Next Article in Journal
Stochastic Ordering of Stationary Distributions of Linear Recurrences: Further Results and Economic Applications
Previous Article in Journal
Analysis of the Impact of the Pandemic on the Growth, Use, and Development of E-Business: A Systematic Review of the Literature
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Empirical Analysis of Inclusive Growth, Information and Communication Technology Adoption, and Institutional Quality

by
Bosede Ngozi Adeleye
1,
Sodiq Arogundade
2,* and
Biyase Mduduzi
2
1
Department of Accountancy, Finance and Economics, University of Lincoln, Lincoln LN6 7TS, UK
2
School of Economics, University of Johannesburg, Auckland Park P.O. Box 524, South Africa
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Economies 2023, 11(4), 124; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11040124
Submission received: 12 February 2023 / Revised: 25 March 2023 / Accepted: 29 March 2023 / Published: 19 April 2023

Abstract

:
Using a sample of 193 countries from 2010 to 2019, this study investigates the impact of institutional quality index (IQI) and information and communication technology (ICT) on inclusive growth. The study engaged the panel spatial correlation consistent (PSCC-FE), instrumental variable-generalized method of moments (IV-GMM), and simultaneous quantile regressions (SQREG) models to assess if the impact differs by economic development (high-, low-, lower-middle- and upper-middle-income countries). The following findings emerge. The effect of IQI is positive across all models from the full sample, while that of ICT is heterogeneous, with mobile phones having a significant positive impact. The interaction effect is observed to be sensitive to the choice of ICT indicator. From the sub-samples, both IQI, ICT and their interaction show significant heterogeneous effect with consistent positive (negative interaction) outcomes in high-income countries. Thus, our findings strongly suggest that policymakers should prioritize institutional quality and ICT to ensure that economic growth translates into better living conditions for people in other income groups.

1. Introduction

Investigations of what makes some countries poor and others rich are ‘long-standing’ and extensively discussed by economists and policymakers. Originating from the careful analysis of Swan (1956) and Solow (1956), the neoclassical growth theory placed emphasis on technological progress as the key contributing factor to economic growth. The neoclassical theory has advanced substantially since Solow and Swan’s time and now gives prominence to other contributing factors such as education (Lucas 1988) and innovation (Romer 1986). Neoclassical theories continue to be influential in shaping our knowledge of economic growth. While the debate persists regarding this key question, some economists have identified institutions and ICT as key drivers of economic growth.
A distinguished body of literature puts a great deal of emphasis on institutionally related explanations of economic growth. According to an ardent and devoted supporter of institutional-augmented growth models (Acemoglu et al. 2005), economic institutions influence a wide range of economic outcomes, including how resources will be distributed. (i.e., the distribution of wealth, physical capital, or human capital). In other words, they impact how the pie is distributed among various societal groups and people.
For economists and policymakers, the role of institutions on economic growth has become an important area of investigation (Ross 2001; Acemoglu and Robinson 2001; Rodrik et al. 2004). More recently, several studies have looked at how institutions can influence military spending-growth nexus (Compton and Paterson 2016); how natural resources may negatively influence growth in the presence of poor institutions (Acemoglu et al. 2009; Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2013); and the role institutions in the nexus between foreign direct investment and poverty (Arogundade et al. 2022a).
The second strand of literature claims that growth acceleration is largely fuelled by the ICT revolution emphasising the role of ICT as the chief determinant of economic growth (Oliner and Sichel 2000). Noticeable scholars in this field include Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000) and Brynjolfsson and Hitt (2000). In these studies, ICT is believed to be growth-enhancing. In contrast to the developed countries, ICT-growth nexus in low-income and middle-income countries is poorly studied. Partly inspired by the ‘leapfrogging hypothesis’ of Steinmueller (2001), some studies have recently attempted to unravel the degree to which less developed countries can benefit from ICT (Adeleye and Eboagu 2019; Tallon and Kraemer 2000). Promisingly, a consensus is emerging that ICT appears to be beneficial for economic growth (Adeleye and Eboagu 2019; Albiman and Sulong 2016), socio-economic development (Roztocki et al. 2019) and more recently, inclusive growth (Adeleye et al. 2021a) in less developed countries.
While this area of investigation (i.e., institutions–growth nexus & ICT–growth relationship) has been gaining momentum more recently (Acemoglu et al. 2005, for a detailed account), far less is known about the effect of institutions and ICT on inclusive growth. As the global economy entered the twenty-first century, there has been growing alertness towards inclusive growth (see Adeleye et al. 2021b). Policymakers in every continent of the world worry that a high level of economic growth is not shared by all the people living there. This is also coming at a time when high levels of unemployment, poverty and inequality accompany growth. The reality and realization that economic growth only benefits some sections of the population (but not all) are gradually becoming part of the development agenda. For example, the operations of the World Bank Group’s support for inclusive growth at the country program and project levels has been paying a great deal of attention to inclusive growth. Despite promising discussions about the potential inclusive growth strategies, the concept of inclusive growth remains loosely defined. Some important scholars in this field (Rauniyar and Kanbur 2010) define inclusive growth as growth associated with reduced inequality.
The scatter plot of inclusive growth1 and institutional quality2 is presented in Figure 1. The plot demonstrates that countries with relatively high institutional quality are characterized with high inclusive growth regardless of the income group classification. In contrast, countries with poor institutional framework are associated with low inclusive growth. The quality of institutions has a direct and significant impact on the performance of economies; as a result, economies with robust institutions—such as the rule of law, efficient and effective government, and property rights—tend to perform better in terms of market efficiency, resource allocation and healthy competition among local businesses. However, nations with weak institutions are frequently characterized by high transaction costs, risk for lengthy trade agreements, ineffective contract enforcement, and corruption, all of which may impede growth and development (Arogundade et al. 2021; Brahim and Rachdi 2014). Hence, it is expected that countries with different levels of institutional quality across regions would have different levels of institutional quality. If not supported by empirical evidence, this conjecture may be nonsensical, lacking objectivity.
This paper is novel and differs from existing empirical studies in several ways. First, unlike the study of Acemoglu and Johnson (2005), we explore the effects of ICT and institutional quality from the inclusive growth perspective derived from the human development index from UNDP (2019). The rationale for using the human development index is that it anchors on three pillars of human development: education, life expectancy and standard of living—the most appropriate measure of inclusive growth (Adeleye et al. 2021a). Policymakers around the world are not interested in stimulating economic growth for the sake of economic growth, but they do so with the intention of reducing poverty and inequality (Ajide et al. 2021). According to Klasen (2010), there is a need to consider measures (such as non-income measures) which encompass more than just income measures.
Secondly, instead of capturing the impact of institutions with a single institutional variable, this study adds to the body of literature by creating an institutional index using the six governance indicators of the World Bank (2020a) using principal component analysis. Because there are so many indicators of institutional quality, it can be difficult to determine which one best represents it or is most relevant for an empirical investigation. This is why the Principal Component investigation is used. Moreover, policymakers need to understand the relationship between institutional quality and inclusive growth because poor or weak institutions can misallocate resources, which negatively impacts the economic growth process (Mbulawa 2015).
Thirdly, we consider the interaction term of an institutional quality index with each indicator of ICT indicator included to determine if the net impact of quality institutions on inclusive growth is boosted or hampered by ICT usage. We also controlled for various factors, including capital, labour, ICT adoption (proxied by mobile subscription and fixed telephones), inflation and trade in the IV-GMM framework, which accounts for endogeneity bias arising from reverse causality and omitted variables.
Lastly, we examine the impact of institutions on inclusive growth by differentiating between countries according to their level of development, such as low-income economies, low-middle-income economies, and high-income economies.
The following sub-questions guide this study: (i) Does institutional quality and ICT influence inclusive growth? (ii) How does ICT adoption interact with institutional quality in determining inclusive growth? (iii) Does the effect of ICT and institutional quality vary by the countries’ economic development level? (iv) Does ICT moderate the impact of institutional quality on inclusive growth?
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides a brief overview of the existing studies on the link between institutions and inclusive growth. Section 3 describes the methodology and data to be used in this paper. Section 4 presents the estimates of the impact of institutions on inclusive growth and discuss the results. Section 5 presents the conclusion with policy recommendations.

2. Brief Literature Review

This section briefly reviews related studies from two empirical standpoints: ICT–growth nexus and institutional quality growth relations. Much empirical research on the effects of ICT and institutional quality on the economy has been conducted. However, those studies have reported varying results. The reason why there is conflicting results is because of the measures of institutional quality and ICT, the scope of the study and the empirical technique(s) used.

2.1. Institutional Quality and Inclusive Growth

The theoretical nexus between quality of institutions and the economy has been established by the studies of North (1990), Olson (1982) and Jones (1987). These studies argue that a sound institution can influence a country’s ability to progress economically. Institutions, according to North (1990), are the rules of the economic game. According to him, institutions establish market regulations, organize relationships between economic players and make sure that these regulations bind economic activity (George et al. 2021). Competition, which promotes technological advancement, creativity, and productivity increases, is always encouraged in an environment safeguarded by market rules. Similarly, Romer (1986) asserts that knowledge and sound institutions are essential for boosting production size and economic growth. By facilitating easier access to information and predictable actor behaviour, effective institutions are necessary to lower the inherent uncertainty in economic interactions. The quality of a nation’s institutions is what determines the total productivity of its production components, according to a similar perspective by Hall and Jones (1999). Additionally, Acemoglu and Robinson (2010) contend that institutions are the fundamental driver of economic progress and are responsible for regional differences in development. Bad institutions, on the other hand, are often characterized by weak contract enforcement, high transaction costs, corruption, and risk for long-term trade commitments (Farole et al. 2011).
Numerous empirical studies on the relationship between strong institutions and long-term economic growth have been conducted. For instance, Sondermann (2018) contends that nations with sound institutions have economic shock resistance. Boschma and Capone (2016) further stressed the necessity of ongoing improvements in institution quality since they promote economic growth and increase product variety. Nawaz et al. (2014) show that institutions play a crucial role in predicting the long-term economic growth of Asian nations using fixed effect and dynamic GMM approaches. The study also demonstrates that the influence of institutional quality on economic growth varies according to economic development levels. Using a panel smooth transition regression model (PSTR) for a sample of 128 developed and developing countries, Marakbi and Turcu (2016) reveal a non-linear relationship between corruption and economic growth conditional on changes in institutional development. Similarly, the study of Arogundade et al. (2021) concludes that sound institutions are germane in enhancing the effect of FDI on inclusive human development in Africa. Despite the overwhelming support for the growth-enhancing impact of institutional quality, studies like Williamson (2009) and Rodrik (2006) could not establish a strong link between a robust institutional framework and economic growth. They argue that since countries may have to follow different development paths, institutions should not be transplanted to enhance economic development.

