1. Introduction
China is a major player in the global economy, particularly in terms production and consumption of forest products. The country’s trade model, which involves the import of substantial quantities of raw materials and the export of a significant volume of manufactured goods, serves as a prime example of the global value chain paradigm [
1,
2]. This paradigm is characterized by substantial intermediate inputs, trade, and cross-border production sharing. Nevertheless, compared with developed countries, China’s forestry industry continues to encounter challenges characterized by inadequate forest resources, low efficiency, and diminished core competitiveness [
3]. The ongoing decline in fertility rates and the accelerated aging of the population have led to indications of a labor shortage in China, which poses a considerable challenge to the labor-intensive forestry industry. The global economic slowdown has resulted in persistent trade frictions, the process of economic globalization has encountered heightened resistance, and China is no longer experiencing robust external demand. The expansion momentum of global value chains has been observed to weaken in the context of the intertwined influences of trade protectionism, the global epidemic, and geo-political conflicts. Furthermore, China’s economic transition towards high-quality development implies that the potential for economic growth through large-scale infrastructure construction has diminished. Consequently, the demand for bulk raw materials, driven by this shift, is expected to reach a steady state over time. The past linear growth trend has come to an end, and the breathtaking expansion of China’s imported timber market is over [
4]. In light of the challenges posed by inadequate domestic timber resources, substandard timber quality, and structural deficiencies, China’s forestry management authority has demonstrated a resolute commitment to enhancing timber supply capacity and efficiency. This commitment is evidenced by the establishment of national reserve forests, the reform of collective forest rights, the precise improvement of forest quality, and the optimization of harvesting management in commercial forests [
5,
6]. Since 2012, China has established over 61.8 million acres of national reserve forests, yielding a cumulative timber yield of approximately 150 million m
3. During the 14th Five-Year Plan period, China intends to complete the construction of an additional 24.5 million acres of national reserve forests, which is expected to increase the reserve forest stock by 70 million m
3 [
7]. Nevertheless, it is not feasible to depend exclusively on the anticipated yield of national reserve forests to ascertain that domestic timber exerts an equivalent crowding-out effect on imported timber. This is due to the fact that trading behavior is spontaneous in the market, and price, quality, and quantity are all salient influencing factors that link supply and demand.
China’s timber supply and demand have been the subjects of ongoing research, particularly with regard to the stability of timber imports, and the substitution of foreign timber with domestic timber [
8,
9]. These issues continue to be a focal point within the academic community. China’s reliance on foreign timber is contingent upon its stage of economic development and the dearth of domestic forest resources [
10]. The ongoing increase in China’s timber imports is primarily driven by the country’s expanding demand for timber in infrastructure projects [
11]. Under the influence of the improvement of forest management and the reform of collective forest tenure rights, China’s forest area and stock have continued to grow. While the timber supply capacity has shown steady improvement, a prevailing concern pertains to the substantial presence of young and middle-aged forests, which has led to a disproportionate focus on the supply of smaller-diameter timber. This has consequently resulted in an under-supply of large-diameter timber, and the market demand for timber may be met after a long period of recuperation of forest resources. Concurrently, China’s substantial bamboo resources possess the capacity to substitute for timber in significant amounts [
12]. The patterns and characteristics of China’s timber imports and their impact on trading partners have generated significant academic interest on the international stage. In consequence of their comparative advantage, certain timber-producing countries have undergone a shift in their export patterns, favoring rough, processed products [
13]. This development has led to an improvement in economic benefits for timber exporters. However, China, leveraging its position within the global value chain, possesses the capacity to exert a positive influence on forest governance practices in upstream timber-producing countries [
14]. A comparison of China’s radiata pine (
Pinus radiata) imports with those of Japan and Korea reveals distinct market characteristics. China’s imports exhibit a lower price elasticity and a higher output elasticity. The primary applications of radiata pine imports in China are for building formwork and scaffolding. However, the reuse rate remains low [
15,
16]. An analysis of China’s timber imports reveals that the country’s expenditure on imported softwood is less elastic than its expenditure on imported tropical timber. Furthermore, softwood and tropical timber are substitutes for each other. There is also a strong substitution between logs and sawn timber of the same species. The price elasticity of China’s sawn timber import demand is high; however, sawn timber exporters possess greater bargaining power compared to log exporters. China’s demand for Canadian sawn timber exhibits a high elasticity, and Canadian and Russian sawn timber are substitutes for each other [
17].
