Revisiting M&M with Taxes: An Alternative Equilibrating Process
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Under-Leverage and Sticky Debt Puzzles
3. A Traditional Model of Debt Determination
4. A Debt Model with Recapitalization Costs in the Presence of a Takeover Market
5. Conclusions
Acknowledgments
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Almeida, Heitor, and Thomas Philippon. 2007. The risk-adjusted cost of financial distress. Journal of Finance 62: 2557–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baker, Malcolm, and Jeffrey Wurgler. 2002. Market timing and capital structure. Journal of Finance 57: 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- DeAngelo, Harry, and Ronald W. Masulis. 1980. Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxes. Journal of Financial Economics 8: 3–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- DeAngelo, Harry, Linda DeAngelo, and Toni M. Whited. 2011. Capital structure dynamics and transitory debt. Journal of Financial Economics 99: 235–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Desai, Mihir A., and Dhammika Dharmapala. 2009. Corporate tax avoidance and firm value. Review of Economics and Statistics 91: 537–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French. 2002. Testing tradeoff and pecking order predictions about dividends and debt. The Review of Financial Studies 15: 1–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fischer, Edwin O., Robert Heinkel, and Josef Zechner. 1989. Dynamic capital structure choice: Theory and tests. Journal of Finance 44: 19–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Flannery, Mark J., and Kasturi P. Rangan. 2006. Partial adjustment toward capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics 79: 469–506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John R. 2000. How big are the tax benefits of debt? Journal of Finance 55: 1901–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John R., and Campbell R. Harvey. 2001. The theory and practice of corporate finance: Evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics 60: 186–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John R., and Mark T. Leary. 2011. A review of empirical capital structure research and directions for the future. Annual Review of Financial Economics 3: 309–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John R., and Krishnamoorthy Narasimhan. 2004. Corporate Survival and Managerial Experiences during the Great Depression. Working Paper. Durham: Duke University. [Google Scholar]
- Graham, John R., and Alan L. Tucker. 2006. Tax shelters and corporate debt policy. Journal of Financial Economics 81: 563–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graham, John R., Mark H. Lang, and Douglas A. Shackelford. 2004. Employee stock options, corporate taxes, and debt policy. Journal of Finance 59: 1585–618. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Green, Richard C., and Burton Hollifield. 2003. The personal tax advantages of equity. Journal of Financial Economics 67: 176–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grier, Paul, and Paul Strebel. 1980. The empirical relationship between taxation and capital structure. Financial Review 15: 45–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hennessy, Christopher A., and Toni M. Whited. 2005. Debt dynamics. Journal of Finance 60: 1129–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huizinga, Harry, Luc Laeven, and Gaetan Nicodeme. 2008. Capital structure and international debt shifting. Journal of Financial Economics 88: 80–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ju, Nengjiu, Robert Parrino, Allen M. Poteshman, and Michael S. Weisbach. 2005. Horses and rabbits? Optimal dynamic capital structure from shareholder and manager perspectives. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 40: 259–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kayhan, Ayla, and Sheridan Titman. 2007. Firms’ histories and their capital structures. Journal of Financial Economics 83: 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Leary, Mark T., and Michael R. Roberts. 2005. Do firms rebalance their capital structure? Journal of Finance 60: 2575–619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lemmon, Michael L., Michael R. Roberts, and Jaime F. Zender. 2008. Back to the beginning: Persistence and the cross-section of corporate capital structure. Journal of Finance 63: 1575–608. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lin, Shannon, Naqiong Tong, and Alan L. Tucker. 2014. Corporate tax aggression and debt. Journal of Banking and Finance 40: 227–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mauer, David C., and Alexander J. Triantis. 1994. Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions: A dynamic framework. Journal of Finance 49: 1253–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miller, Merton H. 1963. The Corporate Income Tax and Corporate Financial Policies. In Commission on Money and Credit, Stabilization Policies. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. [Google Scholar]
- Miller, Merton H. 1977. Debt and taxes. Journal of Finance 32: 261–75. [Google Scholar]
- Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. American Economic Review 48: 261–97. [Google Scholar]
- Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1963. Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: A correction. American Economic Review 53: 433–43. [Google Scholar]
- Morellec, Erwan, and Norman Schürhoff. 2010. Dynamic investment and financing under personal taxation. Review of Financial Studies 23: 101–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Parrino, Robert, and Michael S. Weisbach. 1999. Measuring investment distortions arising from stockholder-bondholder conflicts. Journal of Financial Economics 53: 3–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rauh, Joshua D., and Amir Sufi. 2010. Capital structure and debt structure. Review of Financial Studies 23: 4242–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sametz, Arnold W. 1964. Trends in the volume of composition of equity finance. Journal of Finance 19: 450–69. [Google Scholar]
- Shivdasani, Anil, and Irina Stefanescu. 2010. How do pensions affect corporate capital structure decisions? Review of Financial Studies 23: 1287–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Taggart, Robert A., Jr. 1985. Secular Patterns in the Financing of US Corporations. In Corporate Capital Structures in the United States. Edited by Benjamin M. Friedman. New York: University of Chicago Press, pp. 13–80. [Google Scholar]
- Tserlukevich, Yuri. 2008. Can real options explain financing behavior? Journal of Financial Economics 89: 232–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Welch, Ivo. 2004. Capital structure and stock returns. Journal of Political Economy 112: 106–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Welch, Ivo. 2011. Two common problems in capital structure research: The financial-debt-to-asset ratio and issuing activity versus leverage changes. International Review of Finance 11: 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | The equilibrating force presented in this paper does not require the takeover firm to be a private equity firm. Other institutional investors are potential candidates. Moreover, still other investors—knowing that private equity and other takeover firms may act—may be incentivized to purchase the stocks of the sub-optimally capitalized firms, thus providing for an overall larger pool of capital to finance the purchase of these stocks. |
2 | The notion that external markets can influence the investing, financing, and other decisions of a firm (and, therefore, its value) is not novel. For example, the existence of a hostile takeover market is often cited as a reason for managers to limit their costly agency behaviors. Also, the equilibrating process in standard tradeoff models relies on the existence of a deep external debt marketplace that allows firms to increase their leverage in order to pocket the interest tax shield associated with debt financing. |
3 | While we focus our analysis on a shift in equity value combined with no change in debt usage; the analysis can be readily modified to accommodate a “blended” equilibrium capital structure occasioned by a smaller shift in equity value combined with some increase in debt usage. The under-leverage and sticky debt puzzles continue to be partly explained, at least for a cohort of firms, in this blended, equilibrating approach. |
4 | Again, we emphasize that these arguments might hold only for a cohort of firms—likely smaller firms whose equity purchase can be more readily financed by private equity and other takeover firms. However, the analysis may be applicable to larger firms if just a fraction of their outstanding stock is required to be purchased in order to gain outright control of their financing decisions. |
5 | |
6 | However, others argue that average debt ratios are not too low; see (Green and Hollifield 2003; Hennessy and Whited 2005; Ju et al. 2005). |
7 | See Graham and Leary (2011) for additional references. |
8 | Graham and Narasimhan (2004) document that debt ratios fell by about one third during the Great Depression, suggesting that debt usage may partly reflect managers’ personal experiences. Unfortunately, the literature addressing the persistence of debt levels across vast changes in corporate tax regimes is sparse. |
9 | However, several researchers aver that the speed of adjustment coefficient estimates in Fama and French (2002) are not statistically reliable. Also, some argue that partial adjustment models of within-firm capital structure are too weak to distinguish between leverage targeting and other financing motives. See Graham and Leary (2011) for a discussion of these issues. |
10 | For simplicity, we assume that the interest rate on bonds is identical to the firm’s cost of capital. Footnote 17 discusses alternative assumptions. |
11 | At the interior solution, B* = [(1 − θ)α]γ and X* = θr/γ, which implies that VCS* = −(1 − θ)2α/γ < 0. |
12 | The condition −θαX + [θr − γX]B < 0 ensures that asset values are lower in the presence of taxes than in the non-tax world. The condition is satisfied over the feasible range of B, 0 < B < BMAX. |
13 | The model in this section can be regarded as a static costly adjustment model within the more general class of tradeoff models. See Mauer and Triantis (1994) for a model of the interaction between a firm’s dynamic investment, operating, and financing decisions in the face of operating adjustment and recapitalization costs. See Fischer et al. (1989) for a model of dynamic capital structure choice in the presence of recapitalization costs. |