2.2. ICT Adoption and Inclusive Growth

On the theoretical connection between telecommunications infrastructure and development, there are two schools of thought. Technophiles who believe that telecommunications have a beneficial impact on development make up the first school of thought. ICT, according to technophiles, will increase productivity, increase job prospects, enhance working conditions for many people, and provide a variety of chances for small-scale, autonomous, and decentralized types of production. (Dholakia and Harlam 1994; Castells 1989; Mansell and Wehn 1998). Technophobes, on the other hand, assert that telecommunications have a negative impact on development and widen the information gap between the wealthy and the poor, the literate and the ignorant. (Van Dijk and Hacker 2003; Mansell 1999).
Most of the early empirical literature on the impact of telecommunication technologies concludes that investment in telecommunication infrastructure strongly influences economic growth. Some of these studies include Roller and Waverman (2001), who used data on 21 OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development) countries spanning 20 years; Aghaei and Rezagholizadeh (2017), who looked at how Information and Communication Technology (ICT) affected the economic development of Organization of Islamic Conference (OIC) nations; Toader et al. (2018), who looked at how ICT affected the economic development of European nations over the course of 18 years.
On studies related to developing countries, a growing number of empirical studies have suggested that ICT adoption and investments have a beneficial and significant impact on their economies’ growth. For instance, Adeleye and Eboagu (2019) used the generalized method of moments (GMM) to evaluate the effect of ICT development on economic growth in Africa. The study finds ICT to be crucial toward the economic growth drive of African countries. The study further concludes that the “leapfrogging” hypothesis holds for Africa. Similarly, using the OLS and system GMM model, Batuo (2015) provides empirical evidence for the growth-enhancing impact of ICT development in 44 selected African countries. In addition, using the endogenous growth model, Chavula (2013) argues that telephone main lines and mobile telephony significantly and positively impact the living standards of 49 African countries.
Additionally, Asongu and Le Roux (2017) demonstrate that policies intended to promote ICT (mobile phone, internet, and telephone) penetration will increase inclusive development in the post-2015 sustainable development agenda using a sample of 49 sub-Saharan African (SSA) nations from 2002 to 2012. However, Ejemeyovwi and Osabuohien (2020) used a System Generalised Method of Moments (SGMM) to investigate the relevance of mobile technology adoption on inclusive growth in West Africa. The study concludes that mobile technology adoption has an insignificant impact on inclusive growth in West Africa.

2.3. ICT Adoption and Institutional Quality

To justify the interaction of institutions and ICT in this study, we review some studies on the relationship between ICT and institutional quality. The conjecture is that ICT adoption can improve the quality of governance via information sharing with the public (Zuiderwijk and Janssen 2014; Sassi and Ali 2017). In other words, the efficiency, accountability, and transparency of governance is facilitated on the platform of ICT. The bulk of the literature finds a direct relationship between ICT and the quality of governance (Belanger and Carter 2012; Mohammed et al. 2016; Ziemba et al. 2016; Adam 2020). For instance, Popelyshyn et al. (2019) show that ICT improved governance transparency in Ukraine when open data were adopted. Adam (2020) demonstrates that ICT development and quality of institution significantly mediate the impact of e-government on corruption in Africa. In another dimension, Sassi and Ali (2017) reveal that skilled competency in ICT usage is required to have an appreciable impact on institutions. In addition, Rana et al. (2013) conclude that the dearth of ICT infrastructure contributes to the inefficiency of governance in Africa. However, Darusalam et al. (2021) found a non-significant impact of ICT on institutional quality from a panel of Association of Southeast Asian Nation (ASEAN) countries from 1984 to 2017. Given these outcomes, we tilt towards the general opinion and hypothesize that ICT moderates the impact of institutional quality on inclusive growth.

3. Data and Model

This study uses eleven variables across 193 selected countries3 from 2010 to 2019 to achieve the objectives. The choice of countries and variables was based on data availability. To ensure a detailed investigation of the subject matter, the sample is disaggregated into high, low, lower-middle, and upper-middle-income countries according to the 2020 World Bank Classification to allow for sub-group analysis.

3.1. The Variables

The dependent variable is inclusive growth. Different studies use diverse proxies to measure this phenomenon (Acemoglu et al. 2009; Acemoglu and Robinson 2010; Anand et al. 2013; Johnson 2016; Tella and Alimi 2016; Asongu and Nwachukwu 2017; Asongu and Boateng 2018; Ejemeyovwi and Osabuohien 2020; Oyinlola et al. 2020; Ofori and Asongu 2021) but we chose to proxy inclusive growth using the human development index from UNDP (2019). This is because the index anchors on three pillars of human development: education, life expectancy, and standard of living. Hence, we find it as the most appropriate measure of inclusive growth (Adeleye et al. 2021a).
The main independent variable is an index of institutional quality. Studies have used different indicators (Acemoglu and Johnson 2005; Acemoglu et al. 2009; Acemoglu and Robinson 2010; Acemoglu and Robinson 2013; Adeleye et al. 2017; Arogundade et al. 2022b) and since there is no universally acclaimed measure, we therefore create an institutional index (IQI) from the six governance indicators4 of the World Bank (2020a) using the Principal Component Analysis (PCA). The PCA is justified by the fact that there are several measures of institutional quality and that there is frequently a significant degree of correlation among them, making it difficult to determine which of these indicators best reflects it or which is most relevant for an empirical study. IQI is strongly and positively correlated with all institutions’ variables (as indicated in Table 1) which is an indication that IQI best explains these variables simultaneously.
When calculating IQI, the first component has an eigenvalue (the variance of the component) of 4.9444. It explains 682.41% of the common variance of the series, while the second component has an eigenvalue of 0.4854 and explains 8.09% of the variation. A value greater than one indicates that the component captures more variance than its nominal share of the total variance of the variables. As a result, the first component is applied in this instance, and Appendix A Figure A1 displays the scree plot. A further indicator of sample adequacy is the Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin (KMO) index, which compares partial correlations and correlations between variables. The usage of PCA is justified by a value greater than 0.50. Hence, with a KMO of 0.8848, PCA’s use is justified. Table 2 presents some critical characteristics of the computation of the IQI.
Furthermore, to appraise the impact of ICT, two indicators are used: mobile cellular subscriptions and fixed telephone subscriptions (Asongu and Boateng 2018; Asongu and Nwachukwu 2018; Niebel 2018; Xing 2018; Adeleye and Eboagu 2019; Alshubiri et al. 2019; Adeleye et al. 2021a; Kim et al. 2021). While the former is commonly used among individuals of different income strata, such that owning a mobile phone allows even the poorest in the community to have access to information, the latter is common among corporate organisations. Hence, using these two indicators ensures that ICT usage and penetration is captured adequately. Five control variables are used: individuals using the internet (Adeleye and Eboagu 2019; Adeleye et al. 2021a; Azu and Nwauko 2021), labour participation (Appiah et al. 2020; Isola et al. 2020), gross fixed capital formation (Adeleye et al. 2021a; Adusei and Adeleye 2021; Ebire et al. 2021), trade openness (Hdom and Fuinhas 2020; Kpomblekou and Wonyra 2020; Kong et al. 2020; Adeleye et al. 2021b) and inflation (Oyinlola et al. 2020; Zheng et al. 2020; Adeleye 2021; Ebire et al. 2021).
Finally, to address the main question of this study, the interaction term of institutional quality index with each ICT indicator is added to ascertain whether ICT usage positively or negatively affects the net impact of quality institutions on inclusive growth. All the variables, except the institutional quality score, are converted to their natural logarithms to account for heteroscedasticity, potential outliers, and to construct elasticity correlations. Table 3 includes a description of the variables, a priori expectations and sources.