The market pattern of China’s substantial imports of timber is unlikely to undergo a swift transformation in the near future. The enhancement of the quality and efficiency of the domestic timber supply is a gradual process. The decision to engage in import substitution is ultimately determined by market forces, and the feasibility of such actions is contingent on the comparative quality and cost of domestic and imported timber. In the event that domestic wood producers offer large-diameter timber of equivalent quality to that of imported timber, price will become the primary consideration for market participants. Consequently, as the price of the commodity decreases, demand will increase. Conversely, if the quality of timber provided by domestic wood producers significantly deviates from that of imported timber, market participants will continue to favor the importation of timber. In the context of complex supply shocks (e.g., national reserve forest policy) and demand shocks (e.g., housing market downturns), examining the potential responses of China’s timber market is advantageous for policymakers and the business community to discern risks and opportunities, which is of practical significance. The Global Forest Products Model (GFPM) is a widely used tool to assess global forest policy issues [
18]. In essence, it is based on spatial equilibrium frameworks for commodity trade [
19]. That is, GFPM maximizes the global sum of the consumer and producer surpluses minus trade margins to obtain market equilibrium solutions. However, one of its key assumptions is product homogeneity, which means products from different sources are perfect substitutes. But this may not hold true for the Chinese wood market [
20].
The primary contribution of this paper is its incorporation of a modeling feature that facilitates the reflection of differences between domestic timber and imported timber, as well as between imported logs and lumber. This approach offers a multifaceted, comprehensive perspective, facilitating analysis of the dynamics within China’s wood market from diverse vantage points and at varied levels of granularity. In the context of the modeling efforts aimed at enhancing the capture of the characteristics inherent to the Chinese wood market, this study endeavors to provide an answer to the following question: What if the Chinese forestry sector were to augment its domestic timber supply in the face of adjustments within the housing sector? This question is of paramount importance, as it pertains to critical policy implications that necessitate rigorous academic scrutiny.
3. Results
Four scenarios were considered in this study and classified into three categories: supply shocks, demand shocks, and supply–demand shocks. The supply shock comprises two scenarios: the enhancement of the supply capacity of domestic small-diameter timber (S1) and the enhancement of the supply capacity of domestic large-diameter timber (S2). The demand shock is defined as a scenario in which the demand from the downstream sector of timber decreases (S3). The superimposed impact of supply and demand shocks is the enhancement in the domestic timber supply capacity and a concurrent decline in the demand for timber from the downstream industry (S4). It should be noted that a change in supply capacity does not constitute a direct and equal change in the supply of wood. Rather, it pertains to the shift in the supply curve of wood. This is due to the fact that the supply of wood is an endogenous variable that necessitates resolution within the model. Similarly, a change in demand of the downstream sector does not refer to a direct and equal change in timber demand. Instead, it refers to a shift in the timber demand curve. Timber demand, as an endogenous variable, must be solved within the model.
Table 1 presents the specific meanings of four scenarios, and the percentage of the impact reflects the planning targets of the national reserve forest project and the trend of China’s real estate sector. The potential annual timber yield of national reserve forest is estimated to be 10 million m
3, which is about 10% of China’s annual timber production in recent years. China’s timber import volume in 2022 is about 81 million m
3 (roundwood equivalency), and it is estimated to be no more than 74 million m
3 in 2025 due to sluggish housing market, coupled with the weak external demand for China’s manufactured forest products; a 10% drop in downstream sector’s demand for timber is highly possible. For the sake of brevity, we will make a detailed analysis of the changes in the equilibrium quantity in following subsections, and the changes in the equilibrium price are provided in
Appendix C.