14 | The model can be generalized to include a recapitalization cost function that has a fixed component and a proportional factor that depends on the amount of debt usage. See footnote 17. |
15 | This fixed cost includes expenses relating to data analysis and trading costs associated with the acquisition of shares. |
16 | Increasing the level of debt is likely to raise the firm’s cost of capital. Let rk represent the cost of capital. If we assume that rk = r + r1(B), the model’s quantitative solutions will change but the implications discussed in the paper will remain intact. |
17 | Clearly the equity market valuation in (11) exceeds that in (12). |
18 | Once again, we emphasize that such an acquisition is more likely to occur for smaller firms since less takeover capital (which is in limited supply) is required for these firms. Likewise, we note that the standard tradeoff model requires the debt market to be sufficiently large to absorb a shift in firms’ debt utilization. When viewed in this way, the consequences of the standard model—like those of the approach assumed here—also may be tempered by the reality of limited capital. |
19 | One way to reformulate our model to address the issue of limited takeover capital and its effect on the change in share value is to ascribe a probability (<1) to the takeover market’s ability to acquire a sub-optimally capitalized firm’s equity. The consequence of such a reformulation is to reduce the jump in share price and, therefore, to retain some of the traditional tradeoff model’s requirement of new debt issuance in order for the firm to capture the tax shield. When the ability of the sub-optimally capitalized firm to issue debt is similarly attenuated by introducing an analogous probability reflecting the limited amount of capital available to fund new debt, the overall effect is an inability of firms to collectively capture the entirety of the tax shield. A potentially interesting inquiry concerns which firms capture the interest tax shield and which are left empty-handed in the face of constraints on equity and debt funding available in the takeover and credit markets, respectively. |
20 | The analysis underlying Equations (11) through (16) can be reworked so that the takeover firm borrows at r, buys the sub-optimal firm, recapitalizes it, and pays back the borrowing the next period. However, the ПPE > 0 condition becomes more complicated. |
21 | In this regard, the model implies that the stock value of a firm that does not recapitalize in the presence of a tax shield is not necessarily determined by the standard discounted cash flow model. |
22 | Fischer et al. (1989) find that even small recapitalization costs lead to wide swings in a firm’s debt ratio over time. |
23 | Again, this change in equity value could be assigned a probability that reflects the prospect of a takeover. This probability would be less than one due to limits on capital available to finance takeovers. Another reason that the true change in equity value may not be as large as reflected in Equations (17) and (18) is that investors may suspect that a takeover firm will not pass along all or part of the benefits of the tax shield to equity shareholders. For instance, it has been observed that private equity firms retain the surpluses from their takeover activities. [Analogously, one could opine that, under standard tradeoff models, predatory creditors may require that the lion’s share of the tax shield be passed along to them (presumably in the form of a higher coupon payment) before they provide the debt capital needed to unlock the tax shield.] The effect of takeover companies retaining all or part of the tax shield has the consequence of reducing the jump in equity value predicted by our model, which in turn requires that part of the shield be captured by the traditional tradeoff model’s approach of new debt issuance. |
24 | Again, the sizes of the equity price differential and the proportion of apparently sub-optimally capitalized firms depend on additional factors such as the size of the firm, its voting rights/controlling interest, the availability of equity takeover capital, the availability of capital to purchase new debt, the likelihood that the plausible jump in equity value will be passed along to shareholders by the takeover firm, and the demands of new creditors regarding their share of the benefits of the tax shield. |
© 2018 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Kopecky, K.J.; Li, Z.; Sugrue, T.F.; Tucker, A.L. Revisiting M&M with Taxes: An Alternative Equilibrating Process. Int. J. Financial Stud. 2018, 6, 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010010
Kopecky KJ, Li Z, Sugrue TF, Tucker AL. Revisiting M&M with Taxes: An Alternative Equilibrating Process. International Journal of Financial Studies. 2018; 6(1):10. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010010
Chicago/Turabian StyleKopecky, Kenneth J., Zhichuan (Frank) Li, Timothy F. Sugrue, and Alan L. Tucker. 2018. "Revisiting M&M with Taxes: An Alternative Equilibrating Process" International Journal of Financial Studies 6, no. 1: 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010010
APA StyleKopecky, K. J., Li, Z., Sugrue, T. F., & Tucker, A. L. (2018). Revisiting M&M with Taxes: An Alternative Equilibrating Process. International Journal of Financial Studies, 6(1), 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs6010010