3.2. Theoretical Background and Empirical Model

Our empirical approach is situated within the frameworks of (i) the Rodrik (2005) institutional taxonomy, which posits that institutions are relevant in the growth process; (ii) the Acemoglu et al. (2009) modernization hypothesis, which argues on the relevance of institutions to growth; and (iii) Sein et al. (2018), who offer perspectives and theories on the role of ICT in economic development. Incorporating these theories, the implicit model expresses growth as a function of institutions and ICT:
Growth = f ( institutions ,   ICT )
Hence, in examining the effect of institutional quality and ICT on inclusive growth, the study expresses inclusive growth as a linear function of an index of institutional quality, a column vector of ICT variables5 and a row vector of control variables. It involves a two-part procedure such that in the first part, we analyse the full sample and thereafter, the sub-samples of income groups. The baseline model is stated as:
lnHDI it = α 0 + α 1 IQI it + α 3 ln   Z it + φ t + u it
where HDI it = Human development proxy (inclusive growth proxy); ln = natural logarithm; IQI it = institutional quality index; Z it = vector of control variables (labour participation, gross fixed capital, Internet users, inflation and trade openness); α i = parameters to be estimated; φ t = year dummies (which controls for common shocks such as the global financial crises of 2007–2009); and u it = general error term. Equation (1) tests the hypothesis that institutional quality impacts inclusive growth while controlling for other macroeconomic indicators. Next, we incorporate ICT indicators into Equation (2) to capture how information technology fosters inclusiveness. This relationship is as specified in Equation (3):
lnHDI it = γ 0 + γ 1 IQI it + γ 2 lnICT it + γ 3 ln   W it + d t + e it
where ICT it = vector of information and telecommunication variables (mobile cellular and fixed telephone subscribers); W it = vector of control variables; γ i = parameters to be estimated; d t = year dummies; and e it = general error term.
In addressing the main objective of this paper, we interacted ICT usage with quality institutions on inclusive growth. The conjecture is that ICT represents a channel through which IQI forges inclusiveness. This hypothesis is tested by including the interaction term (IQI*ICT) in Equation (3), and the model becomes:
ln HDI it = η 0 + η 1 IQI it + η 2 ln ICT it + η 3 ln ( IQI ICT ) it +   η 4 ln K it + ω t + v it
where the characteristics of Equation (4) are analogous to those of Equations (2) and (3).
From Equation (4), η 3 offers three pieces of information. First, the sign of the coefficient indicates if the interaction of both variables spurs or hinders inclusiveness. Secondly, the magnitude of the coefficient hints at whether the net impact of IQI (evaluated at the values6 of ICT indicators) on inclusive growth is positive or negative, which is derived as:
ln HDI ln IQI = η 1 + η 3 ln ICT
Thirdly, the statistical significance of the coefficient η 1 and η 3 are relevant in the computation of the net effect. If η 1 is not significant and η 3 is significant, it means that η 1 is statistically not different from zero. Therefore, the net effect of IQI depends on the weight of η 3 and the value of ICT. But if η 1 is significant and η 3 is not significant, it means there is no interaction effect and the net effect of IQI equates to its marginal effect.

3.3. Estimation Techniques

By using the Driscoll and Kraay (1998) robust standard error-type approach, which takes into account cross-sectional dependency, we first engage Equations (2)–(4). It computes the spatial correlation consistent (PSCC) standard errors for linear panel models using the ordinary least squares/weighted least squares, fixed effects (within) regression and the least squares method. These estimators adjust the coefficient estimations’ standard errors for potential dependency (Cameron and Trivedi 2005; Hoechle 2006). Additionally, the instrumental variables techniques nested within the generalized method of moments (IV-GMM) framework by Baum et al. (2003, 2007a, 2007b) is used if economic growth is endogenous, that is, correlated with the error term such that the outcomes are biased and may yield incorrect inferences. Finally, it becomes appropriate to use the simultaneous quantile regressions (SQREG) proposed by Koenker and Bassett (1978), Koenker and Hallock (2001), and Koenker (2005) if the dependent variable does have a normal distribution and the impact of the regressors changes along its conditional distribution. As a result, the SQREG enables assessment of inclusive growth’s shifting structure at various stages using explanatory variables spread throughout the 25th, 50th and 75th quantiles.

4. Empirical Results and Discussions

4.1. Descriptive Analysis

The descriptive and correlation analysis of the variables used in the study is presented in Table 4. The average value of HDI from 2010 to 2019 across 193 countries in the world is 0.706. Niger had the lowest value of 0.331 in 2010, while Norway had the highest value of 0.957 in 2019. On the institutional quality index, the average is 0, and the standard deviation of 2.24 indicates that the sub-regions hover around the sample mean. The minimum is −5, while the maximum is 4.994. The mean value of mobile cellular subscriptions is 35.45 million, the minimum value is 1.600, and the maximum value is 1.75 billion. Fixed telephone subscriptions ranged from 0 to 294 million, with an average value of 4.96 million and a standard deviation of 19.77 million.
The pairwise correlation gauges how closely the dependent and regressor variables are related. The findings show that all variables correlate statistically with inclusive growth, except for gross fixed capital formation (GFCF). However, the signs vary. Table 4 shows that all correlation statistics are less than 0.80 at a glance. This denotes no proof of multicollinearity among the variables as a result.

4.2. Full Sample Results

Table 5 presents the results using the PSCC Fixed Effects technique. The estimated coefficient of labour force participation rate (lnLAB) is negative and statistically significant. This result aligns with the empirical outcome of Adeleye et al. (2021a) and Ongo and Vukenkeng (2014) that rising labour force participation can reduce inclusive growth through the unemployment rate channel. The significant and positive sign of gross fixed capital formation (GFCF) across models indicate that an increase in capital investment and infrastructures create a favourable business climate, which positively impacts productivity and inclusive growth. This result aligns with the empirical outcome of Roztocki et al. (2019). Inflation (INFL) has a positive and statistically significant impact on inclusive growth at the 1% and 5% significance levels. This result supports the structuralists hypothesis that inflation is necessary for economic growth. However, the empirical outcome is not consistent with Gillman et al. (2004) who stated that a rise in consumer prices diminishes household savings, the volume of resources available for domestic investment, capital flows from abroad and inclusive growth.
The impact of trade (lnTR) on inclusive growth is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level across all the models. The intuition is that technological or financial constraints may hinder most countries to take advantage of trade facilitation. Hence, the growth effect of trade may differ according to the level of economic development (Musila and Yiheyis 2015; Jawaid and Waheed 2017). The coefficient of lnNET indicates a positive and significant influence on inclusive growth, suggesting that productive engagement of the Internet will have a progressive effect on growth. Furthermore, the coefficient of IQI suggests a significant and positive relationship with inclusive growth. The results reveal that countries with robust institutional quality systems can minimize widening gaps in income distribution, reduce poverty, and improve inclusive growth (Butkiewicz and Yanikkaya 2006; Nawaz et al. 2014).
Across all model specifications, the impact of ICT (lnMOB and lnFTEL) on inclusive growth is asymmetric. While lnMOB exerts a positive and statistical effect at the 1% level, that of lnFTEL is negative. The positive and significant relationship aligns with previous studies (Osabuohien 2008; Chavula 2013; Ghosh 2016; Adeleye and Eboagu 2019), suggesting that ICT induces inclusive growth. However, the negative effect supports Adeleye et al. (2021a), Adeleye and Eboagu (2019) and Johnson (2016), who find that countries with less robust ICT may experience moderate inclusiveness and a massive digital divide. In gauging the moderating effects of ICT, the interaction term’s coefficient indicating whether ICT impedes or enhances the impact of IQI on growth is positive though statistically significant, with fixed telephones but not with mobile phones. Though the interaction coefficient with mobile phones is significantly not different from zero, the positive signs from both ICT indicators attest to the efficacy of ICT, enabling the sound workings of governance to deliver the gains of inclusive growth. This is a novel contribution to the literature.
For robustness checks, most of the findings of the IV-GMM results presented in Table 6 align with those of Table 5. We found that the moderating effect of ICT is positive and statistically significant from both indicators. We, therefore, arrive at a similar conclusion that ICT enhances the efficiency of IQI on inclusive growth. Consequently, conclusions may be drawn from the outcomes of these augmented regressions.
Next, we examine if the individual impact of IQI, ICT and their interaction differ across the conditional distribution of inclusive growth, and the results from the SQREG approach are shown in Table 7. Restricting interpretations to the variables of interest, from the upper panel (Mobile Phones Model) and across the quantiles, IQI and MOB exert a consistent significant and positive impact on inclusive growth, but their interaction is positive and statistically significant at the 50th quartile. In addition, from the lower panel (Fixed Telephones Model), both IQI and ICT are positive predictors of inclusiveness across the quantiles, but their interaction is negative. These results mirror earlier findings and provide sufficient evidence that ICT plays a crucial role in driving inclusiveness globally, both directly and indirectly (via IQI).

4.3. Sub-Sample Results

Income group results are presented in Table 8 (PSCC-FE). The empirical outcomes indicate that IQI has a positive and statistically significant impact on inclusive growth in high- and upper-middle-income countries, while the impact is negative in low- and lower-middle-income countries. These outcomes align with Dedrick et al. (2013) and Papaioannou and Dimelis (2007) and are unsurprising as more developed economies are characterized by having strong and efficient institutions (regulatory, social, political, and economic) across all strata of the economy. On the impact of ICT, high- and lower-middle-income countries show significant positive outcomes, while the effect is negative for low-income countries regarding fixed telephones. Again, this outcome is expected as more developed economies have the enabling resources to engage in ICT integration which drives inclusiveness. Furthermore, the results of the interaction term suggest that ICT slows the effect of IQI in high- and low-income countries but enhances it in lower- and upper-middle income countries (for mobile phones model); the impact is also positive in lower-middle but negative in low-income countries (for fixed telephones model).
For further robustness checks, we engage the IV-GMM technique, and the results are displayed in Table 9. Similar to the outcomes in Table 8, we observe that the impact of IQI is mixed. It indicates a positive and significant impact on inclusive growth in high- and upper-middle-income countries while it is negative in low- and lower-income countries. Contrarily, the heterogeneous effect of ICT is not quite vivid across the groups as it shows a positive impact in seven out of eight models. The coefficient of the interaction term indicates that ICT attenuates the impact of IQI in high and upper-middle-income countries but improves IQI in low- and lower-middle-income countries.
What stands out from the sub-sample analyses is that IQI has a positive and statistically significant impact on inclusive growth for high- and upper-income groups. In contrast, the impact is negative for lower-middle-income countries and insignificant for the low-income group. An obvious possible explanation for the negative impact of institutional quality on inclusive growth for lower-middle-income countries is the poor institutional configuration in these countries. This explanation is accepted by several (but not all) scholars (see Iqbal and Daly 2014; Aslam et al. 2021). The supposition is the configuration of institutions in lower- and upper-middle-income countries appears to resemble extractive political and economic institutions and therefore, do not contribute to inclusive growth. In addition, the mixed outcomes of ICT may be attributable to the fact that digital inclusion is broadly inexpensive in upper-middle and high-income countries (Aslam et al. 2021). According to Van Ark and Piatkowski (2004), ICT diffusion is largely constrained by low competition levels in the labour and product markets coupled with limited ICT skills of the workforce, shortage of innovation efforts, and insufficient flexibility to reform business organizations negatively impact the pace of ICT diffusion and the productivity effect of ICT.

5. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations

A distinguished body of literature has investigated the relationship between institutions and economic growth, neglecting the interaction effect of institutions and ICT on inclusive growth. Thus, our paper fills this gap using HDI, an index of institutional quality, and two ICT indicators on a panel data of 193 countries from 2010 to 2019. To observe if the outcomes differ by the state of economic development, the full sample is divided along four income delineations and analyses using three robust estimations—PSCC-FE, IV-GMM, and SQREG. Two key results emerge from the study. The full sample estimates suggest that institutional quality and ICT play an important role in stimulating inclusive growth. Our results on the effect of institutional quality are in line with the view that institutions are at the heart of economic growth acceleration and growth inclusiveness (Acemoglu et al. 2005, 2009).
An obvious implication of this finding is that institutional quality in these countries is becoming a strong catalyst to facilitating and promoting inclusiveness. Reassuringly, the estimates derived from the income groups analysis appear to support our choice of investigating the effect of institutional quality at various stages of economic development, given the remarkable differences among income groups that were uncovered. Given our findings, we strongly suggest that policymakers prioritize institutional quality and ICT innovation and usage to ensure that economic growth translates into better living conditions for the populace. Furthermore, given that institutional quality improves the inclusive growth of high- and upper-middle-income countries while it diminishes the growth of low- and lower-middle-income countries, we recommend that developing countries should build a robust institutional quality capable of reducing corruption, increasing transparency, and promoting a business-friendly environment. By implementing these recommendations, developing countries can create a robust institutional quality that will promote inclusive growth and sustainable development.
We agree with several scholars in this field (see Saba and Ngepah 2021) that policymakers in low- and lower-middle-group income countries need to urgently formulate policies that will entrench institutional reforms and such that can facilitate and accelerate the infiltration and the affordability of ICT usage.

Author Contributions

Conceptualized the major idea of this research paper, Prepared the methodology, data collection, analysis, interpretation, and conclusion section, B.N.A.; Prepared the literature review and general editing, S.A.; Prepared the introduction and formatting, B.M. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The datasets used and/or analysed during the current study are available from the author on reasonable request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Figure A1. Scree plot of IQI. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Figure A1. Scree plot of IQI. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Economies 11 00124 g0a1

Appendix B

Table A1. List of Countries and Classifications.
Table A1. List of Countries and Classifications.
S/No.CountryGroupS/No.CountryGroupS/No.CountryGroup
1AfghanistanLI66GeorgiaLMI131NorwayHI
2AlbaniaUMI67GermanyHI132OmanHI
3AlgeriaUMI68GhanaLMI133PakistanLMI
4AngolaLMI69GreeceHI134PalauHI
5Antigua and BarbudaHI70GrenadaUMI135PanamaHI
6ArgentinaHI71GuamHI136Papua New GuineaLMI
7ArmeniaUMI72GuatemalaUMI137ParaguayUMI
8ArubaHI73GuineaLI138PeruUMI
9AustraliaHI74Guinea-BissauLI139PhilippinesLMI
10AustriaHI75GuyanaUMI140PolandHI
11AzerbaijanUMI76HaitiLI141PortugalHI
12Bahamas, TheHI77HondurasLMI142Puerto RicoHI
13BahrainHI78Hong Kong SAR, ChinaHI143QatarHI
14BangladeshLMI79HungaryHI144RomaniaUMI
15BarbadosHI80IcelandHI145Russian FederationUMI
16BelarusUMI81IndiaLMI146RwandaLI
17BelgiumHI82IndonesiaLMI147SamoaUMI
18BelizeUMI83Iran, Islamic Rep.UMI148San MarinoHI
19BeninLI84IraqUMI149Sao Tome and PrincipeLMI
20BhutanLMI85IrelandHI150Saudi ArabiaHI
21BoliviaLMI86IsraelHI151SenegalLI
22Bosnia and HerzegovinaUMI87ItalyHI152SerbiaUMI
23BotswanaUMI88JamaicaUMI153SeychellesHI
24BrazilUMI89JapanHI154Sierra LeoneLI
25Brunei DarussalamHI90JordanUMI155SingaporeHI
26BulgariaUMI91KazakhstanUMI156Slovak RepublicHI
27Burkina FasoLI92KenyaLMI157SloveniaHI
28BurundiLI93KiribatiLMI158Solomon IslandsLMI
29Cabo VerdeLMI94KosovoLMI159South AfricaUMI
30CambodiaLMI95KuwaitHI160South KoreaHI
31CameroonLMI96Kyrgyz RepublicLMI161SpainHI
32Cayman IslandsHI97Lao PDRLMI162Sri LankaLMI
33Central African RepublicLI98LatviaHI163St. Kitts and NevisHI
34ChadLI99LebanonUMI164St. LuciaUMI
35ChileHI100LesothoLMI165St. Vincent and the GrenadinesUMI
36ChinaUMI101LiberiaLI166SudanLMI
37ColombiaUMI102LibyaUMI167SurinameUMI
38ComorosLI103LithuaniaHI168SwedenHI
39Congo, Dem, Rep.LI104LuxembourgHI169SwitzerlandHI
40Congo, Dem. Rep.LI105Macao SAR, ChinaHI170TajikistanLI
41Congo, Rep.LMI106MadagascarLI171TanzaniaLI
42Costa RicaUMI107MalawiLI172ThailandUMI
43Cote d’IvoireLMI108MalaysiaUMI173Timor-LesteLMI
44CroatiaHI109MaldivesUMI174TogoLI
45CubaHI110MaliLI175TongaUMI
46CuracaoHI111MaltaHI176Trinidad and TobagoHI
47CyprusHI112Marshall IslandsUMI177TunisiaLMI
48Czech RepublicHI113MauritaniaLMI178TurkeyUMI
49DenmarkHI114MauritiusUMI179TurkmenistanUMI
50DjiboutiLMI115MexicoUMI180TuvaluUMI
51DominicaUMI116MoldovaLMI181UgandaLI
52Dominican RepublicUMI117MongoliaLMI182UkraineLMI
53EcuadorUMI118MontenegroUMI183United Arab EmiratesHI
54Egypt, Arab Rep.LMI119MoroccoLMI184United KingdomHI
55El SalvadorLMI120MozambiqueLI185UruguayHI
56Equatorial GuineaUMI121MyanmarLMI186UzbekistanLMI
57EstoniaHI122NamibiaUMI187VanuatuLMI
58EswatiniLMI123NauruUMI188Venezuela, RBUMI
59EthiopiaLI124NepalLI189VietnamLMI
60FijiUMI125NetherlandsHI190West Bank and GazaLMI
61FinlandHI126New ZealandHI191Yemen, Rep.LI
62FranceHI127NicaraguaLMI192ZambiaLMI
63French PolynesiaHI128NigerLI193ZimbabweLI
64GabonUMI129NigeriaLMI
65Gambia, TheLI130North MacedoniaUMI
Note: HI: High Income; LI: Low Income; LMI: Lower-middle Income; UMI: Upper-middle Income Source: Authors’ Compilations.

Notes

1
Measured by human development Index.
2
Measured by the average of the six dimensions of institutional quality.
3
See Appendix B Table A1 for the list of countries and their respective classifications.
4
Voice and accountability, rule of law, control of corruption, regulatory quality, government effectiveness and political stability.
5
This stepwise regression approach is taken to observe the marginal effect of each ICT indicator on inclusive growth and to avoid biased inferences due to high collinearity between MOB/FTEL (See Table 3).
6
Mean, minimum or maximum values can be used.