3.1. Improvements of the Supply Capacity of China’s Domestic Timber
The first two scenarios are analyzed in this subsection. To begin with, the impact of a 10% increase in the supply capacity of domestic small-diameter timber on China’s timber market pattern is analyzed according to scenario 1. The simulation results indicate that under the new equilibrium state, the demand for domestic small-diameter timber exhibited an increase of 6.6% compared with the initial status, while the demand for domestic large-diameter timber decreased by 0.7%, and the total demand for domestic timber increased by 4.4%. As shown in
Table 2, the impact on imported timber is further illustrated. The demand for all imported timber has declined due to the increased supply of domestic timber. This has led to a depression in the price of domestically produced timber, which has resulted in a shift in demand from imported timber to domestically produced timber.
Specifically, among China’s import sources for coniferous logs, Oceania and Europe exhibit a substantial change, with a decline of 1.4% and 1.1%, respectively. In the context of China’s import demand for coniferous sawn timber, Russian lumber experience a 1.4% decline, a figure that stands in stark contrast to the reductions observed in other sources. Within China’s import demand for non-coniferous logs, excluding Asia, there is a notable decrease in quantities from other regions, particularly Oceania, which witnesses a 1% reduction. Notably, Asia emerges as the primary driver of the substantial shift in China’s non-coniferous sawn timber import demand, with a 1.2% decline. The percentage change in imports by species can be calculated by determining the weighted average of the percentage change by source, using the share of each source as its weight. Consequently, China’s total imports of coniferous logs and sawn timber experience a 1.1% and 1.2% decline, respectively, while total imports of non-coniferous logs and sawn timber decrease by 0.8% and 0.9%, respectively. When sawn timber is converted to log equivalent at a factor of 1.42, a customary practice among China’s timber trade association [
25], the total amount of imported timber declines by 1.1%. When the changes in the volume of domestic and imported timber are considered, the total demand for timber in the Chinese market increases by 2%.
Furthermore, the impact of a 10% increase in the supply capacity of domestic large-diameter timber under scenario 2 is examined. Given the fundamental characteristics of China’s domestic timber supply, namely its inadequate total quantity and structural shortage, especially the paucity of large-diameter timber, enhancing the domestic supply capacity of large-diameter timber would serve to alleviate the structural imbalances of China’s timber market to a certain extent. From the perspective of the market performance of domestic timber, the demand for domestic large-diameter timber exhibits an 8.5% increase, while the demand for domestic small-diameter timber demonstrates a 1.8% decrease. Consequently, the total demand for domestic timber experiences a 1.3% increase. A comparison of the enhancement in the supply capacity of small logs with the market performance of large-diameter timber under scenario 2 reveals that the latter is more noteworthy. The extrusion effect on domestic small-diameter timber is more pronounced, which also reflects the inelasticity of domestic large-diameter timber supply. The initial supply of large-diameter timber is constrained, resulting in a change in domestic timber supply that is smaller than in scenario 1. However, the optimization of the domestic timber supply structure is evident.
