4.1.2. Static Equilibrium Analysis of Enterprises
If we set , we can also obtain three equilibrium values , , and .
Proposition 4. Enterprises can reach a stable state at any value of if .
Proof of Proposition 4. When , then at any value of . □
Proposition 4 indicates that the enterprise can reach a stable state at any value of , but this is not necessarily an ESS.
Proposition 5. Enterprises can reach a stable state at if (i) , or (ii) and .
Proposition 6. Enterprises can reach a stable state at if (i) , or (ii) and .
Proof of Propositions 5 and 6. If
, we can obtain
and
from
. The derivative of
can be expressed as
The value of the derivative is discussed as follows:
- (1)
If , we can have , then is the stable point.
- (2)
If , we can have , then is the stable point.
- (3)
If , there are two scenarios to discuss:
- (i)
if , then , , is the stable point.
- (ii)
if , then , , is the stable point.
According to Propositions 5 and 6, we can learn that there are two ways to encourage enterprises to choose an active strategy. The first way is to make the indirect benefits of the enterprise exceed the costs, but this is uncontrollable. The second way is to increase the direct cost to the government or the fines on the enterprise. Increasing the direct cost paid by the government helps to supervise the behavior of enterprises and facilitate the relevant training from the perspective of incentives while increasing the fines imposed by the government on enterprises urges enterprises to choose active strategies from the perspective of punishment. □
4.1.4. Simulation Analysis
This section applies the method of system dynamics to simulate the evolution process of the system and uses simulation software Vensim to visualize the stability of the system. The parameter values of the model must meet the conditions
; we set the initial values of the following parameters:
,
,
,
,
, and
. As shown in
Figure 1, the system dynamics model contains two horizontal variables, two rate variables, four intermediate variables, and eight external variables.
It can be seen from
Figure 2 that the game evolution trend of the whole system is a closed rail line ring with periodic movement around the stable center. The game between the local government and enterprises shows an unstable periodic behavior pattern, and the game behavior is not easy to control, indicating that the local government and enterprises are constantly changing their strategies in the process of promoting the bridge employment of the elderly.
If
and
, assuming that the initial probability of the government actively implementing the bridge employment policy
, the initial probabilities of enterprises actively responding to the policy are
and
, respectively. The evolution path of enterprises is shown in
Figure 3a. Assuming that the initial probability of the government adopting active strategy
, the evolution curve of enterprises is shown in
Figure 3b. On the whole, with a given
value and different initial values of
, the evolution path of the enterprise shows periodic fluctuation over time without an evolutionary equilibrium point. In terms of the fluctuation amplitude of the curve, the difference between
Figure 3a,b is not so obvious.
If
and
, assuming that
is the initial probability of the enterprise actively responding to the government’s bridge employment policy, and the initial probability of the local government actively implementing the bridge employment policy is
and
, respectively. The evolution curves of the government’s choice of active strategy are shown in
Figure 3c. Assuming that
is the initial probability of the enterprise adopting an active strategy, the evolution curves of the government are shown in
Figure 3d. On the whole, with a given
value and different initial values of
, the evolution path of the government fluctuates periodically over time, and there is no evolutionary equilibrium point. In terms of the fluctuation amplitude of the evolutionary path, there are obvious differences between
Figure 3c,d. The fluctuation amplitude of
Figure 3c is larger, and the two curves are close to overlapping at the end.
Figure 3 shows that the evolution paths of the game between the government and enterprises vary from different initial values of
and
, but both of them show periodic fluctuations over time and cannot be stable. Specifically, when one party’s strategy changes, the other will adjust its strategy to the other’s strategy.
According to the system dynamics model in
Figure 1, the simulation process of Vensim software indicates that the values of
,
,
, and
will cause significant changes in the evolution path of
and
. Therefore, we vary the values of these four parameters to simulate the changes in government and enterprise behaviors under different circumstances. Under the constraints of
and
, we set the initial values
and
.
Figure 4 presents the impact of the size of the direct costs paid by the government on the evolutionary paths of both parties. It indicates that the increase in
will accelerate the evolution rate of both parties and reduce the probability of them choosing active strategies, but it cannot promote them to reach a stable state.
Figure 5 depicts the impact of the size of indirect benefits on the evolutionary path. For the government, an increase in
makes the amplitude of the curve smaller, and the peaks and troughs move down. It means that the evolution rate of the government will rise with the increase in
, and the probability of the government choosing the active strategy will decrease significantly. As for enterprises, the increase in
shortens the wavelength of the curve, but the changes in amplitude, crest, and trough are relatively insignificant. This means that the increase in
will help accelerate the evolution of the enterprise.
Figure 6 shows the impact of the cost paid by the enterprise on the evolutionary path. In
Figure 6a, there are obvious differences among the three evolutionary paths. With the increase in
, the wavelength becomes shorter, but the amplitude increases, and both the peak and trough of the wave increase significantly. It shows that with the increase in enterprise cost, the probability of the government choosing an active strategy increases. In
Figure 6b, the peaks, troughs, and amplitudes of the three curves do not differ significantly, but the wavelength becomes slightly shorter as
increases. It means that as the cost to an enterprise increases, the rate of evolution of the enterprise also increases slightly.
Figure 7 illustrates the impact of fines on the evolutionary path. In
Figure 7a, as
increases, the wavelength of the curve becomes smaller, and the curve moves downward as a whole. It shows that the increase in fines will increase the rate of government evolution and reduce the probability of active strategy. In
Figure 7b, the wavelength of the curve becomes shorter with the increase in
, but contrary to
Figure 7a, the curve moves up as a whole. It implies that the increase in fines will accelerate the evolution of enterprises and increase the probability of enterprises choosing active strategies.
In general, with an increase in the government’s direct cost (), the enterprise’s indirect income () and fines () will accelerate the evolution rate of the government, while with a decrease in the government’s direct cost, the increase in the enterprise’s indirect income, the increase in the enterprise’s cost (), and the decrease in fines will increase the probability of the government choosing an active strategy. Concerning enterprises, the increase in the government’s direct cost, enterprise’s indirect profit, and enterprise’s cost and fines will improve the rate of the enterprise’s evolution, while the decrease in the government’s direct cost and the increase in fines will improve the probability of enterprises choosing active strategies. Although these four parameters affect the evolution path of both parties to some extent, these changes cannot make the system reach a stable and optimal state.