References

  1. Acemoglu, Daren, and Simon Johnson. 2005. Unbundling Institutions. The Journal of Political Economy 113: 949–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Acemoglu, Daren, and James Robinson. 2001. A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review 91: 938–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Acemoglu, Daren, and James Robinson. 2010. The role of institutions in growth and development. Review of Economics and Institutions 1: 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Acemoglu, Daren, and James Robinson. 2013. Why Nations Fail. London: Profile Books Ltd., vol. 2. [Google Scholar]
  5. Acemoglu, Daren, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson. 2005. Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. Handbook of Economic Growth 1: 385–472. [Google Scholar]
  6. Acemoglu, Daren, Simon Johnson, James Robinson, and Pierre Yared. 2009. Re-evaluating the Modernization Hypothesis. Journal of Monetary Economics 56: 1043–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Adam, Ibrahim Osman. 2020. Examining E-Government development effects on corruption in Africa: The mediating effects of ICT development and institutional quality. Technology in Society 61: 101245. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Adeleye, Bosede Ngozi. 2021. Unbundling Interest Rate and Bank Credit Nexus on Income Inequality: Structural Break Analysis from Nigeria. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 29: 63–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Adeleye, Ngozi, and Chiamaka Eboagu. 2019. Evaluation of ICT development and economic growth in Africa. NETNOMICS: Economic Research and Electronic Networking 20: 31–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Adeleye, Ngozi, Evans Osabuohien, and Ebenezer Bowale. 2017. The role of institutions in the finance-inequality nexus in Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of Contextual Economics 137: 173–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Adeleye, Bosede Ngozi, Festus Adedoyin, and Solomon Nathaniel. 2021a. The Criticality of ICT-Trade Nexus on Economic and Inclusive growth. Information Technology for Development 27: 293–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Adeleye, Bosede Ngozi, Arumugam Sankaran, Abdul Jamal, and Arjun K. 2021b. Internationalization–Industrial output nexus: Evidence from 15 late-industrialized economies. Journal of Public Affairs 22: e2658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Adusei, Michael, and Ngozi Adeleye. 2021. Corporate Disclosure and Credit Market Development. Journal of Applied Economics 24: 205–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Aghaei, Majid, and Mahdieh Rezagholizadeh. 2017. The impact of information and communication technology (ICT) on economic growth in the OIC Countries. Economic and Environmental Studies 17: 257–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ajide, Folorunsho, Tolulope Osinubi, and James Temitope Dada. 2021. Economic Globalization, Entrepreneurship, and Inclusive Growth in Africa. Journal of Economic Integration 36: 689–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Albiman, Masoud Mohammed, and Zunaidah Sulong. 2016. The role of ICT use to the economic growth in Sub Saharan African region (SSA). Journal of Science and Technology Policy Management 7: 306–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Alshubiri, Faris, Syed Ahsen Jamil, and Mohamed Elheddad. 2019. The impact of ICT on financial development: Empirical evidence from the Gulf Cooperation Council countries. International Journal of Engineering Business Management 11: 184797901987067. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Anand, Rahul, Saurabh Mishra, and Shanaka Peiris. 2013. Inclusive Growth: Measurement and Determinants. IMF Woking Paper, WP/13/135. Washington, DC: IMF, pp. 1–27. [Google Scholar]
  19. Appiah, Michael, Fanglin Li, and Doreen Idan Frowne. 2020. Financial Development, Institutional Quality and Economic Growth: Evidence from ECOWAS Countries. Organizations and Markets in Emerging Economies 11: 6–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Arogundade, Sodiq, Mduduzi Biyase, and Joel Eita. 2021. Foreign Direct Investment and Inclusive Human Development in Sub-Saharan African Countries: Domestic Conditions Matter. Economia Internazionale/International Economics 74: 463–98. [Google Scholar]
  21. Arogundade, Sodiq, Mduduzi Biyase, and Joel Eita. 2022a. Foreign direct investment and poverty in sub-Saharan African countries: The role of host absorptive capacity. Cogent Economics & Finance 10: 2078459. [Google Scholar]
  22. Arogundade, Sodiq, Mduduzi Biyase, and Santos Bila. 2022b. Be nice to thy neighbors: Spatial impact of foreign direct investment on poverty in Africa. Economies 10: 128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Aslam, Aribah, Amjad Naveed, and Ghulam Shabbir. 2021. Is it an institution, digital or social inclusion that matters for inclusive growth? A panel data analysis. Quality & Quantity 55: 333–55. [Google Scholar]
  24. Asongu, Simplice, and Agyenim Boateng. 2018. Introduction to Special Issue: Mobile Technologies and Inclusive Development in Africa. Journal of African Business 19: 297–301. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Asongu, Simplice, and Sara Le Roux. 2017. Enhancing ICT for inclusive human development in Sub-Saharan Africa. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 118: 44–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Asongu, Simplice, and Jacinta Nwachukwu. 2017. Foreign Aid and Inclusive Development: Updated Evidence from Africa, 2005–2012. Social Science Quarterly 98: 282–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Asongu, Simplice A., and Jacinta Nwachukwu. 2018. Openness, ICT and Entrepreneurship in Sub-Saharan Africa. Information Technology & People 31: 278–303. [Google Scholar]
  28. Azu, Nnanna, and Philip Nwauko. 2021. Evaluating the Effect of Digital Transformation on Improvement of Service Trade in West Africa. Foreign Trade Review 56: 430–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Batuo, Michael Enowbi. 2015. The role of telecommunications infrastructure in the regional economic growth of Africa. The Journal of Developing Areas 49: 313–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Baum, Christopher, Mark Schaffer, and Steven Stillman. 2003. Instrumental Variables and GMM: Estimation and Testing. Stata Journal 3: 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Baum, Christopher, Mark Schaffer, and Steven Stillman. 2007a. Enhanced Routines for Instrumental Variables/Generalized Method of Moments Estimation and Testing. Stata Journal 7: 465–506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Baum, Christopher, Mark Schaffer, and Steven Stillman. 2007b. ivreg2: Stata Module for Extended Instrumental Variables/2SLS, GMM and AC/HAC, LIML, and k-Class Regression. Boston: Boston College Department of Economics, Statistical Software Components, Stata, USA. [Google Scholar]
  33. Belanger, France, and Lemuria Carter. 2012. Digitizing Government Interactions with Constituents: An Historical Review of E-Government Research in Information Systems. Journal of the Association for Information Systems 13: 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Boschma, Ron, and Gianluca Capone. 2016. Relatedness and diversification in the European Union (EU-27) and European Neighbourhood Policy countries. Sage 34: 617–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Brahim, Mariem, and Houssem Rachdi. 2014. Foreign direct investment, institutions and economic growth: Evidence from the MENA region. Journal of Reviews on Global Economics 3: 328–39. [Google Scholar]
  36. Brynjolfsson, Erik, and Lorin Hitt. 2000. Beyond computation: Information technology, organizational transformation and business performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 23–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Butkiewicz, James, and Halit Yanikkaya. 2006. Institutional quality and economic growth: Maintenance of the rule of law or democratic institutions, or both? Economic Modelling 23: 648–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Cameron, Colin, and Pravin Trivedi. 2005. Microeconometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  39. Castells, Manuel. 1989. The Informational City: Information Technology, Economic Restructuring, and the Urban-Regional Process. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 234–35. [Google Scholar]
  40. Chavula, Hopestone. 2013. Telecommunications development and economic growth in Africa. Information Technology for Development 19: 5–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Compton, Ryan, and Bryan Paterson. 2016. Military spending and growth: The role of institutions. Defence and Peace Economics 27: 301–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Darusalam, Normah Omar, Marijj Janssen, Jamaliah Said, and Kazi Sohag. 2021. The influence of ICT diffusion and globalization on the quality of governance: A study using panel data from ASEAN countries. Information Development 39: 46–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Dedrick, Jason, Kenneth Kraemer, and Eric Chuan-Fong Shih. 2013. Information technology and productivity in developed and developing countries. Journal of Management Information Systems 30: 97–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Dholakia, Ruby Roy, and Bari Harlam. 1994. Telecommunications and economic development: Econometric analysis of the US experience. Telecommunications Policy 18: 470–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Driscoll, John, and Aart C. Kraay. 1998. Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimation with Spatially Dependent Panel Data. Review of Economics and Statistics 80: 549–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ebire, Kolawole, Saif Ullah, Bosede Ngozi Adeleye, and Muhammad Ibrahim Shah. 2021. Effect of Capital Flows on Financial Stability in Middle-Income Countries. Journal of Financial Regulation and Compliance 29: 491–513. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Ejemeyovwi, Jeremiah Ogaga, and Evans Osabuohien. 2020. Investigating the Relevance of Mobile Technology Adoption on Inclusive Growth in West Africa. Contemporary Social Science 15: 48–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Farole, Thomas, Andrés Rodríguez-Pose, and Michael Storper. 2011. Cohesion policy in the European Union: Growth, geography, institutions. JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies 49: 1089–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. George, Tayo, Anthony Onwumah, Mercy Ozoya, and Olawale Olonade. 2021. Good governance, social order, and development in Nigeria: The critical role of gender inclusion. African Journal of Reproductive Health 25: 201–8. [Google Scholar]