As illustrated in
Table 3, the specific changes in the importation of timber under scenario 2 are evident. The augmentation in the availability of domestic large-diameter timber prompts a shift in market demand, with a transition from imported timber to domestic timber. The substitution effect of domestic timber on imported timber is more pronounced in this scenario compared to scenario 1, signifying that diameter class is a pivotal factor for market buyers when deliberating between domestic timber and imported timber. Specifically, China’s import demand for coniferous wood witnesses a 1.6% decrease in logs from Oceania and a 1.3% decrease in logs from Europe. These declines are more significant than those observed for other sources. In the import demand for coniferous sawn timber, Russian and European lumber decrease by 1.6% and 1%, respectively. The Oceania region experiences a 1.2% decrease in the import demand for non-coniferous logs, while logs from Europe, Africa, and Russia also exhibit significant declines. Notably, China’s non-coniferous sawn timber import demand demonstrates the most significant decrease, reaching 1.4%. On the basis of the breakdown data, the importation of coniferous logs, coniferous lumber, non-coniferous logs, and non-coniferous sawn timber demonstrate respective decreases of 1.3%, 1.4%, 0.9%, and 1.1%. The quantity of all imported timber in terms of log equivalency decreases by 1.2%. Combined with the changes in domestic timber demand, it is concluded that the total timber demand in the Chinese market increases by 0.2%. When considered in conjunction with shifts in domestic timber demand, it is determined that the aggregate timber demand within the Chinese market experiences an increase of 0.2%. Given that the base level of domestic large-diameter timber is considerably lower than that of small-diameter timber, enhancing domestic large-diameter timber supply capacity exerts a greater extrusion effect on the market demand for domestic small-diameter timber and imported timber, particularly the former.
3.2. The Impact of Declining Demand for Timber in Downstream Sectors
In Scenario 3, the impact of a 10% decline in downstream timber demand on China’s timber market is examined. It is important to note that our model has the capacity to differentiate between the impact of heterogeneous changes in the downstream demand for domestic and imported timber. However, in order to simplify the explanations, we have set the same demand shocks for both domestic and imported timber. The simulation results indicate a decline in demand for domestic small-diameter timber of 6%, a decrease in demand for domestic large-diameter timber of 2.6%, and a total decrease in domestic timber demand of 5%.
Table 4 shows the impact of demand shocks on timber imports. Specifically, imports of coniferous logs from Oceania and Europe have decreased by 12.4% and 10.3%, respectively. In the context of China’s demand for coniferous sawn timber, imports from Russia and Europe experience a decline of 12.9% and 7.8%, respectively. This decline is notably more substantial than that observed for other sources. In the context of China’s demand for non-coniferous logs, with the exception of Asia, there has been a substantial decline in the volume from all sources, particularly Oceania, which has experienced a decrease of 10.7%. For China’s non-coniferous sawn timber imports, Asia experiences the most substantial shift among all import sources, with a decline of 12.9%. Based on weighted averages, the respective decreases in imported coniferous logs, coniferous sawn timber, non-coniferous logs, and non-coniferous sawn timber are 10.5%, 10.8%, 8.4%, and 9.7%. The total log-equivalent quantity of imported timber decreases by 10.1%. Combined with the change in the amount of domestic timber, the aggregate demand for timber in the Chinese market experiences a 7.2% decline. It can be found that compared with domestic timber, imported timber demand is more sensitive to China’s macroeconomic condition, and its response to changes in downstream demand is stronger.
3.3. The Impact of Superimposed Supply and Demand Shocks
So far, we have shown the separate effects of supply and demand shocks on China’s timber market. Next, the combined effects of the superposition of supply and demand shocks will be analyzed. Whether it is the improvement of domestic timber supply capacity or the decline in downstream demand for timber, it is a negative impact on imported timber. Consequently, it is anticipated that the demand for imported timber will decrease. However, the direction of changes in the demand for domestic timber is contingent upon the extent of the increase in supply capacity and the decline in downstream demand. This could be elucidated through numerical simulations. Under the superimposed impact of supply and demand shocks, the demand for domestic small-diameter timber declines by 1.5%, while the demand for domestic large-diameter timber increases by 5%. The total demand for domestic timber increases by 0.4%.
