, the null hypothesis of no cointegration between the unemployment rate and the real exchange rate is rejected. The rejection of the null hypothesis in both cases implies that a valid long-run relationship (cointegration) exists between unemployment and the real exchange rate included in the models.
Table 4 presents the results of the symmetric ARDL model. The results indicate that in the long-run, the effect of the RERT on the unemployment rate is distinctly inelastic and negatively nonsignificant. This confirms the symmetric test result that an asymmetric model performs better in analyzing the long-run relationship between RERT and unemployment. However, in the short-run, the effect of the RERT is inelastic and negatively significant
. This suggests that a 10% increase in RERT would approximately decrease the unemployment rate by 0.12%. The Wald test of
for complete pass-through in the short-run using Equation (4) is further conducted. The result shows that the
t-statistic of −13.67 and
F-statistic of 60.09 reject the null hypothesis of a complete pass-through at 1% level of significance. The rejection of the null hypothesis in the two test statistics implies that the pass-through effect in the short-run is incomplete. This result aligns with the finding of
Ribero et al. (
2004) and
Demir (
2010). Particularly, Ribero’s study finds that the real exchange rate appreciation has a significantly negative effect on employment creation in manufacturing sectors in Brazil, and
Demir (
2010) reports that the real exchange rate volatility increases unemployment growth of the Turkish manufacturing firms. Our result is similar to
Chang (
2011) who reports that in the long-run, exchange rate uncertainty has an equilibrium relationship with unemployment, while in the short-run, the impact of the exchange rate uncertainty on unemployment is evident with respect to all the measures of uncertainty.
Table 5 presents the results of the dynamic effects of real ERPT to unemployment in Brazil using an appropriate lag length
4. Theoretically, the positive change in the real exchange rate (appreciation) implies an increase in the unemployment rate and the negative change in the real exchange rate (depreciation) shows a decrease in the unemployment rate. The coefficient of the long-run asymmetric pass-through described in Equation (6) indicates that the effect of appreciation on unemployment is inelastic and statistically significant,
. This finding suggests that a 1% increase in the RERT would lead to approximately 0.81% increase in unemployment rate. On the other hand, a depreciation of RERT exerts a negatively significant and inelastic effect on the unemployment rate,
, suggesting that a 1% increase in RERT would lead to about a 0.67% decrease in unemployment rate. The importance of this result is that it confirms that the RERT depreciation causes the unemployment rate to fall by more than the same magnitude appreciation that will cause it to rise. Therefore, the finding aligns with
Fan and Song (
2006) that depreciation of the RERT promotes employment growth and reduces the unemployment rate. This finding is also similar to
Frenkel and Ros (
2006), who find a negative and significant effect of the RERT appreciation on employment growth of 17 Latin American countries.
Turning to the short-term regression associated with the long-run cointegrating model in Equation (2), the result shows that the effect of an appreciation of the RERT on the unemployment rate is elastic and statistically significant
. Specifically, the result shows that a 1% increase in the RERT would inversely change unemployment rate by 4.27%
5, while there is no evidence to support the effect of depreciation of the RERT on the unemployment rate. This finding is inconsistent with the earlier finding of
Edwards (
1989) and
Frenkel and Ros (
2006). While Edward’s finding points to the fact that appreciation of the RERT decreases employment growth of the manufacturing sector in the developing countries and depreciation increases it,
Frenkel and Ros (
2006) hold that the real exchange rate is a major determinant of unemployment in the Latin American region. However, our finding echoes the result of
Nyahokwe and Ncwadi (
2013), who argue that the long-run exchange rate has an impact on unemployment. The only point of departure is that our study focuses on asymmetric effects. Therefore, our finding is novel.
The results of the diagnostic tests conducted on the nonlinear ARDL model used in the study show that the Portmanteau test for autocorrelation, Breusch–Pagan heteroskedasticity test, Ramsey RESET test (F), and Jarque–Bera test on normality could not be rejected. This implies that the nonlinear ARDL model used is correctly specified.
While comparing the results of the symmetric and asymmetric models, it is worth noting that the coefficient of the RERT is not statistically significant in the symmetric ARDL; however, allowing for a long-run asymmetric effect, as suggested by the symmetric test in
Table 3, not only increases the magnitude of the pass-through elasticity, but also become statistically significant. Similarly, in the short-run, the pass-through elasticity of RERT in the asymmetric model is possibly beyond the theoretical expectation. However, using the symmetric model, as suggested by the result of the symmetric test in
Table 3, gives a sense of theoretical validation.
4. Concluding Remarks and Policy Implications
In this paper, an attempt is made to explore the pass-through of the RERT to unemployment in Brazil using a simple approach of combining the symmetric and asymmetric ARDL models over the period 1981M1–2015M11, as suggested by the symmetric test. Given that most studies simply consider the pass-through of the exchange rate to imports and domestic prices, this study contributes immensely to the bulk of literature by taking into account that positive and negative variations of the real exchange rate have symmetrical and asymmetrical effects on unemployment.
Indeed, the results of the ADF and Zivot–Andrews tests for the stationarity properties of the variables show that unemployment rate and RERT are stationary in their first differences; although under ADF, the RERT is stationary at this level. The results of the symmetric and asymmetric models show that there exists a valid long-run relationship between RERT and unemployment in Brazil.
Based on the symmetric and asymmetric ARDL models, it is clear that there is a role of RERT in the determination of the unemployment, even though the pass-through is incomplete in both the short- and long-run. There is a strong evidence that the pass-through of RERT to unemployment is asymmetrical or nonlinear in the long-run, probably because of downward price rigidities, and symmetrical or linear in the short-run, reflecting the assumption that positive and negative variations of the RERT have equal effects on the unemployment rate. However, the pass-through of appreciation is lower than that of depreciation. In other words, the unemployment rate rises less as a result of an appreciation of domestic currency than the amount that a depreciation of the same magnitude will cause it to fall. Therefore, the findings of this paper are important for the government and its managers, desiring to achieve a lower and stable unemployment rate. In specific terms, the knowledge of the directions (positive and negative) of the RERT movements are essential in the determination of the real exchange rate pass-through to unemployment in the long-run; whereas in the short-run, even though the RERT movements account for the changes in the unemployment rate, its effect is symmetrical. This will assist in designing appropriate monetary policy in response to a rise in unemployment rate resulting from a change in the real exchange rate. Our findings also have policy implication for the timing of current account adjustments, as well as the choice of the exchange rate policy. For further studies, we suggest that a threshold model could be applied in order to capture the effects of not only the direction of the changes in the real exchange rate, but also the effect of the size and magnitude of the changes in the real exchange rate.