  50. Ghosh, Saibal. 2016. Does mobile telephony spur growth? Evidence from Indian states. Telecommunications Policy 40: 1020–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Gillman, Mark, Max Harris, and László Mátyás. 2004. Inflation and growth: Explaining a negative effect. Empirical Economics 29: 149–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Hall, Robert, and Charles Jones. 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Hdom, Hélde, and José Alberto Fuinhas. 2020. Energy Production and Trade Openness: Assessing Economic Growth, CO2 Emissions and the Applicability of the Cointegration Analysis. Energy Strategy Reviews 30: 100488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Hoechle, Daniel. 2006. Robust Standard Errors for Panel Regressions with Cross-Sectional Dependence. The Stata Journal 7: 281–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Iqbal, Nasir, and Vince Daly. 2014. Rent seeking opportunities and economic growth in transitional economies. Economic Modelling 37: 16–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Isola, Wakeel Atanda, Bosede Ngozi Adeleye, and Aminat Olayinka Olohunlana. 2020. Boardroom female participation, intellectual capital efficiency and firm performance in developing countries. Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Science 25: 413–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Jawaid, Tehsen, and Abdul Waheed. 2017. Contribution of international trade in human development of Pakistan. Global Business Review 18: 1155–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Johnson, Olawale. 2016. Information and Communication Technologies Adoption and Inclusive Growth: The ICT-Inclusive Growth Pyramid Approach. Master’s thesis, Economics and Development Studies, Covenant University, Ota, Nigeria. [Google Scholar]
  59. Jones, Eric. 1987. The European Miracle, Environments, Economies, and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  60. Jorgenson, Dale, and Kevin J. Stiroh. 2000. Raising the speed limit: US economic growth in the information age. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 125–2011. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Kim, Jinho, Jong Chool Park, and Timothy Komarek. 2021. The impact of Mobile ICT on national productivity in developed and developing countries. Information & Management 58: 103442. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Klasen, Stephan. 2010. Measuring and Monitoring Inclusive Growth: Multiple Definitions, Open Questions, and Some Constructive Proposals. ADB Sustainable Development Working Paper Series, No. 12; Mandaluyong City: Asian Development Bank. [Google Scholar]
  63. Koenker, Roger. 2005. Quantile Regression. New York: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  64. Koenker, Roger, and Gilbert Bassett. 1978. Regression Quantiles. Econometrica 46: 33–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Koenker, Roger, and Kevin F. Hallock. 2001. Quantile Regression. Journal of Econometrics Perspectives 15: 143–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Kong, Qunxi, Dan Peng, Yehui Ni, Xinyue Jiang, and Ziqi Wang. 2020. Trade Openness and Economic Growth Quality of China: Empirical Analysis Using ARDL Model. Finance Research Letters 38: 101488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Kpomblekou, Elom, and Kwami O. Wonyra. 2020. Spatial Diffusion of International Trade in West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU). Scientific African 7: e00295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Lucas, Robert E. 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics 22: 3–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Mansell, Robin. 1999. Information and communication technologies for development: Assessing the potential and the risks. Telecommunications Policy 23: 35–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Mansell, Robin, and Uta Wehn. 1998. Knowledge Societies: Information Technology for Sustainable Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  71. Marakbi, Réda, and Camélia Turcu. 2016. Corruption, institutional quality, and growth: A panel smooth transition regression approach. JEL Classification C 34: D73. [Google Scholar]
  72. Mbulawa, Strike. 2015. Determinants of economic growth in Southern Africa development community: The role of institutions. Applied Economics and Finance 2: 91–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Mohammed, Fathey, Othman Ibrahim, and Norafida Ithnin. 2016. Factors influencing cloud computing adoption for e-government implementation in developing countries: Instrument development. Journal of Systems and Information Technology 18: 297–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Musila, Jacob, and Zelealem Yiheyis. 2015. The impact of trade openness on growth: The case of Kenya. Journal of Policy Modeling 37: 342–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Nawaz, Saima, Nasir Iqbal, and Muhammad Arshad Khan. 2014. The impact of institutional quality on economic growth: Panel evidence. The Pakistan Development Review 53: 15–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Niebel, Thomas. 2018. ICT and Economic Growth—Comparing Developing, Emerging and Developed Countries. World Development 104: 197–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. North, Douglass. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  78. Ofori, Isaac Kwesi, and Simplice Asongu. 2021. ICT Diffusion, Foreign Direct Investment and Inclusive Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. Telematics Informatic 65: 101718. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Oliner, Stephen, and Daniel E. Sichel. 2000. The resurgence of growth in the late 1990s: Is information technology the story? Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 3–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press. [Google Scholar]
  81. Ongo, Emmanuel Nkoa, and Andrew Wujung Vukenkeng. 2014. Does gross capital formation matter for economic growth in the CEMAC Subregion? EuroEconomica 2: 79–88. [Google Scholar]
  82. Osabuohien, Evans. 2008. ICT and Nigerian Banks’ reforms: Analysis of anticipated impacts in Selected Banks. Global Journal of Business Research 2: 67–76. [Google Scholar]
  83. Oyinlola, Mutiu, Abdulfatai Adedeji, Modupe Bolarinwa, and Nafisat Olabisi. 2020. Governance, Domestic Resource Mobilization, and Inclusive Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economic Analysis and Policy 65: 68–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Papaioannou, Sotiris, and Sophia Dimelis. 2007. Information technology as a factor of economic development: Evidence from developed and developing countries. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 16: 179–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  85. Popelyshyn, Olha, Valentyna Tsap, Ingrid Pappel, and Dirk Draheim. 2019. On Leveraging the Potential of Open Data to Enhance Transparency and Accountability—A Case Study from Ukraine. Paper presented at the 2019 Sixth International Conference on eDemocracy & eGovernment (ICEDEG), Quito, Ecuador, April 24–26. [Google Scholar]
  86. Rana, N. P., Y. K. Dwivedi, and Dwivedi Williams. 2013. Analysing challenges, barriers and CSF of egov adoption. Transforming Government: People, Process and Policy 7: 177–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  87. Rauniyar, Ganesh P., and Ravi Kanbur. 2010. Inclusive Development: Two Papers on Conceptualization, Application, and the ADB Perspective. Ithaca: Cornell University. [Google Scholar]
  88. Rodrik, Dani. 2005. Growth Strategies. In Handbook of Economic Growth. Edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier B.V., vol. 1A, pp. 967–1014. [Google Scholar]
  89. Rodrik, Dani. 2006. Goodbye Washington consensus, hello Washington confusion? A review of the World Bank’s economic growth in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform. Journal of Economic Literature 44: 973–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2004. Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development. Journal of Economic Growth 9: 131–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Roller, Lars-Hendrik, and Leonard Waverman. 2001. Telecommunications infrastructure and economic development: A simultaneous approach. American Economic Review 91: 909–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Romer, Paul. 1986. Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94: 1002–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Ross, Michael. 2001. Does oil hinder democracy? World Politics 53: 325–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  94. Roztocki, Narcyz, Piotr Soja, and Heinz Roland Weistroffer. 2019. The role of information and communication Technologies in Socioeconomic development: Towards a multi-dimensional framework. Information Technology for Development 25: 171–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Saba, Charles Shaaba, and Nicholas Ngepah. 2021. ICT Diffusion, Industrialisation and Economic Growth Nexus: An International Cross-country Analysis. Journal of the Knowledge Economy 13: 2030–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  96. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, and Arvind Subramanian. 