Table 5 presents the specific changes in demand for imported wood. China’s demand for imported coniferous logs from Oceania and Europe decreases by 14.9% and 12.4%, respectively. In China’s demand for imported coniferous sawn timber, the volume of Russian sawn timber decreases by 15.5%, marking the most substantial decline among all sources of imports. This is followed by Europe, where the imports volume has experienced a 9.4% reduction. China’s demand for imported non-coniferous logs has experienced a notable decline, with major import sources, including Oceania, Africa, Russia, and Europe, recording a decrease of 12.6%, 9.8%, 9.8%, and 9.4%, respectively. China’s primary importing sources for non-coniferous sawn timber, including Asia, Russia, North America, and Africa, have experienced a decline of 15.1%, 8%, 7.9%, and 7%, respectively. The following changes have been observed in the imports of each timber product: a 12.6% decrease in the import of coniferous logs, a 13% decrease in the import of coniferous sawn timber, a 10% decrease in the import of non-coniferous logs, and a 11.4% decrease in the import of non-coniferous sawn timber. In terms of log equivalency, the total quantity of imported timber decreases by 12.1%, and when combined with the changes in domestic timber, the total timber demand in the Chinese market decreases by 5%.
4. Discussion
4.1. Mechanism of Supply and Demand Shocks on China’s Wood Market Equilibrium
In this study, a model of China’s timber market is constructed to reflect product heterogeneity, and the impact of the improvement of domestic forest supply capacity and the weakening downstream demand on timber market equilibrium is systematically analyzed. This analysis is conducted against the background of national reserve forest policy and downturn of real estate market. The augmentation of domestic timber production capacity has led to an increase in the supply of domestic timber, concomitantly depressing the price of domestic timber. This has engendered a shift in market demand from imported timber to domestic timber. A comparison of the impact of the increase in the production capacity of small-diameter timber reveals that the increase in the production capacity of domestic large-diameter timber exerts a significant extrusion effect on domestic small-diameter timber, as well as a pronounced substitution effect on imported timber. This underscores the significance of the diameter class as a pivotal factor for market participants in their decision-making process regarding trade-offs between domestic timber and imported timber. In comparison with domestic timber, imported timber exhibits a stronger correlation with downstream demand, and its response to changes in downstream demand is more pronounced.
A primary objective of the national reserve forest policy is to enhance the supply capacity of domestic large-diameter timber and precious timber, optimize the supply structure of domestic timber, and reduce excessive reliance on timber importation. Our simulation analysis demonstrates that the effective implementation of forestry policies within a market economy is inseparable from the role of market mechanisms. According to the principles of consumer theory, a decline in the price of a product exerts a dual influence on consumer behavior, inducing a substitution effect and an income effect, which is also referred to as an expenditure effect. As illustrated in
Figure 4, the policy-induced augmentation of domestic timber production capacity exerts a significant influence on the demand for domestic and imported timber. Assuming that the initial optimum of the market is
A, and the new optimal combination is located at point
C. The enhancement of domestic timber supply capacity will lead to a decrease in the price of domestic timber, which will result in an increase in the real income of the downstream industry. This is evidenced by the outward shift in the initial budget line to the new budget line, and the increased amount of domestic timber that can be procured with the same expenditure. The substitution effect on imported timber is the horizontal distance from
A to
B, which represents the reduction in the demand for imported timber while maintaining the same utility
I1. The increase in the real income of the downstream industry is manifested by the outward movement of the yellow dotted line passing through
B to the blue budget line through
C, and the resulting income effect is the horizontal distance from
B to
C. Although the decline in the price of domestic timber under the substitution effect will inevitably lead to a decline in the demand for imported timber, the demand for imported timber has increased in the context of the income effect. Therefore, the final change in the demand for imported timber is the horizontal distance from
A to
C, which is significantly smaller than the situation where only the substitution effect is considered. And that is one of the reasons why the improvement of domestic timber supply capacity has not caused a significant decline in the demand for imported timber.
