A Note on the Core of TU-cooperative Games with Multiple Membership Externalities
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. A Worked Example
2.1. Oligopoly Externalities
2.2. Two-firm, Two-market Numerical Illustration
Industry configuration | Profits (scaled ) | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
market 1 | market 2 | market 1 | market 2 | |
mergers: | ||||
none | (1),(2) | (1),(2) | 4, 1 | 1, 4 |
market 1 | (1,2) | (1),(2) | 4.75 | , |
market 2 | (1),(2) | (1,2) | , | 4.75 |
full merger | (1,2) | (1,2) | 5.25 | 5.25 |
3. The Model
3.1. Externalities
3.2. Feasible Deviations
- Max rule [10]: , taking as given, organizes itself to in order to maximize ’s total worth
- Optimistic [23]: organizes and forms in order to maximize S’s total worth
- Projective [20]: all such that remain organized in the same way, all other coalitions from which members in S deviated form coalitions amongst the remaining
3.3. Superadditivity
4. Coalitional Stability and the Core
4.1. Core Stability
- Z-core:
- Given Z, the Z-core of forming the efficient society of with total payoff allocation x is
- Theorem.
- The Z-core of is nonempty if, and only if, its conjectured worth function z is balanced.
- Characteristic 1:
- If the cores of a superadditive MMG layer-by-layer separately are nonempty, the Z-core of the whole MMGs is also nonempty.While z is always additive over coalitions and layers, v does not need to be additive when externalities are present. In every layer, superadditivity implies that it is beneficial for members of any to form the largest possible coalition . Hence, whenever x is in a Z-core, . Now, describes the game described by the conjectured worth function of layer k, i.e., the conjectured CFG view of layer k. Given any , a core stable allocation of forming the grand coalition in that layer exists if, and only if, every is balanced. Since the sum of balanced games is balanced, the Z-core of is, therefore forcedly, nonempty when all s are balanced.
- Characteristic 2:
- In the presence of cross externalities but without partition and partition-cross externalities, the core is unambiguously defined (independent of conjecture).In the absence of partition and partition-cross externalities, in a society that is separable into and , the worth of any is independent of in all layers: for all coalitions, layers and societies provided , and . Therefore, one unique game described by a characteristic worth function is derived, which implies one unambiguous definition of the core. This unambiguity is independent of the existence of cross externalities that are not partition-cross because deviators endogenize all other cross external variations that may still exist and affect them. The need to conjecture is therefore inherent to the presence of PFG-type (partition and partition-cross) externalities. The core of example 1, for instance, is unambiguously defined.
- Characteristic 3:
- In the presence of positive cross externalities, the core of the MMG may be nonempty even if coalition formation in any of the layers is, ceteris paribus, never beneficial.Example 1 as described by Table 1 illustrates this.
- Characteristic 4:
- In the presence of negative cross externalities, the core of forming the grand coalition in any layer of the MMG may be empty even if coalition formation in all layers is, ceteris paribus, always beneficial.
- Example 2:
- Let and v be described by Table 2.Holding the coalition structure of one layer fixed, any coalition formation in the other layer is beneficial. However, due to the negative cross externality of coalition formation in one layer on the other, the total worth of all coalitions is reduced as coalitions form. The core of forming the grand coalition in one or both of the layers of example 2 is empty: .
Society | Coalition worth | ||
layer 1 | layer 2 | layer 1 | layer 2 |
(1),(2) | (1),(2) | 1, 1 | 1, 1 |
(1,2) | (1),(2) | 3 | 0, 0 |
(1),(2) | (1,2) | 0, 0 | 3 |
(1,2) | (1,2) | 1 | 1 |
- Characteristic 5:
- Multiple membership may facilitate cooperation not because of cross external effects but because the layers “balance each other": Even in the complete absence of externalities when all layers have empty cores, the core of an MMG may be nonempty.(See [13] “Examples 1 and 2” for a 4- and related 5-player examples.)
- Example 3:
- Let , and let there be no externalities so that the MMG is described by two 5-player CFGs, and . Let , (where ε is small) if and otherwise. Let , if and otherwise.is unbalanced: for the balanced collection of the 5 coalitions of size 4, , with balancing weights , . is unbalanced: for the balanced collection of the 10 coalitions of size 3, , with balancing weights , . However, it is easy to verify that is a core allocation of v: z associates , if , if and otherwise.
- Characteristic 6:
- The presence of positive (or negative) cross and/or partition externalities may lead to inefficient herding.