2013. Addressing the natural resource curse: An illustration from Nigeria. Journal of African Economies 22: 570–615. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  97. Sassi, Seifallah, and Mohamed Sami Ali. 2017. Corruption in Africa: What role does ICT diffusion play? Telecommunications Policy 41: 662–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  98. Sein, Maung, Devinder Thapa, Matthias Hatakka, and Øystein Sæbø. 2018. A Holistic Perspective on the Theoretical Foundations for ICT4D Research. Information Technology for Development 25: 7–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  99. Solow, Robert. 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  100. Sondermann, David. 2018. Towards More Resilient Economies: The Role of Well-Functioning Economic Structures. Journal of Policy Modeling 40: 97–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  101. Steinmueller, Edward. 2001. ICTs and possibilities for leapfrogging by developing countries. International Labour Review 140: 193–210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  102. Swan, T. W. 1956. Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic Record 32: 334–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  103. Tallon, Paul, and Kenneth L. Kraemer. 2000. Information technology and economic development: Ireland’s coming of age with lessons for developing countries. Journal of Global Information Technology Management 3: 4–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  104. Tella, Sherriffdeen, and Olorunfemi Alimi. 2016. Determinants of Inclusive Growth in Africa: Role of Health and Demographic Changes. African Journal of Economic Review IV: 138–46. [Google Scholar]
  105. Toader, Elena, Bogdan Narcis Firtescu, Angela Roman, and Sorin Gabriel Anton. 2018. Impact of information and communication technology infrastructure on economic growth: An empirical assessment for the EU countries. Sustainability 10: 3750. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  106. UNDP. 2019. Human Development Index. Available online: http://hdr.undp.org/sites/default/files/hdr2019_technical_notes.pdf (accessed on 16 February 2021).
  107. Van Ark, Bart, and Marcin Piatkowski. 2004. Productivity, innovation and ICT in Old and New Europe. International Economics and Economic Policy 1: 215–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  108. Van Dijk, Jan, and Kenneth Hacker. 2003. The digital divide as a complex and dynamic phenomenon. The Information Society 19: 315–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  109. Williamson, Claudia. 2009. Informal institutions rule: Institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice 139: 371–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  110. World Bank. 2020a. Worldwide Governance Indicators. Available online: http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=worldwide-governance-indicators (accessed on 16 February 2021).
  111. World Bank. 2020b. World Development Indicators. Available online: http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=world-development-indicators (accessed on 16 February 2021).
  112. Xing, Zhongwei. 2018. The impacts of Information and Communications Technology (ICT) and E-commerce on bilateral trade flows. International Economics and Economic Policy 15: 565–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  113. Zheng, Zhijie, Tapas Mishra, and Yibai Yang. 2020. Inflation and income inequality in a variety-expansion growth model with menu costs. Economics Letters 194: 109373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  114. Ziemba, Ewa, Tomasz Papaj, Rafal Żelazny, and Maria Jadamus-Hacura. 2016. Factors Influencing The Success Of E-Government. Journal of Computer Information Systems 56: 156–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  115. Zuiderwijk, Anneke, and Marijin Janssen. 2014. Open data policies, their implementation and impact: A framework for comparison. Government Information Quarterly 31: 17–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Institutional Quality and Inclusive Growth. Source: Authors’ computation using WGI and UNDP, 2019 dataset.
Figure 1. Institutional Quality and Inclusive Growth. Source: Authors’ computation using WGI and UNDP, 2019 dataset.
Economies 11 00124 g001
Table 1. Correlation Matrix (IQI and Institutional Variables).
Table 1. Correlation Matrix (IQI and Institutional Variables).
VariablesIQIPOLSRQROLVACGEFFCCORR
IQI1.000
POLS0.8001.000
RQ0.9210.5991.000
ROL0.9750.7440.8981.000
VAC0.8350.6620.7070.7751.000
GEFF0.9450.6670.9230.9270.6821.000
CCORR0.9560.7280.8540.9430.7440.911.000
Note: IQI = Institutional Quality Index; ROL = Rule of law; CCORR = Control of Corruption; VAC = Voice and Accountability; RQ = Regulatory Quality; Government Effectiveness, and Political Stability. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 2. PCA and Eigenvectors.
Table 2. PCA and Eigenvectors.
VariablesSample
PCA eigenvectors (highest)4.9444
Proportion explained0.8241
Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin0.8848
Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 3. Variables Description, Expected Signs and Sources.
Table 3. Variables Description, Expected Signs and Sources.
VariablesDescriptionSignSource
lnHDIHuman Development IndexN/AUNDP (2019)
IQI *Institutional Quality Index+Authors’ Computation
lnMOBMobile cellular subscriptions+World Bank (2020b) WDI
lnFTELFixed telephone subscriptions+World Bank (2020b) WDI
lnLABLabour force participation rate, total (% of total population ages 15+)+World Bank (2020b) WDI
lnGCFGross capital formation (% of GDP)+World Bank (2020b) WDI
INFLInflation, consumer prices (annual %)+World Bank (2020b) WDI
lnTRTrade (% of GDP)+World Bank (2020b) WDI
lnNETIndividuals using the Internet (% of population)+World Bank (2020b) WDI
Note: * Created using Principal Component Analysis from 6 governance indicators of World Governance Indicators (World Bank 2020a); UNDP = United Nations Development Programme; WDI = World Development Indicators. Source: Authors’ Compilations.
Table 4. Pairwise Correlation Analysis and Summary Statistics.
Table 4. Pairwise Correlation Analysis and Summary Statistics.
VariableslnHDIIQIlnMOBlnFTELlnLABlnGCFINFLlnTRlnNET
lnHDI1.000
IQI0.729 ***1.000
lnMOB0.071 ***−0.140 ***1.000
lnFTEL0.553 ***0.228 ***0.795 ***1.000
lnLAB−0.182 ***0.060 **−0.037−0.185 ***1.000
lnGCF0.034−0.0190.043 *−0.020.095 ***1.000
INFL−0.148 ***−0.281 ***0.137 ***0.036−0.0150.0021.000
lnTR0.342 ***0.398 ***−0.416 ***−0.176 ***−0.0070.127 ***−0.246 ***1.000
lnNET0.883 ***0.663 ***0.055 **0.443 ***−0.182 ***−0.014−0.1410.3041.000
Summary Statistics
Obs177318841834183617701648173117361652
Mean0.706035,446,9364,963,51762.07624.7064.44493.45346.109
Std. Dev.0.1512.2241.28 × 10819,765,27510.4638.7318.85257.29429.158
Minimum0.331−51600036.83−0.098−4.2980.20.25
Maximum0.9574.9971.75 × 1092.94 × 10889.0577.89254.949442.6299.702
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; ln = Natural logarithm; HDI = Human development index; IQI = Institutional quality index; MOB = mobile phone subscriptions; FTEL = fixed telephone subscriptions; GCF = Gross capital formation; LAB = labour force participation rate; INFL = Inflation rate; NET = individuals using the Internet. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 5. PSCC-Fixed Effects Results, Full Sample (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Table 5. PSCC-Fixed Effects Results, Full Sample (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Variables Mobile PhonesFixed Telephones
[1][2][3][4][5][6][7]
lnLAB−0.0769 ***−0.0680 ***−0.0623 ***−0.0615 ***−0.0742 ***−0.0672 ***−0.0682 ***
(−8.652)(−7.647)(−6.878)(−6.397)(−7.341)(−6.767)(−7.167)
lnGCF0.00453 *0.00488 **0.00444 *0.004280.00583 **0.00540 **0.00578 **
(1.808)(1.986)(1.730)(1.628)(2.385)(2.126)(2.142)
INFL0.000422 **0.000326 **0.000406 ***0.000410 **0.000324 **0.000411 **0.000421 **
(2.539)(2.215)(2.630)(2.572)(2.092)(2.513)(2.578)
lnTR−0.00522 ***−0.00722 ***−0.00730 ***−0.00698 ***−0.00519 ***−0.00545 ***−0.00519 ***
(−4.134)(−5.161)(−5.655)(−5.637)(−3.379)(−4.115)(−4.254)
lnNET0.0171 ***0.0138 ***0.0134 ***0.0137 ***0.0173 ***0.0167 ***0.0164 ***
(7.489)(6.977)(6.947)(6.344)(7.128)(7.393)(7.581)
IQI0.00660 *** 0.00614 ***−0.00280 0.00666 ***−0.0136
(5.865) (4.850)(−0.226) (5.278)(−1.450)
lnICT 0.0111 ***0.0103 ***0.0112 ***−0.00480 ***−0.00468 ***−0.00257 ***
(4.922)(4.288)(3.646)(−4.122)(−4.197)(−2.991)
IQI*lnICT 0.000561 0.00150 **
(0.726) (2.213)
Constant−0.116 ***−0.309 ***−0.318 ***−0.338 ***−0.0598 *−0.0874 ***−0.116 ***
(−3.149)(−6.206)(−5.861)(−4.561)(−1.697)(−2.640)(−2.984)
Year DummiesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations1322132013201320130213021302
Number of groups152152152152151151151
F-Statistic4.9 × 1061.383 × 1064.53 × 1062.774 × 1063.85 × 1061.972 × 10636,948
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; t-statistics in ( ); ln = Natural logarithm; HDI = Human development index; IQI = Institutional quality index; ICT = Information and communication technology; GCF = Gross capital formation; LAB = labour force participation rate; INFL = Inflation rate; TR = Trade openness; NET = Individuals using the Internet; Endogeneity corrected using one-period lag of the regressors. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 6. IV-GMM Results, Full Sample (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Table 6. IV-GMM Results, Full Sample (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Variables Mobile PhonesFixed Telephones
[1][2][3][4][5][6][7]
lnLAB−0.0630 ***−0.262−0.0626 ***−0.0610 ***0.0507 **−0.0450 ***−0.0453 ***
(−3.605)(−0.746)(−3.605)(−3.463)(2.265)(−2.802)(−2.828)
lnGCF0.0203 **0.2590.0187 *0.0191 **0.0008500.0240 **0.0221 **
(2.126)(0.939)(1.917)(1.967)(0.0634)(2.570)(2.340)
INFL0.0008800.02830.0006600.000805−0.00240 ***0.0005410.000441
(1.453)(1.014)(1.080)(1.312)(−3.528)(1.050)(0.835)
lnTR0.00274−1.0890.01180.01210.118 ***0.0304 ***0.0292 **
(0.288)(−0.979)(0.953)(0.994)(8.435)(2.604)(2.493)
lnNET0.176 ***0.548 *0.172 ***0.173 ***0.114 ***0.149 ***0.146 ***
(39.44)(1.734)(38.78)(38.17)(7.308)(30.73)(27.19)