Following Evergrande’s official default in 2021, China’s real estate market has undergone a period of profound adjustment, with repercussions that extend from the corporate debt crisis to a nationwide downturn in the sector and a waning of market confidence [
26]. The development of the timber market is profoundly influenced by the trends in the housing sector from the demand side. Nevertheless, the national reserve forest policy will optimize the supply structure of China’s domestic timber. Consequently, it will serve as an excellent embodiment of opportunities in the face of negative demand shocks.
4.2. Why Product Heterogeneity Matters in Analyzing China’s Wood Market
Based on the Law of One Price (LOP), Spatial Price Equilibrium Model (SPE) becomes the standard tool to numerically study the supply and demand of commodity markets. This modeling framework operates under the assumption that, in the absence of trade costs (e.g., transportation expenses, tariffs) among regions, the price of a commodity should remain uniform across all regions [
27]. The utilization of SPE facilitates the investigation of important timber market issues, including the U.S.–Canada softwood timber dispute, Russia’s log export tax, and New Zealand’s log supply capacity constraints [
28,
29,
30]. However, a fundamental supposition inherent to spatial price equilibrium models is the homogeneity of products. This implies that there is no difference between products produced and consumed in different regions, thereby products from different origins can be completely substituted [
31,
32]. This is a significant rationale behind the predominance of SPE models’ restriction of the product to coniferous wood [
33]. Despite the specificity of the product labels for coniferous wood, this degree of segmentation still does not guarantee that the products sourced from different regions are perfect substitutes. A further issue pertains to the process of model calibration, which frequently fails to guarantee that the observed trade flows will be actualized on the basis of pertinent information such as transportation costs and tariffs. Consequently, it is imperative to calculate the shadow price of trade flows using the positive mathematical programming (PMP) method and subsequently adjust trade costs accordingly [
34,
35]. However, when the assumption of homogeneous products is invalidated, LOP is not supported, and the adjusted trade cost based on the PMP is merely a numerical result rather than an economic fact.
If we use the SPE model to analyze the impact of China’s national reserve forest policy, we can find that the augmentation of domestic timber production nearly equates to the diminution of imported timber. The domestic timber exhibits a complete crowding out effect on imported timber, which stands in stark contrast to the prevailing rigid demand for imported timber within China’s timber market. It is possible to incorporate multiple products into the SPE and establish the aggregated social welfare objective function and associated constraints for an optimization problem. However, the model still necessitates homogeneity for each product. This may result in a scenario where the increase in the supply of European logs in the Chinese market is equivalent to the decrease in New Zealand logs, and the increase in the supply of Russian sawn timber is equivalent to the decrease in Canadian sawn timber. The SPE model typically necessitates substantial data requirements, precluding the direct utilization of the original bilateral trade flows from FAOSTAT or UN Comtrade for the construction of the trade matrix. A prerequisite for this analysis is the transformation of original trade flows into net imports or net exports, followed by the adjustment of transportation costs according to the shadow price. Conversely, CWMM does not necessitate substantial alterations to the input data. China is a major importer of timber, sourcing this material from over 100 countries worldwide. However, when assessing the supply and demand dynamics of China’s timber market from a homogeneous perspective, the inherent differences and diversity of this market are overlooked. The partial equilibrium model developed in this study possesses the capacity to differentiate the characteristics of various domestic timber species. Additionally, it is capable of accentuating the heterogeneity of imported timber, a phenomenon attributable to the interweaving of multiple dimensions, including timber species and sources. This model offers a valuable framework for investigating the impact of macroeconomic environment changes, adjustments in timber industry policy, and fluctuations in timber trade costs on China’s timber market.
4.3. Limitations
It is imperative to acknowledge that, despite the fact that the import module of CWMM encompasses a substantial array of import sources, it does not constitute a spatial model. Rather, it is a partial equilibrium model that integrates diverse categories of timber products into a unified market. Additionally, the CWMM model is static and does not incorporate the temporal dynamics of timber supply and demand. A recursive dynamic version of the model would be a promising subject for future research. For the sensitivity analysis, we have doubled or halved the behavioral parameters, including the supply elasticity, the demand elasticity, and the substitution elasticity [
36]. However, the results presented in
Appendix D exhibit minimal deviations from the benchmark results, thereby suggesting that the model structure remains stable under these conditions.
Although CWMM reflects the heterogeneity of products to a large extent, the current classification method can still be further refined. For instance, Douglas fir (Pseudotsuga menziesii) and western hemlock (Tsuga heterophylla) could be distinguished from the coniferous logs sourced from North America. Despite the fact that this splitting increases the variability of imported timber, it also makes the model structure more intricate. The applicability of this extension is not significantly improved from the perspective of academic research.
China is one of the hubs of global value chains, and its timber product supply chain is intricate, both in terms of meeting domestic demand and reaching the international markets. The final destination of domestic and imported timber embedded in manufactured products is often difficult to trace. Consequently, the model does not explicitly delineate the ultimate destination of the timber, characterizing it instead as “downstream demand.” And it is incapable of differentiating between domestic and foreign demand shocks. For instance, the European Union, a prominent global trade partner of China, has introduced a zero-deforestation law [
37]. This dynamic is poised to exert an influence on external demand for Chinese timber products. However, it is imperative to note that this impact is distinct from the fluctuations witnessed in China’s domestic real estate market. At present, our model lacks the capacity to differentiate between the impact of domestic and external demand shocks. Furthermore, the CWMM model focuses on China, and the economic effect of supply and demand shocks is mainly reflected in China’s timber market dynamics. It cannot analyze the spillover effects on the global timber market equilibrium, which is a disadvantage compared with the SPE model. Future research endeavors should combine the local characteristics of CWMM with the global perspective of SPE, and incorporate the heterogeneity of the local market into a global model.
5. Conclusions
In consideration of the heterogeneity and diversity inherent in the Chinese timber market, a partial equilibrium model has been constructed. This model exhibits structural stability and flexibility, allowing for the integration and combination of imported sources, imported timber products, and additional domestic timber categories without altering its fundamental structure. It facilitates the examination of diverse issues concerning China’s wood market. As an application, this paper simulates the structural changes in China’s timber market brought about by the increase in the supply capacity of domestic timber and the decline in the downstream demand. The results indicate that enhancing the supply capacity of domestic large-diameter timber in the face of negative demand shocks presents a favorable opportunity for China to promote timber import substitution.
With the implementation of enhanced forest management practices, China has witnessed a consistent increase in its domestic timber supply, particularly with eucalyptus (Eucalyptus) and poplar (Populus). Concurrently, there has been a decline in the utilization of imported timber for the production of wood-based panels. However, due to the short growth cycle of domestic timber and the prevalence of small- and medium-sized logs, the end uses are quite limited. The imported timber is primarily composed of large-diameter and precious timber, which find extensive application in the construction industry and the production of high-value-added wood furniture and flooring. It has played an important role in the development of China’s infrastructure construction and wood processing industries, effectively addressing the existing deficiencies of domestic timber in terms of quantity and quality. Prior to achieving sufficient domestic timber availability, stability in pricing, and a high level of quality, imported timber will continue to play a significant role in China’s timber demand. However, the international economic and trade order, with globalization at its core, is undergoing an unprecedented test. On the one hand, the localization of production and consumption has increased in strength compared to previous trends. In addition, international trade frictions have increased significantly, which will inevitably affect the stability and sustainability of China’s imported timber supply. Conversely, China’s economic development model has undergone a gradual transition from a focus on high-speed growth to one that emphasizes high-quality development. The paradigm shift in industrial development has also occurred, with the emphasis shifting from external growth to internal maturity. These adjustments and changes in commodity consumption patterns are anticipated to have a significant impact on the timber market. In the face of complex risks and challenges, China’s forest management authority must adhere to long-term strategic plans to optimize the supply structure of domestic timber and ensure a harmonious interaction between domestic market and forests.