- Example 4:
- Let , and for all k, if and otherwise.The Pessimistic-core of forming the inefficient grand coalition in both layers is nonempty because player 1 expects to receive 0 from being the singleton in both layers, e.g., is such a Pessimistic-core allocation. Inefficient herding results from the positive externality: the formation of the coalition of (2,3) in both layers creates worth for player 1, but player 1 is too pessimistic to agree to stay separate. The same effect may be due to negative externalities as a simple variation of v illustrates: consider, for example, with for all k, if and otherwise.
5. Concluding Remarks
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- von Neumann, J.; Morgenstern, O. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1944. [Google Scholar]
- Lucas, W.; Thrall, R. n-Person Games in Partition Function Form. Nav. Res. Log. 1963, 10, 281–298. [Google Scholar]
- Maskin, E. Bargaining, coalitions and externalities. In Presidential Address to the Econometric Society; Institute for Advanced Study: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Haas, E.B. Why Collaborate? Issue-Linkage and International Regimes. World Polit. 1980, 32, 357–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Charnovitz, S. Linking Topics in Treaties. Univ. Pa. J. Int. Econ. Law 1998, 19, 329–345. [Google Scholar]
- Le Breton, M.; Moreno-Ternero, J.D.; Savvateev, A.; Weber, S. Stability and Fairness in Models with a Multiple Membership. Int. J. Game Theory 2013, 42, 242–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gillies, D.B. Solutions to general non-zero-sum games. In Contributions to the Theory of Games 4; Kuhn, H., Tucker, A., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1959; pp. 47–85. [Google Scholar]
- Shapley, L.S. Notes on the n-person game III: Some variants of the von Neumann-Morgenstern definition of solution. In Rand Memorandum; The Rand Corporation: Santa Monica, CA, USA, 1952. [Google Scholar]
- Hafalir, I.E. Efficiency in Coalition Games with Externalities. Games Econ. Behav. 2007, 61, 242–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloch, F.; van den Nouweland, A. Expectation formation rules and the core of partition function games. Games Econ. Behav. 2014, in press. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bondareva, O.N. Applications of Linear Programming Methods to the Theory of Cooperative Games. Probl. Kybern. 1963, 10, 119–139. (in Russian). [Google Scholar]
- Shapley, L.S. On Balanced Sets and Cores. Nav. Res. Log. 1967, 14, 453–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloch, F.; de Clippel, G. Cores of Combined Games. J. Econ. Theory 2010, 145, 2424–2434. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Diamantoudi, E.; Macho-Stadler, I.; Perez-Castrillo, D.; Xue, L. Sharing the surplus in games with externalities within and across issues. In IAE Working Paper 880; Barcelona Graduate School of Economics: Barcelona, Spain, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Shapley, L.S. A value for n-person games. In Contributions to the Theory of Games 2; Kuhn, H., Tucker, A., Eds.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1953; pp. 307–317. [Google Scholar]
- Tijs, S.; Branzei, R. Additive Stable Solutions on Perfect Cones of Cooperative Games. Int. J. Game Theory 2002, 31, 469–474. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloch, F. Sequential formation of coalitions in games with externalities and fixed payoff division. Games Econ. Behav. 1996, 14, 90–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ray, D.; Vohra, R. A Theory of Endogenous Coalition Structures. Games Econ. Behav. 1999, 26, 286–336. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aumann, R. A survey of cooperative games without side payments. In Essays in Mathematical Economics; Shubik, M., Ed.; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1967. [Google Scholar]
- Hart, S.; Kurz, M. Endogenous formation of coalitions. Games Econ. Behav. 1983, 51, 1047–1064. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- de Clippel, G.; Serrano, R. Marginal contributions and externalities in the value. Econometrica 2008, 76, 1413–1436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chander, P.; Tulkens, H. The core of an economy with multilateral environmental externalities. Int. J. Game Theory 1997, 26, 379–401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shenoy, P. On coalition formation: A game theoretical approach. Int. J. Game Theory 1979, 8, 133–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
© 2014 by the authors; licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license ( http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Nax, H.H. A Note on the Core of TU-cooperative Games with Multiple Membership Externalities. Games 2014, 5, 191-203. https://doi.org/10.3390/g5040191
Nax HH. A Note on the Core of TU-cooperative Games with Multiple Membership Externalities. Games. 2014; 5(4):191-203. https://doi.org/10.3390/g5040191
Chicago/Turabian StyleNax, Heinrich H. 2014. "A Note on the Core of TU-cooperative Games with Multiple Membership Externalities" Games 5, no. 4: 191-203. https://doi.org/10.3390/g5040191
APA StyleNax, H. H. (2014). A Note on the Core of TU-cooperative Games with Multiple Membership Externalities. Games, 5(4), 191-203. https://doi.org/10.3390/g5040191