IQI0.0288 *** 0.0294 ***0.00864 0.0269 ***0.0412 ***
(18.71) (19.42)(0.767) (17.05)(4.928)
lnICT −0.8600.00708 ***0.00673 ***0.0659 ***0.0194 ***0.0193 ***
(−1.059)(3.256)(2.973)(6.686)(12.23)(12.28)
IQI*lnICT 0.00128 * −0.000983 *
(1.846) (−1.885)
Constant−0.804 ***16.79−0.942 ***−0.950 ***−2.377 ***−1.178 ***−1.153 ***
(−8.893)(0.966)(−8.498)(−8.658)(−13.72)(−12.27)(−11.54)
Year DummiesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations1173116711711171114811541154
R-squared0.8700.8730.8710.8720.7610.8850.885
F-Statistic494.6123.671470.4445.5249.2521.8522.6
Hansen p-value0.2590.9980.3190.2990.1180.3400.374
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; t-statistics in ( ); ln = Natural logarithm; HDI = Human development index; IQI = Institutional quality index; ICT = Information and communication technology; GCF = Gross capital formation; LAB = labour force participation rate; INFL = Inflation rate; TR = Trade openness; NET = Individuals using the Internet; Endogeneity corrected using one-period lag of the regressors. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 7. Distributional Effects from Bootstrap SQREG Technique, Full Sample (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Table 7. Distributional Effects from Bootstrap SQREG Technique, Full Sample (Dep Var: lnHDI).
VariablesMobile Cellular Subscription Model
Q = 0.25Q = 0.50Q = 0.75Q = 0.25Q = 0.50Q = 0.75Q = 0.25Q = 0.50Q = 0.75
lnLAB−0.0361 **−0.0777 ***−0.0879 ***0.0198−0.0161−0.0287−0.0362 **−0.0807 ***−0.0975 ***
(−2.148)(−4.992)(−4.934)(0.810)(−0.717)(−1.366)(−2.241)(−4.262)(−5.589)
lnGCF0.005420.0268 ***0.0360 ***−0.004910.00314−0.0008620.008140.0289 ***0.0382 ***
(0.500)(3.211)(4.195)(−0.323)(0.267)(−0.116)(0.731)(3.072)(4.056)
INFL−0.001030.00172 **0.00169 ***−0.00293 *−0.00102−0.00125 **−0.001320.001520.00113 ***
(−0.688)(2.081)(3.849)(−1.693)(−1.183)(−2.367)(−0.911)(1.531)(2.855)
lnTR0.005530.00756 **0.004020.0383 ***0.0439 ***0.0311 ***0.0173 ***0.0170 ***0.0154 ***
(1.136)(2.326)(0.819)(4.187)(6.996)(5.558)(4.125)(4.031)(3.104)
lnNET0.192 ***0.171 ***0.153 ***0.233 ***0.210 ***0.194 ***0.186 ***0.168 ***0.146 ***
(31.15)(30.04)(29.68)(38.07)(54.04)(50.73)(32.35)(28.28)(26.30)
IQI0.0279 ***0.0267 ***0.0249 *** 0.01170.004090.0393 ***
(17.40)(22.56)(15.15) (0.956)(0.417)(3.229)
lnMOB 0.00763 ***0.00665 ***0.00624 ***0.00713 ***0.00540 ***0.00933 ***
(2.848)(3.048)(3.598)(3.451)(3.103)(4.913)
IQI*lnMOB 0.001050.00137 **−0.000862
(1.421)(2.275)(−1.186)
Constant−0.929 ***−0.719 ***−0.584 ***−1.500 ***−1.262 ***−1.044 ***−1.085 ***−0.835 ***−0.729 ***
(−11.24)(−9.501)(−8.321)(−11.42)(−10.20)(−10.76)(−14.01)(−8.257)(−9.349)
Year DummiesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Replications100100100100100100100100100
Observations132213221322132013201320132013201320
Fixed Telephone Subscription Model
lnLAB−0.0361 **−0.0777 ***−0.0879 ***0.02550.0161−0.00836−0.0139−0.0505 ***−0.0775 ***
(−1.965)(−4.336)(−4.207)(1.274)(0.693)(−0.409)(−0.767)(−3.375)(−5.803)
lnGCF0.005420.0268 ***0.0360 ***0.0008030.008980.003060.0007470.0333 ***0.0481 ***
(0.469)(2.914)(3.472)(0.0518)(0.819)(0.257)(0.0960)(4.104)(5.640)
INFL−0.001030.00172 **0.00169 ***−0.00231 **−0.00137−0.00158 **−0.00205 *0.0007270.000574 **
(−0.654)(2.577)(4.388)(−2.274)(−1.430)(−2.248)(−1.702)(0.878)(2.075)
lnTR0.005530.00756 **0.004020.0720 ***0.0588 ***0.0476 ***0.0263 ***0.0245 ***0.0193 ***
(1.217)(2.494)(0.866)(9.647)(11.39)(8.594)(5.527)(5.912)(4.279)
lnNET0.192 ***0.171 ***0.153 ***0.193 ***0.186 ***0.165 ***0.165 ***0.146 ***0.122 ***
(33.92)(26.79)(25.83)(26.75)(37.96)(23.95)(35.37)(21.91)(22.20)
IQI0.0279 ***0.0267 ***0.0249 *** 0.0502 ***0.0507 ***0.0535 ***
(18.01)(19.79)(13.85) (5.264)(5.544)(7.853)
lnFTEL 0.0236 ***0.0188 ***0.0183 ***0.0177 ***0.0161 ***0.0156 ***
(12.23)(10.17)(10.99)(9.669)(9.772)(13.31)
IQI*lnFTEL −0.00167 ***−0.00176 ***−0.00200 ***
(−2.663)(−3.044)(−4.558)
Constant−0.929 ***−0.719 ***−0.584 ***−1.764 ***−1.560 ***−1.267 ***−1.248 ***−1.058 ***−0.840 ***
(−10.66)(−7.894)(−6.476)(−20.36)(−15.00)(−12.89)(−12.84)(−13.52)(−13.29)
Year DummiesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Replications100100100100100100100100100
Observations132213221322130213021302130213021302
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; t-statistics in ( ); ln = Natural logarithm; HDI = Human development index; IQI = Institutional quality index; MOB = mobile phone subscriptions; FTEL = fixed telephone subscriptions; GCF = Gross capital formation; LAB = labour force participation rate; INFL = Inflation rate; TR = Trade openness; NET = individuals using the Internet. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 8. PSCC-Fixed Effects Results, Income Groups (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Table 8. PSCC-Fixed Effects Results, Income Groups (Dep Var: lnHDI).
VariablesMobile Phones ModelFixed Telephones Model
HighLowLower-MidUpper-MidHighLowLower-MidUpper-Mid
lnLAB0.0831 ***−0.492 ***−0.146 ***0.0664 *0.0793 ***−0.487 ***−0.147 ***0.0664 *
(5.305)(−10.22)(−7.179)(1.797)(5.458)(−13.32)(−5.405)(1.748)
lnGCF0.00346−0.00522 **0.0106 *0.00434 ***0.00384−0.00441 *0.0105 **0.00529 ***
(1.206)(−2.158)(2.016)(2.835)(1.410)(−2.016)(2.033)(2.993)
INFL0.0002840.000197 *0.0003450.000346 ***0.000476 **0.0001990.000370 *0.000352 ***
(1.495)(1.711)(1.396)(3.552)(2.110)(1.228)(2.011)(3.747)
lnTR−0.00254−0.000790−0.00106−0.000684−0.00163−0.0100 *−0.00210−0.00652 **
(−0.988)(−0.225)(−0.418)(−0.237)(−0.503)(−2.041)(−1.290)(−2.042)
lnNET0.0169 ***0.00587 *0.00332 **0.00554 *0.0142 *0.00725 **0.00504 ***0.00650 ***
(2.700)(1.942)(2.088)(1.984)(1.877)(2.077)(3.270)(2.786)
IQI0.0605 ***0.0589 **−0.0608 **−0.0525 ***0.0244 *0.0497 **−0.0795 ***−0.0151
(5.343)(2.368)(−2.286)(−2.771)(1.803)(2.731)(−3.880)(−1.519)
lnICT0.0137 ***0.001470.0143 *0.005340.00758 **−0.0108 ***0.0116 ***−0.00638
(3.837)(0.181)(1.875)(0.871)(2.026)(−4.542)(3.513)(−1.350)
IQI*lnICT−0.00331 ***−0.00271 *0.00401 **0.00312 ***−0.00116−0.00310 *0.00641 ***0.000979
(−5.109)(−1.743)(2.471)(2.758)(−1.448)(−1.784)(4.262)(1.599)
Constant−0.801 ***1.302 ***−0.187−0.708 ***−0.671 ***1.454 ***−0.105−0.512 ***
(−9.304)(4.592)(−1.547)(−3.093)(−6.489)(9.555)(−0.930)(−5.193)
Year DummiesYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
Observations449195327349447179327349
Groups4725394147243941
F-Statistic3598351714682275392321685542.28192358437
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; t-statistics in ( ); ln = Natural logarithm; HDI = Human development index; IQI = Institutional quality index; MOB = mobile phone subscriptions; FTEL = fixed telephone subscriptions; GCF = Gross capital formation; LAB = labour force participation rate; INFL = Inflation rate; TR = Trade openness; NET = individuals using the Internet. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Table 9. IV-GMM Results, Income Groups (Dep Var: lnHDI).
Table 9. IV-GMM Results, Income Groups (Dep Var: lnHDI).
VariablesMobile Phones ModelFixed Telephones Model
HighLowLower-MidUpper-MidHighLowLower-MidUpper-Mid
lnLAB−0.0410 ***−0.114 *−0.0243−0.0384 **−0.0172−0.0901−0.00853−0.0419 ***
(−3.524)(−1.809)(−0.901)(−2.399)(−1.322)(−0.621)(−0.326)(−2.827)
lnGCF0.00384−0.0350 *0.0291 **0.0218 *0.00920 *−0.467 ***0.0445 ***0.0217 *
(0.745)(−1.757)(2.217)(1.726)(1.800)(−3.310)(3.796)(1.792)
INFL−0.00495 ***0.00229 **0.0007420.00154 ***−0.00428 ***0.0175 ***0.0003880.00115 ***
(−7.253)(2.109)(0.633)(4.274)(−6.102)(2.812)(0.376)(3.476)
lnTR0.00727 ***−0.00850−0.005030.0186 ***0.0107 ***0.717 ***0.009200.0253 ***
(3.205)(−0.382)(−0.336)(3.118)(4.773)(3.275)(0.524)(4.936)
lnNET0.0825 ***0.108 ***0.104 ***0.129 ***0.0807 ***0.0818 ***0.0755 ***0.116 ***
(7.491)(8.998)(9.120)(14.67)(7.528)(3.334)(6.348)(12.61)
IQI0.0828 ***0.133−0.132 ***0.125 ***0.0743 ***−3.315 ***−0.0595 *0.0664 ***
(6.561)(0.816)(−3.315)(6.289)(7.190)(−3.135)(−1.889)(5.548)
lnICT0.0200 ***−0.002110.0174 ***0.00343 *0.0209 ***0.886 ***0.0327 ***0.00736 ***
(8.971)(−0.0774)(4.933)(1.953)(9.490)(3.264)(6.918)(4.620)
IQI*lnICT−0.00373 ***−0.009390.0106 ***−0.00692 ***−0.00372 ***0.289 ***0.00767 ***−0.00381 ***
(−4.824)(−0.917)(4.061)(−5.073)(−5.224)(3.125)(2.960)(−3.936)
Constant−0.731 ***−0.495−1.006 ***−0.838 ***−0.831 ***−12.37 ***−1.234 ***−0.843 ***
(−10.39)(−0.978)(−7.768)(−8.897)(−11.56)(−3.354)(−10.38)(−8.990)
Year DummiesYesYesYesYesYesNoYesYes
Observations402171289309400132289309
R-squared0.8140.4460.5260.7300.822−7.7350.5980.743
F-Statistic156.912.8631.4699.99140.65.43634.44132.0
Hansen p-value0.3040.05660.9450.08910.3740.1050.7550.116
Note: *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1; robust z-statistics in ( ); ln = Natural logarithm; HDI = Human development index; IQI = Institutional quality index; MOB = mobile phone subscriptions; FTEL = fixed telephone subscriptions; GCF = Gross capital formation; LAB = labour force participation rate; INFL = Inflation rate; TR = Trade openness; NET = individuals using the Internet. Source: Authors’ Computations.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Adeleye, B.N.; Arogundade, S.; Mduduzi, B. Empirical Analysis of Inclusive Growth, Information and Communication Technology Adoption, and Institutional Quality. Economies 2023, 11, 124. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11040124

AMA Style

Adeleye BN, Arogundade S, Mduduzi B. Empirical Analysis of Inclusive Growth, Information and Communication Technology Adoption, and Institutional Quality. Economies. 2023; 11(4):124. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11040124

Chicago/Turabian Style

Adeleye, Bosede Ngozi, Sodiq Arogundade, and Biyase Mduduzi. 2023. "Empirical Analysis of Inclusive Growth, Information and Communication Technology Adoption, and Institutional Quality" Economies 11, no. 4: 124. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11040124

APA Style

Adeleye, B. N., Arogundade, S., & Mduduzi, B. (2023). Empirical Analysis of Inclusive Growth, Information and Communication Technology Adoption, and Institutional Quality. Economies, 11(4), 124. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies11040124

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop